ArticlePDF Available

Socially sustainable degrowth as a social–ecological transformation: repoliticizing sustainability

Springer Nature
Sustainability Science
Authors:
SPECIAL FEATURE: EDITORIAL Socially Sustainable Degrowth as a Social-Ecological
Transformation
Socially sustainable degrowth as a social–ecological
transformation: repoliticizing sustainability
Viviana Asara
1,2
Iago Otero
2,3
Federico Demaria
1,2
Esteve Corbera
1,4
Springer Japan 2015
Introduction
In the late 1980s, the sustainable development paradigm
emerged to provide a framework through which economic
growth, social welfare and environmental protection could
be harmonized. However, more than 30 years later, we can
assert that such harmonization has proved elusive. Steffen
et al. (2015) have shown that four out of nine planetary
boundaries have been crossed: climate change, impacts in
biosphere integrity, land-system change and altered bio-
chemical flows are a manifestation that human activities
are driving the Earth into a new state of imbalance.
Meanwhile, wealth concentration and inequality have
increased, particularly during the last 50 years (Piketty
2014). In 2008, the collapse of large financial institutions
was prevented by the public bailout of private banks and,
nowadays, low growth rates are likely to become the norm
in the economic development of mature economies (Sum-
mers 2013; IMF 2015; Teulings and Baldwin 2015). The
three pillars of sustainability (environment, society and
economy) are thus simultaneously threatened by an inter-
twined crisis.
In an attempt to problematize the sustainable develop-
ment paradigm, and its recent reincarnation in the concept
of a ‘‘green economy’’, degrowth emerged as a paradigm
that emphasizes that there is a contradiction between sus-
tainability and economic growth (Kothari et al. 2015; Dale
et al. 2015). It argues that the pathway towards a sustain-
able future is to be found in a democratic and redistributive
downscaling of the biophysical size of the global economy
(Schneider et al. 2010; D’Alisa et al. 2014). In the context
of this desired transformation, it becomes imperative to
explore ways in which sustainability science can explicitly
and effectively address one of the root causes of social and
environmental degradation worldwide, namely, the ideol-
ogy and practice of economic growth. This special feature
aims to do so by stressing the deeply contested and political
nature of the debates around the prospects, pathways and
challenges of a global transformation towards
sustainability.
The ‘growth’ paradigm (Dale 2012; Purdey 2010)is
indeed largely accepted in advanced and developing
countries alike as an unquestioned imperative and natu-
ralized need. It escapes ‘the political’, i.e. the contested
public terrain where different imaginaries of possible
socio-ecological orders compete over the symbolic and
material institutionalization of these visions. In this sense,
the contemporary context of neoliberal capitalism appears
as a post-political space, i.e. a political formation that
forecloses the political, the legitimacy of dissenting voices
and positions (Swyngedouw 2007). As Swyngedouw
(2014:91) argues: ‘‘the public management of things and
people is hegemonically articulated around a naturalization
of the need of economic growth and capitalism as the only
reasonable and possible form of organization of socio-
natural metabolism. This foreclosure of the political in
terms of at least recognizing the legitimacy of dissenting
&Viviana Asara
viviana.asara@gmail.com
1
Institute of Environmental Science and Technology,
Universitat Auto
`noma de Barcelona, Barcelona, Spain
2
Research and Degrowth, Barcelona, Spain
3
Integrative Research Institute on Transformations of Human-
Environment Systems (IRI THESys), Humboldt-Universita
¨t
zu Berlin, Berlin, Germany
4
Department of Economics and Economic History, Universitat
Auto
`noma de Barcelona, Barcelona, Spain
123
Sustain Sci
DOI 10.1007/s11625-015-0321-9
voices and positions constitutes a process of de-politi-
cization. [] (The) wider framework of neoliberal growth
is in itself not contestable.’
Counter-hegemonic discourses and praxis are needed to
re-politicize the debate about what kind of society (and
sustainability) we want to live in and to open up alternative
avenues (Mouffe 2005). Degrowth aims to repoliticize the
debate on the relationships between sustainability, econ-
omy and society (Kallis et al. 2014) and to advance a new
vision of social–ecological transformations. It contributes
to building a counter-hegemonic narrative, in alliance with
equivalent alternative frameworks emerging from the glo-
bal South such as Buen Vivir from Latin America (Gu-
dynas 2011), ecological Swaraj from India (Kothari 2014)
and Ubuntu from South Africa (Metz 2011).
In what follows, we present first the intellectual origins
of degrowth, to explain how such a paradigm understands
the question of sustainability. Special attention is paid to
the social and ecological limits to growth and to the social–
ecological transformation envisioned by the degrowth
paradigm. Next, we discuss the contents of the papers
included in this Special Feature. Finally, we conclude by
stressing the contribution of degrowth to sustainability
science and practice, and argue for a re-politicization of the
science and practice of sustainability.
Degrowth
Origins and foundational scientific premises
The concept de´croissance (degrowth) was first coined by
Andre
´Gorz in a debate organized by Le Nouvel Obser-
vateur in Paris in 1972, as a follow-up of the Limits to
Growth report (Meadows et al. 1972; Demaria et al. 2013).
Participants included philosophers Herbert Marcuse and
Edgard Morin, the ecologist Edward Goldsmith and the
then President of the European Commission Sicco Man-
sholt. Gorz employed the term to question the compati-
bility of the capitalist system with the ‘‘degrowth of
material production’’,
1
and he underscored the importance
of reducing consumption and promoting values like fru-
gality, autonomy and conviviality.
Gorz’s commentary exemplifies the encounter of the
ecologist and culturalist critiques of economics (Latouche
2011,2013; Bonaiuti 2013; Martinez-Alier et al. 2010).
The former draws centrally on Nicholas Georgescu-Roe-
gen’s bio-economics, which relies on ecological science to
challenge orthodox economics (Sorman and Giampietro
2013). The culturalist critique is inspired by ‘post-devel-
opment’ theorists and political ecologists, who critiqued
the widespread adoption of particular technologies and
consumption and production models from the global North
worldwide (Illich 1973,1978; Gorz 1975,1991,2009;
Latouche, 2009,2011). For Bonaiuti (2008,2013), these
two lines of critical thought share similar pre-analytical
premises and they antagonize with the sustainable devel-
opment paradigm, which does not question the anthropo-
logical, political, cultural and institutional premises of
growth economics. Indeed, Georgescu-Roegen’s bio-eco-
nomics unravelled the entropic nature of the economic
process. While economic science was built on the mecha-
nistic paradigm (Newton–Laplace) and on the model of
classic science, the thermodynamic revolution, Georgescu-
Roegen (1971) argued, should urge us to consider the
fundamental element of irreversible time and the increase
of entropy in a closed system. Georgescu-Roegen (1971,
2009) emphasizes the ecological limits to growth (Grine-
vald 2008) and his works, alongside Boulding’s (1966)
thesis on biophysical limitations of economic activity and
Kapp’s (1961,1970) reframing of environmental exter-
nalities as an inherent aspect of modern consumption and
production, are considered the foundations of ecological
economics.
Building on ecological economics research, degrowth
challenges the possibility that economic growth can be
decoupled from material and energy flows (Jackson 2009;
Dietz and O’Neill 2013). It is argued that even if there is
some evidence for relative decoupling—e.g. world GDP
has risen faster than carbon dioxide emissions over the last
18 years (Jackson 2009)—absolute decoupling, i.e. abso-
lute decline in resource use over time while the economy
grows, is not occurring (Ayres et al. 2004; Krausmann et al.
2009; Galeotti et al. 2006; Stern 2004; Soumyananda
2004). Degrowth thus challenges the possibility that some
ideas, such as the dematerialization of the world’s economy
(UNEP 2011), ecological modernization, green growth
(Martinez-Alier 2014; Latouche 2009;Go
´mez-Baggethun
and Naredo 2015, this feature) and the circular economy
(Haas et al. 2015) fulfil their promises. Additionally,
degrowth calls attention to the fact that eco-efficiency gains
are often re-invested in further consumption or economic
activities that counterbalance the improvements achieved
(Jevons’ Paradox or rebound effect, Polimeni et al. 2007).
The interest for critical engagements with economic
growth and development paradigms faded during the last two
decades of the twentieth century, but revived with the turn of
the new one (Kallis et al. 2014). A special issue in 2002 was
published in the journal Silence (No. 280), and a colloquium
entitled ‘‘Unmaking development, redoing the world’’ was
held at UNESCO in Paris on that same year (Duverger 2011;
1
‘The global equilibrium, for which no-growth—or even
degrowth—of material production is a necessary condition, is it
compatible with the survival of the (capitalist) system?’ M. Bosquet
(Andre
´Gorz), Nouvel Observateur, Paris, 397, 19th June 1972, p. IV.
Sustain Sci
123
Muraca 2013). With the organization of the first international
colloquium on sustainable degrowth in Lyon in 2003, which
gathered hundreds of participants from France, Switzerland
and Italy, degrowth established itself as an international
movement (D’Alisa et al. 2014). Degrowth became ‘both a
banner associated with social and environmental movements
and an emergent concept in academic and intellectual circles,
[which] are interdependent and affect each other’’ (Martinez-
Alier et al. 2010:1742). At least five international academic
conferences with civil society participation were subsequently
held in Paris (2008), Barcelona (2010), Venice and Montreal
(2012) and Leipzig (2014) with increasing number of par-
ticipants (in Leipzig there were about 3000 participants) and
the next one will be organized in Budapest in 2016. Once a
marginal perspective, degrowth is starting to being referred to
also in the mainstream debate. For instance, recently Paul
Krugman (2014) in The New York Times noticed that ‘‘anti-
growth environmentalism is a marginal position even on the
Left, but it’s widespread enough to call out nonetheless’’.
Even Pope Francis (2015), in his Encyclical Laudato Si’,
argues that ‘‘the time has come to accept degrowth in some
parts of the world, in order to provide resources for other
places to experience healthy growth’’.
2
Defining principles
As noted above, degrowth was originally placed at the junc-
tion of ecological and cultural critiques to economic growth
and development, but has recently evolved to encompass also
concerns on democracy, justice, meaning of life and well-
being (Flipo 2007; Demaria et al. 2013). Degrowth has thus
given birth to an incipient social movement and activist-led
science and it has been depicted as ‘‘a performative fiction
indicating the necessity of a rupture with the growth society’
(Latouche 2013:7). Some scholars and activists have tried to
define degrowth more concretely as a downscaling move-
ment. Schneider et al. (2010:512) define it as ‘‘an equitable
downscaling of production and consumption that increases
human well-being and enhances ecological conditions at the
local and global level, in the short and long term’’.
The adjective ‘socially sustainable’ has often accompa-
nied the term to stress that the normative content of degrowth
is overall related to the improvement of social well-being and
equity, and to distinguish it from ‘unsustainable degrowth’,
that is, from economic recessions that deteriorate social
conditions (Schneider et al. 2010). The objective of degrowth
is not to reduce GDP, an arbitrary indicator (Fioramonti
2013;Philipsen2015), but to increase social justice and
ecological sustainability. Therefore, degrowth should not be
understood in its literal meaning (i.e. negative growth of
GDP) or just as shrinking of material throughput (Sekulova
et al. 2013;Kallisetal.2014). The mere shrinking of con-
sumption and production levels by themselves would be even
more deleterious than current growth systems. Growth
economies do not know how to degrow: there is nothing
worse than a growth society that does not grow (Latouche
2008:18; Kallis et al. 2012). Degrowth is a provocative slo-
gan to challenge, and escape, the ideology of growth
(Hamilton 2004). It is a social project or, borrowing from
Bloch, a ‘concrete utopia’ (Muraca 2014; Latouche 2009)
that envisions a deep social–ecological transformation.
Emphasis is not put on ‘less’, but on ‘different’: ‘‘In a
degrowth society, everything will be different: different
activities, different forms and uses of energy, different rela-
tions, different gender roles, different allocations of time
between paid and non-paid work and different relations with
the non-human world’’ (Kallis et al. 2014:4).
Ecological and social limits to growth
From a degrowth perspective, the current social–eco-
logical–economic crisis is the result of systemic limits to
growth and the obsession to promote growth at all costs,
including the creation of debt to fuel growth or austerity
policies to restore stability (Kallis et al. 2014,2009;
Bonaiuti 2013). These tensions recall O’Connor’s (1998)
second contradiction of capitalism, which highlights that
capitalism systematically undermines the biophysical
conditions on which it depends in the pursuit of capital
accumulation, although there are no automatic connec-
tions between biophysical limits, increases in costs of
capital and the end of capital accumulation (Klitgaard
2013; see also Harvey 2014). However, recognizing the
importance of defining ecological limits in which the
economic activity should be embedded is not sufficient
(Deriu 2008;Muraca2013). On the one hand, it should
be acknowledged that the ecological crisis directly stems
from the ‘imperial mode of living’ of the global North,
which is ‘‘rooted in prevailing political, economic, and
cultural everyday structures’’ (Brand and Wissen
2012:555). Taking this into account, economic growth is
not only environmentally unsustainable, but also unjust,
and degrowth connects with concepts such as the
recognition and reparation of ecological debt, post-ex-
tractivism and Buen Vivir (Martinez-Alier 2012;
Demaria et al. 2013). On the other hand, degrowth
advocates agree that ecology by itself cannot pinpoint
the way or the normative ground on how to reach the
desired social-ecological transformation (Muraca 2013;
Deriu 2008). Degrowth aims to open up the democratic
discussion of selective downscaling of man-made capital
and of the institutions needed for such a ‘prosperous way
down’ (Odum and Odum 2001). An important lesson
2
Our translation from the original text in Spanish.
Sustain Sci
123
taken from early political ecologists is that degrowth is
about a (collective and individual) democratic movement
of establishing limits within which human well-being
and creativity can flourish (Muraca 2013; Kallis et al.
2014; Asara et al. 2013). The literature on autonomy
emphasizes collective self-limitations, rather than (ex-
ternal) limits to growth, invoked not to protect nature or
avoid disaster, but because simplicity, conviviality and
frugality is how good life is conceived. Limits to growth
therefore become ‘‘a social choice, not []anexternal
imperative for environmental or other reasons’’ (Sch-
neider et al. 2010:513).
Additionally, degrowth scholars are increasingly
engaging with the intersection between income and well-
being. The so-called Easterlin paradox refers to the lack
of positive correlation over time between reported sub-
jective well-being and income growth, at least for coun-
tries with sufficient means to meet basic needs (Easterlin
1974; Helliwell et al. 2012). What Max-Neef (1995)has
called the ‘threshold hypothesis’ holds that, after a certain
threshold point, economic growth does not bring about
improvements in people’s quality of life. Other studies
have shown that income equality is conducive to better
individual and collective health and happiness (Jackson
2009; Chancel et al. 2013; Pickett and Wilkinson 2009).
Such emerging evidence, however, has not yet under-
mined the extended mantra that economic growth can be
‘a magic wand to achieve all sorts of goals’’ (Dale 2012):
from soothing class tension and reducing poverty to
reducing the gap between ‘developed’ and ‘developing
countries’, to fostering social capital and steering envi-
ronmental sustainability through ‘green growth’, among
others.
It can be argued then that such ideological fix on eco-
nomic growth stems from the naturalization of the pre-
vailing social order in which the interests of capital are
identified with the common good (Dale 2012; Purdey
2010). For example, it has been traditionally assumed that
the benefits of economic growth (spurred by financial
benefits accumulated by business and investors) trickle
down to the poorest groups of society through a variety of
means, such as employment and redistribution programs.
More recently, the calls for and rhetoric of ‘green growth’
suggest that fostering resource efficiency measures, pro-
moting more sustainable primary energy sources and
mobilizing new sources of private funding for resource
conservation will allow for continuous capital accumula-
tion whilst generating social benefits, such as new
employment opportunities. Economic growth thinking rests
thus upon the paradoxical combination of promised abun-
dance and structural scarcity, in which desires are trans-
formed into needs and needs are reduced to solvent demand
(Rist 1996).
A radical social–ecological transformation: actors,
strategies and policies
Degrowth implies a critique of ‘commodification’ or
‘economization’, that is the increasing ‘‘conversion of
social products and socio-ecological services and relations
into commodities with a monetary value’’ (Kallis et al.
2014:4). Commodification is a fundamental tool for mak-
ing economic growth possible (Altvater 2012; Victor
2014). Escaping the ‘tyranny’ of economic growth means
opposing economism as a thinking and behavioural para-
digm and root ourselves in the terrain of the political
(Fournier 2008). In doing so, we need to be attentive to
micro- and macro-level transformations (Sekulova et al.
2013) and to challenge the imaginaries of instrumental
rationality, consumerism, utilitarianism and productivism
(Muraca 2013). In this regard, Kallis et al. (2014) have
provided a review of practices, institutions and actors that
might facilitate a degrowth transformation ‘‘to convivial
societies who live simply, in common and with less’’ (ibid:
11). Non-capitalist grassroot economic practices including
eco-communities, cooperatives, ethical banks, urban gar-
dens, time banks and community currencies contribute to
secure the basic needs of people relying on new processes
of commoning with low material throughput. New welfare
institutions such as an unconditional basic income, taxation
on resources or resource caps, redistribution policies, job
guarantee, socialization of care, public control over the
creation of money, reduction of working hours and work
sharing can secure a basic level of subsistence for all and
liberate time from paid work, thus expanding voluntary and
convivial activity and autonomy (Kallis et al. 2012,2014).
Care, education, health or environmental restoration can be
the basis of a new, labour-intensive economy, prosperous
without growth (see Jackson 2009). The role of the state is
hence deemed crucial to facilitate the degrowth transfor-
mation through the implementation of ‘non-reformist
reforms’.
3
Socially sustainable degrowth should thus be
conceived as a consequence of multiple strategies, ranging
from oppositional activism to building alternative institu-
tions to reforming some existing institutions, simultane-
ously implemented across multiple scales, from the local to
the global (Demaria et al. 2013). In terms of actors, the
evidence highlighted above suggests that activists, practi-
tioners and researchers have played a key role in promoting
degrowth, alongside policy makers, politicians, trade
unionists and other lay citizens. What political subjects will
be important in the future remains an open question.
3
Giorgos Kallis and the Collective Research and Degrowth (2014)
presented ten degrowth policy proposals in a press article entitled
‘Yes, we can prosper without growth’’ that was published by several
mainstream European newspapers (see http://www.degrowth.org/yes-
we-can-prosper-without-growth).
Sustain Sci
123
There is a growing consensus among degrowth actors
that degrowth involves a multi-scalar transformation
beyond capitalism. In contrast to a marginal adjustment of
economic and social systems resulting from multiple and
overlapping crisis, the concept of transformation indeed
‘conveys something more radical than mere change or
even transition to a new world’’ (Tschakert et al. 2013:346;
Brown et al. 2012). The concept of transformation implies
the need to go beyond pursuing or simply protesting
against business-as-usual to actively constituting new
meanings and practices. Radical diversion from existing
pathways, as Burch and Harris (2014) assert, may only
occur with intentional action in the realms of practice and
policy, which O’Brien (2012) calls ‘deliberate transfor-
mation’, through the imagination of a post-capitalist future.
This differentiates degrowth from previous approaches to
sustainability based on a transitory or reformist pathway.
Therefore, the transformative nature of socially sus-
tainable degrowth breaks with the political and cultural
status quo and opens up spaces for new political and cul-
tural imaginaries. Degrowth is both a critique of the ide-
ology of growth (so-called ‘decolonization of the
imaginary’, see Latouche 2014) and a proposal for an
alternative desired direction. Transition discourses instead
entail the persistence of pre-existing trajectories without
changing the end goals (i.e. economic growth) and do not
question the hegemonic neoliberal mode of governance
(Brown et al. 2012). Incremental changes, the realm of
sustainable development and mainstream sustainability
thinking, may end up resulting in obstacles to sustainability
by increasing investment in the existing system and nar-
rowing down alternatives for change (Rickards and How-
den 2012). Transition approaches fail to fundamentally
rethink social structures, because they do not engage crit-
ically with the root causes of unsustainability.
However, we acknowledge that transformation is a
concept with diverse, fragmented and, at times, contested
meanings manifested at both agency (personal attitudes,
political organization) and structure (institutions, socio-
economic arrangements) levels (Brown et al. 2013).
Transformative approaches go far beyond keeping the main
functions of a given socio-ecological system intact by
adjusting to changing conditions (Brown et al. 2013). They
aim instead to alter the fundamental attributes of a system,
such as the economic mode of production, political insti-
tutions, ideologies, societal norms, everyday life, ecology
(ibid; Brown et al. 2012) and so-called ‘social natures’, i.e.
combined socio-ecological assemblages that are spatially,
temporally as well as socially and materially produced, a
result of power relationships and cultural meanings (Hey-
nen et al. 2006; Swyngedouw and Heynen 2004). Trans-
formations involve non-linear processes, because they deal
with dynamic multidimensional and complex systems and
understand social innovation as a key driving force of such
processes (Brand et al. 2013). They involve multiple scales
and system levels, from the local to the regional, national
and international levels, and functional levels such as the
markets, states and civil society (Brand et al. 2013).
The contributions to this special feature
This special feature brings together six contributions
selected from papers presented at the Third and Fourth
International Conferences on Degrowth for Ecological
Sustainability and Social Equity (Venice 2012, and Leipzig
2014) and an ad hoc call for papers that we launched in
August 2013. While early degrowth scholarly contributions
were generally focused on problem diagnostics, i.e. ‘‘Why
degrowth?’’ (Schneider et al. 2010; Saed 2012; Martinez-
Alier et al. 2010; Cattaneo et al. 2012), more recent debates
have focused on the prognosis, i.e. ‘‘What needs to be done
and how?’’ (D’Alisa et al. 2014; Sekulova et al. 2013;
Kallis et al. 2012; Kosoy 2013). This special feature pro-
vides: first, some light on the discursive weaknesses of the
sustainable development paradigm and on the economic
and ecological implications of a global downscaling of
resource and energy consumption; second, it provides new
evidence on the actual practice of degrowth by analysing
distinct political and social initiatives developed at distinct
administrative and spatial scales, from local to regional and
global levels. Overall, the articles shed light on some of the
opportunities and challenges involved in the transformation
that socially sustainable degrowth entails while contribut-
ing to challenge contemporary economic development
narratives.
Go
´mez-Baggethun and Naredo open the collection of
papers with a critical analysis of the shifting discourses on
the relationship between growth and the environment in
international sustainability policy. The authors review key
policy documents from the publication of the Limits to
Growth report and the celebration of the first Earth Summit
in Stockholm (1972) to the celebration of the last Earth
summit in Rio (2012). They identify three major discursive
shifts in these policy documents over the studied period.
First, whereas in the first years of international sustain-
ability policy in the 1970s, perpetual economic growth was
considered the origin of environmental problems, it is now
fully acknowledged as the solution to them. A key insight
is that the concept of sustainable development, as presented
by the 1987 Brundtland Report, played a key role in the
restoration of growth as a desirable objective from an
environmental and social point of view. Second, the
authors identify a discursive shift from states and public
regulation to private initiatives and market-based instru-
ments as preferred means for addressing global ecological
Sustain Sci
123
problems. Third, the politically committed tone of the first
declarations in the 1970s—linking sustainability to equal-
ity, autonomy and cooperation, among other societal
goals—gave way to the current technocratic approach
where sustainability is presented as an apolitical problem to
be tackled through technical fixes. The authors conclude
that from the sustainable development consensus, sustain-
ability principles have been over time re-shaped to fit
dominant economic ideas, including the axiomatic neces-
sity of unconstrained growth. These ideas, they argue, have
to be broken down to move towards a radical turn in
international sustainability policy that effectively tackles
the roots of ecological and social degradation. A critical
question for future research and action concerns whether
and how the degrowth movement can help in this endeavor.
Capella
´n-Pe
´rez et al. address the potential limits of
global economic growth by applying a system dynamics
global model that allows economic, energy and climate
dynamics to be analysed in an integrated way under dif-
ferent socioeconomic alternatives. Their results suggest
that expanding the use of coal as a means to maintain
global economic growth in the future would not only be
unfeasible due to supply limits, but also undesirable
because of the climate impacts that would unfold during
the next decades. Subsequently, they explore the economic
and energy implications of an anticipated democratic col-
lective shift towards a smaller and equitable economy
which does not depend on economic growth. Some
guidelines are derived for such a transformation including:
the prompt application of strong sustainable and transition
energy policies, the decrease of around 10 % in global total
primary energy demand, a radical transformation of the
transportation sector and equal sharing of the total primary
energy supply per capita. In terms of GDP, such a transi-
tion would imply a global convergence to the current world
average level, whereby industrialized countries would
reduce their per capita GDP four times while the Southern
countries would increase it threefold. The transition would
also require that the most energy-intensive countries should
reduce their current per capita energy consumption by
70 % to allow the least energy-intensive ones to increase it
by 30 %.
Gerber’s is the first of three papers providing insights on
new forms of practising degrowth. He offers a preliminary
overview of the main types of local credit systems, ascer-
taining their possible role in the degrowth transformation.
He evaluates classical credit systems and modern credit
alternatives to highlight their relevance for socially sus-
tainable degrowth. He argues that post-growth-friendly
credit arrangements should also consider the use of alter-
native forms of money, because the money we use on a
daily basis has been created by commercial banks through
credit and as such it creates constant pressures towards
growth. He thus proceeds with an evaluation of local credit
systems based on alternative money, from negative interest
credit to social credit and mutual credit. He finds that the
transformation towards a post-growth credit system apt for
degrowth should go through different stages and levels. At
the community level, local mutual credit systems could
integrate the national currency and represent a good start-
ing point for the degrowth transformation. At the national
level, a Douglasian-type social credit scheme (with uni-
versal basic income and ticketing system) combined with a
large-scale socialization of investment credit would cancel
much of the routine needs for credit.
Kunze and Becker discuss the role that small-scale
renewable energy cooperatives can play in a degrowth
social–ecological transformation, thus enriching emerging
debates about economic democracy and cooperativism
within the degrowth literature (Johanisova and Wolf 2012;
Johanisova et al. 2013). The authors define a new concept
that would be able to embody such a challenge through its
embedded normative goals: collective and politically
motivated renewable energy projects (CPE). The political
motivation rests on a participatory and democratic organ-
isational structure combined with collective legal owner-
ship and collective benefit allocation mechanisms. CPEs
also include at least one of the following normative goals:
an overall reduction of energy consumption, the protection
of biodiversity, sustainable agriculture, a transition town
agenda or more social equity and the empowerment of
disadvantaged groups. Starting from an European survey
on renewable energy projects, the study further narrows
down the research scope upon sixteen projects, where in-
depth interviews are carried out, and presents the results of
four emblematic cases from Wales, Italy, Spain and Ger-
many. The cases analysed show that CPE can involve an
upscaling movement, growing beyond the niche in which
they emerged. The authors argue that if CPEs and alter-
natives more generally emerge at multi-scalar levels, they
could embody a transformational potential beyond
capitalism.
Missoni deals with health, an almost neglected topic
within degrowth scholarship (an exception is Borowy
2013). While acknowledging the important role of com-
munity action for local change and individual lifestyle
changes, Missoni argues that these experiences would fail
if not embedded in a global governance system aiming at
correcting socioeconomic determinants of health. The
author argues that trade liberalization and deregulation
processes intensified the commodification and commer-
cialization of vital social determinants of health, affecting
it through a variety of mechanisms, including changes in
lifestyles, environmental degradation, reduced human
security, privatization and commercialization of health
care. Further, global public–private partnerships allowed
Sustain Sci
123
private interest to influence global and national health
policies. In this regard, the author uses two case studies
from the food and tobacco industries to exemplify the need
for public regulation in contrast to corporate practices
inducing unhealthy lifestyles, and he highlights the
importance of transnational social movements in pushing
the prioritization of health and equity goals in policy-
making. The author advocates for a more comprehensive
analysis of the relations between health and degrowth,
which should extend beyond medicine and health-care
systems to focus also on the social determinants of health
and the study of how such determinants might change
during and after the transformation advocated by degrowth.
According to Missoni, health policy in the context of
degrowth should be governed by the principle of ‘doing
better with less’ (Benatar 2013), i.e. focusing on the pro-
motion of healthy lifestyles and choices, the control of
medical consumerism and a more cautious use of techno-
logical resources in health services. Missoni argues that the
World Health Organisation can potentially play an impor-
tant role in promoting these changes in health governance
through, for example, international standards or a new
legally binding global health treaty.
The special feature ends with a review article by
Escobar who situates degrowth and post-development
theory within the larger context of transition discourses. He
presents an overview of transition discourses and initia-
tives. Then he pays attention to the resurgence of post-
development debates in Latin American social movements
through notions such as ‘Buen Vivir’. The author under-
scores that both degrowth and post-development theory
challenge the centrality of development, capitalism, market
and growth in economic and cultural representations; they
share intellectual sources and converge in the link between
ecology and social justice; and they are aimed towards
radical societal transformations. Escobar also argues that
both approaches can learn from each other in a number of
critical issues. For example, degrowth could emulate some
of the post-development epistemic practices in which local
knowledges are central to cross-scale political and eco-
nomic changes, while post-development could create
scholarly networks similar to those of degrowth to gain
greater impact on academic circles. Post-development
scholars’ interest in biocentrism and non-dualist approa-
ches could be a fruitful input to develop in greater depth
the critique to modernity embedded in degrowth thinking,
whereas degrowth’s notion of conviviality could be helpful
to advance a critique to over-consumption in the global
South. Finally, Escobar stresses the importance for transi-
tion discourses to move away from a view of globalization
as the universalization of modernity and adopt instead a
view of globality as the struggle to preserve and foster the
‘pluriverse’.
The articles together make evident that degrowth aims at
re-embedding the economy within local communities and
environments by means of re-localization and self-reliance
through grassroot innovations and alternatives, and at the
same time it is aware that such practices are insufficient for
the transformation required unless major shifts in national
and supra-national political and economic structures also
take place. Additionally, the articles implicitly suggest that
‘the local’ is not contained or mobilized as a form of
‘militant particularism’ (Harvey 1996): radical localizers
do not argue against connections out of the locality per se
(such as in the form of networks), but argue against reifi-
cation of connections as always inevitable and good, thus
emphasizing the ‘materiality’ of scale (North 2005,2010).
Repoliticizing the science and practice
of sustainability
In the opening article of this journal, Komiyama and
Takeuchi (2006) regretted the political biases of the con-
cept of sustainable development, to which sustainability
science is inextricably linked (Kates et al. 2001). Such
biases, they argued, raised concerns about the solidity of its
scientific basis, which remained unclear to many
(Komiyama and Takeuchi 2006). For degrowth, the
weakness of sustainable development as a truly transfor-
mative concept directly stems from its falsely consensual
nature (Hornborg 2009). Degrowth unveils the ideological
role of capitalist growth (Purdey 2010) and opens up the
debate about the relations between economy, society and
sustainability, including their cognitive, material and
political interactions. In other words, degrowth helps to
further emphasize the existing contradictions between
growth, the environment and social well-being, and envi-
sions a potential multi-scalar transformation pathway
towards smaller and localized economies that redistribute
wealth, supported by state and supra-national policies. In
doing so, degrowth aspires to repoliticize the debates on
the science and practice of sustainability.
It has been suggested that sustainability scientists have
embraced a ‘thin sustainability’ concept—‘‘meeting
human needs, both now and in the future, without
degrading the planet’s life support systems’’ (Miller
2013:283). Such a definition encourages widespread
agreement, but limits the degree to which deeper discus-
sions over a ‘thick sustainability’ and what it might mean
to different people in different contexts take place (Miller
2013). By providing a thicker meaning of sustainability,
degrowth re-politicizes the debate and asks the following
question: If we are to guarantee a sustainable and just
future for present and future generations, why should our
economies grow?
Sustain Sci
123
Almost 15 years after sustainability science was coined
as a new scientific endeavour (Kates et al. 2001), the
problems it aims to address have not diminished but
exacerbated. The mismatch between a growing scientific
field and effective and sustainable social–ecological
change can be explained by different factors, including
insufficient scientific engagement with stakeholders,
anachronistic academic institutions and incentives, lack of
meta-studies making transdisciplinary sustainability
research available to scholars and practitioners and, in
general, a missing link between knowledge production and
action (Wiek et al. 2012; van der Leeuw et al. 2012;
Kauffman and Arico 2014; Miller et al. 2014). Accord-
ingly, ways forward have been advanced including funda-
mental reforms in the academy, more comparative studies
making sustainability insights accessible and applicable,
and a new social contract between scientists and society in
which scientists participate in the co-production of
knowledge for action with other stakeholders (Wiek et al.
2012; Kauffman and Arico 2014; Wittmayer and Scha
¨pke
2014). Important as these factors may be, we argue that if
they are not articulated into a broader critique of the fun-
damental underpinnings of our societies, such as that
offered by degrowth and other transformation approaches
(Escobar 2015, this feature), sustainability science is unli-
kely to meaningfully inform the social–ecological trans-
formation required to confront the global environmental
crisis. Uncovering the ideology and practice of economic
growth (connected to capitalism) as the ultimate driver of
unsustainability may help sustainability science to further
flourish and be more influential in re-defining the Earth’s
sustainable future.
Acknowledgments Jonas Ø. Nielsen provided helpful comments to
an earlier draft of the paper. We acknowledge the financial support of
the Spanish government through the project BEGISUD ‘‘Beyond
GDP growth: Investigating the socio-economic conditions for a
Socially Sustainable Degrowth’’ (CSO2011-28990). EC has also been
supported by the Spanish Research, Development and Innovation
Secretariat through a ‘‘Ramo
´n y Cajal’’ research fellowship (RYC-
2010-07183).
References
Altvater E (2012) Crecimiento econo
´mico y acumulacio
´n de capital
despue
´s de Fukushima. Ens FEE 33(1):7–32
Asara V, Profumi E, Kallis G (2013) Degrowth, democracy and
autonomy. Environ Values 22:217–239
Ayres RU, Ayres LW, Warr B (2004) Is the US economy
dematerializing? Main indicators and drivers. In: van den Bergh
JCJM, Janssen MA (eds) Economics of industrial ecology.
Materials, structural change, and spatial scales. MIT Press,
Cambridge, pp 57–93
Benatar SR (2013) Global health and justice: re-examining our
values. Bioethics 27(6):297–304
Bonaiuti M (2008) Introduzione. In: Bonaiuti M (ed) Obiettivo
decrescita. Editrice Missionaria Italiana, Bologna
Bonaiuti M (2013) La grande transizione. Dal declino alla societa
´
della decrescita. Bollati Boringhieri, Torino
Borowy I (2013) Degrowth and public health in Cuba: lessons from
the past? J Clean Prod 38(C):17–26
Boulding KE (1966) The economics of the coming spaceship earth.
In: Jarrett H (ed) Environmental quality in a growing economy:
essays from the sixth RFF forum. John Hopkins University Press,
Baltimore
Brand U, Wissen M (2012) Global environmental politics and the
imperial mode of living: articulations of state–capital relations in
the multiple crisis. Globalizations 9(4):547–560
Brand U, Brunnengra
¨ber A, Omann I, Schneidewind U, Andresen S,
Driessen P, Haberl H, Hausknost D, Helgenberger S, Hollaender
K, Læssøe J, Oberthu
¨r S (2013) Debating transformation in
multiple crises. In: World Social Science Report 2013: Changing
Global Environments. ISSC, UNESCO, Paris
Brown G, Kraftl P, Pickerill J, Upton C (2012) Holding the future
together: towards a theorisation of the spaces and times of
transition. Environ Plan A 44:1607–1623
Brown K, O’Neill S, Fabricius C (2013) Social science understand-
ings of transformations. In: World social science report 2013:
changing global environments. ISSC, UNESCO, Paris,
pp 100–106
Burch Sarah L, Harris Sara E (2014) Understanding climate change:
science, policy, and practice. University of Toronto Press,
Toronto
Cattaneo C, D’Alisa G, Kallis G, Zografos C (2012) Degrowth futures
and democracy. Futures 44(6):515–523. doi:10.1016/j.futures.
2012.03.012
Chancel L, Demailly D, Waisman H, Guivarch C (2013) A post-
growth society for the 21st century. In: Does prosperity have to
wait for the return of economic growth? Studies no 08/13, Iddri,
Paris, France
Dale G (2012) The growth paradigm: a critique. Int Soc 134
Dale G, Mathai MV, Puppim de Oliveira JA (2015) Green growth:
ideology, political economy and the alternatives. Zed Books,
London
D’Alisa G, Demaria F, Kallis G (eds) (2014) Degrowth. A vocabulary
for a new era. Routledge. Taylor and Francis, New York
Demaria F, Schneider F, Sekulova F, Martinez-Alier J (2013) What is
degrowth? From an activist slogan to a social movement.
Environ Values 22(2):191–215
Deriu M (2008) Una rivoluzione dell’immaginario. In: Bonaiuti M
(ed) Obiettivo decrescita. Editrice Missionaria Italiana, Bologna
Dietz R, O’Neill D (2013) Enough is enough: building a sustainable
economy in a world of finite resources. Routledge, New York
Duverger T (2011) La de
´croissance, une ide
´e pour de
´main : une
alternative au capitalisme : synthe
`se des mouvements. Sang de la
terre, Paris
Easterlin RA (1974) Does Economic Growth Improve the Human
Lot? In: David PA, Readers MW (eds) Nations and households
in economic growth: essays in honour of moses abramovitz.
Academic Press, New York
Escobar A (2015) Degrowth, postdevelopment, and transitions: a
preliminary conversation. Sustain Sci. doi:10.1007/s11625-015-
0297-5
Fioramonti L (2013) Gross domestic problem: the politics behind the
world’s most powerfull number. Zed Books, London
Flipo F (2007) Voyage dans la galaxie de
´croissante. Mouvements
50(2):143–151
Fournier V (2008) Escaping from the economy: the politics of
degrowth. Int J Soc Soc Policy 28(11/12):528–545. doi:10.1108/
01443330810915233
Sustain Sci
123
Galeotti M, Lanza A, Pauli F (2006) Reassessing the environmental
Kuznets curve for CO
2
emissions: a robustness exercise. Ecol
Econ 57(1):152–163
Georgescu-Roegen N (1971) The entropy law and the economic
process. Harvard University Press, Cambridge
Georgescu-Roegen N (2009) Bioeconomia: verso un’altra economia
ecologicamente e socialmente sostenibile. Bollati Boringhieri,
Torino
Go
´mez-Baggethun E, Naredo JM (2015) In search of lost time: the
rise and fall of limits to growth in international sustainability
policy. Sustainab Sci. doi:10.1007/s11625-015-0308-6
Gorz A (1975) [1978].
_
Ecologie et politique. E
´ditions du Seuil, Paris
Gorz A (1991) Capitalisme, socialism, e
´cologie. E
´ditions Galile
´e,
Paris
Gorz A (2009) Ecologica. Jaca Books, Milano
Grinevald J (2008) Georgescu-Roegen, bioeconomia e biosfera. In:
Bonaiuti M (ed) Obiettivo decrescita. Editrice Missionaria
Italiana, Bologna
Gudynas E (2011) Buen vivir: today’s tomorrow. Development
54(4):441–447
Haas W, Krausmann F, Wiedenhofer D, Heinz M (2015) How
circular is the global economy?: an assessment of material flows,
waste production, and recycling in the European union and the
world in 2005. J Ind Ecol. doi:10.1111/jiec.12244
Hamilton C (2004) The growth fetishism. Pluto Press, London
Harvey D (1996) Justice, nature and the geography of difference.
Blackwell, Oxford
Harvey D (2014) Seventeen contradictions and the end of capitalism.
Oxford University Press, Oxford
Helliwell J, Layard R, Sachs J (2012) World happiness report. Earth
Institute, Columbia University
Heynen N, Kaika M, Swyngedouw E (2006) In the nature of cities.
Urban political ecology and the politics of urban metabolism.
Routledge, London
Hornborg A (2009) Zero-sum world. Int J Comp Sociol
50(3–4):237–262
Illich I (1973) Tools for conviviality. Fontana/Collins, Glasgow
Illich I (1978) Towards a history of needs. Panthe
´on, New York
IMF (International Monetary Fund) (2015) Where are we headed?
Perspectives on potential output, Ch. 3. In: World economic
outlook. Uneven growth: short- and long- term factors. IMF,
Washington DC, pp 69–110
Jackson T (2009) Prosperity without growth. Earthscan, London
JohanisovaN, Wolf S (2012) Economic democracy: a path for the future?
Futures 44(6):562–570. doi:10.1016/j.futures.2012.03.017
Johanisova N, Crabtree T, Fran
ˇkova
´E (2013) Social enterprises and
non-market capitals: a path to degrowth? J Clean Prod 38:7–16.
doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2012.01.004
Kallis G, Martinez-Alier J, Norgaard RB (2009) Paper assets, real
debts: an ecological-economic exploration of the global eco-
nomic crisis. Crit Perspect Int Bus 5(1/2):14–25. doi:10.1108/
17422040910938659
Kallis G, Kerschner C, Martinez-Alier J (2012) The economics of
degrowth. Ecol Econ 84:172–180. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2012.
08.017
Kallis G, Demaria F, D’Alisa G (2014) Introduction: degrowth. In:
D’Alisa G, Demaria F, Kallis G (eds) Degrowth: A vocabulary
for a new era. Routledge, London
Kapp KW (1961) Toward a science of man in society: a positive
approach to the integration of social knowledge. Martinus
Nijhoff, The Hague
Kapp KW (1970) Environmental disruptions and social costs: a
challenge to economists. Kyklos 23:833–847
Kates RW, Clark WC, Corell R et al (2001) Sustainability science.
Science 292(5517):641–642
Kauffman J, Arico S (2014) New directions in sustainability science:
promoting integration and cooperation. Sustain Sci 9:413–418
Klitgaard K (2013) Heterodox political economy and the degrowth
perspective. Sustainability 5(1):276–297. doi:10.3390/
su5010276
Komiyama H, Takeuchi K (2006) Sustainability science: building a
new discipline. Sustain Sci 1:1–6
Kosoy N (ed) (2013) Degrowth: the economic alternative for the
anthropocene, special issue. Sustainability 5
Kothari A (2014) Radical ecological democracy: a path forward for
India and beyond. Great transition. http://www.greattransition.
org/publication/radical-ecological-democracy-a-path-forward-for-
india-and-beyond. Accessed 29 June 2015
Kothari A, Demaria F, Acosta A (2015) Buen vivir, degrowth and
ecological swaraj: alternatives to development and the green
economy. Development (forthcoming)
Krausmann F, Gingrich S, Eisenmenger N, Erb KH, Haberl H,
Fischer-Kowalski M (2009) Growth in global materials use,
GDP and population during the 20
th
century. Ecol Econ
68(10):2696–2705
Krugman P (2014) Errors and emissions. Could fighting global
warming be cheap and free? The New York Times, 18 Sept.
http://www.nytimes.com/2014/09/19/opinion/paul-krugman-
could-fighting-global-warming-be-cheap-and-free.html?_r=1.
Accessed 29 June 2015
Latouche S (2008) Breve trattato sulla decrescita serena. Bollati
Boringhieri Editore, Torino
Latouche S (2009) Farewell to growth. Polity Press, Cambridge
Latouche S (2011) Come si esce dalla societa
`dei consumi. Corsi e
percorsi della decrescita. Bollati Boringhieri, Torino
Latouche S (2013) Prefazione. In: Bonaiuti M (ed) La grande
transizione: Dal declino alla societa
`della decrescita. Bollati
Boringhieri, Torino
Latouche S (2014) Imaginary, decolonization of. In: D’Alisa G,
Demaria F, Kallis G (eds) Degrowth: a vocabulary for a new era.
Routledge, London
Martinez-Alier J (2012) Environmental justice and economic
degrowth. An alliance between two movements. Capital Nat
Social 23(1):51–73
Martinez-Alier J (2014) Environmentalism, currents of. In: D’Alisa
G, Demaria F, Kallis G (eds) Degrowth: a vocabulary for a new
era. Routledge, London
Martinez-Alier J, Pascual U, Vivien F, Zaccai E (2010) Sustainable
de-growth: mapping the context, criticisms and future prospects
of an emergent paradigm. Ecol Econ 69:1741–1747. doi:10.
1016/j.ecolecon.2010.04.017
Meadows DH, Meadows DL, Randers J (1972) Limits to growth.
Universe books, New York
Metz T (2011) Ubuntu as a moral theory and human rights in South
Africa. Afr Hum Rights Law J 11(2):532–559
Miller TR (2013) Constructing sustainability science: emerging
perspectives and research trajectories. Sustain Sci 8:279–293
Miller TR, Wiek A, Sarewitz D et al (2014) The future of
sustainability science: a solutions-oriented research agenda.
Sustain Sci 9:239–246
Mouffe C (2005) On the political. Routledge, London
Muraca B (2013) De
´croissance: a project for a radical transformation
of society. Environ Values 22(2):147–169. doi:10.3197/
096327113X13581561725112
Muraca B (2014) Between doom and utopia: Degrowth as a way out
of the crisis? In: Speech given at the fourth international
conference on degrowth for ecological sustainability and social
equity, 2–6 September 2014
Neef M (1995) Economic growth and quality of life: a threshold
hypothesis. Ecol Econ 15(2):115–118
Sustain Sci
123
North P (2005) Scaling alternative economic practices? Some lessons
from alternative currencies. Trans Inst Br Geogr 30:221–233
North P (2010) Eco-localization as a progressive response to peak oil
and climate change—a sympathetic critique. Geoforum
41:585–594
O’Brien Karen (2012) Global environmental change II: from
adaptation to deliberate transformation. Prog Hum Geogr
36(5):667–676
O’Connor J (1998) Natural causes: essays in ecological marxism. The
Guilford Press, New York
Odum HT, Odum EC (2001) [2008] A prosperous way down.
University Press of Colorado, Boulder
Philipsen D (2015) The little big number: how GDP came to rule the
world and what to do about it. Princeton University Press,
Princeton
Pickett K, Wilkinson R (2009) The spirit level. Why equality is better
for everyone. Penguin Books, London
Piketty T (2014) Capital in the twenty-first century. Belknap Press,
Cambridge
Polimeni J, Mayumi K, Giampietro M, Alcott B (2007) The jevons
paradox and the myth of resource efficiency improvements.
Earthscan, New York
Pope Francis (2015) Encyclical letter laudato si’. On care for our
common home. http://w2.vatican.va/content/francesco/en/ency
clicals/documents/papa-francesco_20150524_enciclica-laudato-
si.html. Accessed 29 June 2015
Purdey SJ (2010) Economic growth, the environment and interna-
tional relations: the growth paradigm. Routledge, New York
Rickards Lauren, Howden Mark S (2012) Transformational adapta-
tion: agriculture and climate change. Crop Pasture Sci
63(3):240–250
Rist G (1996) [2008] History of development. From Western origins
to global faith. Zed Books, London
Saed (2012) Introduction to the degrowth symposium. Cap Nat Soc
23(1):26–29. doi:10.1080/10455752.2011.648836
Schneider F, Kallis G, Martinez-Alier J (2010) Crisis or opportunity?
Economic degrowth for social equity and ecological sustainabil-
ity. J Clean Prod 18:511–518
Sekulova F, Kallis G, Rodrı
´guez-Labajos B, Schneider F (2013)
Degrowth: From theory to practice. J Clean Prod 38:1–6. doi:10.
1016/j.jclepro.2012.06.022
Sorman A, Giampietro M (2013) The energetic metabolism of
societies and degrowth paradigm: analyzing biophysical con-
straints and realities. J Clean Prod 38:80–93
Soumyananda D (2004) Environmental Kuznets curve hypotesis: a
survey. Ecol Econ 49(4):431–455
Steffen W, Richardson K, Rockstro
¨m J et al (2015) Planetary
boundaries: guiding human development on a changing planet.
Science 347:6223
Stern D (2004) The rise and fall of the environmental Kuznets curve.
World Dev 32(8):1419–1439
Summers L (2013) Why stagnation might prove to be the new normal.
Financial times. http://www.ft.com/cms/s/2/87cb15ea-5d1a-
11e3-a558-00144feabdc0.html. Accessed 26 May 2015
Swyngedouw E (2007) Impossible/undesirable sustainability and the
post-political condition. In: Krueger JR, Gibbs D (eds) The
sustainable development paradox. Guilford Press, New York,
pp 13–40
Swyngedouw E (2014) Depoliticization (‘the political’). In: D’Alisa
G, Demaria F, Kallis G (eds) Degrowth: a vocabulary for a new
era. Routledge, London
Swyngedouw E, Heynen NC (2004) Urban political ecology, justice
and the politics of scale. Antipode 35(5):898–918. doi:10.1111/j.
1467-8330.2003.00364.x
Teulings C, Baldwin R (2015) Secular stagnation: facts, causes and
cures. CEPR Press, London
Tschakert P, van Oort B, St. Clair AL, LaMadrid A (2013) Inequality
and transformation analyses: a complementary lens for address-
ing vulnerability to climate change. Clim Dev 5(4):340–350
UNEP (United Nations Environmental Program) (2011) Decoupling
natural resource use and environmental impacts from economic
growth. In: Fischer-Kowalski M, Swilling M, von Weizsa
¨cker
EU, Ren Y, Moriguchi Y, Crane W, Krausmann F, Eisenmenger
N, Giljum S, Hennicke P, Romero Lankao P, Siriban Manalang
A (eds) Report of the working group on decoupling to the
international resource panel. UNEP, Nairobi
van der Leeuw S, Wiek A, Harlow J et al (2012) How much time do
we have? Urgency and rhetoric in sustainability science. Sustain
Sci 7:115–120
Victor PA (2014) Growth. In: D’Alisa G, Demaria F, Kallis G (eds)
Degrowth: a vocabulary for a new era. Routledge, London
Wiek A, Farioli F, Fukushi K et al (2012) Sustainability science:
bridging the gap between science and society. Sustain Sci 7:1–4
Wittmayer JM, Scha
¨pke N (2014) Action, research and participation:
roles of researchers in sustainability transitions. Sustain Sci
9:483–496
Sustain Sci
123
... In the recent literature, LESECs have been described, inter alia, as a "journey towards community resilience" (Hopkins, 2011), as "resilience pioneers" (Barry, 2012), as the "imagination of a postcapitalist future" (Asara et al., 2015), as "seeds of a good Anthropocene" (Bennett et al., 2016), as "pioneers of change" (Brand, 2016), as "concrete utopias" (Muraca, 2017), as "grassroots innovation movements" (Smith et al., 2017), and as a "new politics of sustainable materialism" (Schlosberg, 2019). This variety of labels immediately signals, how diverse the portrayals and interpretations of recent LESECs are. ...
... From this perspective, socio-ecological problems are traced back to oppressive, alienating, socially as well as ecologically exploitative societal structures of domination, unjust power relations as well as capitalist imaginaries and modes of living (Brand and Wissen, 2018;Schlosberg, 2019). Fundamental societal change, it is argued, necessitates a thorough rethinking and emancipatory reconfiguration of established humannature relations embedding societies in their material preconditions and multispecies landscapes (Asara et al., 2015;Schlosberg, 2019;Tsing, 2015). While resilience and sufficiency might come into view considering unjust distributions of environmental vulnerabilities, the shift towards more sustainable nature-society relations is mainly expected to be driven by collective claims for autonomy, equality, justice, and emancipation (Bergame et al., 2023;Eversberg and Schmelzer, 2018). ...
Article
Full-text available
In the social sciences literature, experimentation in civil society as in food co-ops, urban gardens, repair cafés, or sharing platforms is widely considered as promising to address mounting socio-ecological problems. But is this confidence justified at a point in time when fundamental change is more urgent than ever? After all, these forms of experimentation have a history that reaches back to the very beginnings of environmentalism. Why should they trigger a comprehensive socio-ecological transformation today, if they have not done so in the past? For academic confidence in transformative change through experimentation to be plausible, at least one of two conditions would have to be fulfilled: either academic accounts plausibly demonstrate that the meanings and functions of present experiments fundamentally differ from those in the past. Or these accounts convincingly show that societal context conditions today are much more favourable for transformative change through experimentation than in the past. To assess whether or to what extent at least one of these conditions is fulfilled, we pursue a comparative analysis of past and present discourses on eco-political experimentation in civil society and a conjunctural analysis of current context conditions for transformative change through experimentation. Our findings suggest that neither the criterion of substantial difference nor that of favourable context conditions is fulfilled. For this reason, the current academic trust in transformative change through experimentation, arguably, remains implausible. Hence, we caution against spreading hope when doubt seems in order, for unwarranted narratives of hope may come with an unintended side-effect: ‘sustaining the unsustainable.'
... Low UER levels mean a sharp conflict between humans and nature, which will not only harm human health, but also cause social poverty and discrimination, thereby exacerbating social instability, having a serious negative impact on social productivity, and hindering economic development. The improvement of the ecological environment can provide strong support for innovation and diversified development in various industries and promote the development of NQP [50]. ...
Article
Full-text available
Enhancing urban ecological resilience (UER) is important in promoting sustainable urban development, and developing new quality productivity (NQP) is an intrinsic requirement to promote industrial change and high-quality development. The coordinated development of UER and NQP can help realize the green transformation and upgrading of various industries. This study considered 30 provinces in China as research objects, quantified their UER from nature, economy, and society, and explored the essential connotation of NQP under the guidance of Marx’s productivity theory. The entropy weight-CRITIC method and TOPSIS model were used to comprehensively measure the development levels of the UER and NQP from 2011 to 2022, and their coupling coordination degree (CCD) of UER and NQP was measured by combining the coupling coordination degree model. Consequently, the Global Moran’s I index and Geographical and Temporal Weighted Regression (GTWR) model were used to explore the effects of different influencing factors on the CCD from the spatiotemporal variability perspective. The results indicated the following: (1) UER and NQP improved during the study period but with large differences between the regions. (2) The overall CCD evolved from a mild imbalance to primary coordination. The average CCD values ranged from low to high in the northeastern, western, central, and eastern regions. (3) The GTWR results showed that the levels of economic development, urbanization rate, and technological innovation contributed positively to the CCD, with the urbanization rate having the strongest positive effect. Foreign investment, environmental regulations, and industrial structure generally negatively inhibit the CCD.
... Según las personas que conocían la antigüedad de las lavadoras, la mayoría eran modelos que aún no habían incorporado tecnologías de ahorro de agua y energía. Al igual que ocurre con otros electrodomésticos, las lavadoras eficientes se hallan fuera del alcance de muchos hogares debido a su coste económico, de ahí que los hogares vulnerables muchas veces no puedan beneficiarse de tecnologías ambientalmente sostenibles (Asara et al., 2015;March & Saurí, 2016) y deban recurrir a cambios de comportamiento con poco o ningún costo económico, en contraste con los hogares más acomodados que sí pueden acceder a electrodomésticos más eficientes, aunque también más caros. Finalmente, y con relación a hábitos de uso de grifería, duchas e inodoros, los datos obtenidos indican una preocupación por el ahorro que es máxima en casos como cierre del grifo durante el cepillado bucal, enjabonado en la ducha o el lavado de platos. ...
Article
Full-text available
Este artículo aborda la problemática de la denominada “pobreza hídrica”, término que en los países desarrollados se utiliza para identificar a personas o hogares con dificultades para pagar el recibo del agua. La pobreza hídrica puede implicar cambios sustanciales en los usos y hábitos de uso de agua en los hogares con una tendencia extrema al ahorro de agua que puede repercutir en el confort y bienestar de los residentes. Además del ahorro extremo, la pobreza hídrica también estimula estrategias en forma de iniciativas para obtener subsidios y otras ayudas. A fin de investigar estas cuestiones y mediante entrevistas que combinan datos cuantitativos y cualitativos, el trabajo caracteriza los usos y hábitos de uso de agua, así como las estrategias para reducir el importe de los recibos en 40 hogares vulnerables del municipio de Manresa (Barcelona), un municipio en estancamiento socioeconómico. Entre las conclusiones más importantes del trabajo destacaríamos los enormes esfuerzos realizados para ahorrar agua sin que ello implique renunciar a hábitos de higiene y confort que se consideran imprescindibles como la ducha diaria por muy breve que sea ésta. Igualmente, la pobreza hídrica se suma a otras privaciones características de un sector de la ciudad degradado y en declive.
... The examination of the social dimensions and determinants of sufficiency invites us to consider the policy implications of our findings. In the prevailing paradigm of unsustainable growth that underpins our societal structures (Asara et al, 2015), wasting energy continues to be structurally encouraged in various contexts (Kuss and Nicholas, 2022). To mainstream sufficiency, policies must have the capacity to succeed in establishing a low-carbon, high wellbeing lifestyle as the standard and accessible choice for all (Verfuerth et al, 2019). ...
Article
Full-text available
Sufficiency consists of less materially intensive consumption patterns that focus on wellbeing rather than material wealth. Such consumption patterns are commonly referred to as sufficiency lifestyles and are increasingly seen as a key driver for achieving decarbonisation. However, while research finds that sustainable consumption and environmental behaviour are often associated with high social status, lower carbon footprints and lower consumption more broadly are associated in the literature with poverty and deprivation. This article aims to investigate whether a combination of low carbon footprint and high wellbeing exists, what socio-demographic characteristics are associated with it, and to explore the actual experiences of people engaged in sufficiency lifestyles through initiatives and their characteristics. We use a mixed-methods design with data from demographically representative surveys in Denmark, Germany, Italy and Latvia (N=5,080), and in-depth interviews with participants from sufficiency-oriented intentional communities (N=90). We find that sufficiency lifestyles are linked to a stronger inclination towards sufficiency orientation or a heightened stronger environmental identity, accompanied by a negative correlation with social deprivation aspects. Drawing on the interviews, we find that individuals engaged in sufficiency-oriented practices tend to benefit from economic, social and cultural resources that allow them to overcome energy dependency and constraints, and that their motivations are not limited to pro-environmental behaviour. Based on these empirical findings, we explore potential avenues for the diffusion of sufficiency-oriented lifestyles, including the establishment of binding rules through a democratic process that curb overconsumption while providing attractive low-carbon lifestyles for all.
... Firstly, international policy increasingly emphasizes sustainability, influenced by organizations like the United Nations (UNESCO, 2017). Secondly, there is a rising public movement advocating for development models that prioritize human well-being and environmental concerns (Asara et al., 2015;Kaul et al., 2022). This situation places significant responsibility on educational institutions and policymakers to equip individuals with the skills and knowledge necessary for a sustainable future (Chankseliani & McCowan, 2021;Pegalajar et al., 2022). ...
Article
Full-text available
There is no standardized definition or measurement tool for sustainability competence, which hinders comparative research. This study addresses this gap by developing a new test based on the European reference framework GreenComp. The proposed instrument, consisting of eleven multiple-choice items, was validated through expert review and exploratory and confirmatory factor analysis, showing strong construct validity and high internal consistency reliability. Applied to students aged 8 to 12, it revealed a prevalence of basic and anthropocentric perspectives on sustainability. This promising tool can assess sustainability competence in primary education and has the potential for use across European countries.
Chapter
Full-text available
Sustainability transitions are employed as a key conceptual term in science, politics and societal debate. While often employed as an umbrella term for policy programmes aiming for a more environmentally and socially conscious shift of societal conduct, the understanding of its variegated processes has sparked an array of epistemological frameworks and approaches. Much research is criticised for an insensitivity to the socio-spatial complexities and multi-scalar relations of becoming, and the domination of large-scale, centralised and urban-oriented socio-economic development pathways calls for a rescaling of sustainability transitions with small-scale, localised and rural approaches. The rescaling of sustainability transitions in this sense plays out in multiple forms and rather than confining research to a streamlined conceptual frame, we see value in drawing on partially aligned, yet diverse accounts. Through engagement with different shades of rescaling, this book aims at a deeper, more diverse understanding of how sustainability transitions manifest in different spatial contexts, are framed by multi-scalar and continuously shifting socio-spatial relations and the role of (contested) spatial imaginaries on the capacities for ‘rescaled’ future trajectories.
Article
Full-text available
Identifying research gaps and priorities is paramount to advance sustainability science and contribute to a sustainable future. This editorial contributes to this effort by contemplating the sustainability science research agenda and aligning it with recent changes in global dynamics. Drawing on consultations with the editorial board members of the Sustainability Science journal and a review of relevant literature, we identified 12 key research topics. These topics are interpreted within a strategic framework encompassing three key themes: (1) goals that drive sustainability science, (2) approaches to attain these goals, and (3) tools to advance sustainability science research. In so doing, this editorial emphasizes a sustainable development agenda extending beyond 2030, fostering equity and justice, and tackling issues related to power dynamics and geopolitical conflicts. It underscores the significance of research approaches to attaining sustainability goals, in particular, theorizing, co-production of knowledge and action, attaining clarity in conceptual descriptions, and developing systems-oriented analytical frameworks. Additionally, it highlights the value of place-based approaches, learning from significant systemic shocks, and nurturing inner transformations. It also underlines the need to explore emerging technologies and data-intensive methodologies as a tool to address sustainability concerns. The systematic contemplation of the sustainability science research agenda presented in this editorial piece aims to invoke further discussion among researchers and practitioners about a fresh and relevant agenda that promotes the sustainable integration of nature and society.
Article
Full-text available
This paper argues that the current growth-centric paradigm of sustainable development is fundamentally flawed and proposes a paradigm shift towards the biblical concept of the Sabbath. It critiques the internal contradictions of the SDGs and challenges the unsustainable pursuit of infinite growth in addressing social and ecological crises. By exploring Sabbath's principles of rest, recalibration, and redistribution, the paper offers an ethical foundation for self-limitation and a basis for human identity beyond productivity—addressing the shortcomings of the degrowth movement. It proposes practical applications of Sabbath principles at individual, community, and structural levels, drawing upon empirical examples to demonstrate their potential as pathways to environmental justice. These multi-level applications aim to bridge the gap between the intentions of international agreements and impactful local action. The paper concludes that Sabbath presents a transformative vision for sustainable development and environmental justice, fostering a harmonious relationship between humanity and the planet. Keywords: Sustainability, Development, Sabbath, Degrowth, Capitalism, Environmental Justice, Poverty, Well-being, Ethics, Religion.
Book
Full-text available
The discourse of ‘green growth’ has recently gained ground in environmental governance deliberations and policy proposals. It is presented as a fresh and innovative agenda centred on the deployment of engineering sophistication, managerial acumen and market mechanisms to redress the environmental and social derelictions of the existing development model. But the green growth project is deeply inadequate, whether assessed against criteria of social justice or the achievement of sustainable economic life upon a materially finite planet. This volume outlines three main lines of critique. First, it traces the development of the green growth discourse quaideology. It asks: what explains modern society’s investment in it, why has it emerged as a master concept in the contemporary conjuncture, and what social forces does it serve? Second, it unpicks and explains the contradictions within a series of prominent green growth projects. Finally, it weighs up the merits and demerits of alternative strategies and policies, asking the vital question: ‘if not green growth, then what?’
Article
Full-text available
Book
In one lifetime, GDP, or Gross Domestic Product, has ballooned from a narrow economic tool into a global article of faith. As The Little Big Number demonstrates, this spells trouble. While economies and cultures measure their performance by it, GDP only measures output. It ignores central facts such as quality, costs, or purpose. Sustainability and quality of life are overlooked. Losses don't count. The world can no longer afford GDP rule―GDP ignores real development. Dirk Philipsen demonstrates how the history of GDP reveals unique opportunities to fashion smarter goals and measures. The Little Big Number explores a possible roadmap for a future that advances quality of life rather than indiscriminate growth.