Technical ReportPDF Available

International Industrial Policy Experiences and the Lessons for the UK

Authors:

Abstract

The present study reviews a diverse set of countries with the most successful industrial policy experiences since the Second World War – namely, the US, Germany, Japan, Italy, Finland, (South) Korea, Singapore, China, and Brazil – with a view to deriving lessons for the UK. In Section 1, we start by reviewing the current state of the manufacturing sector in the UK, especially, although not exclusively, comparing it with the nine countries whose industrial policy we review in this state. The picture that emerges is an alarming one, in which the UK’s industrial performance distinguishes itself for being poor and is still declining further. In Section 2, we discuss some of the key theoretical issues in the debate on industrial policy. We discuss: (a) different definitions of industrial policy, especially focusing on the relationship between and the relative merits of ‘horizontal’ (or ‘general’) and ‘vertical’ (or ‘selective’) industrial policies; (b) the special role of the manufacturing sector in the overall economy, especially as the source of productivity growth, innovation, learning, and resilience; (c) main theoretical justifications for certain notable industrial policy tools and institutions used in the countries reviewed. In Section 3, we review the industrial policy experiences of the nine comparator countries. While historical material dating back from the 18th century is covered when appropriate, the focus is more on the recent period, since the 1980s or the 1990s, depending on the country. In Section 4, we draw lessons for the UK’s industrial policy from the nine country experiences that we review in Section 3, filtered through the theoretical discussions provided in Section 2. We draw the lessons along several dimensions: (a) the role of ‘vision’; (b) institutional settings (e.g., coordination within the government, the role of surrounding institutional networks); (c) finance and corporate governance; (d) promotion of innovation; (e) management of transnational corporations (TNCs); (f) support for SMEs; (g) skills and training. In Section 5, we look ahead for the future of the UK’s manufacturing sector, taking into account our theoretical discussions, country case reviews, and the lessons we have drawn from those discussions.
Future of Manufacturing Project: Evidence Paper 4
Foresight,GovernmentOfficeforScience
International industrial
policy experiences and the
lessons for the UK
International industrial policy
experiences and the Lessons for
the UK
By
Professor Ha-Joon Chang, Dr Antonio Andreoni & Ming Leong Kuan
University of Cambridge
October 2013
This review has been commissioned as part of the UK Government’s Foresight Future of
Manufacturing Project. The views expressed do not represent policy of any government
or organisation
Contents
Executive summary.......................................................................................................................4
1. Introduction................................................................................................................................5
2. Theoretical issues .....................................................................................................................9
2.1. Definitional issues.................................................................................................................9
2.2. The special role of the manufacturing sector......................................................................10
2.3. Theories of industrial policy.................................................................................................12
2.4. Implementation issues ........................................................................................................16
2.5. Evaluating industrial policy..................................................................................................18
3. Country case studies ..............................................................................................................21
3.1. Japan: the quintessential example......................................................................................21
3.2. Germany: the teacher? .......................................................................................................24
3.3. The US: the real pioneer.....................................................................................................27
3.4. Korea: the most dramatic example .....................................................................................30
3.5. Singapore: the ultimate pragmatist .....................................................................................33
3.6. Finland: defying gravity?.....................................................................................................35
3.7. Italy: small is beautiful?.......................................................................................................37
3.8. Brazil: against all odds........................................................................................................39
3.9. China: the new frontier........................................................................................................42
4. Lessons for the UK..................................................................................................................45
4.1. Some general remarks on ‘drawing lessons’ from international experiences.....................45
4.2. Specific issues....................................................................................................................46
5. Looking ahead .........................................................................................................................54
References ...................................................................................................................................55
Appendix ......................................................................................................................................69
Executive summary
The present study reviews a diverse set of countries with the most successful industrial
policy experiences since the Second World War – namely, the US, Germany, Japan,
Italy, Finland, (South) Korea, Singapore, China, and Brazil – with a view to deriving
lessons for the UK.
In section 1, we start by reviewing the current state of the manufacturing sector in the
UK, especially, although not exclusively, comparing it with the nine countries whose
industrial policy we review in this state. The picture that emerges is an alarming one, in
which the UK’s industrial performance distinguishes itself for being poor and is still
declining further.
In section 2, we discuss some of the key theoretical issues in the debate on industrial
policy. We discuss: (a) different definitions of industrial policy, especially focusing on the
relationship between and the relative merits of ‘horizontal’ (or ‘general’) and ‘vertical’ (or
‘selective’) industrial policies; (b) the special role of the manufacturing sector in the
overall economy, especially as the source of productivity growth, innovation, learning,
and resilience; (c) main theoretical justifications for certain notable industrial policy tools
and institutions used in the countries reviewed.
In Section 3, we review the industrial policy experiences of the nine comparator
countries. While historical material dating back from the 18th century is covered when
appropriate, the focus is more on the recent period, since the 1980s or the 1990s,
depending on the country.
In Section 4, we draw lessons for the UK’s industrial policy from the nine country
experiences that we review in Section 3, filtered through the theoretical discussions
provided in Section 2. We draw the lessons along several dimensions: (a) the role of
‘vision’; (b) institutional settings (e.g., coordination within the government, the role of
surrounding institutional networks); (c) finance and corporate governance; (d) promotion
of innovation; (e) management of transnational corporations (TNCs); (f) support for
SMEs; (g) skills and training.
In Section 5, we look ahead for the future of the UK’s manufacturing sector, taking into
account our theoretical discussions, country case reviews, and the lessons we have
drawn from those discussions.
4
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
1. Introduction
Since the 2008 global financial crisis, there has been a widespread acceptance – even
among many of the traditional proponents of finance-led service economy – that the UK
needs to ‘rebalance the economy’ and generate a ‘manufacturing revival’ through what
George Osborne, the Chancellor of the Exchequer, called ‘the march of the makers’ (BIS,
2012, and TSB, 2012 are the recent examples). However, few people realise the scale of
challenge that the UK faces in engineering a manufacturing renaissance.
The UK was the epicentre of the Industrial Revolution, which has given birth to the modern
world. And until the late 19th century, its industrial dominance was absolute. In 1860, it
produced 20% of world manufacturing output, despite having only about 2.5% of the then
world population (28 million out of 1.2 billion). Today, China produces only about 15% of
world manufacturing value-added (MVA) (see Table A.1 in the appendix), despite having
19% of world population (1.3 billion out of 6.9 billion). In 1870, the UK accounted for 46%
of world trade in manufactured goods. The current Chinese share in world exports is only
around 14% (Table A.1 in the appendix).
Today, the UK’s manufacturing sector is a pale shadow of its former self. People often
have taken comfort in the fact that the country is still the 8th largest manufacturing nation in
the world, but in per capita terms (MVA per capita), it is only the 24th in the world (see
Table 1), behind even Iceland (ranked the 16th) and Luxembourg (ranked the 19th), not to
speak of the Japans and the Finlands of this world. By 2012, it had also fallen behind its
traditional rival, France (ranked the 22nd, with $3,810 against the UK’s $3,731) (Table A.2
in the appendix provides more indicators for the top 60 manufacturing nations).
And it is not just the shrinking size of the manufacturing sector that is the cause for
concern. The fact that the UK has failed to generate a manufacturing export boom despite
a 30-35% devaluation of its currency since the 2008 global financial crisis is a powerful
testimony to the underlying weakness of its manufacturing sector.
Table 1. Ranking of countries by per capita MVA in 2012 (in 2000 dollars)
Rank Country Per capita MVA Rank Country Per capita
MVA
1 Ireland 11,772 33 Kuwait 2,391
2 Switzerland 10,191 34 Hungary 2,347
3 Singapore 8,800 35 Poland 2,336
4 Finland 7,997 36 Turkmenistan 1,962
5 Japan 7,693 37 Portugal 1,945
6 Sweden 7,489 38 Bahrain 1,909
7 Austria 7,300 39 Seychelles 1,771
8 Germany 7,075 40 Lithuania 1,750
9 South Korea 6,226 41 Malaysia 1,715
10 United States 5,786 42 Malta 1,708
11 Norway 5,690 43 Estonia 1,634
12 San Marino 5,452 44 Belarus 1,570
13 Denmark 5,421 45 Greece 1,560
5
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
14 Belgium 5,227 46 Turkey 1,533
15 Netherlands 4,948 47 Mexico 1,522
16 Iceland 4,926 48 Saudi Arabia 1,453
17 Taiwan 4,856 49 Oman 1,436
18 Qatar 4,179 50 Argentina 1,398
19 Luxembourg 4,083 51 Croatia 1,316
20 Italy 3,885 52 Romania 1,205
21 Canada 3,830 53 Thailand 1,186
22 France 3,810 54
China 1,147
23 Czech Republic 3,755 55 Chile 1,094
24 United Kingdom 3,731 56 Cyprus 1,042
25 Australia 3,680 57 Costa Rica 1,001
26 New Zealand 3,474 58 Mauritius 996
27 Slovenia 3,437 59 Uruguay 978
28 Israel 3,192 60 Russia 947
29 United Arab Emirates 3,161
30 Spain 2,780 67
Brazil 764
31 Brunei Darussalam 2,723 85
Indonesia 444
32 Slovakia 2,417 117
India 163
Note: Countries whose names are in italics are the ones included in this report.
Data source: UNIDO (2013)
The UK’s de-industrialisation, which started in the 1970s, has progressed at a continuous
and alarming pace. As we see from Figure 1, no country among the 10 countries that we
have chosen to study in this report for comparison with the UK (in alphabetical order,
Brazil, China, Finland, Germany, Italy, Japan, Singapore, South Korea, and the United
States) has experienced de-industrialisation in the relentless way in which the UK has
experienced it.
Table 2 shows the comparative manufacturing performance of the 10 countries during the
20-year period between 1990 and 2010 across a diverse range of indicators compiled by
UNIDO (2013). The table shows that the UK performed the worst (or joint-worst) in 7 out of
8 indicators across our 10 countries. Three aspects are worth highlighting here.
6
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Figure 1. Share of Manufacturing in GDP, 1990-2010
10%
15%
20%
25%
30%
35%
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
China
Finland
Germany
Italy
Brazil
United States
Singapore
Japan
Korea
United
Kingdom
Data source: UNIDO (2013)
Table 2. Manufacturing indicators in selected countries, per annum rate of change
(%), 1990-2010
Country MVA
per
capita
MVA as
% of
GDP
MHT
MVA as
% of
total
MVA
MVA as
% of
World
MVA
MX
per
capita
MX as
% of
total
exports
MHT
MX as
% of
total
MX
MX as
% of
WMT
Brazil 0.5% -1.1% -1.7% -0.6% 7.5% -0.5% -0.2% 1.2%
China 10.7% 1.1% 0.2% 8.5% 17.6% 0.8% 4.3% 10.0%
Finland 3.6% 2.0% 1.5% 1.4% 4.4% -0.2% 0.8% -2.8%
Germany -0.1% -1.3% 0.9% -2.6% 5.8% -0.3% 0.3% -1.9%
Italy -0.5% -1.2% -0.4% -2.8% 4.6% -0.1% 0.4% -2.7%
Japan 0.2% -0.6% 0.3% -2.2% 4.6% -0.3% -0.2% -2.8%
Korea 6.2% 1.7% 1.3% 4.2% 9.7% 0.1% 2.0% 2.4%
Singapore 3.8% -0.4% 0.6% 3.3% 6.2% -0.2% 0.5% 0.6%
UK -0.8% -2.4% -0.3% -2.9% 3.3% -0.3% -0.2% -3.8%
US 1.4% -0.1% 0.3% -0.1% 4.2% -0.3% -0.6% -2.3%
Source: Authors’ calculations based on UNIDO (2013)
Notes: Manufacturing Value Added (MVA) and GDP are in constant 2000 US dollars.
MHT, MX and WMT refer to medium and high-technology, manufacturing exports and
world manufacturing trade respectively. Due to data gaps, China’s compounded annual
growth rates (CAGRs) were calculated for the period 1992-2010 while Germany’s CAGRs
were for the period 1991-2010.
First, the UK de-industrialised at the fastest pace among the 10 countries during this
period (2.4% p.a. decline in the share of MVA as a percentage of GDP), resulting in the
lowest manufacturing share in GDP (11.4%) in 2010 among the 10 countries, as shown in
Figure 1.
7
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
8
Second, the UK’s industrial competitiveness has been eroded at a faster pace than the
other countries. Both the shares of the country’s MVA in World MVA and its share of
manufacturing exports (MX) in world manufacturing trade (WMT) fell faster in the UK (-
2.9% p.a. and -3.8% p.a. respectively) than in the other countries between 1990 and 2010.
Third, the UK has not successfully upgraded the quality of its manufacturing sector.
Among the developed economies in the sample, it was the only country that saw declines
in both the share of medium and high-technology (MHT) MVA in total MVA (-0.3% p.a.)
and the share of MHT MX in total MX (-0.2% p.a.) between 1990 and 2010.
The typical, albeit increasingly less frequent, response to the kind of information that we
have provided so far is that the UK’s industrial decline is the result of market forces and
therefore that there is nothing to be done about it. However, those apparently ‘natural’
market outcomes are in the end the results of deliberate decisions by economic agents –
productive enterprises, financial investors, and trade unions. And shaping all these
decisions is the government, which sets the boundaries of the market, decides on the
types of permissible behavior, and (explicitly and implicitly) manipulates incentives through
interest rates, taxes, subsidies, regulations, procurement decisions, and many other
means. Particularly important in relation to the manufacturing sector is industrial policy,
which is policy specifically targeted at industries, rather than more general policies (e.g.,
monetary policy, fiscal policy) or policies targeted at other things (e.g., social policy,
education policy) – we will provide a more rigorous definition in the next section.
In this report, we discuss how the UK government may improve the country’s
manufacturing sector performance through industrial policy by looking at the industrial
policy experiences of nine other countries, all with important achievements and strengths
at least in some respects. We have deliberately chosen a range of countries in terms of
size (from huge China, the US, and Brazil to tiny Singapore and Finland), level of overall
economic development (from the richest US and Finland to the poorest Brazil and China),
and areas of strengths in terms of industries (from electronics in Japan and Korea to
aircraft in the US and Brazil), firm size (from huge firms in the US and Korea to medium-
sized firms in Germany and Japan and small firms in Italy), and technological intensity
(from high-tech Japan, Finland, and Korea to medium-tech Germany and Italy to low-tech
China).
Before we look at individual country experiences, however, we need to look at some
general issues related to industrial policy, including its definition, theoretical justifications,
and evaluation, in order to provide a framework for our case discussions.
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
2. Theoretical issues
2.1. Definitional issues
The controversial nature of industrial policy is testified to by the fact that there is actually
no universally agreed definition of the term (see Warwick, 2013, pp. 14-18).
The most literal interpretation of industrial policy would be to define it to include any
policy that affects industry (usually interpreted as the manufacturing industry), in the
same way in which we would define fiscal policy as policy that affects government
revenue and spending, and monetary policy as policy that affects monetary variables.
Indeed, some commentators who adopt this definition would include even infrastructure
policy, education policy and tax policy as parts of industrial policy (see Chang, 1994a, pp.
58-61, for some examples).
The majority of the commentators on industrial policy, however, define industrial policy to
mean ‘selective’ industrial policy, ‘sectoral industrial policy’ or ‘targeting’ – namely, a
policy that deliberately favours particular industries/sectors (or even firms) over others,
against market signals, usually (but not necessarily) to enhance efficiency and promote
productivity growth, for the whole economy as well as for the targeted industries
themselves.1
Industrial policy thus defined has been even more controversial than more generally
defined industrial policy.2 Many people believe that industrial policy should be of general
(or functional or horizontal) kind, rather than of selective (or sectoral or vertical) kind. In
this view, industrial policy should focus on ‘public goods’ that benefit all industries equally
but are likely to be under-provided by the market – e.g., education, research and
development (R&D), and infrastructure – and not involve ‘picking winners’.
The fundamental problem with this view is that the distinction between selective and
general industrial policies cannot take us very far. In a world with scarce resources, every
policy choice you make, however general the policy involved may look, has
discriminatory effects that amount to implicit targeting.
For example, many people believe that education is one of those general industrial
policies, but beyond the basic level (say, the first 9 years), education becomes
specialised. So, for example, when we produce engineers, it does not produce some
generic engineers but engineers specialised in certain areas. Therefore, a government
providing more funding to electronics engineering departments than to chemical
engineering departments is implicitly favouring the electronics industry. Likewise, there is
no such thing as generic physical infrastructure. Physical infrastructure is always
location-specific, so it affects different industries differently. Moreover, different modes of
transportation have different impacts on different industries – bulky goods (e.g., iron ore,
1 This is a more refined version of the definition provided in Chang (1994a, ch. 3, pp. 60-1), which defines
industrial policy as a policy aimed to affect particular industries (and firms as their components) to achieve
the outcomes which are perceived by the state to be efficient for the economy as a whole.
2 OECD (1975), World Bank (1993) and UNCTAD (1998 and 2009) adopt the narrower industrial policy
definition of selective, sector-specific measures, while OECD (2009) and the European Commission (2002
and 2010) include horizontal policies within industrial policy.
9
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
wheat) will be helped more by developments of seaports and railways, while lighter
goods, especially when they are perishable (e.g., flowers, fresh fish), will be helped more
by developments of airports. Finally, if a government is giving out R&D subsidies, it is
implicitly favouring the more R&D-intensive higher-tech sectors.
Thus seen, selectivity (targeting) is inevitable. Except in the case of the provision of basic
education, calling which an ‘industrial policy’ is really stretching the term beyond
credulity, there is really no policy that does not involve some degree of targeting.3
Now, it may be said that, while targeting may be unavoidable, the less targeted a policy
is, the better it is. However, this is a one-sided view. While less targeted policies may
open themselves less to the possibilities of lobbying and ‘regulatory capture’, thus
making it easier to maintain the necessary myth that the government is impartial, they are
more costly to implement. Being less precise and thus more difficult to monitor, they have
more ‘leakages’ than more targeted policies. Indeed, many mainstream economists have
long argued – and many politicians, including the members of the current British
government – that the welfare state should be more precisely targeted because there are
simply too many leakages in the system of universal welfare (on targeting in social policy,
see Mkandawire, 2005). It is curious that this point is almost entirely ignored in relation to
industrial policy.
Given all this, we have to admit that we cannot ‘not target’ and should try to attain the
best possible degree of targeting, which may differ across industries and countries. We
cannot assume that there is a linear relationship, positive or negative, between the
degree of targeting and policy success. Some degree of targeting is inevitable, while
some more of it may be desirable, but too much of it may not be good, although how
much is too much is debatable (and one’s position on it will depend on one’s economic
theories and political values). The best way to think about it is ‘targeting within
universalism’, as some people propose in relation to social policy (Skocpol, 1991, as
cited in Mkandawire, 2005, p. 23), rather than ‘targeting vs. universalism’.
2.2. The special role of the manufacturing sector
Industrial policy, according to our definition, does not involve only manufacturing
industries. It could target service industries, as the UK, Ireland, Iceland, and Dubai did
with the financial industry in the last two, three decades – albeit all unfortunately with
highly negative consequences. Or it could involve promotion of certain industries in the
primary sector – prominent examples include the dairy industry in Denmark in the late
19th and the early 20th century (Chang, 2009a and 2009b), and more recently, the salmon
and the forestry industries in Chile (Meissner, 1988; Clapp, 1995; UNCTAD, 2006) and
the soybean industry in Brazil (Hosono & Hongo, 2012; Andreoni, 2013a).
3 Karl Aiginger, a key author of the European Commission’s industrial policy, acknowledges that, while the
Commission has maintained “the primarily horizontal approach [in which] measures are general and provide
for a favourable competitive environment (that is, they are not industry-specific, selective, or conducive to the
deceleration of structural change)”, it increasingly acknowledges that “the effects of broad horizontal policies
can vary significantly from industry to industry, that competitiveness needs specific policy mixes for specific
sectors, and that some sectors may require complementary measures that are not necessary or relevant in
other sectors” (Aiginger & Sieber, 2006, p. 579).
10
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
However, those who are interested in selective industrial policy tend to put great
emphasis on the need to promote the manufacturing sector. The reasons to promote the
manufacturing industries are many and diverse.
First, it is widely recognised that the manufacturing sector is the main source of
technology-driven productivity growth in modern economies. It is not much of an
exaggeration to say that manufacturing is what has made the modern world. Thanks to
the fact that the manufacturing activities lend themselves much more easily to
mechanisation and chemical processing than do other types of economic activities, the
manufacturing sector has been the main source of productivity growth throughout history.
Productivity increase in agriculture is highly constrained by nature in terms of time,
space, soil, and climate. By their very nature, many service activities are inherently
impervious to productivity increases. In some cases, the very increase in productivity will
destroy the product itself. If a string quartet trots through a 27-minute piece in nine
minutes, we won’t say that its productivity has trebled. For some other services, the
apparently higher productivity may be due to the de-basement of the product. A lot of the
increases in retail service productivity in countries like the US and the UK have been
bought by lowering the quality of the retail service itself – fewer shop assistants, longer
drives to the supermarket, lengthier waits for deliveries, etc. The 2008 global financial
crisis has also revealed that much of the recent productivity growth in finance had been
achieved through the de-basement of the products – that is, the creation of overly
complex, riskier, and even fraudulent products.
Second, many economic historians and economists argue that the manufacturing sector,
especially the capital goods sector, has been the ‘learning centre’ of capitalism in
technological terms (Rosenberg, 1963 and 1982; Kaldor, 1981; Cohen & Zysman, 1987;
Rowthorn & Wells, 1987; Park & Chan, 1989; Mokyr, 1990 and 2002; Mowery &
Rosenberg, 1999; Guerrieri & Meliciani, 2005). Because of its ability to produce
productive inputs (e.g., machines, chemicals), what happens in the manufacturing sector
has been extremely important in the productivity growth of other sectors. The increases
in agricultural productivity that we have seen in the last century and half would not have
been remotely possible without the developments of manufacturing industries producing
agricultural machinery, chemical fertilizers, pesticides, and increasingly genetic
engineering. The rapid increases in the productivity of services like logistics and retail in
the last couple of decades were also made possible by manufacturing industries
producing more efficient transport equipment, computers, and mechanised warehouses.
Third, the manufacturing sector has also been the source of organisational innovation.
Productivity growth in the last two centuries has been driven not just by technological
changes but also organizational changes, most of which originated in the manufacturing
sector. For example, these days many fast food restaurants use ‘factory’ techniques,
turning cooking into an assembly job and sometimes even delivering food on conveyor
belts (Yo! Sushi being the most familiar example for the UK citizens). For another
example, large retail chains – be they supermarkets, clothes shop chains, or on-line
retailers – apply modern inventory management techniques, developed in the
manufacturing sector. Even in the agricultural sector, productivity has been raised in
some countries through the application of manufacturing-style organisational knowledge,
like computer-controlled feeding (the Dutch agriculture is the prime example here).
Fourth, the manufacturing sector has been the main source of demand for high-
productivity activities in other industries. For example, most of the service activities that
have high productivity and have seen high productivity growths – sometimes even faster
11
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
than those of some sub-sectors of manufacturing – recently (e.g., finance, transport, and
business services) are ‘producer’ services, whose main customers are manufacturing
firms. Of course, countries can specialise in those services, but in the case of many
producer services (e.g., engineering, design, management consulting), their ability to
export cannot be maintained in the long run without a strong manufacturing sector. In
those services, insights gained from the production process and the continuous
interaction between the provider and the clients are crucial. Given this, a weakening
manufacturing base will eventually lead to a decline in the quality, and exportability, of
those services (Tassey, 2010; Fuchs & Kirchain, 2010; Pisano & Shih, 2012).
Fifth, the manufacturing sector, producing physical and non-perishable products, has
higher tradability than agriculture and, especially, services. At the root of the low
tradability of services lies the fact that many services require their providers and
consumers to be in the same location. No one has yet invented ways to provide haircut
or house cleaning long-distance. Of course, this problem will be solved if the service
provider (the hairdresser or the cleaner in the above examples) can move to the
customer’s country, but that in most cases means immigration, which most countries
severely restrict. Given this, a rising share of services in the economy means that the
country, other things being equal, will have lower export earnings. This, in turn, means
that, unless the exports of manufactured goods rise disproportionately, the country won’t
be able to pay for the same amount of imports as before. Also, the high tradability of
manufacturing imparts a crucial resilience to an economy with a strong manufacturing
sector, as it can better protect itself from external shocks – as we have seen this with the
resilience of the German economy, following the 2008 financial crisis.
2.3. Theories of industrial policy
Unless we live in the fantasy world of perfect markets, industrial policy does not lack
theoretical justifications (for reviews, see Dosi et al., 1989; Chang, 1994a and 2011;
Stiglitz, 1996; Lall, 2004; Rodrik, 2004 and 2008; Aiginger & Sieber, 2006; Bianchi &
Labory, 2006; Cimoli et al., 2009; Spence, 2008; Aghion et al., 2012). This is not a place
to review these theories in any detail, so let us just provide an overview of the key types
of arguments.
2.3.1. Interdependences
There are various arguments that justify industrial policy, especially of selective type, on
the basis of the existence of interdependence between different activities.
The best-known of this type of argument are those based on demand complementarities
and increasing returns (to scale) in manufacturing industries, which were prominent in
Classical Economics and in early Development Economics (Toner, 1999, provides an
excellent review; also see Andreoni & Scazzieri, 2013). The first variety of these is the
so-called Big Push argument – or the balanced growth model – of Paul Rosenstein-
Rodan (1943) and Ragnar Nurkse (1952), which argues that there needs to be a
coordination of investment between interdependent activities, as their returns depend on
there being all the complementary investments. Using a similar insight, the so-called
linkages argument of Albert Hirschman (1958) advocates industrial policy that first
promotes industries with particularly strong interdependences with other sectors, whether
as suppliers of inputs into other industries (forward linkages) or as purchasers of outputs
of other industries (backward linkages), thus setting off chain reactions in different
12
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
directions. This argument is also known as the unbalanced growth model, in the sense
that the government initially focuses on the leading industries, rather than trying to
promote all industries together.
Second, there are less well-known justifications for industrial policy based on
interdependences between competing – rather than complementary – activities. In
oligopolistic industries with lumpy investments, simultaneous investments by competing
firms may result in excess capacity, which may push some firms into bankruptcy, which
in turn means that the resources invested in them will have been wasted – unless the
machines and skills involved are of very general nature and can be redeployed
elsewhere easily, which rarely is the case in modern industries. In order to prevent such
‘wasteful competition’, countries, especially Japan and Korea, have used entry
restrictions and government-approved investment cartels so that investments are
staggered at suitable intervals (see Chang, 1994a, pp. 66-7; Amsden & Singh, 1994).
Coordination problems among competing investments may be related not only to
investment but also to situations of temporary disinvestment or structural change in the
industrial sector. Recession cartels and mechanisms of negotiated exit have been widely
used to face periods of economic crisis or accompany structural transformation (Dore,
1986, is the classic study). In these situations industrial policies introduce “a ‘protective’
element – that is ‘helping losers’ by temporarily shielding them from the full forces of the
market” (Chang, 2003, p. 262). More generally, support for declining sectors may be
seen as an attempt to socialise risk to encourage and sustain the process of structural
change and productivity growth, from which economic development derives.
Third, there is the externality argument (Scitovsky, 1954), in which industrial policy is
deployed to compensate for under-investment in (and thus under-production of) certain
activities due to the fact that their providers do not reap the full benefits from their efforts.
Supports for basic R&D or worker training are classic cases. More recently, some
commentators have developed an argument for industrial policy based on ‘information
externality’. The argument is that investments are not made in industries because the
potential ‘pioneer’ firm is afraid of providing ‘free experiment’ to competitors, who may
then imitate it and deprive it of what Schumpeter would have called ‘entrepreneurial
profit’ (Hausmann & Rodrik, 2003; Rodrik, 2004 and 2008; Lin, 2012). Lin’s (2012) new
structural economics proposes the ‘growth identification and facilitation framework’, while
Hidalgo and Hausmann (2009) develop the so-called ‘atlas of economic complexity’,
whose aim is to reveal the existence of linkages and different countries’ capability
endowments.
2.3.2. Capabilities
Another important set of arguments for industrial policy is based on the time-consuming
and costly nature of the process of accumulating productive capabilities (Lall, 1992 and
2001; Chang, 1994a; Lall & Teubal, 1998; Loasby, 1999; Andreoni, 2013b). Productive
capabilities are personal and collective skills, productive knowledge and experience that
are embedded in physical agents and organisations (Andreoni, 2011).4
4 Production capabilities are those capabilities specifically needed for firms to perform different production
tasks as well as to adapt and undertake in-house improvements across different technological and
organisational functions.
13
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
The most famous argument along this line is the infant industry argument. This is based
on the understanding that productive capabilities can be accumulated only over time and
in an unpredictable way. Given this, new producers need a period of protection – through
tariffs, subsidies (related to equipment investments, R&D, and worker training), regulation
on foreign direct investment (FDI), and other measures – from competitive forces coming
from abroad, in the same way in which children need protection before they can go out
and compete in the labour market unassisted. This argument applies to the catching-up
economies particularly strongly, but can hold for all countries, insofar as their producers
in certain sectors are trying to catch up with superior producers abroad. The ultimate
example of the latter case is the development of Airbus by the European governments
against what looked like an insurmountable US dominance in the civilian aircraft market.
Another capabilities-related justification for industrial policy is based on policies providing
support for small producers – such as small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) in the
manufacturing sector and small farms. The problem is that capability accumulation needs
some indivisible inputs (thus high fixed costs) that small producers cannot provide on
their own – whether in R&D, machinery, or worker training. There are many industrial
policy measures intended to solve this problem. The government can directly provide
these inputs into the capability building process through public R&D, training of workers
in public universities and training institutes, and the provision of ‘extension service’ for
small firms and small farmers. It may subsidise those inputs through the provision of R&D
subsidies, credit guarantees (which will promote physical investments, among other
things), or training subsidies. Not all of the above-mentioned measures are specifically
targeted at small producers, but they may be of disproportionate help to such producers
insofar as they are disproportionately disadvantaged in providing such inputs through
market-based arrangements. On top of all these, the government may provide legal and
other backings for voluntary cooperative arrangements among small producers – such as
tax advantages for cooperatives among small producers or subsidies for particular joint
activities (e.g., R&D, processing, export marketing).
The third capability-based justification for industrial policy rationale is known as the
‘industrial commons’ argument. The argument is rooted in the fact that productive
capabilities have a fundamental collective nature, that is, their development and
application is very much the result of interdependent processes of learning and
production, each of which involves a variety of actors (Richardson, 1972 and Abramovitz,
1986 are the classic references). Given these interdependences, the effective
coordination of actors endowed with different capabilities becomes a key determinant of
the competitiveness of any sectoral innovation system (Metcalfe, 1995, Malerba, 2002:
for a review, see Laranja et al., 2008). Such coordination has become increasingly
important in modern manufacturing systems. As eloquently documented in Tassey
(2010): “Most modern technologies are systems, which means interdependencies exist
among a set of industries that contribute advanced materials, various components,
subsystems, manufacturing systems and eventually service systems based on sets of
manufactured hardware and software” (p. 6). The modern global economy is therefore
constructed around supply chains, whose tiers (industries) interact in complex ways”. A
representative study in this line of argument is Pisano and Shih (2009). Using information
from the semiconductor, electronics, pharmaceutical and biotech industries, the study
shows how the production and innovation capacities of a given economic system depend
on the presence of multiple resources, such as R&D know-how, engineering skills,
technological capabilities, and specific manufacturing and prototyping competences. The
study points out that many of these resources are scattered across a large number of
manufacturing and services companies as well as other organisations (such as
14
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
universities and vocational schools), so all those actors need to be located close to each
other, if they are to utilise those ‘common pool’ resources effectively.
The industrial commons literature stresses that even the development of high-tech
cutting-edge products often depends (amongst other factors) on the commons of a
mature manufacturing industry. The maintenance of industrial commons necessitates not
only the maintenance of a manufacturing base of a certain size and diversity but also
various forms of what we call in this report ‘intermediate institutions’ – industry
associations, trade unions, research institutes, and educational institutions. These
institutions maintain and nurture the industrial commons by developing research and
innovation activities in new industrial processes and products, both within and across
sectors (O’Sullivan, 2011; Best, 2011; Andreoni 2012a).
Fourth, there are measures to do with the establishment of local technological
capabilities in cases of ‘direct’ technology imports. The problem being addressed here is
that, when technologies are imported in a ‘direct’ way through technology licensing or
FDI, there is less incentive, on the part of both the importer and the provider, to create
technological capabilities in the importing country than when compared to cases of
‘indirect’ technology imports through machines. On the one hand, the buyer of technology
would find it easier not to develop its own capabilities to adapt and improve the imported
technologies, which means that they either import obsolete, ‘easier’ technologies or
become dependent on the provider in technological terms. On the other hand, the
provider would be reluctant to transfer core technologies, for fear of losing future customs
and creating another competitor. In order to overcome this problem, the government can
impose conditions on these direct forms of technology imports. Some countries (e.g.,
Japan, Korea) require approval for technology imports, to ensure that overly obsolete
technologies are not imported while the licensing fees for up-to-date technologies are not
excessive. In relation to FDI, many countries we have reviewed – Japan, Korea, Finland,
and even FDI-friendly China and Singapore – have used ‘carrots’ and ‘sticks’ to ensure
that core technologies are transferred and, more importantly, that the relevant local
technological capabilities are created. The ‘carrots’ include the customised provision of
necessary skills and subsidies for the establishment of R&D facilities. The ‘sticks’ include
requirements for TNCs for technology transfer, local sourcing, hiring of local workers in
higher capabilities, and exports (as export markets typically have higher quality
requirements).
2.3.3. Risk and uncertainty
There are a lot of justifications for industrial policy that are based on the recognition that
there are inherent discrepancies in the ability to deal with risk and uncertainty between
individual producers (whether they are corporations or individual workers) and the society
as a whole – often expressed somewhat misleadingly as ‘capital market failure’ (implying,
implausibly, that a ‘perfect’ capital market will finance any project that is viable).
One classic argument of this kind is based on the observation that the government often
has the ‘deepest pocket’ in the country and thus the strongest ability to deal with risk.
This is why many ambitious, high-risk projects have had to be subsidised by the
government – as in the case of Airbus – especially when the country’s capital market is of
‘impatient’ variety, like in the UK. When it comes to backward economies entering
technologically most demanding industries, the risk is incalculable and thus turns into
uncertainty. In such cases, establishing state-owned enterprises (SOEs) may be the only
solution. Korea’s steel-maker (POSCO), established in the late 1960s when the country’s
15
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
income was only 4% of the US income, and Brazil’s aircraft manufacturer (EMBRAER),
established in the late 1950s when the country’s income was only 8% of the US income,
are the supreme examples of this kind.
Second, governments have often deployed industrial policy to restructure companies in
trouble on the recognition that a major corporate restructuring – or even restructuring of
an entire industry (like the shipbuilding industry in Japan in the 1980s or the automobile
industry in the US after 2008) – requires risk of scales that private sector investors are
simply not interested in taking. Policies involved include government taking of an equity
stake (which often results in majority control), state-mediated mergers, coordinated
capacity scrapping, provision of loan guarantees, public subsidisation of severance
payments, and transitional subsidies.
Third, some governments, especially those in Scandinavia, have taken cognisance of the
fact that, in a fast-changing world, individual workers are exposed to levels of risk that
they cannot simply bear on an individual basis. On this recognition, these governments
have provided a comprehensive welfare state – especially strong unemployment
insurance, job search services, subsidised retraining, and even subsidies for re-location
(e.g., government providing bridging loans to workers who have to sell their house to
move to their new jobs) (Landesmann, 1992; Chang, 1994b). These are not ‘industrial
policies’ in the sense we have defined in this report, but they help industrial
developments by promoting smoother structural change.
2.4. Implementation issues
All the above justifications of industrial policy, of course, do not mean that industrial
policy measures are bound to succeed. From the disasters of China’s Great Leap
Forward to the white elephant of Concorde, there have been many cases of industrial
policy that have failed because the goals were set wrongly. Moreover, industrial policy
measures that are theoretically sound can also fail because of various types of
‘government failure’, owning to lack of political commitment, ‘capture’ by interest groups,
lack of bureaucratic capabilities, and other reasons. Therefore, we need to understand
why some attempts succeed and others fail and think of ways to maximise the chance of
success and minimise the chance of failure. The industrial policy literature since the
1980s has always highlighted the implementation issues, but these issues have been
getting renewed attention and more refined discussions in the more recent literature
(Chang, 2011; OECD, 2013; Andreoni, 2013c).
First, the success of industrial policy depends critically on the country’s political economy.
If there is no political base for industrial policy, it will fail in the face of policies that
undermine it. It is well known that countries with a strong landlord class or a strong
financial capitalist class have always found it difficult to implement good industrial policy,
as those classes want policies that may be detrimental to manufacturing. One such
prominent example is the US landlords in the South up till the Civil War constantly putting
pressure for free trade despite the fact that it would have deterred the development of the
country’s manufacturing sector. In the more recent period, we have seen the strong
financial capitalist classes of the UK and Brazil wanting policies that lead to overvalued
exchange rates, thereby destroying large swathes of their export-oriented manufacturing
industries.
However, all of this does not mean that a country is bound by its history. New political
coalitions can be built and policies changed. For example, in the late 19th century,
16
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Bismarck managed to make the landlord class (the Junkers) accept high tariff protection
and other industrial policy measures for the emerging heavy and chemical industries by
providing it with its own protection too – in the so-called ‘marriage of iron and rye’. For
another example, in 1860, the Northern manufacturing states of the US established their
national hegemony by establishing the Republican Party, which brought on board the
Western states, traditionally in favour of free trade, by offering them free distribution of
public land (embodied in the Homestead Act of 1862) – and eventually winning the Civil
War. For a more recent example, the recent counter-offensive by the industrial capitalists
in Brazil following the 2008 global financial crisis has led to the fall of real interest rates
and a diminution of currency overvaluation, which had beleaguered the country’s
manufacturing sector since 1996.
Second, the relationship between the government and the industrial capitalist class
matters. Experiences show the importance of continuous dialogue and exchange of
information between the two, if the policies are going to be well informed and relevant.
However, it is also important that the government does not get beholden to particular
industrial interests and thus avoid the danger of ‘capture’. Peter Evans (1995), the
eminent American sociologist, has captured this point beautifully in his notion of
‘embedded autonomy’, which means that the government needs to have roots in the
society (‘embeddedness’) but also has to have its own will and power (‘autonomy’) in
order to be effective in its intervention. Autonomy without embeddedness can create a
state that imposes an ‘inorganic’ vision on the society through force, while
embeddedness without autonomy means that the state is turned into Marx’s executive
committee of the bourgeoisie. Evans used the case of Japan, Korea, and Taiwan to
illustrate this point, but the other countries that we have examined in this report – most
notably Singapore, Germany, Italy (local governments), and Finland – fit this case.
Third, the nature of a country’s prevailing ideology matters. If the ideology is too rigid –
like the free-market ideology in the UK from the 1980s until the 2008 financial crisis, or
the autarchic variety of communism practised in Mao’s China – a country will use
industrial policy of wrong type in wrong quantity. All the countries we have reviewed in
this report showed a considerable degree of flexibility in ideological terms during most of
the periods reviewed (except for the obsession with inflation control in Brazil between
1996 and 2008). And their industrial policy was compromised when ideologies became
hardened, as in the case of the free-market ideology in Korea, especially between the
1997 financial crisis until the last government (2007-12). Singapore is the ultimate
example of industrial policy success based on pragmatism, mixing some of the most ‘free
market’ measures (free trade) with some of the most ‘communist’ ones (public ownership
of land, huge role for SOEs).
Fourth, the capabilities of the organisations implementing industrial policy matter. Not
only the relevant government ministries and public agencies but also the private sector
agencies needed in actually implementing some of the policy measures (e.g., employers’
association, industry associations, trade unions) need to have adequate policy
capabilities. This requires staffing these organisations with individuals with appropriate
skills and experiences. One important thing to note is that capabilities here do not imply
training in standard economics, as testified to by the fact that the industrial policy-makers
of the East Asian ‘miracle’ economies were mainly non-economists – lawyers in Japan
and, to a lesser extent, Korea and scientists and engineers in Taiwan and China (see
Chang, 2011). Moreover, capabilities are not just those possessed by the individuals
working in those organisations. Organisations themselves possess capabilities in the
forms of particular command structure, institutional routines, and organisational
17
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
‘memories’ (e.g., past records). Of course, the difficulty is that it takes time and
investments to build up these capabilities and coherences, although they are not as
difficult to build up as many critics of industrial policy would like us to believe (see Chang,
2011).5
Fifth, not only the capabilities of but also the interactions between the organisations
implementing industrial policy are important. The relevant bodies (public and private)
need to have good working relationships with each other. They also need some
mechanisms to coordinate their actions, whether through some intellectual exercises
(e.g., indicative planning, foresight exercise) or through organisational structures that
make coordination easier (e.g., some coordinating super-ministry, such as France’s
Planning Commission or Korea’s Economic Planning Board [EPB]).
Last but not least, how sensible the policies are obviously matters, although what is
‘sensible’ would be different across different commentators. Two aspects – policy realism
and policy adaptation – need consideration. First, as for ‘policy realism’, policy targets
need to be commensurate with the capabilities of the producers (and, secondarily, those
of the policy-makers themselves). This is true for all countries but particularly relevant for
countries at early stages of development, whose inadequate productive capabilities make
industrial upgrading risky. Given the risk, these countries should not try to leap too far
from where they are. However, the nature of the game is such that, without some risk-
taking, industrial policy will achieve little (Chang in the Lin-Chang debate emphasises this
point; see Lin & Chang, 2009). Striking the balance between realism and the need for
risk-taking is, of course, not easy, but it can be – and has been – done.6 As for ‘policy
adaptation’, policy targets need to be adjusted according to changes in conditions,
especially the country’s technological capabilities (which take long and cumulative
processes to build and efforts to maintain, as we emphasised above) and the world
market conditions (e.g., overall demand conditions, what the existing and potential
competitors are doing). It is widely recognised that, as the country moves up the
technological ladder, the focus of industrial policy needs to shift to innovation policy. It is
less widely recognised that countries at higher stages of economic development need
timely but orderly phasing-out of ‘geriatric’ (as opposed to ‘infant’) industries (see Chang,
1994, ch. 3, for further discussions).
2.5. Evaluating industrial policy
There have been various attempts to ascertain the effectiveness of selective industrial
policy by looking at the relative performances of the targeted industries against those of
non-targeted industries. Apart from various methodological and factual problems with
individual studies (two prominent studies – World Bank, 1993 and Lee, 1996 – are
reviewed in Chang, 2011), there is a problem with this general approach.7
5 An interesting consideration in the context of poor developing countries is that they can be locked up in
what Pritchett et al. (2012) calls ‘capability trap’. This refers to a situation in which a developing country
government develops only a narrow set of standard capabilities that are necessary for the continuous
attraction of foreign aid, which in the long run undermine its ability to develop policies that are genuinely
necessary for the country. OECD (2013) also discusses this issue.
6 So, for example, Japan and Korea succeeded in their industrial upgrading efforts because they started
developing difficult industries well before they looked ‘realistic’ – the automobile industry for Japan in the
1950s or the steel industry for Korea in the 1960s – by using the export earnings from industries like textiles,
cheap garments, and electronics, which conformed to their comparative advantage at the time.
7 Rodrik (2008) stresses that ‘[t]he conceptual difficulties involved in statistical inference in this area are so
great that it is hard to see how statistical evidence could ever yield a convincing verdict’ (p. v).
18
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
First, there are serious problems with the way in which these studies identify targeted
sectors. Some studies define targeted industries in terms of some general characteristics
without actually ascertaining that the industries were in practice favoured by government
policies. For example, the famous East Asian Miracle report of the World Bank argues
that industrial policy in the East Asian ‘miracle’ economies (except for some periods in
Japan) was a failure on the grounds that the targeted sectors did not perform better
(World Bank, 1993). However, the study assumed that the higher it’s value-added
component and the higher its capital intensity, the more favoured an industry was.
However, industrial targeting was never practiced in this kind of simplistic way in those
countries. For example, during the 1970s and the 1980s, the textile industry was
promoted heavily as a ‘strategic’ industry in Korea, as it was the most important export
industry (see Chang, 1995, for further details).
Other studies do look at the actual (as opposed to theoretical) degree of state support to
define targeted sectors. For example, Lee (1996), in analysing Korean industrial policy
for the 1962-83 period looks at tariffs, non-tariff barriers, tax incentives, and subsidised
loans for each sector and finds no correlation with a number of performance indicators
(e.g., labour productivity, total factor productivity or TFP, and capital intensity), thus
concluding industrial policy to have been ineffective. However, many important industrial
policy measures cannot by definition be captured through quantifiable indicators. Such
measures include: (i) coordination of complementary investments (the Big Push); (ii)
coordination of competing investments; (iii) policies to ensure scale economies (e.g.,
licensing conditional upon production scale, emphasis on the infant industries starting to
export from early on, state-mediated mergers and acquisitions); (iv) regulation on
technology imports; (v) regulation on foreign direct investment.
More recent studies (see the special issue edited by Lenihan et al., 2007) have overcome
the problems of identifying the promoted sectors and the supports they get by looking at
very specific programmes, such as R&D tax credits (Cappelen et al., 2012), government
sponsored R&D consortia (Lechevalier et al., 2010) or programmes for supporting
manufacturing jobs (Criscuolo et al., 2012), using micro data and industrial surveys. They
then try to identify the effects of those policies by comparing the ‘treated firms’ with ‘non-
treated firms’, using the randomisation technique or the ‘differences in difference’
technique.8
However, even these studies do not give us reliable results.
First of all, there are inherent difficulties in clearly linking the observed changes in the
targeted sector (or firms) with the implemented policy. This is because it is not easy to
understand how policies implemented in different sectors, geographical locations, and
timing interact with each other (Lenihan, 1999; Wren, 2007).
8 More specifically in relation to randomized controlled trials (RCTs), they can be useful techniques for
evaluating policies that are implemented at the local level because they have fewer problems with selection
bias than observational methods do. However, they tend to be less effective when we want to evaluate
policies, like industrial policy, whose aim is to generate spillovers and long term impacts. Even when RCTs
have strong “internal validity,” meaning that they are very likely to have identified the effect of treatment
among the participants (e.g. certain firms receiving a research grant), they are less likely than observational
methods to have “external validity”, meaning that the causal effect found among the participants may not
apply to other groups (Rodrik, 2008). Also, because most randomized controlled trial studies cannot
measure the outcomes very frequently, the evaluators may miss the true causal effect if the policy has a
nonlinear effect, as it is often the case (Woolcock, 2009).
19
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
20
Moreover, our definition and discussions above emphasised that, while industrial policy
may target certain industries (or even firms), this is done ultimately for the benefit of the
overall economy – a lot of selective industrial policy is about externalities, linkages,
coordination, and shifts across industries, with the aim of upgrading the structure of the
entire economy. If this is the case, it will be wrong to evaluate industrial policy only in
terms of its direct outcomes in the targeted industries. We also need to look at its indirect
impacts on the rest of the economy by adopting system-level evaluation techniques. For
example, when we assess the industrial policy of a particular country, we need to look at
things like its ability to generate new technologies, make structural shifts, and compete in
the world market, and not just what is going on in the targeted industries. All of these will
be ultimately reflected in the country’s growth rate, but it is a rather catch-all indicator, so
we may have to supplement it with more specific indicators regarding things like the
(overall and sectoral) balance of payments, changes in the share of manufacturing in
total output, or the changes in the world market share overall and, in particular, ‘leading’
industries with technological dynamism and demand expansion (see, for example,
UNIDO, 2002 and 2013).
The problem of evaluating industrial policies does not end with the difficulties related to
addressing systemic effects (such as displacement effects or linkage effects) of the
policy. An added layer of problem is that the evaluation framework has to account for the
existence of long-run effects arising from cumulative dynamics (Wren, 2007). Even if we
recognize the existence of ‘time lags’ – and thus of qualitative transformations,
discontinuities, truncations, and reversals – we still have to explicitly take into account the
question of time scale – that is, the amount of time that firms require to build productive
capabilities (as a result of, say, an infant industry policy) and move from low- to medium-
and high-tech industries (Andreoni, 2011).
These time issues become increasingly complex when we attempt an evaluation of a full
package of industrial policies but are also extremely relevant even in the more narrow
evaluation of specific policies, such as the increasingly widely-adopted randomised
control trials. This technique implicitly assumes that the effect of a certain treatment (i.e.,
policy) unfolds in a ‘proper’ way, that is, in a monotonically increasing and linear manner.
However, this is not often the case, and therefore we can come out with completely
different evaluation results, depending on the moment we compare the observed (e.g.
treated firms) and the counterfactual (non-treated firms). As Woolcock (2009) highlighted,
“[w]e know we need ‘baseline’ (at time t0) and follow-up data (at time t1), but the content
and shape of the proverbial ‘black box’ connecting these data points remains wholly a
mystery, to the development industry’s peril” (p. 3).
This section has reviewed various issues related to the evaluation of industrial policy.
Problems related to actually identifying the targeted sectors and the benefits they
received were discussed. We also pointed out the problem arising from the systemic
nature of industrial policy – linkages, displacements, and other interactions between
industries make it difficult to evaluate a sectoral policy purely in terms of its impacts on
the targeted sector. Time factors – problems associated with time lags and time scales –
also need to be considered. All of these issues, of course, do not mean that we should
not, or cannot, evaluate industrial policy. Good evaluation is necessary to improve policy.
However, they mean that we need to use a plurality of both quantitative and qualitative
evaluation tools and be cautious about any evaluation result.
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
3. Country case studies
3.1. Japan: the quintessential example
Japan is not the only country that has successfully used industrial policy. However, it
occupies a special place in the modern debate on industrial policy in the sense that it is
the rise of Japan as an industrial powerhouse between the 1960s and the 1980s that
prompted such debate (the early debate is summarised in Chang, 1994a, ch. 3).
Japan’s industrial policy remained lopsided and unsystematic until the Second World
War, being constrained by external forces (the country could not use tariff protection until
1911, when the so-called unequal treaties, signed upon the forced opening of 1853,
expired) and driven by unrealistic imperialist ambitions, which over-developed the heavy
and chemical industries (on pre-WWII Japanese industrial policy, see Allen, 1981;
Johnson, 1982; Macpherson, 1987). Until the Second World War, Japan was actually on
the whole not the economic superstar that it later became. Between 1900 and 1950,
Japan’s per capita income growth rate was only 1% p.a., which was below the average
for the 16 largest now-OECD economies, which was 1.3% p.a. (Maddison, 1989).9
Japan went through an extremely difficult patch following the end of WWII, in which
output collapsed by almost half (from the peak of $2,897 in 1941 to $1,555 in 1946, GDP
per capita in 1990 dollar; Maddison, 2001, p. 206, table A-j) and enterprises were in such
a state that even Toyota had to be bailed out with public money (in 1949). It started to
recover rapidly from 1950, partly thanks to the export boom due to the Korean War
(1950-3), but until the late-1950s, the country was still not very developed – its biggest
export item was still silk and silk-related products and its export products were bywords
for shoddy products.
However, from the 1950s, the Japanese government used strong industrial policy to
develop higher value-added industries, such as steel, automobile, electronics, and
machinery (further details can be found in Magaziner & Hout, 1980; Johnson, 1982; Hall,
1986; Dore, 1986; Okimoto, 1989).10
The Japanese government did not give much outright subsidies (thus making some
people who equate industrial policy with subsidies believe that it did not have much
industrial policy), but provided long-term finances through the Japanese Development
Bank (JDB) and other public financial institutions, such as the Long-Term Credit Bank of
Japan and the Industrial Bank of Japan. Protectionist measures (tariffs and quantitative
restrictions) were actively used, while the country had arguably the world’s toughest
regulations on FDI (Chang, 2004) and on technology imports (to make sure that imported
technologies were not overly outdated and the royalties paid were reasonable). The
targeted industries were often also provided with subsidies for export, investment, R&D,
and utility bills, while also being given preferential tax breaks (Goto & Wakasugi, 1988).
9 The 16 countries are Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy,
Japan, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, the UK, and the USA.
10 Even some measures that are frequently thought to be Japanese inventions are, when we go back in
history, not so – for example, export promotion through tariff rebate on inputs used for exported goods,
which many believe to be a postwar Japanese invention, is a measure that was actively used by the UK in
the 18th century, especially by the government of Robert Walpole (see Chang, 2002, on the history of
development policy in today’s rich countries).
21
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
The Japanese government also used indicative planning and foreign exchange rationing.
Laws were introduced in the 1950s to prevent large firms from abusing their monopsony
or oligopsony positions to squeeze their suppliers, which prompted the large firms to
invest in enhancing the capabilities of their suppliers (e.g., some equity participation,
secondment of technicians), rather than constantly squeezing them and thus depriving
them of the resources to invest in capability enhancement.
The Japanese performance after the 1950s, especially during the “Golden Age of
Capitalism” (1950-73), was simply spectacular. During this period, per capita income in
Japan grew at the amazing rate of 8.05%, which is more than double the average of the
12 European countries (3.93%).11 It was over 3% points higher than the second-best
performer, West Germany (5.02%), and over 3 times higher than that of the USA
(2.45%). By the 1970s, Japan started breaking into markets that had until then been
considered the exclusive domains of only Europe and North America – automobile, steel,
shipbuilding, electronics, and so on. By the 1990s, Japanese products, represented by
Toyota’s luxury car, Lexus, had become synonymous with quality, innovative design, and
reliability.
Behind the success of these industrial policies were the corporate governance and
financing structures that made long-term-oriented investments possible. Between the
mid-1960s and the late 1990s, Japanese companies insulated themselves from short-
termist pressures through cross-shareholding among friendly enterprises, which
accounted for 35-50% of all Japanese shares during this period (it is still 20% today, after
two decades of battering by economic recession). Banks were closely involved with
enterprises and provided not only ‘patient capital’ but also de facto management
consultancy for smaller firms, which could not afford them in the open market. The ‘core’
workers – roughly, 2/3 of the workers in large firms and 1/3 of them in the smaller ones –
were integrated into the enterprise governance structure through the granting of lifetime
employment and opportunities for consultation. With more cooperative workforces, firms
found it easier to restructure themselves and thus minimised the need for hostile
takeover.
As we mentioned earlier, in today’s industrial policy debate, Japan plays the role of the
benchmark. However, many of the industrial policy measures used by the Japanese
government until 1990 were not very different from the ones used by other governments.
And we are not talking about countries like Korea, Taiwan, and China, which emulated
Japanese industrial policy to one degree or another, but we are also talking about most
of other developed countries today, including Britain (between the mid-18th to the mid-
19th century), the US (between the mid-19th and the mid-20th century), Germany (in the
late 19th and the early 20th century), and post-WWII France (see Chang, 2002, for further
details).
However, this is not to say that Japan was only repeating what other countries had done
before. Japan’s postwar industrial policy involved some important policy ‘innovations’.
Two things are notable here.
One notable Japanese innovation is the establishment of deliberation councils for policy-
making in key industries, comprising the government officials, industry representatives,
and more ‘objective’ observers (e.g., journalists, academics). These councils are said to
11 The 12 countries are Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands,
Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, and the UK.
22
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
have made industrial policy more effective by improving information flows between the
government and the private sector, on the one hand, and between the private sector
firms themselves, on the other hand.
Another Japanese innovation, or rather improvement over past practices of its own and in
other countries, is the improved technique of managing cartels. Rather than regarding all
cartels as negative, as has the US done, the Japanese government recognised that
cartels can help industrial development by reducing ‘wasteful competition’ that destroys
profit and undermines the capacities to invest and innovate in the long run. Of course, the
problem, as Japan itself (and many European countries) had seen in the pre-war period,
is that cartels can also become conservative forces that prevent progress. Therefore, in
the postwar period, the Japanese government tried to minimise this problem by allowing
cartels only under clear conditions in terms of their aims (e.g., avoiding duplicative
investments, upgrading technology, avoiding price wars in the export market, orderly
phasing-out of declining industries) and life spans.
The stock market crash of 1990, followed by the so-called ‘lost decade’, triggered
profound changes in the government approach to industrial policies (OECD, 1998; Nezu,
2007).12 Overall, industrial policy became less targeted at the sectoral level and more
decentralised to the regional level. For example, between 1989 and 1993, SME
development, R&D investments and export credit insurance programmes accounted for
almost 90% of total expenditure. Policy interventions for SMEs programmes alone were
half of the total budget and were managed and financed by regional governments.13
Funds for sectoral policies targeting, focused on the energy, computer and shipbuilding
industries, accounted for less than 10%.
During the mid-1990s, the industrial policy agenda became increasingly dominated by
the deregulation agenda, further weakening the traditional industrial policy framework. In
2000, this change in the industrial policy approach culminated in the institutional
transformation of the MITI (Ministry of International Trade and Industry) into the METI
(Ministry of Economy, Trade and Industry) and, later, with an amendment to the
Japanese Corporate Law that allowed mergers and acquisitions (M&A) by foreign
companies of Japanese enterprises through swapping of stocks. Despite these changes,
considerable amount of industrial policy has continued in the two new key areas of SME
promotion and innovation.
SMEs have always played a key role in the Japanese economy as suppliers of
components and intermediate inputs to internationally successful large firms, especially
in the automotive, electronics and other assembly industries. However, in the stagnation
12 In the last two decades, the Japanese economy has not done as well as the four decades preceding it.
However, its economic performance, especially in the 2000s, has not been as bad as people often think.
First of all, despite two decades of lacklustre growth, at 4-5%, its rate of unemployment has remained one
of the lowest in the OECD. In terms of growth, during the 1990s, at 1.0%, Japan was the second most
slowly-growing economy (in per capita terms) in the OECD (the slowest was Switzerland at 0%). In the
2000s, however, its performance was basically median among the 16 core OECD countries (see footnote 2
above for the list). Its annual per capita GDP growth rate, at 0.9%, was higher than that of Italy (-0.3%),
Denmark (0.5%), and France (0.6%) and basically the same as those of the US, the UK, Canada, Belgium,
and Norway (all 1.0%) and only marginally lower than those of Germany and Switzerland (both 1.1%).
During this period, Australia and Finland did best at 1.8%, followed by Sweden (1.6%), Austria (1.4%), and
the Netherlands (1.2%).
13 Over the 1990s, only 37 of the 235 implemented programmes were administered by the central
government.
23
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
of the 1990s and the early years of the 2000s14, they were particularly stressed by the
slow growth of internal demand and the increasingly competitive international
environment. During this period, Japanese SMEs were indirectly helped by the injection
of public funds into the banking sector, which enabled them to have access to low
interest-rate borrowing. On top of that, the Japanese government deployed a
comprehensive package of industrial and innovation policies under the coordination of
the METI’s council for SMEs, in order to promote start-ups and boost the innovation
capacities of existing SMEs. Various forms of subsidies (such as favourable tax
treatment for R&D investment) and regulatory reforms (such as the removal of the
minimum capital requirement for start-ups) were mixed with measures aiming at nurturing
the science and technological infrastructure.
From 2001 to 2010, the Science & Technology Plan had a budget of almost 50 trillion yen
(very roughly £400 billion), which were invested in four major priority areas: life science,
ICT, environment, and nanotech/materials. Also, a number of industries were identified
as key for satisfying future social needs. They are: robots, fuel cells, digital content, and
digital consumer electronics. METI’s policy targets and selection of key technologies
were underpinned by a strategic technology roadmap. Among the policy measures,
particular emphasis was given to the establishment of ‘regional consortium clusters’
(defined as networks of regional industries, on the one hand, co-located universities and
research centres, on the other), linked by both cooperative and competitive relationships
(Weiss, 2005; Goto & Kodama, 2006). Finally, in 2006, the new policy initiative for
competitiveness and productivity encapsulated in the idea of an ‘Innovation Super High-
Way’ for Japan stressed the importance of strengthening the linkages between science,
technology and industry.
3.2. Germany: the teacher?
Especially given its influence on Japanese industrial policy, Germany is often considered
to be the ‘teacher’ for Japan. This was true, however, only in the old days. After WWII,
Germany’s industrial policy was considerably different from that of Japan or of other
European countries such as France, Italy and the UK, as we shall see below.
During the first two decades after the WWII, Germany’s recovery was driven by those
industries in which the country had a long-standing competitive advantage and it was
sustained by the high demand of investment goods from the rest of Europe. Between
1950 and 1970, investments remained high at 22-24% of national income, while exports
rose from 9% to 19% of national income.
After the war, the giant chemical company, I.G. Farben, was broken up into Bayer,
Hoechst (now part of Aventis), Agfa, and BASF. These companies allowed Germany to
regain a world leading position in the modern science-based chemical industry. In
electrical engineering Siemens quickly became a European leader in power engineering,
telecommunications and other electronics. The non-electrical machinery and, more
broadly, machine tools industries developed thanks to a dense network of highly
productive small and medium sized firms, the so-called Mittelstand, supported by a whole
array of public and quasi-public institutions (see below).
14 It is reported that, between 1991 and 2004, ‘the percentage of closure of enterprises was systematically
higher than the percentage of new business launches’ (Buigues & Sekkat, 2009, p.188).
24
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
The German model (Modell Deutschland), as Helmut Schmidt called it in the 1970s, was
developed during the first two decades after the WWII thanks to an articulated package
of industrial policies operating both at the national and regional (Lander and
municipalities) levels. The German industrial policy mainly focused on four axes:
regulation of the labour market, the development of an integrated vocational training
system, creation of a basic science and industrial research infrastructure, and public
support for industrial finance.
In the early 1950s, the Works Constitution Act and the Collective Bargaining Law
introduced a set of legally binding sectoral collective bargaining agreements between
employers’ associations and unions. These agreements introduced a ‘labour constraint’
for employers with respect to the remuneration, mandated or state-provided social
security benefits, working condition, dismissal of workers, and rights of work councils
(Muller-Jentsch, 1995; Vitols, 1997; Feldenkirchen, 1999).
Such measures had four main effects. Firstly, they guaranteed a low level of wage
dispersion across firms, much lower than those of the US, the UK, and even Japan, and
even declining throughout the 1980s (OECD, 1993; Streeck, 1992). Second, they
encouraged long-term attachment of employees to firms – for example, in 1993, the
average length of employment was 7.5 years, as against 4.4 years in the UK and 3 years
in the US. Low turn-over, in turn, encouraged firms to invest in developing firm-specific
skills and in retraining (Abraham & Houseman, 1993). Third, these measures enabled
work councils to get involved in firms’ strategic decisions regarding the introduction of
new technologies or organisations, hiring and firing, mass layoffs, working hours, and
early retirement pensions. Finally, they prevented companies, especially those exposed
to international competition, from building their competitiveness on lower wage costs,
producing a ‘productivity whip’, whereby less productive companies were forced to
change or to leave the market (Vitols, 1997).
The potential competitive disadvantages introduced by strict labour regulations were
counterbalanced by a set of measures aimed at providing companies with a highly skilled
labour force. Differently from the US and the UK, the public vocational training system
was expanded and training standards upgraded throughout the three decades after
WWII. The so-called ‘dual’ training system was based on the idea of mixing company-
based training with theoretical instruction in specialised vocational schools. In 1969, the
Vocational Training Law regulated apprenticeship contracts by defining company’s duties
as well as by assigning the responsibility to supervise and assess the achievement of
certain training standards to Chamber of Commerce and Industry or Chambers of
Artisans, the latter funded by compulsory fees for all companies.
While this integrated vocational training system increased the functional flexibility of
workers and their adaptability to technological change, a series of laws were passed for
alleviating the tensions arising from more radical structural changes as well as from
business cycles (e.g. the Work Promotion Act in 1969). For example, adjustments to
short-term demand contractions were dealt with through reductions of the average hours
worked instead of reductions in the number of workers (Abraham & Houseman, 1993).
During the crises in the mid- 1970s, beginning of the 1980s, and the early 1990s,
regional labour offices widely resorted to subsidies for shorter working hours or even to
early retirement schemes, to keep unemployment down. The latter were particularly
important for facilitating the maintenance of a balanced age structure, especially in
traditional sectors (Vitols, 1997; Feldenkirchen, 1999).
25
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
From the mid- 60s until the mid- 70s Germany’s investments in basic science and
industrial research tended to be sectoral and technology-targeted. In 1962 the Ministry
for Atomic Questions was converted into the Ministry of Research and Technology
(BTFM). Three major industrial strategies were implemented. The first was on data
processing and computer hardware development, which channeled resources mainly to
Siemens. The second was on nuclear power, focusing on fast breeder reactors. Third,
both the federal and land governments heavily supported civil aircraft projects through
subsidies and organised ‘rationalisation’ and concentration, which led to the creation of
the MBB group, later one of the main partners in the Airbus consortium (Owen, 2012).
Even when the federal government decided to privatise national companies – starting
from the 1960s (e.g. Volkswagen and VEBA) and increasingly since the 1980s (e.g.
Deutsche Telekom AG and Deutsche Post AG).15 – the Länder governments often
maintained their shares in the company, as in the case of Volkswagen (the government
of Lower Saxony) (Fasbender, 2004; OECD, 2003; TUC, 2011).
Since the mid-1970s, the German government increasingly developed its public R&D
infrastructure built around two publicly funded networks of institutes, the Fraunhofer
Society and the Max Planck Society. Fraunhofer institutes were explicitly aimed at filling
the gap between basic science and company-based industrial research and at
overcoming the disadvantages and scale bottlenecks faced by Mittlestand companies,
that is, firms with a number of employees between 100 and 500. This public technological
infrastructure was also complemented by a network of sectoral and local associations,
focused on technology transfer, provision of training, and organization of focus groups for
problem-identification and cooperative problem-solving.
The last pillar of the German model was a banking system focused on long-term lending
to industry. During the 1950s, the German government built a number of public or quasi-
public special-purpose banks, whose functioning and mandate adapted over the years
with the changing needs of industries. For example, the Bank for Reconstruction (KfW),
founded in 1947, increasingly moved away from direct lending and became a long-term
refinance bank specialized in lending to banks strongly linked with industrial
companies.16 The Mittelstand companies were mainly served by the German Bank for
Settlements (AG) as well as by a strong network of public saving banks and credit
cooperatives, linked by a ‘three tier’ organizational structure, which allowed them to
overcome scale disadvantages by aggregating credit demands (as well as savings) at the
upper tiers (regional or national) while remaining strongly embedded in the local
community.
The German Model went through important changes since the 1980s due to internal
dissatisfaction and the re-unification.
In 1982, Helmut Kohl began to reduce the role of the government by cutting public
expenditure and taxes as well as partially de-regulating the labour market.17 These
measures, coupled with a massive privatization, involving sales of shares of companies
15 In the 1960s, additional shares of some state-owned companies (Volkswagen, VEBA, etc.) were issued at
sub-par value so that they could be bought by people with limited incomes for a preferential price. These
shares were called people’s shares (Volksaktien). This procedure enabled some 4.5 million Germans to
become shareholders with a total amount of roughly 500 million Euro. Later on, this complicated procedure
(because of the necessity of reviewing the income situation of purchasers) was changed (Fasbender, 2004).
16 Today KfM is still owned by the Federation (80%) and the Lander (20%).
17 The measures aimed at introducing higher degrees of flexibility in the labour market and reducing
unemployment rates were also at the core of Schroder’s Agenda 2010.
26
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
like Volkswagen and Lufthansa, reduced the size of the government from 52% to 46% of
GDP between 1982 and 1990.
With the reunification, the government adopted a dual system of industrial policy:
continuity of the industrial policy for West Germany (alte/old Länder) and policies directed
towards East Germany (Neue/new Länder) (OECD, 1998). The industrial policy
measures in East Germany focused on the creation and development of new SMEs (both
in manufacturing and services), infrastructural investments, and the privatisation and
rationalisation of state owned enterprises (SOEs) (the public agency in charge was
Treuhand Gesellschaft). In West Germany, industrial policy has remained very much
focused on existing Mittelstand companies and their innovative capacity, especially those
large medium-size companies (up to 1,000 employees), known as ‘hidden champions’,
many of which dominate global niches, with 40%-90% of the global market shares
(Simon, 1996; Venohr & Meyer, 2007).
The exact extent and details of Germany industrial policy are difficult to ascertain, as
there are many different measures and actors (federation, Länder or municipalities) and
different statistics cover different things.18 However, it is fair to say that it has one of the
most active industrial policies in Europe (Karl et al., 2003).
Even with recent changes, the German public sector still owns important shares in
companies and uses public procurement strategically. In 2006, the federal government
had important direct holdings of more than 25% in 33 enterprises and owned some
shares in further 112 enterprises. Resources obtained through privatisation have been
used, especially by Länder governments, for venture capital and public support for
innovation.19 Public procurements are, while transparent, strategically designed. For
example, they prescribe the use of certain materials, technologies or compliance to
certain standards, which enables the government to promote certain types of companies
or technologies.
Despite the maintenance of the basic policy framework, there has been a major shift in
German industrial policy since the mid-1990s. Almost half the public spending on
industrial policy has been devoted to environmental sustainability, energy efficiency, and
renewable energy. Also, the support for the enhancement of the innovation capacities
and synergies of Mittelstand companies has been further strengthened, as testified by
the ZIM project for Mittlestand and the BioRegio programme aimed at the creation of
regional public-private partnerships.
3.3. The US: the real pioneer
In the contemporary debate on industrial policy, the US is often considered to be the
antithesis of Japan and the other East Asian countries in this respect. Whether they
praise the US model or criticise it, most commentators start from the assumption – and it
is no more than an assumption, as we shall see below – that the US does not have much
18 The German government’s statistics include financial subsidies, interest free-grants, subsidies for R&D
and (increasingly) tax reliefs as public industry support. However, aids to SOEs or semi-public institutions as
well as funds for basic research and institutes such as Fraunhofer, Max Planck, Leibnitz and Helmholtz are
not included (Buigues & Sekkat, 2009).
19 The emphasis and destination of resources to high tech and innovation is also detailed in the recent
Government Report on ‘The High Tech Strategy for Germany’ 2010.
27
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
industrial policy. However, the US has employed a huge amount of industrial policy
throughout its history.
First of all, from its early days, the US was a pioneer of industrial policy (Chang, 2002
and 2007; Rauchway, 2007). One key justification of industrial policy we mentioned
above – the infant industry argument – was invented by none other than the first
American finance minister (Treasury Secretary), Alexander Hamilton, in his 1791 Report
on the subject of Manufactures by the Treasury Secretary. The Report was, contrary to
what many believe, not narrowly focused on tariff protection but discussed a whole range
of (general and selective) industrial policy measures, including targeted subsidies,
infrastructural development, financial development (the banking system, the government
bond market), and the promotion of innovation through the development of the patent
system.
Although it took a few decades since the publication of the Report before the pro-
industrial-policy faction in US politics became strong enough to implement Hamilton’s
programme, from the 1830s, the US remained the most protectionist country in the world
until World War II. Although its tariff protection lacked the careful selectivity of its East
Asian counterpart, it was not a blanket protection either, as some sectors were more
protected than others. Especially between the mid-19th century and the mid-20th century,
the US government also invested heavily in infrastructure (e.g., the Pacific Railways, the
mid-western canals), higher education (e.g., land grant colleges), and R&D (especially in
agriculture), all with a considerable degree of explicit and implicit targeting.
Even after WWII, when the country attained industrial supremacy and started
championing the cause of free trade and free markets, the US did not abandon industrial
policy. Throughout the Cold War period, the US implemented a comprehensive industrial
policy package including long-term procurement contracts, subsidies, investment
guarantees, and strategic bailouts (Markusen, 1996). However, the post-WWII world
order made it necessary for the US to play the role of new hegemon of the ‘free trade’
system and of the defender of the ‘free enterprise’ system against Communism, so it had
to pretend that it was not engaged in industrial policy. As a result, industrial policy in the
US after WWII was conducted under other names – defence policy, health policy,
agricultural policy, and what have you – prompting the eminent American economic
sociologist Fred Block to talk of a ‘hidden developmental state’ (Block, 2008).
Post-WWII US industrial policy was also strongly focused on translating cutting-edge
technological research, much of which was generated through massive public funding of
R&D (especially in defence and health), into commercial use. This was achieved through
cooperation among a network of people with high levels of technological expertise –
variously situated in state agencies (e.g. the ARPA [Advanced Projects Research
Agency] of the Pentagon, the NIHs [National Institutes of Health], the NSF [National
Science Foundation], and NASA [National Aeronautics and Space Administration]),
industries, universities, and other research institutes. Between the 1950s and 1980s, the
share of government funding in total R&D in the supposedly free-market US accounted
for, depending on the year, between 47% and 65%, as against around 20% in Japan and
Korea and less than 40% in several European countries (e.g., Belgium, Finland,
Germany, Sweden).20
20 The share of federal government in total R&D spending in the US was 53.6% in 1953, 56.8% in 1955,
64.6% in 1960, 64.9% in 1965, 57.1% in 1970, 51.7% in 1975, 47.2% in 1980, 47.9% in 1985, and 47.3%
in 1989 (estimated). See Mowery & Rosenberg, 1993, p. 41, table 2.3.
28
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
More recently, R&D funding has taken the form of grants, deferral of liability, tax
provisions and exemption (62% of which was spent on accelerated depreciation of
machinery and equipment). During the 2000s, these industrial policy tools were
structured within three main programmes. The first of these programmes, the Advanced
Technology Program (ATP), managed by the National Institute of Standards and
Technology (based under the US Commerce Department), focuses on the specific
industrial technological needs and promotes private-public sectors partnerships, early-
stage investment and risk-sharing in order to promote innovative technologies.21 The
second programme, called the Small Business Innovation Research (SBIR), supports
small technology companies by funding early-stage R&D projects and guaranteeing them
full IPRs on the new technologies they develop, even though it was partly funded by the
SBIR. To be eligible for this programme, companies must be American owned,
employing less than 500 employees and being for profit. The third programme, that is,
the Small Business Technology Transfer (STTR) addresses the same company types
but, differently from the SBIR, it funds only R&D collaborations among a plurality of
institutions and organisations (university, federally-funded R&D centres, non-profit
research institutes) (Buigues & Sekkat, 2009)
Direct measures in support of R&D and SMEs are coupled with both trade policies and a
strategic use of public procurements by local (that is ‘state’) governments. As for the
former policy, bilateral agreements are used for opening new markets for American firms
but, also, for restricting foreign competition and providing short-term economic reliefs to
industries under stress. Even though antidumping and countervailing duty measures
have been less frequently used since 2001, sectors such as agriculture, textiles forest
products and steel have known various forms of protection or were subsidised (WTO,
2006; Ketels, 2007). As for demand side industrial policies, that is, public procurements,
each local governments has its own procurement agency and defines its strategy
independently under the overall supervision of the Office of Management and Budget
(OMB). Some states assign preferences to local manufacturers or set local contents
requirements.
Unfortunately, the ‘clandestine’ nature of post-WWII US industrial policy has meant that it
has suffered from unstable funding, lack of coordination across different policy areas and
between different actors, and excessive commoditisation of knowledge (Block, 2008;
Ketels, 2007). In 2006, for instance, while the American Competitiveness Initiative
established by President Bush announced a renewed commitment to science and
technology policy, the Congress reversed this decision and proceeded with spending
cuts in many programmes (Buigues & Sekkat, 2009, p. 172).
However, on the whole, post-war industrial policy in the US has been quite successful, as
testified to by the fact that the majority of the industries in which the US has international
competitiveness have been developed through public funding of R&D and public
procurement, especially in the names of ‘defence’ (computer, semiconductors22, aircraft,
21 The positive and significant impact of the ATP projects on multi-use innovation, infrastructural
technologies and inter-industry licensing is assessed in Nail and Brown (2006).
22 Semiconductors were first developed through US defense research funding. When the two main firms –
Fairchild and Texas Instruments – subsequently got locked in costly patent suits, the US Department of
Defense intervened to resolve the situation by imposing a patent pool between the two companies
(Perelman, 2003, p. 56). The US government gave the industry a further boost by setting up SEMATECH,
a joint venture of 12 firms with ARPA funding, in 1987 set up as a means to fight off the Japanese
technological challenge (see Block, 2008, on SEMATECH).
29
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
internet) and ‘health’ (drugs, genetic engineering) (Medeiros, 2003; Block, 2008;
Mazzucato, 2011; Pisano & Shih, 2012).
3.4. Korea: the most dramatic example
Between the 1960s and the 1980s, Korean industrial policy has followed a trajectory that
is very similar to the Japanese one, but in a much more dramatic fashion than the
Japanese one. This was partly out of necessity – Korea, technologically being so much
more behind than Japan was, needed more forceful government intervention if it were to
raise internationally competitive firms. However, it was also because, for historical
reasons23 the private sector was far weaker than in Japan so that the Korean
government was far less constrained in dictating the private sector than its Japanese
counterpart did.
Korean industrial policy-making and -implementation were also more centralised than the
Japanese ones (see Chang, 1993, for further details). The Korean planning ministry, the
Economic Planning Board (EPB), which was ultimately in charge of industrial policy
(although the Ministry of Commerce and Industry executed many of the policy
measures), was much more powerful than the Japanese planning agency (not even a full
ministry), the Economic Planning Agency. The EPB even controlled the government
budget, which is in most countries including Japan the turf of the finance ministry. As a
result, Korea’s ‘indicative’ planning (the Five Year Plans for Economic Development,
practised between 1962 and 1993) – and industrial policy as a key component of it – was
much more directive than the Japanese or even the French counterparts. As in Japan,
deliberation councils existed, but the private sector firms had much less influence in their
decisions than their Japanese counterparts.
Especially in the early days of the country’s economic development, the Korean private
sector was totally at the mercy of government rationing of credit and foreign exchanges.
Credit rationing was possible because all banks, and not just special-purpose banks as in
the case of Japan, were state-owned until 1983 and because even the privatised ones
were in effect controlled by the government through heavy regulations until the early
1990s.24 Foreign exchange rationing was conducted through the so-called ‘foreign
exchange budgeting’ system, which was based on legally mandated government
monopoly of all foreign exchange transactions until the early 1990s (see Chang, 1993, for
details). This gave the government a huge leverage over private sector companies, as
Korea’s then low level of technological development and its paucity of raw materials
meant that, without access to foreign exchanges, companies could not acquire necessary
capital goods, intermediate goods, or raw materials.
23 Compared to Japan, Korea had a shorter history of capitalism, having been forced to open up to the
outside world only in 1876, as opposed to 1853, in the case of Japan. Also, during the colonial rule by
Japan (1910-45), growth of Korean capitalists was discouraged, if not made impossible. The political and
social turmoils that followed the end of the colonial rule and the Korean War (1950-53) also resulted in a lot
of churning in the enterprise hierarchy. On top of that, the government of General Park Chung Hee, which
came to power in a coup d’etat in 1961, nationalised all banks in 1961 (see Amsden, 1989, for historical
backgrounds to Korean industrialisation).
24 For example, until the early 1990s, the government de facto decided who are going to become the top
managers of the banks.
30
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
The infant industries were heavily protected from imports – average manufacturing tariff
rates were 30-40% until the 1970s and quantitative restrictions (e.g., import quotas)
abounded well into the late 1980s (Chang, 1993 and 2005). Foreign exchange rationing
also gave producers manufacturing consumer goods some ‘natural’ protection, as
imports of those goods were far down the priority list in the government foreign exchange
budget and therefore they could often not be imported due to the lack of the means to
pay for it, not due to import controls and tariffs. Sometimes domestic taxes (e.g., luxury
consumption tax) were used to restrain the imports of luxury consumption goods, even
though their tariffs were not ‘prohibitive’ – in the 1980s, Scotch Whiskies, which had ‘only’
100% tariff, fetched 9 times world market prices (Chang, 1993).
Domestic producers in strategic sectors were also protected from competition from TNCs
producing in Korea, as there were regulations on FDI that were almost as strict as the
Japanese ones (Chang, 1998). There were also regulations on technology licensing
(both in terms of the quality and the price of the imported technology). As in the
Japanese case, the purpose was eventually developing local producers with world-class
productive capabilities.
Unlike in Japan, where there have been no significant SOEs in the manufacturing sector
since the early 20th century, the government in Korea did not mind using SOEs when
necessary. The most prominent example in this regard is the now-privatised (privatised in
2000) POSCO (Pohang Steel Company), which was the second largest steel producer in
the world until the recent mega-mergers in the world’s steel industry and still the fourth
largest.25
The Korean government was also a lot more involved in corporate restructuring in the
private sector than the Japanese government was, not least because stock market
regulations made hostile Mergers and acquisitions (M&A) virtually impossible. Especially
when business downturns put firms into the danger zone, the Korean government would
wade in to initiate M&A and production rationalisation (see Chang, 1993 and 2006, for
further details). The state-owned development bank (Korea Development Bank) played a
key role in the process, sometimes providing subsidised loans on extended maturity to
firms under restructuring and sometimes taking a stake in those firms (sometimes even
majority stakes, thereby in effect nationalising the firms in question).
Since the 1990s, the Korean industrial policy has gone through some dramatic changes –
mostly decline (see Chang & Evans, 2005, for further details), although we may be
entering a period of at least partial revival with the new government (as of 2013) showing
distinctively more interest in industrial policy than any government since the mid-1990s.
Strongly influenced by neo-liberal ideologies propagated by US-trained free-market
economists and intense lobbying by the private-sector conglomerates (the so-called
25 When the Korean government decided in 1968 to apply to build its first modern steel mill, the World Bank
advised a group of donor countries to decline the application on the grounds that the project was not viable.
This was not an unreasonable advice, given the circumstances. The country’s biggest export items at the
time were fish, cheap apparels, wigs, and plywood. The country did not even possess deposits of the key
raw materials of iron ore and coking coal. At the time, it could not even import them from nearby China
because of the Cold War, so they had to be imported from Australia and Canada. And, to cap it all, the
Korean government proposed to run this as an SOE. A perfect recipe for disaster from the mainstream
view, but the company became the most efficient steel-producer in the world within 10 years of
establishment and is now the second largest steel producer in the world. For further details on POSCO,
see Amsden (1989) and Chang (2010, ch. 12).
31
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
chaebols) increasingly impatient to break away from state control, the Korean
government started scaling down industrial policy since 1993. The most symbolic of this
move were the termination of the Five Year Plan in 1993 and the abolition of the
Economic Planning Board (EPB) in 1994 (it was merged with the Ministry of Finance).
There was a further round of reduction of industrial policy following the 1997 financial
crisis, which established neo-liberal ideological hegemony in the country. One important
result of this round of reform was the transfer of international trade policy remit from the
Ministry of Trade and Industry (MOTI) to the Ministry of Foreign Affairs (MOFA), which
signalled that the government now understood international trade to be a matter of
diplomatic negotiation (based on the international consensus that completely free trade is
the goal) rather than an element of industrial policy.26
Capital market liberalisation since 1997 has exerted short-term pressures on companies
and has negatively influenced the private sector’s role in investment and R&D. Between
1998 and 2010, private gross fixed capital formation (GFCF) as a percentage of GDP
averaged 18.4%, a significant step down from the 23.7% between 1990 and 1997
(OECD, 2012c). The share of gross domestic expenditure on R&D (GERD) that was
financed by the private sector also declined from 76.3% in 1995 to 71.8% in 2010
(OECD, 2012a).
Despite this general trend towards the diminution of industrial policy in the last two
decades, the practice of designating certain industries as ‘strategic’ and providing
targeted supports has continued in Korea, albeit at a lower key. Bio-tech, nano-tech, and
green-tech industries have been subject to such support, in the forms of R&D funding,
credit guarantees and public funding for training (especially for the green-tech industries)
(Kim & Koh, 2010). While these supports were not of the scope and scale of pre-1990s
industrial policy, they were not insignificant either. The share of public spending in total
R&D spending has crept up from the traditional 20% region to 26.7% in 2010. Given the
continuous rise of R&D spending as a share of GDP in Korea in the recent decades, this
means that the country, at 1.00% in 2010, has one of the highest government-financed
R&D as a proportion of GDP in the world, behind Austria (1.08%) and Iceland (1.03%),
tying with Finland, and above the OECD average of 0.74%. Since the late 1990s, there
have also been attempts to develop industrial clusters in economically weaker regions
(MKE, 2010; OECD, 2012b), but these have not been very successful, due to the lack of
the thick institutional networks present in countries like Germany and Italy that have been
the most successful with those policies.
26 This change has been reversed by the in-coming government (as of 2013), which is one clear signal that
it takes industrial policy more seriously than recent governments.
32
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
3.5. Singapore: the ultimate pragmatist
Not least because of its status as a small27 city-state without natural resources,
Singapore’s industrial policy has been very different from those of other East Asian
countries, but in many ways the most successful – its per capita GDP (at current market
prices) rose from US$516 in 1965 (when it gained independence) to US$50,123 in 2011
(SDOS, 2012). As of 2010, it had become the most industrialised country in the world,
producing the highest MVA in the world (see Table 1).
Singapore’s small domestic market (2 million people at the time of separation from
Malaysia in 1965) meant that it had to rely exceptionally heavily on external demand to
industrialise.28 Accepting this, the country adopted a free-trade regime, making its
industrial policy regime very different from those of the other East Asian countries.
Moreover, given the paucity of local entrepreneurial talent and the lack of industrial
technology, the Singapore government decided to work with TNCs much more closely
than the other East Asian countries. As a result, its FDI as a share of GFCF was the
highest in the world (22.9% between 1971 and 1995), higher than even that of laissez-
faire Hong Kong (7.6%) (Chang, 2006).
However, all of this does not mean that Singapore pursued a laissez-faire industrial
policy, as many free-market economists suggest. On the contrary, the Singapore
government has consistently taken a proactive role to support the manufacturing sector’s
growth.
First of all, the Singaporean government has shown itself to be even more interventionist
than that of Japan or Korea in certain respects, such as forced saving schemes, the
labour market, and public housing programmes.29 The Central Provident Fund, which
imposed mandatory contributions by employers and workers, accounted for 30% of
domestic savings or 12% of national income since the early 1980s (Findlay & Wellisz,
1993, p. 8). The high saving rates stimulated higher levels of investments and capital
accumulation in the Singapore economy – according to Huff (1999), Singapore had the
highest national savings rate in the world in the1980s (over 40%) and 1990s (48.2%
between 1990 and 1997). The labour market was also highly regulated. Singapore
initially started as a high-cost manufacturing producer (Huff, 1995, p. 1424), whose wage
costs were higher than other competing newly industrialising Asian countries (Lim, 1983,
p. 757). However, to enhance the competitiveness of Singapore’s labour-intensive
industries, the government introduced a series of labour market regulations that included
wage repression between 1972 and 1979 and curbs on wage increases through a
centralised wage system (Fields & Wan, 1989). Through its Housing Development Board,
the Singapore government has supplied around 85% of all housing in the country.
Second, precisely because of the recognised scarcity of resources and vulnerabilities as
a small open economy, the government has set explicit directions to nurture the
27 The land area of Singapore was 582km2 when it gained independence in 1965, one-third the size of
London (1,570km2) and half the size of New York City (1,213km2).
28 Between 1970 and 2010, the sum of total trade (exports and imports) as a percentage of GDP, a
measure of an economy’s openness, averaged 345%, significantly higher than the US (20.8%), Japan
(22.7%), Germany (53.8%) and Korea (66.6%) (World Bank, 2012).
29 Interestingly, even in Hong Kong, the only laissez-faire country in East Asia, all land is publicly-owned.
This shows the particular importance that housing has in city-states.
33
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
manufacturing sector’s growth. In 2010, a high-level committee (comprising the
government, labour movement, private sector and academia), tasked by the Prime
Minister to formulate medium-term economic strategies, recommended the retention of a
“globally competitive manufacturing sector” at between 20-25% of the economy (SESC,
2010). As a city-state, policy formulation is highly centralised, with the implementation of
industrial policy falling primarily under the mandate of the Economic Development Board
(EDB) (see Schein, 1997; Chan, 2011, for more details on the EDB and its work).
Strategic manufacturing clusters that are assessed to have long-term economic potential
are identified and targets are actively pursued. During the nascent stage of building the
biomedical manufacturing cluster in the early 2000s, Singapore targeted to attract 15
world-class biomedical science companies by 2010. This goal was surpassed, with
Singapore succeeding in attracting over 30 leading companies by 2012. Most recently in
2013, Singapore announced ambitious plans to build manufacturing capabilities in
satellites to serve the space industry.
Third, Singapore’s policy towards TNCs, while extremely friendly, has not been laissez
faire. Rather than taking a hands-off approach to the inflows of FDI and let the TNCs
decide what to do, the Singaporean government has worked hard to attract FDI into
certain areas that it regards as important for the future of the country’s economy, by
offering a whole slew of custom-designed financial incentives. Subsidies offered to TNCs
targeted desirable industries based on criteria such as employment, growth potential,
technical contents, and value-added (Huff, 1999, p. 39). Between 1980 and 1990,
Singapore received more FDI than any other developing country (Huff, 1995, p. 1425).
Today, Singapore continues to offer Pioneer incentives (corporate tax exemptions on
income from qualifying activities), Development and Expansion incentives (reduced
corporate tax rate on incremental income from qualifying activities), and the Research
Incentive Scheme for Companies (grants to develop R&D capabilities in strategic areas
of technology). Singapore’s generous incentives were cited as a key reason why hard
disk manufacturer Seagate chose to invest in Singapore over Hong Kong and Korea in
1982 despite Singapore’s lack of a domestic supply base (Peebles & Wilson, 2002, p.
100). This initial investment eventually earned Singapore the distinction of being the
largest producer of hard disk drives in the world (45-50% of annual world output)
between 1986 and 1996 (Wong, 2000, p. 155).
Fourth, in sectors assessed to be critical, the Singapore government set up SOEs –
comprising Government-linked Companies (GLCs) and government statutory boards
(such as the Housing Development Board) – rather than inviting TNCs. The world-
famous Singapore Airlines is an SOE, while industries such as shipbuilding and
telecommunications are also run by SOEs. As a result, it has a huge SOE sector
(estimated to be 21.8% of GDP in 1998) (SDOS, 2001).30 For example, between 1970
and 1990, the share of the public sector in GFCF in Korea was around 10%, whereas the
corresponding figure in Singapore was over 30% – 36% in the 1960s, 27% in the 1970s
and 30% in the 1980s (Shin, 2005). It would not be an exaggeration to say that virtually
all large firms in Singapore that are not transnational corporation (TNC) subsidiaries are
SOEs.
Fifth, land use policies in Singapore incorporate a significant sectoral-targeting
dimension, particularly given its lack of land resources.31 For instance, waterfront land
30 In 2001, GLCs were estimated to account for 12.9% of Singapore’s GDP in 1998, with the non-GLC
public sector accounting for another 8.9% (SDOS, 2001).
31 The majority of land in Singapore is publicly owned, with the government empowered to acquire the rest.
34
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
that is allocated to the petrochemicals industry cannot be used to expand the port (and
grow maritime services). In a recent land use plan (with a time horizon until 2030), the
government announced new manufacturing zones “to support the growth of the
manufacturing sector” (SMND, 2013). Land-related industrial policy measures also target
specific clusters within the manufacturing sector. For instance, the land mass of seven
small islands was tripled and amalgamated through the reclamation of 22km2 of land to
create Jurong Island – a petrochemicals hub. Contiguous land was also allocated to
facilitate the growth of clusters in industries such as aerospace (Seletar Aerospace Park)
and pharmaceuticals (Tuas Biomedical Park and Biopolis).
3.6. Finland: defying gravity?
On the back of state-led corporatist industrialisation, Finland radically transformed itself
from one of the poorest economies in Europe into one of the richest. According to the
authoritative statistical work of Maddison (1989), among the 16 largest rich countries of
today, only Japan (3.1%) achieved a higher rate of annual per capita income growth than
Finland (2.6%) during the 1900-87 period (p.15, table 1.2).32 Norway tied with Finland in
second place, and the average for all 16 countries was 2.1%.33
Industrial policy in Finland involved close cooperation between the state, trade unions
and private sector agents, such as the banks and industrial firms. This corporatist nature
of Finland’s growth model has led to comparisons with the Asian economies, such as
Korea and Taiwan (Vartiainen, 1999).
Like Singapore, Finland is a small open economy that emphasised state-directed capital
accumulation that was supported by high public savings.34 During the 1950s and 1960s,
public savings comprised as much as 30% of aggregate savings, and these surpluses
were used to support private investments in capital equipment and to form public
companies (Jäntti & Vartiainen, 2009).35 SOEs were established in industries that were
more capital-intensive or deemed too risky for private enterprises. These industries
included basic metal (Rautaruukki), pulp and paper (Stora Enso), chemical fertilizer
(Kemira), and petroleum and oil products (Neste). In the early 1980s, SOEs were
estimated to contribute 18% to Finland’s industrial value-added (Kosonen, 1992).36
However, unlike Singapore, Finland eschewed foreign involvement during its early phase
of industrialisation. Having been subjugated to foreign rule for centuries, draconian
restrictions were imposed on foreign investments.37 In 1919, soon after the
32 For the list of the 16 countries, see the Japan section.
33 Despite the massive external shock that it received following the collapse of the Soviet Union, which
accounted for over one-third of its international trade, Finland ranked at a very respectable joint-5th among
the 16 countries in terms of per capita income growth during the 1990s. According to the World Bank data,
its annual per capita income growth rate during 1990-99 was 2.1% (equal to the Netherlands), exceeded
only by Norway (3.2%), Australia (2.6%), and Denmark and the USA (2.4%).
34 Public investments were primarily to strengthen the industrial base and encourage private capital
accumulation (Kosonen, 1992).
35 Following the Second World War, the Finnish government made a strategic decision not to lower the tax
rate to pre-war levels.
36 Industrial value-added includes the value-added from both manufacturing activities and the processing of
raw materials. In Norway, another Nordiac country that established SOEs in basic industrial sectors, SOEs
contributed only 10% of industry value-added in the early 1980s (Kosonen, 1992).
37 From the 12th century until 1809, Finland was part of Sweden; thereafter, it existed as an autonomous
Grand Duchy within the Russian empire until 1917.
35
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
independence from over a century of Russian rule (which was preceded by six centuries
of Swedish rule), it was stipulated that foreigners had to get special permission to
establish a business and guarantee in advance the payment of taxes and other charges
due to the central and the local states. In the 1930s, a series of laws were passed in
order to ensure that no foreigner could own land and mining rights. It was also legislated
that a foreigner could not be a member of the board of directors or the general manager
of a firm. Companies with more than 20% foreign ownership were officially classified as
‘dangerous companies’ and therefore foreign ownership of companies was effectively
restricted to 20%. As a result, while there was considerable foreign borrowing, there was
little FDI during this period, a pattern that persisted at least until the 1980s when there
was some liberalisation of foreign investment.38
To achieve high levels of investments, the Finnish government invested heavily in
productive equipment and offered accelerated depreciation and investment allowances.39
Other measures encouraging capital accumulation included interest rate controls and
preferential credit for investments in capital equipment. Between 1961 and 1990,
Finland’s share of investments (GFCF) in GDP was 26.9%, higher than the OECD
average of 22.8% (World Bank, 2012).
To enhance the competitiveness and growth of its export industries, Finland repeatedly
devaluated its currency in 1957, 1967, 1977 and 1982. Although devaluations are
generally regarded as a ‘horizontal’ macroeconomic stabilisation policy, it also involves
implicit targeting of sectors, as we highlighted earlier (see section 2.1). In Finland’s case,
more outward-oriented sectors, such as the paper and pulp industry, benefited more from
the devaluations than industries dependent on the domestic market.
In the past few decades, Finland’s industrial policy focus has shifted towards promoting
innovation in general rather than particular industries, with the government continuing to
play a key role, directly through R&D spending and indirectly through ‘horizontal’
measures that strengthen the science and technology foundation for industries. During
the recession in the early 1990s, the government remained committed to raising public
R&D, even as it reduced most public expenditures (Georghiou, et al., 2003). Within the
OECD, Finland had the third highest government-funded GERD (normalised by GDP)
(1.00%) in 2010.
Finland’s ‘horizontal’ measures to create an enabling business environment that is
conducive for innovation mark a departure from past initiatives which explicitly targeted
specific sectors. Nonetheless, these measures still involve some degree of implicit
targeting at technology-intensive sectors, as we had argued earlier.
First, access to funding for innovation was improved through various government
initiatives (e.g., the Finnish Innovation Fund – SITRA) and organisations (e.g., Tekes –
the Finnish Funding Agency for Technology and Innovation). SITRA, supervised by the
Finnish Parliament, provided corporate funding to companies and played a key role in
developing the venture capital industry in the early 1990s (Ylä-Anttila & Palmberg, 2007).
Tekes, on the other hand, is the main source of R&D subsidies in Finland (see Toivanen,
2006, for more details on Tekes and the impact of Finland’s R&D subsidies.)
38 Nonetheless, although the foreign ownership ceiling of companies was raised to 40% in 1987, this was
still subject to the consent of the Ministry of Trade and Industry (Bellak & Luostarinen, 1994, p. 17).
39 Accelerated depreciation allowances benefited holders of existing capital while investment allowances
encouraged firms to invest in new capital.
36
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Second, nationwide networks of science parks and centres of expertise were developed
from the 1980s to facilitate technology transfer and the commercialisation of research
results (Lemola, 2002). At the macro-level, new innovations were supported through the
specialisation of and cooperation between regions and clusters. At the micro-level, spin-
off projects and incubators were nurtured by the science parks.
Third, Finland pioneered the concept of a ‘national innovation system’ in the 1990s
(Miettinen, 2002), to foster public and private sector cooperation in developing, diffusing
and utilising new knowledge and technologies. This involved adopting a broader and
more holistic approach towards innovation processes and policies, ranging from
education and science to innovations by firms and commercialisations of technological
innovations (Georghiou et al., 2003). Today, the Strategic Centres for Science,
Technology and Innovation (SHOKs) continues to emphasise innovation through the
enhancement of collaborative platforms between the government, private sector,
universities and research institutes.
3.7. Italy: small is beautiful?
In 1960, Luigi Spaventa described Italy as a country whose economic position “is in
between that of an underdeveloped and an advanced economy”. He pointed out that
“though the initial ‘big push’ took place later than elsewhere, the Italian economy as a
whole has been growing at a good, and often rapid pace over the past eighty years or so.
[However] there has been some growth in the South only in recent years and only owing
to heavy public intervention…” (Spaventa, 1960, p. 1077)
During the first two decades after the Second World War, the persistent technological
backwardness of the Italian economy as well as the problems encountered by the central
government in developing the South (the so-called ‘Mezzogiorno’) were at the centre of
the policy agenda.
The central government tried to encourage the reconstruction and the expansion of the
production capacity in selected strategic sectors, such as automobile, by providing
money as well as subsidised intermediate goods (produced by SOEs) to private
companies, such as FIAT. Moreover, engineering and mechanical companies that were
not able to pay state loans back were nationalised under the holding company, the EFIM
(Ente Finanziamento Industrie Meccaniche). Nationalisation was also used with respect
to certain strategic industries, the most remarkable example being the constitution of
ENEL in 1962, a new national agency for the provision of (very often subsidised) electric
energy (Baldassarri, 1993; Federico & Giannetti, 1999).
During the 1950s and 1960s, SOEs were also very active in the modernisation of utilities,
building of infrastructure, and investments in heavy industries, such as steel (through the
Sinigaglia Plan) (Barca & Trento, 1997) and energy, initially with AGIP (for gas) and later
with ENI (for oil and chemical products) (Sapelli, 1992). The IRI (Istituto per la
Ricostruzione Industriale), a multi-sectoral holding company founded in 1933 and fully
owned by the state, was a major tool for supporting the central government’s industrial
policies aimed at reducing the North-South gap. A major innovation was represented by
the Law No. 634/1957, according to which SOEs had to have 40% of their total
investments and make 60% of new investments in Southern Italy.
37
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
IRI’s strategic investment was also complemented by the loans provided by the Cassa
per il Mezzogiorno (Cassa), a development bank set up in 1950 with the strong support
of the US Government (USAID), as well as the Ten Year Development Plan for
Employment and Income (Schema di sviluppo della occupazione e del reddito del
decennio, 1955-1964), better known as ‘Schema Vanoni’. During the 1960s, thanks to
the reform of the Cassa, as well as to a number of special banks supporting industrial
and public investment such as Special Banks for Industry and Infrastructure
Development, or Istituti di Credito Speciale per l’industria e le opera pubbliche (ICS) –
new resources were channelled towards a selected number of capital-intensive
industries, such as steel and chemicals, or traditional sectors, such as food processing
and textiles.40
Throughout the 1950s and 1960s, while the Southern regions experienced a state-led
process of ‘dependent industrialisation’ (Andreoni, 2013d), the SMEs of the Northern
regions experienced a fast export-led development. In 1957, by joining the European
Economic Community, Italy signed a quadrennial plan of tariffs cuts (30% each time)
which would have to be totally removed by 1969 (in fact Italy achieved this goal a few
years ahead of schedule!). As it was accompanied by equivalent tariff cuts by other
members, the fast industrialising regions in the North were able to boost the export of
strategic products such as machine tools and automotive as well as textiles and other
low-tech products, in which Italy was then competitive thanks to lower wages.
Differently from other European countries, during the 1970s Italy’s attempt to face the oil
crisis through incomes policy resulted in massive failures. The government’s response to
the crisis led to an overall increase in public subsidies from 1.2% of GDP in 1964 to 4.6%
in 1975, up to 8.9% in 1985 (Federico & Giannetti, 1999). Unfortunately, subsidies were
not strategically used for encouraging structural adjustments. For example, subsidies for
temporary lay-offs of workers became permanent and were indifferently applied across
industries. Strategic industries (steel-making, energy, petrochemicals) were granted
subsidies and other measures for facilitating their industrial restructuring (Adams, 1991).
Many troubled firms in strategic (and non-strategic) sectors were bailed out, resulting in
the expansion of the SOE sector.41
While national champions struggled over the 1970s, Northern SMEs, very often operating
in traditional labour-intensive sectors (e.g. textiles, machine tools, furniture, etc.),
successfully found their own flexible institutional responses to the crisis. ‘Industrial
districts’ developed, based on clusters of co-located SMEs whose flexibility and
productivity were mainly driven by external economies of scale, complementarities in
production, industrial commons, and reduced transaction costs (Piore & Sabel, 1984;
Becattini, 1987; Gobbo, 1989). Although industrial districts initially developed
spontaneously, the national and regional governments encouraged their diffusion and
growth by providing soft loans, which accounted for one-third of the total funds for
investments over the 1970s.
The economic crisis and policy failures of the 1970s led to a profound reformulation of
Italy’s industrial policy strategy. The 1980s witnessed a significant shift in industrial policy
40 With the centre-left government in power in 1963, which attempted an overall redesign of the national
industrial plan (the so called piano straordinario) and the reform of the Cassa in 1965, investments in
manufacturing development reached half of total IRI’s investments.
41 The number employed in manufacturing SOEs went from 185,000 in 1953 to 451,500 in 1974 (Federico
& Giannetti, 1999).
38
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
targets that became more and more focused on supporting R&D, innovation, and
competitiveness, as well as the enlargement and the modernisation of SMEs increasingly
challenged by increasing international competition especially in traditional medium- and
low-tech sectors. With the exception of Japan, in the early 1980s, Italy saw the highest
increase in public investments in R&D, although the results were quite modest, given the
narrow range of policy tools adopted and the complex bureaucratic system which
regulated the access to public support.
While other European countries started implementing privatisation and liberalisation
policies over the second half of the 1980s, Italy resisted until 1992 when it faced the risk
of a national bankruptcy. Over the 1990s, privatisation and liberalisation were aimed at
reducing public debt but also improving the productivity of the newly privatised
companies, while reducing SOE monopoly and inter-SOE collusion. Privatisations
proceeded in two steps: firstly, major national banks owning shares of many public
corporations were sold; secondly, SOEs were directly sold to private companies. In some
sectors, privatisation produced the desired results, while in many others the lack of
strategic vision led to the loss of control of strategic production assets, minimal benefits
for consumers, and even the simple replacement of public monopolies with private
monopolies (examples are in the telecommunications, with Telecom Italia, and in
infrastructure, with Autostrade).
During the mid- 2000s the privatisation process slowed down and state-owned holding
companies (e.g., ENEL and ENI) even managed to increase their presence in the
European and global markets. At the same time, the government intervened in the
restructuring of FIAT by allowing the company to benefit from a strong line of credit
offered by recently privatised banks. The short-lived government of Romano Prodi (2007-
8) attempted to start a new industrial policy course by both deregulating the service
sector and, more importantly, proposing a new national industrial policy agenda called
Industria 2015.
The Industria 2015 agenda recognised the need for coordinating some of the industrial
policies that regional governments (almost exclusively in Northern regions such as Emilia
Romagna) had been implementing over the years. The industrial policy package of
Industria 2015 pursues three main strategies: (i) promotion of investments in innovation
projects in areas of energy efficiency, logistics, life sciences, and the protection of artistic
heritage; (ii) promotion of network amongst firms; (iii) new national venture capital funds.
The political instability of the last years has, unfortunately, largely undermined the
effectiveness of this national industrial policy strategy.
3.8. Brazil: against all odds
The period of 1950-1980 in Brazil was characterised by a long period of state-led
industrialisation (Ocampo, 2006). Public sector indicative planning was the norm in Brazil
as well as in the rest of the Latin American region. Industrial policy was mainly aimed at
creating new industrial sectors, changing the prevalent pattern of specialisation in
primary commodities and promoting technology-intensive activities.
The main industrial policy strategy of this period was set up in the 1950s and consisted in
the introduction of a protectionist regime based on ad valorem tariffs. The Federal
Government had the discretionary power to control the level and the types of imports.
The Law of Similarities (Lei do Similar Nacional) stated that a product could only be
imported if it could be proved that a similar product was not produced in Brazil. These
39
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
measures were intensified during the 1960-80 period within an import substitution
industrialisation (ISI) strategy.
As a result of these industrial policy measures, Brazil successfully entered new strategic
sectors, such as petrochemical and renewable fuels (ethanol production with the Pro-
alcohol policy which led to Petrobas) and established the bases for the development of
new technologies. Brazil’s upgrading into new technological areas was sometimes very
successful, as in the case of the aircraft industry (Embraer) or agribusiness (Embrapa;
see Andreoni, 2013a) but not in some others, such as in the attempt to develop the
computer industry or in the attempt to upgrade existing sectors, such as textiles and
automotive.
The Debt Crisis during the 1980s induced the Brazilian government to introduce, at least
formally, a ‘New Industrial Policy’ package (1985-1988). The total number of special
trade regimes was reduced and the average manufacturing tariff rates went from 90% to
43%. However, given the strong opposition of domestic producers, reforms were not so
radical. Non-tariffs barriers and the Law of Similarities were not removed, and these,
together with the remaining tariffs, allowed many marginal producers to survive (Kume,
1989; Hay, 2001; Figueiredo, 2008). During the late 1980s and throughout the 1990s
structural adjustment policies (financed by conditional financing programmes from the
IMF and the World Bank) were initially directed to trade liberalisation and privatisation of
public enterprises, while from the mid-1990s they increasingly focused on
macroeconomic stabilization (the ‘Real Plan’).
The 2000s signaled the return of selective (sector specific) industrial policies in Brazil. In
November 2003, the first Lula government announced the Guidelines for an Industrial,
Technology and Foreign Trade Policy (PITCE), whose goals were twofold: (i) increasing
industrial competitiveness by boosting technological development in key sectors and,
thus, promoting the export of higher value-added products; (ii) developing the scientific
and technological systems for capturing opportunities in production activities such as oil
and gas, agriculture and pharmaceuticals. The Brazilian Industrial Development Agency
(ABDI) and the Council for Industrial Development (CNDI) (made up of 23 Government
Ministers, the BNDES President and 14 industry representatives) were created for
coordinating and implementing the new PITCE industrial policy package and for
facilitating the dialogue between the public and private sectors. Four strategic sectors
were targeted: semi-conductors, software, pharmaceuticals and medicines, and capital
goods.
In terms of innovation strategy, PITCE was focused on three industries: biotechnology,
nanotechnology and biomass/renewable energies. Also, a new legal framework was
introduced comprising the Innovation Act (Lei do Bem), the Biosecurity Act and the
Biotechnology Development Policy. Both industrial and innovation policies were coupled
with highly specific financing programmes, such as the Profarma (pharmaceutical) and
the Prosoft (software) as well as two super-sectoral programmes called Strong Industry
and Innovate Brazil, managed by the Brazilian Development Bank BNDES (for a total
investment of R$ 4.4 billion). The sectoral programmes are aimed at overcoming
infrastructural bottlenecks and increasing Brazil’s competitiveness in targeted sectors.
The super-sectoral programme targets the innovation capacity of Brazil and promotes
various forms of cooperation and partnerships among private companies, universities
and research institutes, government agencies and labour unions. In 2004, the adoption of
an integrated funds management model ‘made it possible to integrate a large fraction of
40
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
investments in funds by transversely bridging them in line with government policies,
eliminating duplication and scattershot initiatives’ (ABDI, 2006, p. 20).
For the 2008-10 programme, the second Lula government launched an ambitious
industrial policy package Productive Development Policy: Innovate and Invest to Sustain
Growth (PDP) aimed at addressing for main challenges: (i) to sustain the expansionary
cycle by maintaining the rate of growth in GFCF ahead of the GDP; (ii) to upgrade and
diversify the export basket, which is dominated by primary commodities and low-tech
manufactures; (iii) to boost the innovation capacity of Brazilian companies through
specialisation in high value production activities and through the development of large
firms controlling global value chains; (iv) to increase the competitive and distributive
effects of the expansionary cycle by broadening access to credit for micro- and small
enterprises.
The PDP is a complex policy package structured along three main axes. First, there are
programmes promoting strategic areas (healthcare, ICT, nuclear energy, defense,
nanotech and biotech), managed by the Ministry of Science and Technology (Bothelo,
2011). Second, there are programmes to consolidate and expand international market
positions with the help of the state-owned development bank, the National Bank for
Economic and Social Development (BNDES). The targets of these programmes are:
aeronautics, oil, natural gas and petro-chemicals, bio-ethanol, mining, steel, pulp and
paper, and meat. Third, there are programmes to strengthen industrial competitiveness
under the direct control of the Ministry for Development, Industry and Foreign Trade
(MDIC) (Government of Brazil, 2008; Ferraz et al., 2009).
During the implementation of the PDP, particular emphasis was given to the increase in
competitiveness and the increase in international investments by the national champions
in resource-based industries (Devlin & Moguillansky, 2012, p. 13). Also, the funding base
of BNDES was substantially expanded in order to allow the country to reach the GFCF of
21% by 2010 while the spread for credit lines in trade of capital goods was substantially
reduced (Government of Brazil, 2008 p. 24).
The current industrial policy – Plano Brasil Maior (PBM), issued by the Roussef
government in August 2011, embraces a broader scope and concentrates more on
infrastructure, compared to the PDP. PBM also focuses on strengthening production
chains and diversifying/upgrading exports (especially for SMEs) through tax reliefs, trade
remedies (e.g., anti-dumping measures), and financing and loan guarantees for
exporters. Since the 2008 global financial crisis, Brazilian producers have been protected
from exchange rate appreciation and the worldwide economic slowdown, especially
through the financial support of the BNDES, exemption of payroll taxes, and preferences
in government procurement.
In the last few years, the Brazilian government has finally changed its restrictive
macroeconomic policies, implemented since 1996, which contributed hugely to the
dramatic premature de-industrialisation of Brazil – the share of manufacturing in GDP fell
from the peak of 27.2% in the mid-1980s to 14.6% in 2011 (World bank:
http://www.tradingeconomics.com/brazil/manufacturing-value-added-percent-of-gdp-wb-
data.html). First, tentatively following the 2008 crisis and then aggressively since 2012, it
has abandoned the high interest policy (for much of the time since 1996, it had literally
the highest real interest in the world). The lowering of interest rates has naturally led to
the depreciation of (the very overvalued) Real, the local currency. These macroeconomic
41
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
changes have significantly relieved pressure on the manufacturing industry as a whole
and especially the export-oriented firms.
In April 2012 the PBM entered in its second phase and is now concentrating on the
Brazilian industrial competitiveness challenges (Canuto et al., 2013). The PBM is
redesigning the policy target based on production systems concepts, instead of
production chain ones, and trying to identify new instruments to strengthen industrial
policy effectiveness and favour public-private collaboration (such as by establishing a
new public-private governance scheme, including sectoral competitiveness councils)
(Kupfer, 2012).
3.9. China: the new frontier
Since the late 19th century, the Chinese government has played an important role, with
varying degrees of success, in mobilising resources, developing infrastructure and
nurturing strategic industries, regardless of the political regime (the Qing dynasty, the
Nationalist government, and the Communist government).42
During the transition towards a market economy in the 1980s and the 1990s, industrial
policy continued to weigh heavily on the minds of Chinese state planners and many
initiatives in the 1980s were inspired by the experiences of Japan and Korea. In 1987, an
Industrial Policy Department was established under the State Planning Commission and
in March 1989 the concept of industrial policy was explicitly mentioned for the first time in
an official document, that is, the State Council’s paper Decision on Current Industrial
Policy Priorities. It was followed by the more comprehensive and integrated Outline of
State Industrial Policies for the 1990s in March 1994, which highlighted the need to
accelerate the development of mainstay and high-technology industries, and to readjust
the composition of foreign trade by strengthening manufacturing competitiveness. The
June 1995 Provisional Regulations of Guidance on Foreign Direct Investment and
subsequent December 1997 revision mapped out guidelines for high-technology sectors
where foreign investments were encouraged, restricted or prohibited (see Zhang & Long,
1997; Yu, 1999, pp. 75-6; Liu, 2005, pp. 34-43, for further details).
China’s industrial policies are embodied within its Five-Year Plans. The Sixth Plan (1981-
1985) marked a departure from past industrial plans by being more comprehensive and
outward-oriented. Foreign trade and capital were encouraged in order to facilitate the
import of advanced technology into the country. Promotion of high-technology industries
and R&D were recurring themes in later Five-Year Plans. Strategic industries, or “pillar
industries”, were identified based on their importance to China’s national security and
economy (e.g., defence, coal, electric power and grid, telecommunications, petroleum
and petrochemical, civil aviation and shipping in 2006) and growth potential (e.g.,
alternative fuel cars, biotechnology, environmental and energy-saving technologies,
alternative energy, advanced materials, new-generation information technology, and
high-end equipment manufacturing in 2007).
As China undertook economic liberalisation, it drew on the experiences of East Asia.
Similar to Singapore, China’s export growth has been supported by the investments of
42 Written archives of industrial planning in China generally date back to Sun Yat-sen’s (1922) Shiye Jihua
(Industrial Plan), which emphasised the state’s key role in creating “socialism” and developing basic heavy
industries (Kirby, 1990).
42
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
TNCs. Like Korea and Japan, China has successfully developed large domestic
enterprises. As such, China’s industrial policy shares certain characteristics with its East
Asian counterparts and goes beyond direct tariffs, subsidies and trade protectionism.43
First of all, key industries that have been identified in the Five-Year Plans for
development were given targeted supports. They were protected from foreign
competition through tariffs and non-tariff barriers, such as local contents requirements.
They were supplied with subsidised loans from state ‘policy banks’, such as the Export-
Import (Exim) Bank of China, the Agricultural Development Bank of China (ADBC) and
China Development Bank (CDB).44 Commercial bank loans were also made in line with
industrial policy goals.45 According to Ferri and Liu (2010), SOEs received 65% of the
loans from commercial banks between 1998 and 2003, despite accounting for only 25%
of China’s economy. Imputed interest rates on debts offered to private enterprises were
also found to be 25% to 33% higher than that offered to SOEs.
Second, through the licensing system, investments were directed in strategic ways. For
example, foreign investments were channelled into targeted sectors46 and designated
geographical areas such as Special Economic Zones (SEZs). For another example, the
government also controlled the geographical distribution of investments. This was evident
in the 1960s when the government located new industries in inland areas so as to
distribute industrial development away from the concentrated coastal areas.47 In the early
days of the open-door policy, coastal areas were reprioritised for government
investments, in order to maximise their growth impacts and the access to foreign
markets. More recently, the growing concern with regional disparities has once again
compelled the government to shift the focus of its investments (especially infrastructural
investments) to the inland areas.48
Third, to develop what Nolan (2001) described as a ‘national team’ of enterprises in
strategic sectors, the Chinese state initiated M&A by administrative decree. For example,
state-mediated consolidation of smaller, uncompetitive firms in the electronics industry
led to the formation of larger companies such as China Electronics Corporation and SVA
Group. Over the years, the government has continued to pursue its policy of industry
consolidation to develop large internationally competitive companies49, with one recent
example involving the merger of two SOEs – when China Electronics Corporation
acquired Irico Group, a photovoltaic equipment manufacturer – in early 2013.
43 Chang (2011) provides a detailed list of industrial policy measures in East Asia.
44 Marukawa (2011) provides examples on how companies in the automobile industry benefited from state
credit. For example, Chery expanded into overseas markets with financial support from the China Exim Bank
while Geely borrowed funds from local governments to finance the acquisition of Volvo Cars in 2010.
45 Chapter IV, Article 34 of the 1995 Law of the People’s Republic of China on Commercial Banks highlights
that “A commercial bank shall conduct its loan business in accordance with the need for the development of
the national economy and social progress and under the guidance of the state industrial policy”.
46 Foreign investments are classified into four categories in different industries: (i) encouraged, (ii) permitted,
(iii) restricted, and (iv) prohibited.
47 In the early 1950s, the coastal area contributed 70% of China’s industrial output, despite making up less
than 20% of total land area (Zhang & Long, 1997).
48 Between 1993 and 2003, the average annual FDI inflows as a percentage of GDP was significantly higher
in eastern coastal regions such as Guangdong (13%) and Fujian (11%) compared to the national average
(4%) (Poncet, 2010, p. 115).
49 China’s policy stance on industry consolidation was reaffirmed by its Ministry of Industry and Information
Technology (MIIT)’s Guidance on Corporate Mergers and Acquisitions to Accelerate the Growth of Key
Industries in January 2013, which highlighted its aim to grow global champions in the automotive, iron and
steel, cement, shipbuilding, aluminium, rare earth metals, electronics and pharmaceutical industries (MIIT,
2013).
43
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Fourth, industrial clusters were promoted to harness the benefits of agglomeration
effects, such as closer integration between suppliers, producers and customers, on the
one hand, and more rapid innovation growth, on the other hand (OECD, 1999; Arvanitis
& Qiu, 2008; Barbieri et al., 2012). Emphasis was placed on developing clusters in
different towns and cities with unique pillar industries. For instance, manufacturing
districts such as Shunde specialise in electrical goods while manufacturing towns such
as Xiaolan (locks and electronic acoustics) and Guzhen (lighting fittings) have also
emerged within major cities such as Zhongshan.
Fifth, policies were deployed to facilitate transfers of technologies from more
economically advanced nations. There were regulations on technology imports and TNCs
were made to form joint ventures with Chinese companies, most of them being SOEs or
associated with government partners.50 Through joint ventures, the state retained
effective control over foreign affiliates so as to advance Chinese interests (Roehrig,
1994). Other technology transfer strategies included majority-stake acquisitions of and
mergers with foreign companies from advanced countries (some more successful than
others) – including Sweden (Volvo), the UK (MG Rover), the US (IBM’s personal
computer business), Austria (Fischer Advanced Composite Components), France
(Adisseo) and Korea (Ssangyong Motors)51 – and incentives to entice foreign companies
to set up R&D centres in China.
Finally, export subsidies and currency devaluations have been used in order to enhance
China’s export competitiveness in international markets. China’s export restraints, such
as on rare earth used by industries, have also influenced global supply and prices. With
export subsidies and restraints prohibited under the World Trade Organization (WTO),
trade disputes against China’s alleged practices remain commonplace (USTR, 2010,
2012a, 2012b).
50 While explicit technology transfer conditions are curtailed under China’s WTO obligations, implicit
measures are not forbidden. In China’s 2011 Catalogue for the Guidance of Foreign Invested Industries,
ownership restrictions are listed in most manufacturing industries.
51 Ssangyong, acquired by SAIC in 2004, was sold on to Mahindra Motors of India in 2011.
44
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
4. Lessons for the UK
4.1. Some general remarks on ‘drawing lessons’ from
international experiences
Before we draw concrete policy lessons for the UK from the experiences of other
countries, let us make a few remarks on the exercise itself.
It should be made absolutely clear right at the beginning that we are not trying to derive
from the case studies presented in this study some universal recipes transferable to any
country, when each country has its unique political conditions, policy traditions, and
economic conditions (see Rose, 1991, on the limits of policy transferability). Instead they
are aimed at expanding policymakers’ imagination by presenting a plurality of possibilities
in terms both of policy goals and of policy tools.
Attempts to draw lessons from other countries in relation to any policy generate
scepticism in all countries, but that reaction is particularly strong when it comes to
industrial policy in the UK – industrial policy, it is often argued, however successful it may
have been in other countries, like Germany, China, or Finland, simply cannot work over
here, because it is against the country’s history of laissez-faire capitalism and its tradition
of individualism.
One problem with this view is that it is based on a mistaken view of the British history. As
we briefly mentioned earlier, between the industrial policy reform of Robert Walpole in
1721 until the country’s transition to free trade in the 1860s, Britain (as it was then) was
in fact the pioneer of industrial policy (Chang, 2002, pp. 19-24). It is because he knew
this history that Friedrich List, the German economist who is mistakenly known as the
father of the infant industry argument (when the real father is Alexander Hamilton), wrote
in the 1840s that Britain’s preaching of free trade to relatively backward nations, like
Germany and the US, was like ‘kicking away the ladder’ (Chang, 2002, pp. 4-5). In turn,
Alexander Hamilton is known to have drawn inspirations from Walpole’s policies in
inventing his infant industry argument, so much so that he was accused of being a
‘Walpolean’ by his opponents who did not like his belief in government intervention
(Chang, 2002, p. 25). So, it is a convenient myth for the opponents of industrial policy
that industrial policy is against the British tradition, but this is simply not true.
Now, even those who acknowledge the importance of the Walpolean tradition in
propelling Britain to the position of the world’s leading industrial economy may, rightly,
point out that the tradition has been forgotten over the last two centuries, with a partial
exception of the period between the 1940s and the 1960s, when the country tried – not
very successfully – to establish a more systematic industrial policy, prompted by the
successes of Germany and France, which then used such policy much more actively.
How would you revive a tradition that has been dormant for most of the last 150 years?
However, one should remember that old traditions can be, and have been, revived after
long intervals. Indeed, France, a country that most British people think has been run on
an unbroken policy tradition of active state intervention, was very non-interventionist
between the fall of Napoleon in 1815 and the end of World War II in 1945 (and much less
protectionist in the first half of the 19th century) (Kuisel, 1981; Chang, 2002). Its
interventionist tradition was revived after a 130-year hiatus.
45
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
More generally, all the success cases of industrial policy are countries that have actively
learnt from the more successful countries, despite the fact that the latter are very different
from themselves, in terms of policy traditions, institutional set-ups, and culture. Just to
cite some prominent examples from the countries we examined in this report: in the 18th
and the early 19th century, the US and Germany learnt from Britain’s industrial policy; in
the late 19th century Japan imported a lot of policies and institutions from Germany; in the
20th century, Korea and China have aggressively learnt from Japan. Indeed, the history of
economic policy shows that the most successful countries are those that willingly admit
their shortcomings and do their utmost to learn from other more successful countries.
Also, there is a curious asymmetry in the view of the British sceptics of learning lessons
from other countries. While they are very keen to emphasise the difficulty of the UK
learning lessons from countries with different institutions and history, they tend to be
quite cavalier when it comes to other countries learning lessons from the UK’s policies
and institutions, as seen especially in the constant lecturing by those people to their
European neighbours that they should make their labour market more flexible or their
financial markets more liberal, following the British examples (although these lectures
have become less frequent and less strident after the 2008 crisis). They never explain
why the British institutions and policies are easier to transplant than others, but the
argument is, at best, based on the unwarranted (implicit) assumption that more market-
oriented institutions are somehow more ‘natural’ and therefore more easily transplantable
and, at worst, a blatant case of double standards.
Indeed, if anything, an active use of industrial policy has been much more widespread
than the UK model of ‘industrial policy by default’. As we mentioned above, the UK itself
had used industrial policy actively in the past, and almost all the other successful
economies have used active industrial policy to one degree or another at one point of
time or another. While this does not mean that it will be easy to transplant some industrial
policy measures from Finland or Brazil to the UK, it does mean that there cannot be any
presumption that such transplantation would be impossible.
4.2. Specific issues
4.2.1. Vision
One thing that comes out strongly through the review of industrial experiences in other
countries is the importance of the national vision. If Hamilton’s vision that his country can
one day become a powerful industrial nation, like Britain, lost out to Jefferson’s vision,
harking back to the days of yeoman farmers, the US may have remained a richer version
of Argentina today. Without Japan daring to dream that one day it will beat the Americans
in the car industry (in 1955, the US produced 7 million cars, against 70,000 for Japan),
we would have had no Toyota, and its luxury brand, Lexus. If Finland – a tiny nation of 3-
4 million people with seven centuries of colonial history – did not aspire to compete in the
most difficult industries with the best nations in the world, it would have maintained its
specialisation in logging – not an easy thing to avoid, when you have one of the largest
endowments of timber per capita in the world. Without China – once one of the poorest
nations in the world – believing itself to be capable of becoming the next superpower
(which may or may not come true), its industrial policy efforts would have been much less
ambitious than what it has been and the result of it much more modest. And so on.
Economists are usually averse to talk in terms of ‘vision’ because it introduces an
element of unpredictability and arbitrariness in what they see as a ‘science’. Indeed, the
46
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
rationalist framework with which most economists work these days has become a critical
hindrance to our understanding of the economic world, as it reduces all our decisions to a
totally predictable (at least in probabilistic terms) response to structurally given
incentives. However, the world is shaped by those people who refuse to do the ‘rational’
things and who come up with an alternative vision that most other people think will fail.
That is what the inventors of radical new technologies do. That is what entrepreneurship
is really about. And that is what the successful industrial policy-makers have achieved.
In the last three decades, the UK has been dominated by a vision of its future that has
turned out to be highly misleading. This vision has told people that the decline of the
British manufacturing industry is nothing to worry about – or even something to celebrate
– given that we have now entered a post-industrial society where manufacturing does not
matter anymore. The vision has exaggerated the extent of and the potential for
productivity growth in the financial industry by ignoring the extent of fraudulent and/or
socially unproductive financial activities. This vision has constantly told people that
industrial policy is not a reason why other countries may be doing better than the UK and
that, even if that were the case, such policy cannot be used in the UK because it is
fundamentally against the country’s tradition and values.
The events following the 2008 financial crisis have given a shock to the UK national
complacency based on this faulty vision. Now there is a greater recognition in the UK
establishment that the vision that it has held over the last three decades may have been
mistaken and that there has to be an alternative long-term economic vision. However, old
habits die hard and the old vision keeps re-asserting itself, not least because powerful
financial interests back it up, so the UK has not been able to come up with a viable
alternative vision for its future.
Without a new vision rejecting the comforting stories about the inevitability of the British
industrial decline and the futility of industrial policy, the UK will never be able to come up
with a viable economic strategy for the coming years, whatever the detailed measures of
industrial policy it may want to adopt. We are glad to report that the Secretary of the
Department of BIS himself was effectively stressing the same thing when he said in a
private letter to the UK Prime Minister and Deputy Prime Minister that “sense however
that there is still something important missing - a compelling vision of where the country
is heading beyond sorting out the fiscal mess; and a clear and confident message about
how we will earn our living in future [italics added]” (Cable, 2012).
4.2.2. Institutional settings
Our review shows that different countries have run industrial policies in very different
institutional settings, which have differed not just across countries but also across time
within the same country. The conclusion we draw from our case studies is that, while
some institutional settings are more favourable for the success of industrial policy, it is
not as if there is one particular institutional setting that a country must have in order to
have a successful industrial policy. Two aspects may be highlighted.
First, our study reveals that a ‘joined-up’ government – with good communication
between different departments and between different levels (national, regional, and
municipal) and ideally with an effective coordinating agency (like the French Planning
Commission, Japan’s MITI, or Korea’s EPB) – is certainly more conducive for successful
industrial policy. This is not only because a lot of industrial policy is about coordinating
interdependent activities but also because different things are done more effectively in
47
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
different departments and at different levels of government, which inevitably leads to a
coordination problem. In this regard, it is also helpful to be explicit about the existence of
industrial policy, as pretending that it does not exist increases the chance of different
departments failing to coordinate their activities or even undermining each other, as we
have seen in the case of the US.
In this regard, the current institutional setting of the UK government is actually not against
an effective industrial policy. The Department of Business, Innovation, and Skills (BIS)
may not have the budgetary control that Korea’s EPB had (which actually was a huge
exception), but it has a remit that is much broader than what a typical ‘ministry of trade
and industry’ has had in most countries, including many we have reviewed in this report.
The BIS controls and works with agencies in a variety of issues, ranging from skills
development to insolvency, from consumer protection to intellectual property rights, from
international trade to land use, and from low-pay issues to space technology. If the
activities between these agencies are well coordinated, it can actually be a very powerful
vehicle for industrial policy.
The second institutional dimension of industrial policy that we wish to highlight concerns
non-governmental institutions. Our study confirms the conclusion from earlier studies,
mostly related to the Japanese and other East Asian experiences (Johnson, 1982; Dore,
1986; Wade, 1990; World Bank, 1993) that ‘intermediate’ institutions that promote
communication and cooperation between the government and the private sector increase
the likelihood of industrial policy success. General employers’ associations, sectoral
industry associations, ‘deliberation councils’ (especially in Japan and Korea), and trade
unions (especially in Germany and Finland) have played important roles in this regard.
Our study actually permits us to go one step further and argue that industrial policy
success is promoted by the existence of thick networks of public, semi-public, and private
agencies, variously (depending on the country) made up of government agencies, large
enterprises (both private-sector – national and foreign – enterprises and SOEs), key
financial institutions (including regional, as opposed to national), alliances of SMEs,
sectoral industry associations, trade unions (and other bodies representing worker
interests), universities, research institutes, and so on.
Depending on how they are structured and interact with each other, these networks of
institutions have played key roles in innovation in cutting-edge technologies (especially in
the US, Finland, Brazil, and Korea), diffusion of technologies (especially in Singapore,
Germany, Brazil, and China), skills formation (especially in Japan, Germany, and
Singapore) and the development of world-class SMEs (especially in Italy, Japan, and
Germany). Once again, there are no set formulas here, but the lesson is that the
‘industrial commons’ – created through the cooperation in the provision of inputs with
public goods character and/or high fixed costs and through the cross-fertilisation of ideas
– that these networks establish and nurture are vital in promoting technological
innovations and quality improvements.
The UK may not be able to easily replicate these networks, given that they have been the
results of a long evolutionary process, based on trial-and-error (with some degree of luck
thrown in), but there are some of the above-mentioned institutions that may be
established without fundamentally changing the country’s overall institutional structure
and political economy. We discuss some of these in the issue-based sections below
(e.g., institutions that may promote more ‘patient’ capital or help SME developments).
48
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
4.2.3. Finance and corporate governance
One thing that should be obvious from our review is how much of industrial policy is not
about money. There are many important industrial policy measures that are about the
sharing of vision, coordination among interdependent activities, network-building among
relevant actors, and encouraging selective cooperation among potentially competing
agents, in which financial transfers play at best the role of sweeteners. This is good news
in times of ‘austerity’.
However, many industrial policy measures are about money. When so many
technologies are embodied in machines, there is no way a significant increase in
productivity or a significant shift in production structure that can happen without major
investments. Provision of adequate infrastructure and skills also costs money –
sometimes vast sums, especially in countries like the UK that has neglected these things
for substantial periods. A serious increase in R&D will require a lot of money, while even
the schemes to help SMEs may require a non-negligible amount of money, if they are to
have significant impacts. In countries with more successful industrial policy records,
various ways have been found to finance and subsidise these necessary things through
government intervention and public-private partnerships.
The UK government of course spends vast sums of money in funding or subsidising R&D
and infrastructural development, but, compared to other countries, these spending are
often less (in proportional terms) and less well targeted. The UK’s government-financed
R&D spending as a percentage of GDP was 0.58% in 2010, lower than the average in
the European Union-27 (0.68%), OECD (0.74%), and the US (0.92%), a vocal advocate
against government intervention. Arising from weaker public investments, the UK’s
average share of government GFCF in GDP was 1.8% between 2000 and 2010, lower
than its OECD counterparts such as Korea (5.4%), Japan (3.8%), Finland (2.6%), the
USA (2.5%) and Italy (2.3%) (OECD, 2012c).52
Recently, the establishment of a national development bank in the UK, in the image of
the likes of the German KfW or the Brazilian BNDES, has been discussed, but
unfortunately the coalition government has settled for creating a small investment fund,
rather than a real development bank. But, given the positive role that development banks
have played – not just in Brazil and Germany but also in Japan and Korea, this option
should be considered more seriously.
Financial regulation could also play an important role in industrial policy. Even if the UK
does not want to go as far as countries like Japan and Korea in the old days, or China
today, and explicitly compel banks to lend to particular industries or projects (‘directed
lending’) or to introduce regulation requiring that they lend more than a certain proportion
of their money to productive enterprises, it could introduce other regulatory measures to
simulate the effects. For example, it could discourage consumer loans and housing loans
by increasing capital reserve requirements for them. This would, as well as dampening
the housing bubble and reducing consumer debts, indirectly increase loans to productive
enterprises. With two major banks (the RBS and the HBOS) in public ownership, such re-
direction of lending does not even have to be based on a new regulation – it could be
done simply through an internal directive of a corporation. The fact that the British
52 Among our chosen countries within the OECD, only Germany had a lower share of government GFCF in
GDP (1.6%) between 2000 and 2010, compared to the UK.
49
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
government refuses to do even such a thing shows how beholden it is to the financial
sector lobby – it is not even willing to exercise the ultimate shareholder prerogative, the
supposed bedrock of Anglo-American capitalism, for fear of offending the financial sector.
More broadly speaking, the UK needs to find a way to make its financial market provide
more ‘patient capital’ so that long-term-oriented industrial policy is in sync with enterprise
management. Of course, this cannot be done in a way that was done in, say, Germany
(where the co-determination system made hostile takeover virtually impossible) and
Japan (where cross-shareholding made it very difficult). However, the point is to reduce
the power of short-term shareholders, and we can certainly find some other measures
that provide such service without fundamentally changing the architecture of the British
financial system. Possible measures include, most mildly, the prevention of the
publication of quarterly results (as recommended by the Kay report), tax reduction for
dividends from longer-term shareholding, heavier taxes for capital gains made from
shorter-term shareholding, and, most strongly, the introduction of greater voting rights for
longer-term shareholders.
4.2.4. Innovation
Countries with successful industrial policy all show strong commitments to innovation and
technological developments. Of the seven advanced countries reviewed in this report
(that is, nine countries minus China and Brazil), only Italy had a lower R&D intensity
(gross R&D spending as a percentage of GDP) than the UK in 2010 (1.26% vs. 1.80%).53
The UK’s figure was lower than that of Singapore (2.09%) and the OECD average
(2.38%), while the other countries were more than 55% higher (Germany, 2.80%; the US,
2.83%; Japan, 3.26%). Notably, Korea (3.74%) and Finland (3.90%) had more than
double that of the UK.
Of particular concern is also how the UK’s R&D intensity has declined over the years.
Among the 10 countries in our study, the UK is the only country that saw a fall in its R&D
intensity between the periods 1991-1995 (1.98%) and 2006-2010 (1.79%) (Table A.2 in
the appendix). Improvements for the other countries ranged from 0.12%-points (Italy) to
1.54%-points (Finland) during the period.
The UK is certainly capable of doing much better than this, not least because it is one of
the world leaders in scientific research (around 10% of world output). However, such
research is poorly translated into industrial strength (it produces only around 1% of world
patents). Between 2004 and 2011, the number of patents in force in the UK fell by 6%
(from 473,904 to 445,380) (WIPO, 2012). By contrast, the number of patents rose in the
US (by 29%, 1.63 million to 2.11 million), Japan (by 40%, 1.10 million to 1.54 million) and
Korea (by 105%, 331,437 to 678,005) over the same period. Korea, which lagged behind
the UK less than a decade ago, now has 1.5 times the number of UK patents. Some
believe that the solution to this problem is to introduce the US-style system, where
maximum incentive is created for academics to establish profit-making firms based on
their research, but other countries – Japan, Finland, Korea, and Singapore – have
promoted their technological developments mainly through other means. Alternative
arrangements need to be explored (see O’Sullivan, 2011; Wessner & Wolff, 2012), while
current efforts like the catapult centres as well as the attempts to overcome the so-called
53 The UK’s R&D intensity is also higher than China (1.76%) and Brazil (1.13% in 2008) but this is cold
comfort as the two countries are at a different stage of development.
50
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
51
‘valley of death’ and the scaling-up challenges should be strongly supported (House of
Commons, 2013).
The UK government also needs to reassert its role in boosting innovation. The UK’s poor
performance in total R&D expenditure is to an important degree due to its weak support
for public R&D spending.54 In the OECD, the UK had the second lowest publicly-funded
R&D (as a percentage of GDP) at 0.59% in 2010, marginally ahead of Italy (0.55%) – a
result that is reflected in its relatively low and declining R&D intensity (Table A.2 in the
appendix). Even the US government, the supposed champion of free markets, spent
significantly more on public R&D. Its publicly-funded R&D intensity was 1.01% in 2010.
4.2.5. Managing TNCs
As it should have been clear throughout our report, one important – and increasingly
important – issue in industrial policy is how to maximise the benefits from the presence of
TNCs, while minimising their costs.
In the UK context, the most contentious issue regarding TNCs has been tax avoidance
through transfer pricing, especially through the overcharging of brand licenses,
technology fees, and certain inputs. While this has significant fiscal implications,
especially in the short run, it is less important for the long-term health of the economy, for
which what the TNCs do in terms of technology transfer, training, and local sourcing
matter far more than the tax revenue they generate.
Until recently, countries, including many of the ones reviewed in this report (especially
Japan, Finland, Korea, and China), have put explicit conditions on technology transfer,
local sourcing, and ownership restrictions (including joint venture requirements). These
days, some of these – such as local contents requirements and foreign exchange
balancing requirements (where the subsidiary of a TNC is required to export at least as
much as it imports) – are banned through the TRIMs (Trade-related Investment
Measures) agreement of the WTO. However, there are other measures that are not, such
as those imposing conditions regarding joint venture requirement, the hiring of local
labour, technology transfer, and the conduct of R&D in the host country. Governments
can also provide targeted subsidies, directed credits, and tailor-made infrastructure for
TNCs, provided that these do not violate the MFN (most-favoured nation) provision
(Thrasher & Gallagher, 2008, cited in Chang, 2011).
Moreover, even explicitly banned performance conditions for TNCs have always been
used informally, based upon negotiations with the TNC concerned, including by the UK
government in the 1980s and the 1990s. However, if these informal requirements are to
be effective, the government needs to know what it wants to achieve through them, so
the establishment of a clear vision is going to be helpful in this respect too. Moreover, the
UK, now increasingly dependent on attracting and retaining TNCs in manufacturing
industries, should learn from the more active use of ‘carrots’ by the Singapore
government, often tailor-made for the needs of the particular TNCs that it wants to attract.
54 A large body of research indicates that public R&D spending does not crowd out private R&D spending,
but rather, has a complementary effect across a diverse range of countries: Finland (Czarnitzki et al., 2007),
Germany (Aerts & Schmidt, 2008; Hussinger, 2008), Japan (Koga, 2005) the United States (Feldman &
Kelley, 2006) and the OECD (Guellec & Van Pottelsberghe, 2003; Falk, 2006).
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
4.2.5. SMEs
Different countries reviewed in our report have helped SMEs in different ways, and with
different degrees of successes, but some of the measures used may be applicable to the
UK. Realistically speaking, it will be very difficult for the UK to replicate the thick
institutional tissues supporting the SMEs in Germany or Italy – made up of industry
associations, local banks, universities, specialised training institutes, and so on – but it
can do at least some certain things to improve its support for SMEs.
First of all, it should be able to at least increase financing for SMEs. Once again, given
the country’s existing financial structure and political economy, it may be very difficult for
the UK to set up a specialised bank for SMEs, whether explicitly (as in Korea) or implicitly
(as in the case of regional banks in Germany or Italy), but the UK government can still
increase credit availability for SMEs by imposing some conditions on the lending by the
state-owned banks or in relation to the ‘funding for lending’ scheme in such a way that
financing for SMEs is increased.
Second, it would be possible for the UK to replicate some of the institutions that help
SMEs in countries like Germany and Italy. Organisation of similar SMEs into cooperative
arrangements for high fixed-cost activities – like export marketing, R&D, and the
purchase of technical or management consultancy services – may be encouraged. The
UK government may help this by providing subsidies or tax reductions for these
arrangements or providing some subsidies towards bringing in Italian or German experts
to advise on the issue. It may also provide some of these inputs itself, by setting up
agencies providing ‘extension services’ for SMEs.
4.2.7. Skills and training
Our study shows that more skills, higher-level skills and different kinds of skills need to
be developed, if the UK wants to be able to enhance its industrial competitiveness, that
is, expanding and scaling-up its manufacturing base and developing industrial activities
with higher value-added and higher wages. The UK government cannot ignore the
existence of skills gaps and mismatches, which are hindering the country’s firms’
capacities for transforming and translating research outputs into industrial activities at the
shopfloor level. Skills cannot be built in a day: their development requires long-term
investments in learning processes and institution building, as the development of the
German integrated vocational training system has shown. Moreover, today’s skills supply
not only has to match today’s skills demands but should also anticipate tomorrow’s skills
demands, as the Singaporean and Korean success stories have shown.
Future transformations of the industrial landscape in a given country are not only the
results of quantitative expansions of existing activities but continuous introduction of new
activities and qualitative changes in existing activities. This means that existing
companies’ perceptions of future skill needs may not necessarily be accurate. A way to
prepare the country for both these quantitative (more skills) and qualitative (different and
higher skills) transformations is to develop what we call skill profiles benchmarks, based
on the knowledge of industry-specific skill profiles, which are stylised representations of
the kinds of skills that the generic firm in a specific industry has to be equipped with in
order to perform certain productive activities (Andreoni, 2013e). Skill profile benchmarks
complement the assessment of current industrial skills gaps and mismatches by
52
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
53
suggesting the specific kind of industrial skills required by countries which want to
prepare their future manufacturing landscape.55
55 Of course, defining specific skill profile benchmarks for each industry should not make us forget that the
same production process can actually be performed by different combinations of production capabilities. Nor
should we be tempted to ignore the fact that these skills have to be complemented by appropriate
investments in the expansion of firms’ production capacity.
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
5. Looking ahead
Policies for the future depend on key decisions that are made today. The continued loss
of manufacturing capabilities in the UK disadvantages the economy over the long-term
because the manufacturing sector boosts technologically-driven productivity growth and
has strong interdependencies with other high-value sectors, especially high-value-added
services, in the economy. Although exactly what would be high-value industries in 20, not
to speak of 50, years’ time is difficult to predict, what is certain is that the UK’s potential
to tap into the most profitable supply chains of the future and capture value will largely
depend on the industrial capabilities that it builds and retains today.
Despite what the opponents of industrial policy may have us believe, industrial policy has
always been around, even though some countries have given it another name, like the
US has done throughout its history, and even though others have had it without realizing
and thus failing to properly organise it, like the UK has done in the last three decades.
However much it thinks it is avoiding ‘bad’ kind of industrial policy by avoiding targeting,
the UK government is still targeting its policies at different types of activities. Given this, it
is better to accept that targeted industrial policy is necessary and try to get the targeting
right, rather than pretending that there is no targeting and making a mess of the policy.
And industrial policy is here to stay. Countries like China and Brazil are going to step up
their industrial policies, as they try to break into the premier league of world industry.
Whatever the big rhetoric at the central government is, a lot of industrial policy is going to
chug along in countries like Germany and Italy, as their industrial policies are deeply
rooted in local structures. The US will keep at its industrial policy through federal R&D
funding, and perhaps keep denying that it has any industrial policy. Singapore may
continue its emphasis on free trade, but it will keep targeting strategic industries and
setting explicit goals, in order to maintain its manufacturing base. Countries like Japan
and Korea, having toned down their industrial policies since the 1990s for various good
and bad reasons, are now trying to revive at least some of their industrial policy
measures, especially in high-technology industries. Finland has successfully restructured
its industrial policy by putting great emphasis on funding innovation and will press on with
that strategy. Most of the countries we have reviewed in this report are also very keen to
take pole positions in the ‘green’ technologies and are introducing a lot of industrial policy
measures to promote them.
By constantly being in denial about the need for better industrial policy, the UK is going to
fall further and further behind in manufacturing industries. The once-comforting thought
that this does not really matter because the City will step into the breach is looking
increasingly unrealistic. Unless something is done to reverse the manufacturing decline
of the country – and industrial policy will be an integral part of that something – the UK
risks falling behind.
54
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
References
ABDI (Brazilian Agency for Industrial Development). (2006). An Industrial Policy for
Brazil. Brasilia: ABDI.
Abraham, K., & Houseman, S. (1993). Job Security in America: Lessons from Germany.
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Abramovitz, M. (1986). Catching Up, Forging Ahead, and Falling Behind. The Journal of
Economic History, 46(2), 385-406.
Adams, P. (1991). State Policy and the Chemical Industry in Western Europe. In A.
Martinelli (Ed.), International Markets and Global Firms: A Comparative Study of
Organized Business (pp. 91-113). London: Sage.
Aerts, K., & Schmidt, T. (2008). Two for the Price of One? Additionality Effects of R&D
Subsidies: A Comparison between Flanders and Germany. Research Policy, 37, 806-
822.
Aghion, P., Dewatripont, M., Du, L., Harrison, A., & Legros, P. (2012). Industrial Policy
and Competition. NBER Working Paper 18048.
Aiginger, K., & Sieber, S. (2006). The Matrix Approach to Industrial Policy. International
Review of Applied Economics, 20(5), 573-601.
Allen, G. C. (1981). A Short Economic History of Modern Japan. London and
Basingstoke: Macmillan.
Amsden, A. H. (1989). Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization. New
York: Oxford University Press.
Amsden, A. H., & Singh, A. (1994). The Optimal Degree of Competition and Dynamic
Efficiency in Japan and Korea. European Economic Review, 38(3/4), 941-951.
Andreoni, A. (2011). Productive Capabilities Indicators for Industrial Policy Design.
UNIDO Working Paper 17.
Andreoni, A. (2013a). Manufacturing Agrarian Change. Agricultural Production,
Intermediate Institutions and Intersectoral Commons: Lessons from Latin America. PhD
Thesis, Third Essay. University of Cambridge.
Andreoni, A. (2013b). Structural Learning: Embedding Discoveries and the Dynamics of
Production. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, forthcoming.
Andreoni, A. (2013c). Making Structural and Industrial Policy More Effective, Report of
the International Workshop on Structural and Industrial Policy organized by BMZ
(German Federal Ministry for Economic Cooperation and Development), GIZ (German
Development Agency) and UNIDO, Berlin (23-24 May).
55
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Andreoni, A. (2013d). Industrial Policy for Manufacturing Development. Structural
Dynamics and Institutional Changes in a Dual Economy: A Case of Dependent
Industrialisation in the Italian Mezzogiorno. PhD Thesis, Fifth Essay. University of
Cambridge.
Andreoni, A. (2013e). Industrial Skills: Driving the Structural Transformation of Production
Systems. In UNIDO Toolkit for Industrial Skills Analysis. Vienna: UNIDO (forthcoming).
Andreoni, A., & Scazzieri, R. (2013). Triggers of Change: Structural Trajectories and
Production Dynamics. Cambridge Journal of Economics, forthcoming.
Arvanitis, R., & Qiu, H. (2008). Research for Policy Development: Industrial Clusters in
South China. In Fuelling Economic Growth (pp. 39-85). Ottawa: Practical Action
Publishing.
Baldassarri, M. (Ed.). (1993). Industrial Policy in Italy, 1945-90. New York: St. Martin's
Press.
Barbieri, E., Di Tommaso, M. R., & Bonnini, S. (2012). Industrial Development Policies
and Performances in Southern China: Beyond the Specialised Industrial Cluster
Program. China Economic Review, 23, 613-625.
Barca, F., & Trento, S. (1997). La Parabola delle Partecipazioni Statali: Una Missione
Tradita. In F. Barca (Ed.), Storia del Capitalismo Italiano dal Dopoguerra a Oggi (pp. 186-
234). Rome: Donzelli.
Becattini, G. (1987). Mercato e Forze Locali: Il Distretto Industriale. Bologna: Il Mulino.
Bellak, C., & Luostarinen, R. (1994). Foreign Direct Investment of Small and Open
Economies: Case of Austria and Finland. Helsinki: Helsinki School of Economics and
Business Administration.
Best, M. H. (2011). The American System for Creating High Tech Industries: the Historic
Place of Greater Boston. Paper presented at the DRUID Annual Conference, Denmark
(15-17 June).
Bianchi, P., & Labory, S. (2006). International Handbook on Industrial Policy.
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
BIS (Department for Business, Innovation & Skills). (2012). Industrial Strategy – UK
Sectoral Analysis. London: BIS.
Block, F. (2008). Swimming Against the Current: The Rise of a Hidden Developmental
State in the United States. Politics and Society, 36(2), 169-206.
Buigues, P-A., & Sekkat, K. (2009). Industrial Policy in Europe, Japan and the USA:
Amounts, Mechanisms and Effectiveness. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Cable, V. (2012). Industrial Policy. Private Letter to the Prime Minister and Deputy Prime
Miniter (8 February). Retrieved December 23, 2012, from BBC:
http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/shared/bsp/hi/pdfs/06_03_12_vince_cable_letter.pdf
Canuto, O., Cavallari, M., & Reis, J. G. (2013). The Brazilian Competitiveness Cliff.
Economic Premise, 105.
56
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Cappelen, Å., Raknerud, A., & Rybalka, M. (2012). The Effects of R&D Tax Credits on
Patenting and Innovations. Research Policy, 41(2), 334-345.
Chan, C. B. (Ed.). (2011). Heart Work 2 – EDB & Partners: New Frontiers for the
Singapore Economy. Singapore: Straits Times Press.
Chang, H-J. (1993). The Political Economy of Industrial Policy in Korea, Cambridge
Journal of Economics, 17(2), 131-157.
Chang, H-J. (1994a). The Political Economy of Industrial Policy. London and
Basingstoke: Macmillan.
Chang, H-J. (1994b). State, Institutions and Structural Change. Structural Change and
Economic Dynamics, 293-313.
Chang, H-J. (1995). Explaining 'Flexible Rigidities' in East Asia. In T. Killick (Ed.), The
Flexible Economy: Causes and Consequences of the Adaptability of National Economies
(pp. 197-221). London: Routledge.
Chang, H-J. (1998). Globalization, Transnational Corporations, and Economic
Development: Can the Developing Countries Pursue Strategic Industrial Policy in a
Globalizing World Economy? In D. Baker, G. Epstein, & R. Pollin (Eds.), Globalization
and Progressive Economic Policy (pp. 97-113). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Chang, H-J. (2002). Kicking Away the Ladder: Development Strategy in Historical
Perspective. London: Anthem Press.
Chang, H-J. (2003). Trade and Industrial Policy Issues. In H.-J. Chang (Ed.), Rethinking
Development Economics (pp. 257-276). London: Anthem Press.
Chang, H-J. (2004). ‘Regulation of Foreign Investment in Historical Perspective’,
European Journal of Development Research, 16(3), 687-715.
Chang, H-J. (2005). Why Developing Countries Need Tariffs – How WTO NAMA
Negotiations Could Deny Developing Countries' Right to a Future. Geneva: South
Centre.
Chang, H-J. (2006). Industrial Policy in East Asia – Lessons for Europe. EIB Papers,
11(2), 106-132.
Chang, H-J. (2007). Bad Samaritans – Rich Nations, Poor Policies, and the Threat to the
Developing World. London: Random House.
Chang, H-J. (2009a). Rethinking Public Policy in Agriculture: Lessons from Distant and
Recent History. Rome: Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations.
Chang, H-J. (2009b). Under-explored Treasure Troves of Development Lessons:
Lessons from the Histories of Small Rich European Countries. In M. Kremer, P. Van
Lieshout, & R. Went (Eds.), Doing Good or Doing Better: Development Policies in a
Globalizing World (pp. 81-106). Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.
Chang, H-J. (2010). 23 Things They Don't Tell You About Capitalism. London: Penguin
Group.
57
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Chang, H-J. (2011). Industrial Policy: Can We Go Beyond an Unproductive
Confrontation? In J. Y. Lin, & B. Pleskovic (Eds.), Annual World Bank Conference on
Development Economics 2010, Global: Lessons from East Asia and the Global Financial
Crisis (pp. 83-109). Washington, DC: World Bank.
Chang, H-J., & Evans, P. (2005). The Role of Institutions in Economic Change. In S. D.
Paula, & G. A. Dymski (Eds.), Reimagining Growth: Institutions, Development, and
Society (pp. 99-140). London: Zed Press.
Cimoli, M., Dosi, G., & Stiglitz, J. E. (Eds.). (2009). Industrial Policy and Development:
The Political Economy of Capabilities Accumulation. New York: Oxford University Press.
Clapp, R. A. (1995). Creating Competitive Advantage: Forest Policy as Industrial Policy in
Chile. Economic Geography, 71(3), 273-296.
Cohen, S., & Zysman, J. (1987). Manufacturing Matters: The Myth of the Post-Industrial
Economy. New York: Basic Books.
Criscuolo, C., Martin, R., Overman, H., & Van Reenen, J. (2012). The Causal Effects of
an Industrial Policy. NBER Working Paper 17842.
Czarnitzki, D., Ebersberger, B., & Fier, A. (2007). The Relationship Between R&D
Collaboration, Subsidies and R&D Performance: Empirical Evidence from Finland and
Germany. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 22, 1347-1366.
Devlin, R., & Moguillansky, G. (2012). What’s New in the New Industrial Policy in Latin
America? World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 6191.
Dore, R. P. (1986). Flexible Rigidities: Industrial Policy and Structural Adjustment in the
Japanese Economy, 1970-80. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Dosi, G., Tyson, L. D., & Zysman, J. (1989). Trade, Technologies and Development: A
Framework for Discussing Japan. In C. Johnson, L. D. Tyson, & J. Zysman (Eds.),
Politics and Productivity: How Japan's Development Strategy Works (pp. 3-38). New
York: HarperBusiness.
Evans, P. (1995). Embedded Autonomy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
European Commission. (2002). Industrial Policy in an Enlarged Europe. Brussels:
European Commission.
European Commission. (2010). An Integrated Industrial Policy for the Globalisation Era:
Putting Competitiveness and Sustainability at Centre Stage. Brussels: European
Commission.
Falk, M. (2006). What Drives Business Research and Development (R&D) Intensity
across Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries?
Applied Economics, 38(5), 533-547.
Fasbender, K. (2004). Selected principles, elements and experiences of privatisation in
Germany. HWWA Report 245.
58
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Federico, G., & Giannetti, R. (1999). Italy: Stalling and Surpassing. In J. Foreman-Peck,
& G. Federico (Eds.), European Industrial Policy: The Twentieth-Century Experience (pp.
124-151). New York: Oxford University Press.
Feldenkirchen, W. (1999). Siemens, 1918–1945. Columbus: Ohio State University Press.
Feldman, M. P., & Kelley, M. R. (2006). The Ex Ante Assessment of Knowledge
Spillovers: Government R&D Policy , Economic Incentives and Private Firm Behavior.
Research Policy, 35, 1509-1521.
Ferraz, J. C., Nassif, A., & Oliva, R. (2009). Avanços, Desafios e Oportunidades para
Políticas de Desenvolvimento Produtivo na América Latina. Rio de Janeiro: Banco
Nacional de Desenvolvimento Econômico e Social.
Ferri, G., & Liu, L. (2010). Honor Thy Creditors Beforan Thy Shareholders: Are the Profits
of Chinese State-Owned Enterprises Real? Asian Economic Papers, 9(3), 50-71.
Fields, G. S., & Wan, H. (1989). Wage-Setting Institutions and Economic Growth. World
Development, 17(9), 1471-1483.
Figueiredo, P. N. (2008). Industrial Policy Changes and Firm-Level Technological
Capability Development: Evidence from Northern Brazil. World Development, 36(1), 55-
88.
Findlay, R., & Wellisz, S. (1993). Five Small Open Economies. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Fuchs, E., & Kirchain, R. (2010). Design for Location? The Impact of Manufacturing
Offshore on Technology Competitiveness in the Optoelectronics Industry. Management
Science, 56(12), 2323-2349.
Georghiou, L., Smith, K., Toivanen, O., & Ylä-Anttila, P. (2003). Evaluation of the Finnish
Innovation Support System. Helsinki: Ministry of Trade and Industry, Finland.
Gobbo, F. (Ed.). (1989). Distretti e Sistemi Produttivi alla Soglia degli Anni ’90. Milan:
Franco Angeli.
Goto, A., & Kodama, T. (2006). Japan’s Innovation System: Rebuilding the Engine of
Growth. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press .
Goto, A., & Wakasugi, R. (1988). Technology Policy. In R. Komiya, M. Okuno, & K.
Suzumura (Eds.), Industrial Policy of Japan (pp. 183-204). New York: Academic Press.
Government of Brazil. (2008). Productive Development Policy: Innovation and Investment
for Sustainable Growth. Brasilia: Government of Brazil.
Guellec, D., & Van Pottelsberghe, B. (2003). The Impact of Public R&D Expenditure on
Business R&D. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 12(3), 225-243.
Guerrieri, P., & Meliciani, V. (2005). Technology and International Competitiveness: The
Interdependence between Manufacturing and Producer Services. Structural Change and
Economic Dynamics, 16, 489-502.
59
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Hall, P. (1986). Governing the Economy: The Politics of State Intervention in Britain and
France. New York: Oxford University Press.
Hamilton, A. (1791 [2001]). Report on the Subject of Manufactures, 5 December 1791.
As reprinted in Alexander Hamilton – Writings. New York: The Library Classics of the
United States.
Hausmann, R., & Rodrik, D. (2003). Economic Development as Self-discovery. Journal of
Development Economics, 72(2), 603-633.
Hay, D. A. (2001). The Post-1990 Brazilian Trade Liberalisation and the Performance of
Large Manufacturing Firms: Productivity, Market Share and Profits. The Economic
Journal, 111(473), 620-641.
Hidalgo, C. A., & Hausmann, R. (2009). The Building Blocks of Economic Complexity.
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America,
106(26), 10570-10575.
Hirschman, A. (1958). The Strategy of Economic Development. New Haven and London:
Yale University Press.
Hosono, A., & Hongo, Y. (2012). Cerrado Agriculture: A Model of Sustainable and
Inclusive Development. Tokyo: Japan International Cooperation Agency Research
Institute.
House of Commons. (2013). Bridging the Valley of Death: Improving the
Commercialisation of Research, Eighth Report of Session 2012-13. London: House of
Commons.
Huff, W. G. (1995). The Developmental State, Government, and Singapore's Economic
Development Since 1960. World Development, 23(8), 1421-1438.
Huff, W. G. (1999). Singapore's Economic Development: Four Lessons and Some
Doubts. Oxford Agrarian Studies, 27(1), 33-55.
Hussinger, K. (2008). R&D and Subsidies at the Firm Level: An Application of Parametric
and Semiparametric Two-Step Selection Models. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 23,
729-747.
Jäntti, M., & Vartiainen, J. (2009). The Finnish Developmental State and its Growth
Regime. World Institute for Development Economics Research Paper No. 2009/35.
Johnson, C. A. (1982). MITI and the Japanese Miracle. Stanford: Stanford University
Press.
Kaldor, N. (1981). The Role of Increasing Returns, Technical Progress and Cumulative
Causation in the Theory of International Trade and Economic Growth. Economie
Appliquée, 34(4), 593-617.
Karl, H., Moller, A., & Wink, R. (2003). Regional Industrial Policies in Germany. Ceris-Cnr
Working Paper No. 9/2003.
Ketels, C. H. (2007). Industrial Policy in the United States. Journal of Industry,
Competition and Trade, 7(3/4), 147-167.
60
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Kim, D., & Koh, Y. (2010). Korea's Industrial Development. In I. SaKong, & Y. Koh (Eds.),
The Korean Economy: Six Decades and Development (pp. 83-122). Seoul: Korea
Development Institute.
Kirby, W. C. (1990). Continuity and Change in Modern China: Economic Planning on the
Mainland and on Taiwan, 1943-1958. The Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs(24), 121-
141.
Koga, T. (2005). R&D Subsidy and Self-Financed R&D: The Case of Japanese High-
Technology Start-Ups. Small Business Economics, 24, 53-62.
Kosonen, K. (1992). Saving and Economic Growth from a Nordic Perspective. In J.
Pekkarinen, M. Pohjola, & R. Rowthorn (Eds.), Social Corporatism: A Superior Economic
System (pp. 178-209). New York: Oxford University Press.
Kuisel, R. F. (1981). Capitalism and the State in Modern France. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Kume, H. (1989). A Proteção Efetiva Proposta na Reforma Tarifária de 1988. Rio de
Janeiro: Funcex.
Kupfer, D. (2012). Case Studies of Successful and Unsuccessfull Industrial Policies: The
Case of Brazil. Presentation at the World Bank Roundtable on New Thinking on Industrial
Policy, Washington, DC (22-23 May).
Lall, S. (1992). Technological Capabilities and Industrialization. World Development,
20(2), 165-186.
Lall, S. (2001). Competitiveness, Technology And Skills. Cheltenham, UK and
Northampton, USA: Edward Elgar.
Lall, S. (2004). Selective Industrial and Trade Policies in Developing Countries:
Theoretical and Empirical Issues. In C. Soludo, O. Ogbu, & H-J. Chang (Eds.), The
Politics of Trade and Industrial Policy in Africa: Forced Consensus? (pp. 75-109).
Trenton, New Jersey and Asmara, Eritrea: Africa World Press.
Lall, S., & Teubal, M. (1998). "Market-Stimulating" Technology Policies in Developing
Countries: A Framework with Examples from East Asia. World Development, 1369-1385.
Landesmann, M. (1992). Industrial Policies and Social Corporatism. In J. Pekkarinen, M.
Pohjola, & R. Rowthorn (Eds.), Social Corporatism: A Superior Economic System (pp.
242-279). New York: Oxford University Press.
Laranja, M., Uyarra, E., & Flanagan, K. (2008). Policies for Science, Technology and
Innovation: Translating Rationales into Regional Policies in a Multi-level Setting.
Research Policy, 37(5), 823-835.
Lechevalier, S., Ikeda, Y., & Nishimura, J. (2010). The Effect of Participation in
Government Consortia on the R&D Productivity of Firms: A Case Study of Robot
Technology in Japan. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 19(8), 669-692.
Lee, J-W. (1996). Government Interventions and Productivity Growth. Journal of
Economic Growth, 1(3), 391-414.
61
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Lemola, T. (2002). Convergence of National Science and Technology Policies: The Case
of Finland. Research Policy, 31, 1481-1490.
Lenihan, H. (1999). An Evaluation of a Regional Development Agency's Grants in Terms
of Deadweight and Displacement. Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy,
17(3), 303-318.
Lenihan, H., Hart, M., & Roper, S. (2007). Industrial Policy Evaluation: Theoretical
Foundations and Empirical Innovations: New Wine in New Bottles. International Review
of Applied Economics, 21(3), 37-41.
Lim, L. (1983). Singapore's Success: The Myth of the Free Market Economy. Asian
Survey, 23(6), 752-764.
Lin, J. Y. (2012). New Structural Economics: A Framework for Rethinking Development
and Policy. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Lin, J., & Chang, H-J. (2009). Should Industrial Policy in Developing Countries Conform
to Comparative Advantage or Defy it? A Debate between Justin Lin and Ha-Joon Chang.
Development Policy Review, 27(5), 483-502.
Liu, L. (2005). China's Industrial Policies and the Global Business Revolution: The Case
of the Domestic Appliance Industry. Oxford: Routledge.
Loasby, B. (1999). Knowledge, Institutions and Evolution in Economics. Routledge:
London and New York.
Macpherson, W. J. (1987). The Economic Development of Japan, 1868-1941.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Maddison, A. (1989). The World Economy in the 20th Century. Paris: OECD.
Maddison, A. (2001). The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective. Paris: OECD.
Magaziner, I. C., & Hout, T. M. (1980). Japanese Industrial Policy: A Descriptive Account
of Postwar Developments with Case Studies of Selected Industries. London: Policy
Studies Institute.
Malerba, F. (2002). Sectoral Systems of Innovation and Production. Research Policy,
31(2), 247-264.
Markusen, A. (1996). Interaction between Regional and Industrial Policies: Evidence from
Four Countries. International Regional Science Review, 19(1/2), 49-77.
Marukawa, T. (2011). Technology Acquisition by Indigenous Firms: The Case of the
Chinese and Indian Automobile Industries. In M. Ohara, M. Vijayabaskar, & H. Lin (Eds.),
Industrial Dynamics in China and India: Firms, Clusters, and Different Growth Paths (pp.
63-79). Basingstoke: Macmillan Publishers Limited.
Mazzucato, M. (2011). The Entrepreneurial State. London: Demos.
Medeiros, C. A. (2003). The Post-War American Technological Development as a Military
Enterprise. Contributions to Political Economy, 22, 41-62.
62
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Meissner, F. (1988). Technology Transfer in the Developing World: The Case of the Chile
Foundation. New York: Praeger.
Metcalfe, J. S. (1995). Technology Systems and Technology Policy in an Evolutionary
Framework. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 19(1), 25-46.
Miettinen, R. (2002). National Innovation System – Scientific Concept or Political
Rhetoric. Helsinki: Edita Prima Ltd.
MIIT (Ministry of Industry and Information Technology of the People's Republic of China).
(2013, January). Guidance on Corporate Mergers and Acquisitions to Accelerate the
Growth of Key Industries. Retrieved February 14, 2013, from Ministry of Industry and
Information Technology of the People's Republic of China:
http://www.miit.gov.cn/n11293472/n11293832/n11293907/n11368223/15130615.html
Mkandawire, T. (2005). Targeting and Universalism in Poverty Reduction, Social Policy,
and Development Programme. Programme Paper No. 23. Geneva: United Nations
Research Institute on Social Development.
MKE (Ministry of Knowledge Economy, Korea). (2010). The Industrial Complex Cluster
Program of Korea. Seoul: MKE.
Mokyr, J. (1990). The Lever of the Riches: Technology Creativity and Economic
Progress. New York: Oxford University Press.
Mokyr, J. (2002). The Gifts of Athena: Historical Origins of the Knowledge Economy.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Mowery, D. C., & Rosenberg, N. (1993). The U.S. National Innovation System. In R. R.
Nelson (Ed.), National Innovation Systems: A Comparative Analysis (pp. 29-75). New
York: Oxford University Press.
Mowery, D. C., & Rosenberg, N. (1999). Paths of Innovation: Technological Change in
20th-Century America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Müller-Jentsch, W. (1995). From Collective Voice to Co-management. In J. Rogers, & W.
Streeck (Eds.), Works Councils: Consultation, Representation, and Cooperation in
Industrial Relations (pp. 53-78). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Nail, J., & Brown, H. (2006). Identifying Technology Flows and Spillovers Through NAICS
Coding of ATP Project Participants. Gaithersburg, MD: National Institute of Standards
and Technology.
Nezu, R. (2007). Industrial Policy in Japan. Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade,
7, 229-243.
Nolan, P. (2001). China and the Global Economy: National Champions, Industrial Policy,
and the Big Business Revolution. New York: Palgrave.
Nurkse, R. (1952). Some International Aspects of the Problem of Economic
Development. The American Economic Review, 42(2), 571-583.
O’Sullivan, E. (2011). A Review of International Approaches to Manufacturing Research.
Cambridge: University of Cambridge Institute for Manufacturing.
63
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Ocampo, J. A. (2006). Latin America and the World Economy in the Long Twentieth
Century. In K. S. Jomo, The Great Divergence: Hegemony, Uneven Development and
Global Inequality (pp. 44-93). New York: Oxford University Press.
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). (1975). Objectives
and Instruments of Industrial Policy: A Comparative Study. Paris: OECD.
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). (1993). Employment
Outlook 1993. Paris: OECD.
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). (1998). Spotlight on
Public Support to Industry. Paris: OECD.
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). (1999). Boosting
Innovation: The Cluster Approach. Paris: OECD.
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). (2003). Privatising
State-owned Enterprises: An Overview of Policies and Practices in OECD Countries.
Paris: OECD.
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). (2009). Roundtable
on Competition Policy, Industrial Policy and National Champions. Paris: OECD.
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). (2012a). Main
Science and Technology Indicators Database. Paris: OECD.
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). (2012b). Industrial
Policy and Territory Development: Lessons From Korea. Paris: OECD.
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). (2012c). National
Accounts Statistics Database. Paris: OECD.
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). (2013). Perspectives
on Global Development 2013: Industrial Policies in a Changing World: Shifting Up a
Gear. Paris: OECD.
Okimoto, D. I. (1989). Between MITI and the Market: Japanese Industrial Policy for High
Technology. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Owen, G. (2012). Industrial Policy in Europe since the Second World War: What Has
Been Learnt? ECIPE Occassional Paper No. 1.
Park, S-H., & Chan, K. S. (1989). A Cross-Country Input-Output Analysis of Intersectoral
Relationships between Manufacturing and Services and their Employment Implications.
World Development, 17(2), 199-212.
Peebles, G., & Wilson, P. (2002). Economic Growth and Development in Singapore: Past
and Future. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.
Perelman, M. (2003). The Weakness in Strong Intellectual Property Rights. Challenge,
46(6), 32-61.
Piore, M. J., & Sabel, E. C. (1984). The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities For
Prosperity. New York: Basic Books.
64
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Pisano, G. P., & Shih, W. C. (2012). Producing Prosperity: Why America Needs a
Manufacturing Renaissance. Boston, MA: Harvard Business Review Press.
Pisano, G. P., & Shih, W. C. (2009). Restoring American Competitiveness. Harvard
Business Review, 114-125.
Poncet, S. (2010). Inward and Outward FDI in China. In D. Greenaway, C. Milner, & S.
Yao (Eds.), China and the World Economy (pp. 112-134). Croydon: Palgrave Macmillan.
Pritchett, L., Woolcock, M., & Andrews, M. (2012). Looking Like a State: Techniques of
Persistent Failure in State Capability for Implementation. UNU-WIDER Working Paper
No. 2012/63.
Rauchway, E. (2007). The Nineteenth-century US as a Developmental State. Paper
presented at the Harvard International History Seminar, Cambridge, MA (14 November).
Richardson, G. B. (1972). The Organisation of Industry. The Economic Journal, 82(327),
883-896.
Rodrik, D. (2004). Industrial Policy For The Twenty-First Century. Paper prepared for
UNIDO. John F. Kennedy School of Government, Boston.
Rodrik, D. (2008). Normalizing Industrial Policy. Commission on Growth and
Development Working Paper No. 3. Washington, DC: The World Bank.
Rodrik, D. (2009). The New Development Economics: We Shall Experiment, but How
Shall We Learn? In J. Cohen, & W. Easterly (Eds.), What Works in Development?
Thinking Big and Thinking Small (pp. 24-47). Washington, DC: The Brookings Institute.
Roehrig, M. F. (1994). Foreign Joint Ventures in Contemporary China. New York: St.
Martin's Press.
Rose, R. (1991). What is Lesson-Drawing? Journal of Public Policy, 11(1), 3-30.
Rosenberg, N. (1963). Technological Change in the Machine Tool Industry, 1840-1910.
The Journal of Economic History, 23(4), 414-443.
Rosenberg, N. (1982). Inside the Black Box. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Rosenstein-Rodan, P. N. (1943). Problems of Industrialisation of Eastern and South-
Eastern Europe. The Economic Journal, 53(210/211), 202-211.
Rowthorn, R., & Wells, J. (1987). De-Industrialization and Foreign Trade. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Sapelli, G. (1992). Technical Change, Microeconomic Evolution and Growth: An
Introduction View of Italian Industrial Development. In G. Dosi, R. Giannetti, & P. M.
Toninelli (Eds.), Technology and Enterprise in a Historical Perspective (pp. 291-313).
New York: Oxford University Press.
Schein, E. H. (1997). Strategic Pragmatism: The Culture of Singapore's Economic
Development Board. Boston, MA: MIT Press.
65
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Scitovsky, T. (1954). Two Concepts of External Economies. The Journal of Political
Economy, 62(2), 143-151.
SDOS (Singapore Department of Statistics). (2001). Contribution of Government-linked
Companies to Gross Domestic Product. Occasional Paper on Economic Statistics, 22.
SDOS (Singapore Department of Statistics). (2012). SingStat Time Series (STS) Online
System. Singapore: SDOS.
SESC (Economic Strategies Committee of Singapore). (2010). Report of the Economic
Strategies Committee: High Skilled People, Innovative Economy, Distinctive Global City.
Singapore: Government of Singapore.
Shin, J. (2005). Globalization and Challenges to the Developmental State: A Comparison
between South Korea and Singapore. Global Economic Review, 34(4), 379-395.
Simon, H. (1996). Hidden Champions: Lessons from 500 of the World's Best Unknown
Companies. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.
Skocpol, T. (1991). Targeting within Universalism: Politically Viable Policies to Combat
Poverty in the United States. In C. Jencks, & P. Peterson (Eds.), The Urban Underclass
(pp. 411-436). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
SMND (Singapore Ministry of National Development). (2013). A High Quality Living
Environment for All Singaporeans: Land Use Plan to Support Singapore's Future
Population. Singapore: Government of Singapore.
Spaventa, L. (1960). Problems of Intermediate Stages of Growth. The Economic Weekly,
12(27), 1077-1082.
Spence, M. (2008). The Growth Report: Strategies for Sustained Growth and Inclusive
Development. Washington, DC: The World Bank.
Stiglitz, J. E. (1996). Some Lessons from the East Asian Miracle. The World Bank
Research Observer, 11(2), 151-177.
Streeck, W. (1992). Social Institutions and Economic Performance: Studies of Industrial
Relations in Advanced Capitalist Economies. London: Sage.
Sun, Y-S. (1922). The International Development of China. New York and London: The
Knickerbocker Press.
Tassey, G. (2010). Rationales and Mechanisms for Revitalizing US Manufacturing R&D
Strategies. Journal of Technology Transfer, 35, 283-333.
Thrasher, R. D., & Gallagher, K. P. (2008). 21st Century Trade Agreements: Implications
for Long-Run Development Policy. The Pardee Papers 2, Frederick S. Pardee Center for
the Study of the Longer-Range Future. Boston, MA: Boston University.
Toivanen, O. (2006). Innovation and Research Policies: Two Case Studies of R&D
Subsidies. EIB Papers, 11(2), 54-79.
Toner, P. (1999). Main Currents in Cumulative Causation: The Dynamics of Growth and
Development. New York: St. Martin's Press.
66
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
TSB (Technology Strategy Board). (2012). A Landscape for the Future of High Value
Manufacturing in the UK. London: TSB.
TUC (Trades Union Congress). (2011). German Lessons: Developing Industrial Policy in
the UK. London: TUC.
UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development). (1998). Objectives
and Instruments of Industrial Policy: A Comparative Study. Geneva: UNCTAD.
UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development). (2006). A Case
Study of the Salmon Industry in Chile. New York and Geneva: UNCTAD.
UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development). (2009). The
Relationship Between Competition and Industrial Policies in Promoting Economic
Development. Geneva: UNCTAD.
UNIDO (United Nations Industrial Development Organization). (2002). Industrial
Development Report 2002/2003: Competiting through Innovation and Learning. Vienna:
UNIDO.
UNIDO (United Nations Industrial Development Organization) (2011). Industrial
Development Report, 2011. Vienna: UNIDO.
UNIDO (United Nations Industrial Development Organization). (2013). The Industrial
Competitiveness of Nations. Flagship Report on Industrial Competitiveness. Vienna:
UNIDO (forthcoming).
USTR (Office of the United States Trade Representative). (2010). United States
Requests WTO Dispute Settlement Consultations on China’s Subsidies for Wind Power
Equipment Manufacturers. Retrieved December 29, 2012, from Office of the United
States Trade Representative: http://www.ustr.gov/about-us/press-office/press-
releases/2010/december/united-states-requests-wto-dispute-settlement-con
USTR (Office of the United States Trade Representative). (2012a). United States Seeks
to Eliminate China’s Unfair Export Restraints on Rare Earths. Retrieved December 29,
2012, from Office of the United States Trade Representative: http://www.ustr.gov/about-
us/press-office/press-releases/2012/june/us-seeks-to-eliminate-china-restrictions-on-
rare-earths
USTR (Office of the United States Trade Representative). (2012b). Obama
Administration Challenges China’s Export Subsidies To Auto and Auto Parts
Manufacturers in China. Retrieved December 2012, 29, from Office of the United States
Trade Representative: http://www.ustr.gov/about-us/press-office/press-
releases/2012/september/obama-administration-challenges-china-auto-subsidies
Vartiainen, J. (1999). The Economics of Successful State Intervention in Industrial
Transformation. In M. Woo-Cumings (Ed.), The Developmental State (pp. 200-234). New
York: Cornell University Press.
Venohr, B., & Meyer, K. E. (2007). The German Miracle Keeps Running: How Germany’s
Hidden Champions Stay Ahead in the Global Economy. Berlin School of Economics
Working Paper No. 30.
67
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
68
Vitols, S. (1997). German Industrial Policy: An Overview. Industry and Innovation, 4(1),
15-36.
Wade, R. (1990). Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government
in East Asian Industrialization. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Warwick, K. (2013). Beyond Industrial Policy: Emerging Issues and New Trends. OECD
Science, Technology and Industry Policy Papers No. 2.
Weiss, L. (2005). Global Governance, National Strategies: How Industrialized States
Make Room to Move Under the WTO. Review of International Political Economy, 12(5),
723-749.
Wessner, C. W., & Wolff, A. W. (Eds.). (2012). Rising to the Challenge: U.S. Innovation
Policy for the Global Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press.
WIPO (World Intellectual Property Organization). (2012). WIPO Statistics Database.
Geneva: WIPO.
Wong, P. K. (2000). Singapore. In D. G. McKendrick, R. F. Doner, & S. Haggard (Eds.),
From Silicon Valley to Singapore: Location and Competitive Advantage in the Hard Disk
Drive Industry (pp. 155-183). Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Woolcock, M. (2009). Toward a Plurality of Methods in Project Evaluation: A
Contextualized Approach to Understanding Impact Trajectories and Efficacy. Journal of
Development Effectiveness, 1(1), 1-14.
World Bank. (1993). The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy. New
York: Oxford University Press.
World Bank. (2012). World Development Indicators Database. Washington, DC: World
Bank.
Wren, C. (2007). Reconciling Practice with Theory in the Micro-Evaluation of Regional
Policy. International Review of Applied Economics, 21(3), 321-337.
WTO (World Trade Organization). (2006). World Trade Report 2006: Exploring the Links
between Subsidies, Trade and the WTO. Geneva: WTO.
Ylä-Anttila, P., & Palmberg, C. (2007). Economic and Industrial Policy Transformations in
Finland. Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade, 7, 169-187.
Yu, Q. (1999). The Implementation of China's Science and Technology Policy. Westport,
CT: Quorum Books.
Zhang, X., & Long, G. (1997). China's Industrial Policies in the Process of Marketization.
In S. Masuyama, D. Vandenbrink, & S. Chia (Eds.), Industrial Policies in East Asia (pp.
255-290). Tokyo: Nomura Research Institute.
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Appendix
Table A.1: Manufacturing Indicators for the 10 Countries in the Study, 2010
Country MVA
per
capita
MVA
as %
of
GDP
MHT
MVA as
% of
total
MVA
MVA as
% of
World
MVA
MX per
capita MX as
% of
total
exports
MHT
MX as
% of
total
MX
MX
as %
of
WMT
Brazil 622 13.5 35.0 1.7 668 67.3 36.3 1.2
China 820 34.2 40.7 15.3 1,124 96.2 60.5 14.1
Finland 6,795 24.7 45.4 0.5 12,001 91.1 49.0 0.6
Germany 4,667 18.6 56.8 5.3 13,397 86.8 72.3 10.2
Italy 2,848 14.9 39.3 2.3 6,935 91.6 53.9 3.8
Japan 7,994 20.4 53.7 14.1 5,521 91.6 79.8 6.5
Korea 4,783 29.1 53.4 3.2 9,280 96.9 75.8 4.2
Singapore 8,198 24.5 73.4 0.5 35,709 89.8 69.0 1.5
UK 3,162 11.4 42.0 2.7 5,248 79.5 63.2 3.0
US 5,522 14.9 51.5 24.0 2,736 76.8 64.7 8.0
Data source: UNIDO (2013)
Notes: Manufacturing Value Added (MVA) and GDP are in constant 2000 US dollars.
MHT, MX and WMT refer to medium and high-technology, manufacturing exports and
world manufacturing trade respectively.
69
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Table A.2: Manufacturing Indicators for Top 60 Manufacturing Nations by MVA per
capita, 2010
Country MVA
per
capita
MX per
capita
MHT
MVA
as %
of
total
MVA
MVA
as %
of
GDP
MHT
MX as
%
of
total
MX
MX as
% of
total
exports
MX
as %
of
WMT
MVA as
% of
World
MVA
1 Singapore 8,198 35,709 73.4 24.5 69.0 89.8 0.52 1.5
2 Japan 7,994 5,521 53.7 20.4 79.8 91.6 14.13 6.5
3 Switzerland 7,168 23,652 34.9 18.4 69.7 91.5 0.75 1.7
4 Finland 6,795 12,001 45.4 24.7 49.0 91.1 0.50 0.6
5 Sweden 6,559 15,376 47.0 20.0 57.7 89.7 0.84 1.3
6 Ireland 6,507 23,960 64.1 23.1 53.8 91.6 0.41 1.0
7 Taiwan 6,153 10,825 61.9 29.9 72.4 96.0 1.97 2.3
8 United States 5,522 2,736 51.5 14.9 64.7 76.8 24.04 8.0
9 Austria 4,869 14,926 41.7 18.4 60.0 87.0 0.57 1.2
10 Korea 4,783 9,280 53.4 29.1 75.8 96.9 3.22 4.2
11 Germany 4,667 13,397 56.8 18.6 72.3 86.8 5.32 10.2
12 Iceland 4,008 4,001 14.2 11.4 45.6 26.8 0.02 0.0
13 Denmark 3,887 12,839 30.5 12.5 51.9 72.8 0.29 0.7
14 Belgium 3,794 34,138 42.3 15.0 54.9 87.4 0.55 3.3
15 Norway 3,767 7,396 24.1 9.2 52.2 27.1 0.25 0.3
16 Luxembourg 3,737 24,557 5.0 6.6 38.0 85.8 0.02 0.1
17 Netherlands 3,325 22,081 40.1 12.5 55.0 74.0 0.76 3.4
18 Israel 3,236 7,728 55.6 13.8 55.8 96.2 0.33 0.5
19 United
Kingdom 3,162 5,248 42.0 11.4 63.2 79.5 2.69 3.0
20 Canada 3,078 6,668 37.3 11.9 55.7 62.1 1.44 2.1
21 France 2,885 7,237 45.4 12.2 65.8 88.4 2.49 4.2
22 Italy 2,848 6,935 39.3 14.9 53.9 91.6 2.33 3.8
23 Slovenia 2,716 11,094 45.5 20.9 63.0 90.8 0.08 0.2
24 Australia 2,661 4,521 23.0 10.1 20.0 46.7 0.79 0.9
70
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Country MVA
per
capita
MX per
capita
MHT
MVA
as %
of
total
MVA
MVA
as %
of
GDP
MHT
MX as
%
of
total
MX
MX as
% of
total
exports
MX
as %
of
WMT
MVA as
% of
World
MVA
25 Slovakia 2,304 11,125 43.3 27.4 66.3 93.8 0.17 0.6
26 Kuwait 2,224 6,899 18.1 10.3 13.5 40.9 0.09 0.2
27 Czech
Republic 2,148 11,816 44.6 28.1 67.9 91.0 0.30 1.1
28 Qatar 1,989 8,817 17.4 2.8 28.2 15.9 0.02 0.1
29 New Zealand 1,986 3,214 13.9 12.8 21.3 46.4 0.12 0.1
30 Spain 1,897 4,572 34.3 12.0 57.4 83.7 1.18 1.9
31 Argentina 1,749 878 25.8 16.4 45.0 52.4 0.99 0.3
32 Portugal 1,504 4,098 22.4 12.9 40.5 90.2 0.22 0.4
33 Poland 1,490 3,640 35.3 22.5 58.1 87.8 0.78 1.3
34 Malaysia 1,427 5,931 41.8 27.1 63.5 83.3 0.55 1.5
35 Uruguay 1,343 626 13.4 14.5 22.6 39.1 0.06 0.0
36 Greece 1,290 1,429 17.2 9.1 37.2 73.7 0.20 0.1
37 Malta 1,257 8,407 44.9 11.3 56.2 93.0 0.01 0.0
38 Hungary 1,210 8,292 53.5 21.1 78.0 87.0 0.17 0.8
Table A.2 cont.: Manufacturing Indicators for Top 60 Manufacturing Nations by MVA
per capita, 2010
Country MVA
per
capita
MX
per
capita
MHT
MVA
as %
of
total
MVA
MVA
as
% of
GDP
MHT
MX as
%
of
total
MX
MX as
% of
total
exports
MX
as %
of
WMT
MVA as
% of
World
MVA
39 Saudi Arabia 1,157 2,021 41.1 11.8 35.5 21.7 0.42 0.5
40 Thailand 1,054 2,517 46.2 36.6 61.8 83.9 0.95 1.5
41 Costa Rica 1,035 1,421 16.6 20.1 58.9 73.3 0.07 0.1
42 Turkey 1,013 1,287 30.0 20.2 42.5 87.7 1.09 0.9
43 Mexico 1,008 2,166 38.5 16.0 78.7 80.1 1.54 2.2
44 Croatia 999 2,356 31.8 16.2 49.5 90.4 0.06 0.1
71
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
45 Estonia 979 8,360 25.7 15.5 42.3 86.2 0.02 0.1
46 Chile 972 1,943 18.9 15.4 11.8 47.0 0.23 0.3
47 Lithuania 964 5,343 18.5 18.3 37.8 85.6 0.04 0.2
48 Oman 941 1,858 16.8 8.2 42.7 16.3 0.04 0.0
49 Cyprus 918 641 12.3 6.6 60.4 75.2 0.01 0.0
50 Belarus 907 2,362 18.8 32.9 39.0 89.2 0.12 0.2
51 Venezuela 895 750 34.3 16.5 8.1 32.5 0.36 0.2
52 Trinidad &
Tobago 868 5,480 39.4 8.4 17.7 74.0 0.02 0.1
53 China, Macao
SAR 832 265 3.6 2.2 7.1 43.5 0.01 0.0
54 China 820 1,124 40.7 34.2 60.5 96.2 15.33 14.1
55 Mauritius 804 1,104 3.0 15.6 2.9 95.6 0.01 0.0
56 Lebanon 625 727 19.9 9.2 46.8 72.2 0.04 0.0
57 Brazil 622 668 35.0 13.5 36.3 67.3 1.71 1.2
58 South Africa 567 991 21.2 14.9 45.7 68.3 0.39 0.5
59 El Salvador 513 564 19.1 22.9 14.9 89.6 0.05 0.0
60 Russia 504 1,029 23.1 17.1 24.4 36.1 0.98 1.3
Data source: UNIDO (2013)
Notes: Countries whose names are in italics are the ones included in this report.
Manufacturing Value Added (MVA) and GDP are in constant 2000 US dollars. MHT, MX
and WMT refer to medium and high-technology, manufacturing exports and world
manufacturing trade respectively.
Table A.3: Gross R&D expenditure as a percentage of GDP (%) (average)
Country 1991-
1995 1996-
2000 2001-
2005 2006-
2010 2010
Brazil1 0.83 0.87 0.97 1.08 1.132
China 0.68 0.71 1.14 1.54 1.76
Finland 2.16 2.92 3.41 3.70 3.90
Germany 2.29 2.32 2.51 2.68 2.80
Italy 1.08 1.02 1.10 1.21 1.26
Japan 2.64 2.91 3.16 3.39 3.26
72
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Korea 2.06 2.30 2.57 3.38 3.74
Singapore 1.053 1.64 2.11 2.30 2.09
UK 1.98 1.80 1.75 1.79 1.80
USA 2.56 2.61 2.62 2.80 2.83
Source: Authors’ calculations based on OECD (2012a)
Notes: 1/ Excludes missing data for 1991-1993, 1997-1999 and 2009-2010; 2/ Data is for
latest available year of 2008; 3/ Data gaps for the period 1991-1993 were supplemented
with data from SDOS (2012).
73
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
Table A.4: Gross Fixed Capital Formation (GFCF) as a percentage of GDP (%)
(average)
Country 1991-
1995 1996-
2000 2001-
2005 2006-
2010 2010
Private 15.8 na na 16.2 16.5
Public 2.7 na na 2.7 2.9
Brazil1
Total 18.52 16.7 16.1 18.12 19.5
Private 7.9 8.0 9.9 20.4 23.7
Public 26.5 25.7 28.3 22.1 22.1
China1
Total 33.52 33.7 38.2 42.4 45.7
Private 15.8 16.4 16.8 17.7 16.4
Public 3.0 2.7 2.6 2.5 2.5
Finland
Total 18.8 19.2 19.4 20.3 18.9
Private 19.7 19.3 16.5 16.4 15.8
Public 2.2 1.9 1.6 1.6 1.7
Germany1
Total 22.72 21.3 18.2 17.9 17.4
Private 17.4 17.3 18.5 18.3 17.5
Public 2.6 2.3 2.3 2.3 2.1
Italy
Total 20.0 19.6 20.7 20.6 19.6
Private na na 18.6 18.5 16.8
Public na na 4.3 3.2 3.3
Japan1
Total 29.4 26.4 22.8 21.7 20.1
Private 32.0 27.1 23.5 23.6 23.2
Public 5.2 5.5 5.5 5.2 5.1
Korea
Total 37.2 32.6 29.0 28.8 28.3
Private 27.4 28.2 19.5 21.0 20.5
Public 5.8 6.7 5.2 3.2 3.7
Singapore
Total 33.2 34.9 24.7 24.2 24.2
Private 14.5 15.8 15.3 14.1 12.4 UK
Public 2.2 1.3 1.4 2.2 2.5
74
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
75
Total 16.7 17.1 16.7 16.3 14.9
Private 14.5 16.7 16.3 14.7 12.0
Public 2.4 2.4 2.5 2.5 2.5
US
Total 16.9 19.1 18.8 17.2 14.4
Source: Authors’ calculations based on World Bank (2012), OECD (2012c), SDOS (2012)
Notes: 1/ The public-private GFCF breakdown was unavailable in the countries for some
periods: Brazil (1995-2007), China (1991-1994), Germany (1991-1994), and Japan (1991-
2000); 2/ Percentages for private GFCF and public GFCF may not sum to total GFCF
because their averages use a shorter time period due to data limitations.
International industrial policy experiences and the lessons for the UK
© Crown copyright 2013
Foresight
1 Victoria Street
London SW1H 0ET
www.bis.gov.uk/foresight
URN 13/814
... Until recently, offshoring and outsourcing have been dominant attributes of the global economy (Bailey & De Propris, 2014;UNCTAD, 2013). A combination of the GFC, growing trade tensions, and mounting concerns about strategic capability have caused a fundamental reassessment of manufacturing and the role of industrial policy within developed economies (Chang, Andreoni & Kuan 2013). Following decades of de-industrialisation (World Bank, 2019), Anglo economies shifted their focus towards rebuilding industrial capacity and reshoring (Pegoraro, De Propris & Chidlow, 2022). ...
... While neo-classical economics has guided public procurement decisions for several decades, economic challenges faced by developed economies have led to growing calls for renewed industrial policy focus. Spring et al. (2017) and Chang, Andreoni and Kuan (2013) outline how concerns about de-industrialisation in developed economies have gained traction since the GFC with public procurement transitioning from an operational into a more strategic and value-additive government function (Telgen, Harland, & Knight, 2007). These forces have been accentuated by supply chains disruptions triggered by recent trade wars, geopolitical tensions and the COVID-19 pandemic. ...
... This increases research efficiency and allows findings to be triangulated . Chang, Andreoni and Kuan (2013) detail how the complexity of evaluating the impacts of industrial strategy interventions requires the use of both quantitative and qualitative techniques. Use of an approach in isolation is likely to result in a shallow level of analysis and risk overlooking important, yet obscured, factors. ...
Thesis
Full-text available
Recent pressure to use public procurement more proactively to support the capability and health of domestic industry has been met with scepticism by proponents of least cost competitive tendering. In this thesis, I present a novel framework to assist reconciliation of these views of public procurement through monetising the significant and often overlooked value of domestic investment within advanced manufacturing clusters that results from the public procurement process. By estimating the financial value generated by various forms of onshore manufacturing in the passenger rail rolling stock sector, my findings demonstrate that onshore design and manufacture of rolling stock can deliver substantial financial value and the best overall outcome in circumstances where domestic resources are not being gainfully utilised elsewhere. This result strengthens with the increased sophistication of onshore production and can enable government to support domestic industry within the neo-classical paradigm of competitive markets. My thesis finds that public procurement officials have largely failed to account for significant sources of financial value. This has resulted in important value-added activities being overlooked and the formulation of politically, rather than financially, driven local content provisions. I find that five fundamental tents of public procurement embedded within economic, management and contractual theory are damaging the health and competitiveness of onshore industry in cases where government is a major, or the only, buyer of specialised equipment. My research also highlights how movement of intellectual property through multinational companies has the potential to undermine comparative advantage theory for small knowledge intensive economies. I postulate a conceptual refinement to comparative advantage and suggest a renewed focus regarding onshore commercialisation alongside greater support to grow local businesses into competitive global companies.
... While some academic literature stipulate that industrial policy has returned to the European agenda (Wade 2012;Weiss 2016), others argue that it has never left (Chang et al. 2013;Naqvi et al. 2018). This is because industrial policy is mostly distinguished between horizontal or 'functional' and vertical or 'selective' industrial policy 2 (Weiss 2016;Pianta et al. 2020;Otsubo/Otchia 2021), classifying vertical incentives as strategically more important. ...
... The remarkable success of the industry, prevalent even after the 2007-2008 financial crisisas described by Krpata (2021) was accomplished through three strategies: leveraging of the European single market; 13 utilisation of economic globalisation and re-orientation on emerging markets, namely China and the protection of high-value-added activities in Germany. It is rather important to embed the understanding of the industry's success in the context of: (i) the German Model, whichamong other featureswas based on a continuous provision of the high-value-added manufacturing at home; and (ii) to contemplate broader institutional dynamics that characterised the post-war Fordist periodactive industrial policies, heavy and targeted investments in Research and Development (R&D) and technological advancement (Chang et al. 2013). These institutional, socio-economic, geopolitical and historical peculiarities provide an ample framework to comprehend the special position acquired by the German auto industry. ...
Article
Full-text available
The European Union (EU) and Germany were already being confronted with rapidly changing dynamics on the economic, ecological, and technological terrains prior to the Covid-19 crisis. The pandemic, however, has fully exposed critical global value chain (GVC) dependencies, jeopardising the already troubled automotive industry. By employing a historical-institutional and a pre- and post-Covid-19 industrial policy analysis, this article finds that, despite previous attempts, it was during the height of the pandemic that the implementation of green and digital industrial policy gained significant political support in Germany and the EU. In this context, there is an increased relevance of vertical industrial policy, which is geared towards the ‘twin transition’, partly altering the primarily horizontal industrial policy framework manifested in the post-Maastricht period.
... Johnstone et al. (2021) found that Germany is perceived as a proactive leader in industrial policy. Among EU member states, it is recognized for actively pursuing industrial regulation (Mazzucato, 2011;Chang et al., 2013). ...
Article
Full-text available
Industrial policy has regained political attention due to the challenges associated with global market integration, technological changes, and the need for sustainable transformation. However, the lack of a consistent understanding of industrial policy hampers systematic comparisons. This paper develops a novel concept of industrial policy portfolios that captures different dimensions of industrial policy outputs across countries and over time. We illustrate this approach by comparing the policy dynamics in the United States and Germany over the last four decades and show that despite similar dynamics of policy growth, the countries display pronounced variation in the areas and instruments they prioritized.
... Por medio de estas, así como del crédito subsidiado, del gasto y de la inversión pública, continuó promoviendo la industria naciente con orientación al mercado interno e internacional. Particularmente, los estímulos estuvieron dirigidos a sectores manufactureros considerados relevantes por cuestiones de seguridad nacional, a aquellos destacados en términos de desarrollo tecnológico y a los sectores vinculados al suministro de insumos estratégicos para China (Chang et al., 2013). Seguido al éxito de la inserción china en la economía mundial a través de las ZFE, y habiendo avanzado en el desarrollo de capacidades productivas domésticas estratégicas, la industrialización del país continuó su curso, centrándose en el desarrollo de capacidades de I+D locales, la expansión de los vínculos nacionales y la diversificación de su estructura productiva. ...
Article
Full-text available
En el presente trabajo se examina una discusión abierta en el campo de los estudios del desarrollo: la importancia de estimular desde el Estado el desenvolvimiento del sector industrial para viabilizar procesos de transformación estructural en la economía capitalista contemporánea. Sobre la base de relevamiento bibliográfico y de técnicas de análisis de contenido, en primer lugar, se presenta una evolución histórica de esta discusión para, luego, hacer foco en el debate contemporáneo. Se identifican aquí dos posturas que, sin ser excluyentes, otorgan diferente centralidad al sector manufacturero y a las políticas estatales orientadas a su estímulo para impulsar el desarrollo. Procurando profundizar en el examen, se analizan experiencias de desarrollo reciente a fin de identificar los procesos y políticas implementadas. Se concluye remarcando la necesidad de diseñar e implementar políticas que estimulen la actividad manufacturera para viabilizar procesos de transformación estructural en el escenario capitalista actual.
... Nesse sentido, os argumentos favoráveis à política industrial consideram que o setor manufatureiro é capaz de promover mudanças estruturais responsáveis por acelerar o progresso tecnológico e incentivar tanto o seu desenvolvimento quanto o científico (CHANG; ANDREONI; KUAN, 2013;RODRIK, 2010). Ademais, a política industrial possui um componente minimizador de incertezas. ...
Article
Full-text available
Due the importance of diversifying production for the industrial sector, this study seeks to assess whether the level of diversification of a productive structure influences the adoption of industrial policies. For this, data for 5,570 Brazilian municipalities in 2015 and Hidalgo and Hausmann’s (2009HIDALGO, C. A.; HAUSMANN, R. The Building Blocks of Economic Complexity. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, v. 106, n. 26, p. 10570-10575, 2009.) method of reflections are used. Descriptive statistics ordinary least squares are used to evaluate the tested hypotheses. Results show a positive and significant relation between the effective diversity of activities and the adoption of industrial policies in all analyzed scenarios. Therefore, results reinforce the argument that industrial policies are adopted in response to specific productive activities and are conditioned by the diversification structure of municipalities. KEYWORDS: Industrial policy; economic complexity; productive activities; Brazilian municipalities
Chapter
Entrepreneurship in Sierra Leone has gained significant attention from scholars and policymakers in recent years due to its potential to promote economic growth and development. There have been several initiatives, from legislations and government agencies tasked to facilitate entrepreneurship and business venturing, to the creation of enterprise hubs, enterprise competitions and trainings. However, in comparison with its more widely known sub-Saharan African neighbours, Nigeria and Ghana, entrepreneurship research on Sierra Leone is limited and fragmented and fails to provide a clear overview of the status-quo of entrepreneurship in the country. This book chapter explores some of the contributory factors to the current state quo of entrepreneurship in Sierra Leone. It considers key socioeconomic and political factors which have shaped and influenced the business environment of the country and explore their impact on the country’s entrepreneurial landscape. This exploration highlights key challenges to entrepreneurship encompassing issues such as infrastructure and sociocultural barriers. It also examines pro-active measures taken by the Government of Sierra Leone (GoSL) to nurture and strengthen its entrepreneurial ecosystem. The chapter concludes by highlighting potential areas for further research and suggesting policy interventions to promote entrepreneurship in Sierra Leone.
Research
Full-text available
In dit onderzoek kijken de auteurs naar de ontwikkeling van het Nationaal Groeifonds. Dit fonds werd in 2020 geïntroduceerd met als doel om het Nederlandse verdienvermogen te versterken via publieke investeringen. De auteurs concluderen dat het bewonderingswaardig is hoe in een zeer korte tijd een behoorlijk goed functionerende en lerende organisatie tot stand is gekomen.
Chapter
Since 2000, the production landscape in the Western Balkan (WB) countries has undergone profound structural change. These structural dynamics have been driven mostly by the systemic changes that occurred in the 1990s, a period marked by dramatic deindustrialization in these economies. Deindustrialization (i.e., loss of strategic manufacturing industries), in parallel with increased trade imbalances and much reduced technological dynamism, has been a major concern for policy makers in the WBs. The model of economic growth based primarily on extraction of natural resources has been questioned and the policymaking focus has shifted to measures aimed specifically at promoting the production sector.
Book
Yu gives Western readers a full view of China's science and technology policy, plus a historical perspective on the development of her science, technology, and industrial enterprises. A realistic, objective review that will help overcome tendencies to under- or overestimate China's technological and industrial strength and potential for the future, his book focuses on the transition of her scientific, technological, and industrial systems from a planned to a market economy. It identifies the latest science-technology policy readjustment in China and gives Westerners a way to assess the successes and failures of technological-industrial development attributable to policy causes. Yu describes the evolution of China's scientific and technological systems before and after her economic reforms. He covers changes in science-technology policy in their socioeconomic context, and highlights all major steps in her economic development that have spurred China's scientific-technological progress. Mr. Yu views these as a driving force for economic development, while the success of science-technology policy is determined by its effectiveness in implementing various economic activities. His book also provides in-depth coverage of changes in major industrial sectors, including agriculture, infrastructure, mainstay, high-tech, and township industries and non-governmental science-technology enterprises. The result is a unique opportunity to gain an authoritative, reliable understanding of China's scientific and technological activities, her industrial development, and the interaction between them.
Chapter
At the end of the 20th century with stagnating industrial output, unemployment in many European countries has climbed to levels not seen since the 1930s. Interventionist industrial policies thus find new popularity after the gentle flirtation with liberalization in the early 1990s. Under the Maastricht Treaty, the European Union was granted industrial policy powers for the first time. The present study aims to contribute to an understanding of European industrial policy by introducing an historical perspective. National policy continuities and the considerable time over which industrial performance responds to changed environments emerge with greater clarity in the long run. The chapters in this book take a broad view of industrial policy, including those policies that establish the `framework', such as competition law, as well as sector for firm specific policies. The overall conclusion is that improved framework policies, such as liberalization and re-regulation, are still essential. Monetary union in the `core' will increase tensions arising from economic inflexibility. Although there are often strong political barriers blocking implementation of appropriate industrial policies, they will be even more necessary under monetary union.
Chapter
The authors of this book challenge mainstream thinking about the nature of globalization. While not hostile to markets per se, they believe that capitalist market processes, left to operate freely, tend to generate injustice, insecurity, instability, and inefficiency. Taking account of the new realities of globalization, this volume explores an unusually wide range of subjects, including trade integration, multinational corporations, labor markets and migration, international capital flows, macroeconomic and environmental policy, and the central roles of the IMF and World Bank. It proposes alternatives to neo-liberal orthodoxy, developing policy measures that counter the destructive features of markets and promote equality as well as efficiency. The approach in this volume is particularly illuminating for understanding the Asian financial collapse of 1997–98 and similar recent crises. The volume also includes comments on each chapter by a wide range of distinguished economists, producing a lively and often controversial set of interchanges.