ArticlePDF Available

Abstract and Figures

The academic literature emphasizes that shared capitalism positively affects employees’ attitudes at work. This paper investigates that issue by testing the relationship between shared capitalism and withdrawal behaviors (turnover and absenteeism). Recent literature interprets shared capitalism as a gift exchange between employers and employees. This paper builds on that literature. The analysis, based on an econometric case study, focuses on a five-year panel dataset of more than 800 subsidiaries belonging to a unique French-listed company. Our results show that only long-term shared capitalism translates into better withdrawal behaviors.
Content may be subject to copyright.
HAL Id: halshs-01256759
https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-01256759v2
Submitted on 31 Dec 2018
HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access
archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci-
entic research documents, whether they are pub-
lished or not. The documents may come from
teaching and research institutions in France or
abroad, or from public or private research centers.
L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est
destinée au dépôt et à la diusion de documents
scientiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non,
émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de
recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires
publics ou privés.
How Shared Capitalism Aects Employee Withdrawal:
An Econometric Case Study Of A French-Listed
Company
Nicolas Aubert, Xavier Hollandts
To cite this version:
Nicolas Aubert, Xavier Hollandts. How Shared Capitalism Aects Employee Withdrawal: An Econo-
metric Case Study Of A French-Listed Company. Journal of Applied Business Research, Clute Insti-
tute, 2015, �10.19030/jabr.v31i3.9226�. �halshs-01256759v2�
1
How shared capitalism affects employee withdrawal:
An econometric case study of a French-listed company1
AUBERT Nicolas23
HOLLANDTS Xavier, Kedge Business School4
Nicolas Aubert: Professor, Aix-Marseille University (France).
is a Professor of nance at Aix-Marseille University University (CERGAM, EA 4225) and an Afliate
Professor at Inseec. His main research interests include corporate governance, employee ownership and
company based savings plans. He is a research fellow at the French Institute of Corporate Governance
(IFGE/EM Lyon). His research has been published in Journal of financial services research, Finance, Economic
Modelling.
Xavier Hollandts: Associate Professor, Kedge Business School (France).
Ph.D in Management Science, he’s associate professor at Kedge Business School (France). Research fellow of
CRCGM and IFGE (France). His main research’s interest is on corporate governance and more precisely on the
impact of employee participation on corporate strategy and performance. His research has been published in
French-language journals (Management International, Revue Française de Gestion, Revue Française de
Gouvernance d’Entreprise) and international journals (Corporate Governance, Journal of Institutional
Economics). Since 2012, he’s co-head of Alter-Governance Chair (CRCGM).
1 The authors wish to thank Thibault Daudigeos for helping us collecting the data.
2 Aix-Marseille University (CERGAM EA 4225), 13540, Puyricard, France , niaubert@gmail.com.
Corresponding author.
3 French corporate governance institute.
4Kedge Business School, CRCGM and French Corporate Governance Institute, xavier.hollandts@free.fr
2
How shared capitalism affects
employee withdrawal: An econometric case study of a French-listed
company
Abstract
The academic literature emphasizes that shared capitalism positively affects employees’ attitudes at work. This
paper investigates that issue by testing the relationship between shared capitalism and withdrawal behaviors
(turnover and absenteeism). Recent literature interprets shared capitalism as a gift exchange between employers
and employees. This paper builds on that literature. The analysis, based on an econometric case study, focuses
on a five-year panel dataset of more than 800 subsidiaries belonging to a unique French-listed company. Our
results show that only long-term shared capitalism translates into better withdrawal behaviors.
Keywords: Shared capitalism, employee ownership, profit sharing, turnover, absenteeism.
JEL: J33, J54, J63, L74, L85, M52
3
INTRODUCTION
It is often argued that employee participation in a firm’s financial performance aligns the interests of the
employees with those of the employer. This would lead to better corporate performance through fewer
withdrawal behaviors, namely, turnover and absenteeism, among others. Direct employee participation in a
firm’s financial performance can take several forms, including profit sharing, gain sharing, employee ownership
and broad-based stock options. Freeman et al (2010) define these practices as “employment relations where the
pay or wealth of workers is directly tied to workplace or firm performance” and call them shared capitalism.
They restrict this term to “plans that tie worker pay or wealth to the performance of their own workplace,
whether at the level of the work group, establishment, or company” (p. 5). This definition ex cludes individual
performance-based pay. Shared capitalism is widespread in several Western countries. According to Freeman et
al (2010), almost half of American private-sector employees participate in shared capitalism. In the United
Kingdom, 62% of employees are covered by at least one of the programs that comprise shared capitalismBryson
and Freeman, 2010).
The literature underlines that, due to the combined effects of various HRM outcomes, shared capitalism
positively affects corporate performance: the employee-owners are more satisfied, more involved and more
motivated, and they develop a feeling of psychological ownership (Pierce et al, 1991) that improves their
attitudes at work. From a collective point of view, shared capitalism has a positive impact on individual and
collective outcomes, such as staff turnover and absenteeism. Recent attempts to investigate how shared
capitalism affects absenteeism and turnover include Blasi et al (2010) and Kruse et al (2012). Blasi et al (2010)
find that shared capitalism decreases turnover but increases absenteeism. Kruse et al (2012) also find that shared
capitalism decreases turnover. In France, Brown et al (1999) investigate the relationship between profit sharing,
employee ownership and absenteeism and find that whether they are separated or combined, profit sharing and
employee ownership are associated with lower absenteeism. Fakhfakh (2004) emphasizes that employee
ownership reduces voluntary quits, whereas pure profit sharing has no effect on this variable. Previous
researchers’ conclusions are not unanimous regarding the effects of different forms of shared capitalism on
withdrawal behaviors, namely, turnover and absenteeism.
This paper investigates the relationship between three shared capitalism practices and employees’
withdrawal behaviors, using a five-year panel dataset of more than 800 subsidiaries of a unique, French-listed
corporation. By testing the relationship between turnover, absenteeism and shared capitalism in France, this
paper is innovative in three ways. First, this paper tests how three shared capitalism practicesout of the four
mentioned by Freeman et al (2010)are related to turnover and absenteeism. Before Freeman et al (2010),
shared capitalism was not systematically regarded as a unified management practice. Consequently, many
empirical studies investigated the relationship between one specific form of shared capitalism and corporate
performance. For instance, the literature investigated separately how employee ownership, profit sharing or gain
sharing affects performance. Second, this paper tests the studied relationships in France, a country in which
shared capitalism has been promoted since the 1960s. In 2010, more than half of the French private-sector
workforce (excluding agricultural workers) had access to shared capitalism (DARES, 2012). This proportion is
even higher than that reported by Freeman et al (2010). France also is a singular case because it is the only
country in the world in which profit sharing is mandatory for all companies employing more than 50 people.
Lastly, our empirical design is based on a recent approach, namely, an econometric case study. Following the
suggestion of Jones et al (2010), this research design allows us to make a more in-depth test of the various forms
of shared capitalism.
In this paper, we look at more than 800 subsidiaries belonging to a single, French-listed company over a five-
year period. Our results demonstrate that shared capitalism decreases absenteeism and turnover and constitute a
first step toward showing that employee ownership has an overall positive impact on a firm. This paper is
organized as follows. Section 1 presents a literature review investigating the relationship between shared
capitalism, absenteeism and turnover. It also formulates research hypotheses. Section 2 presents our empirical
approach, which is based on an econometric case study of the subsidiaries of a French-listed company. Section 3
presents our results. Section 4 discusses those results and presents the perspectives created by this research.
Section 5 is the conclusion.
LITERATURE REVIEW
Shared capitalism implements collective performance pay systems in the workplace. Shared capitalism results in
employers and workers sharing in the benefits of increased production. However, Kruse et al (2010) mention
two main reasons why shared capitalism is often criticized. First, shared capitalism results in free-riding
behaviors: workers are not motivated to make a full effort at an N-person firm when in the end they only receive
1/Nth of the payoff for their effort. Second, shared capitalism puts a larger proportion of employees’ wealth and
income at risk. Profit sharing and gain sharing affect employees’ income, and employee ownership affects their
wealth. The first concern can be compensated for through employees’ mutual monitoring and improved
4
cooperation (Freeman et al, 2010). The second concern can be addressed by portfolio diversification (Markovitz
et al, 2010) and/or a combination of various forms of shared capitalism, such as profit sharing and stock options
(Blasi et al, 2010).
Despite these strong arguments, no theory won unanimity among the empirical researchers investigating the
output of shared capitalism until recently. After a vast investigation of shared capitalism in the US economy,
Kruse et al (2010, p. 378) conclude, “Our overall interpretation builds on the ideas of reciprocity and gift
exchange, and the body of theory and research on bundles of high performance work practices”. Since then,
Kruse et al (2012), Bryson and Freeman (2012) and Pendleton (2011) explicitly mention gift exchange and
reciprocity as theoretical backgrounds that explain shared capitalism outputs. Bryson and Freeman (2012)
investigate how employee stock purchase plan (ESPP) participation affects employees’ behaviors. Engelhardt
and Madrian (2004) in the US and Rapp and Aubert (2011) in France emphasize that the decision to participate
is affected by liquidity constraint, imperfect knowledge of the plan, asset choice and transaction costs. Bryson
and Freeman (2012) offer another interpretation. Because stocks frequently are offered by the employer at a
discounted price, they claim, an ESPP creates a gift exchange between workers and employers. They find that
workers who have purchased shares at subsidized prices work harder for longer hours and have lower quit and
absence rates than workers who do not join the plan; however, employees who are plan members are no more
involved in co-monitoring the performance of fellow employees than are non-plan members. From this
perspective, the link between shared capitalism and employees’ withdrawal can be viewed as a gift exchange
involving reciprocity between an employer and its employees. Akerlof (1982) introduced the concept of gift
exchange in economics to explain involuntary unemployment. He says that “On the worker’s side, the “gift”
given is work in excess of the minimum work standard; and on the firm’s side the “gift” given is wages in
excess of what these women could receive if they left their current jobs. As a consequence of worker sentiment
for one another, the firm cannot deal with each worker individually, but rather must at least to some extent treat
the group of workers with the same norms, collectively” (p. 544). Where shared capitalism exists, a gift
exchange takes place between the worker and the employer. The employer gives the worker a share in the
success of the business. The worker reciprocates this gift with a better attitude and behavior in the workplace,
resulting in increased firm performance. Gift exchange also explains why collective incentives work.
The employees’ perception that the gift exchange is fair should decrease employees’ withdrawal by improving
their attitudes in areas such as motivation, satisfaction, involvement and commitment. Mobley (1982) regards
employee turnover and absenteeism as measuring employees’ withdrawal behaviors. However, turnover and
absenteeism are not similar. These two phenomena demonstrate different stages of employee withdrawal.
Mobley (1977) notes that absenteeism is one of the first phases of an employee’s process of progressive
withdrawal, which may finally result in his voluntary departure. From this point of view, an employee’s
withdrawal has several stages. Absenteeism is one of the first stages and leaving is the last.
On the empirical side, several studies investigate the relationship between various forms of shared capitalism
and employees’ withdrawal. In an attempt to review the literature on employee financial participation, Pérotin
and Robison (2003) conclude, Schemes that offer a larger financial involvement have higher productivity
effects. Cash profit-sharing schemes seem to have a short-term effect, whereas share schemes, which are more
long-term oriented, probably have a more sustained effect.” Indeed, employee ownership is specifically
mentioned because it engages employees and employers in a longer-term relationship. In the shared capitalism
literature, some studies focus on employee ownership with the overall idea that long-term forms of shared
capitalism could significantly decrease withdrawal behaviors. Kaarsemaker (2006) offers an exhaustive
literature review of the empirical knowledge of the link between employee ownership and employees’
withdrawal. He finds that 59 studies worldwide are dedicated to understanding how employee ownership affects
employees’ attitudes and behaviors. Ten out of these 59 studies look at turnover and absenteeism, and seven of
them conclude that employee ownership affects turnover and/or absenteeism. Fakhfakh (2004), Brown et al
(1999) and Festing et al (1999) collect data in France and investigate both profit sharing and employee
ownership. Focusing on several European countries, Festing et al (1999) find that profit sharing negatively
affects turnover and absenteeism, but their findings regarding employee ownership are not straightforward.
Brown et al (1999) show that companies with employee ownership have significantly lower absentee rates than
companies without employee ownership. In the study by Brown et al (1999), absenteeism decreases 14% at
companies that provide only employee ownership, whereas the combination of profit sharing and employee
ownership lead to an 11% decrease. When only profit sharing is implemented, the decrease in absenteeism is
7%. Fakhfakh (2004) shows that employee ownership always has a negative effectthat always is strongly
significanton employee voluntary quits. This association is not significant for profit sharing. This effect is all
the more interesting in that it falls between the two extremes of employee withdrawal behavior: the initial stage
(absenteeism) and the terminal stage (staff turnover). In the US context, Blasi et al (2010) find that shared
capitalism affects workplace performance. Shared capitalism is linked to lower turnover. However, shared
capitalism is inversely related to absenteeism. All of these results interact with other workplace practices such as
high-performance policies, low levels of supervision and fixed pay at or above market levels. For instance, the
5
puzzling result pertaining to absenteeism disappears when controlling for its interactions with high-performance
policies and closeness of supervision. Previous studies suggest that different forms of shared capitalism affect
employees’ behaviors differently. Additionally, shared capitalism seems to be closely related to other workplace
practices.
Taking into account the theoretical and empirical literature on the relation between employee ownership and
absenteeism and turnover, we formulate the following hypotheses:
Hypothesis 1: There is a negative relationship between shared capitalism and turnover.
Hypothesis 2: There is a negative relationship between shared capitalism and absenteeism.
DATA AND METHODS
Data
Jones et al (2006) explain that econometric case studies employ econometric methods and focus on a single
organization, where the unit of analysis is typically some subunit of the organization (e.g., plant, production
line, team or individual). It is a quite recent empirical approach that has crucially been influenced by the
development of personnel economics”. This method is very appropriate to our empirical data. Indeed, we use a
five-year panel (from 2003 to 2007) of 840 subsidiaries of a single, French-listed company. The subunit of the
organization is the subsidiary. Although all of the French subsidiaries have access to the same employee
ownership plan, each subsidiary’s manager is free to determine that subsidiary’s compensation policy mix. We
voluntarily exclude foreign subsidiaries because shared capitalism plans are very different from one country to
another, especially with respect to tax incentives. Such differences make comparisons very difficult. For
instance, profit sharing is mandatory when a company has more than 50 employees. The 840 French subsidiaries
that we studied hired 105,000 employees in 2007. By the time the data were collected (2008), the company had
hired 158,000 employees around the world and had operations in five sectors: road, concession, energy,
construction and real estate. The company studied had the 18th-highest total market capitalization on the Paris
Stock Exchange and the top market capitalization in its industrial sector.
Employee ownership was introduced at the company in 1995. A representative of the employee-owners has held
a seat on the board of directors since 2002. On average during the 2003-2007 period, employee ownership
represented 9% of the shareholders’ equity. ESPPs are frequent in this company. They occur three or four times
per year. Three employees out of four are employee-owners (72% in 2007). All of the ESPPs have been fully
subscribed or oversubscribed. From 2003 to 2007, these transactions took place in a very favorable context;
during this period the company stock price experienced an average annual increase of 25%. In France, amounts
invested in an ESPP cannot be withdrawn during the first five years of the employee’s investment Early
withdrawals are only possible in specific situations, such as layoff, divorce, bankruptcy, the purchase of a
principal residence or the birth of a new child. French law authorizes a maximum 20% discount on the price of
each stock purchased by a company’s employees. For the studied company, employee ownership gives rise to a
strong feeling of belonging to the group, even though the company’s subsidiaries vary greatly in size. At the end
of 2007, the average portfolio value was 10,110 Euros. Therefore, employee ownership is a significant part of
the company’s compensation policy. In 2007, 326 million Euros were paid to 84% of the company’s French
employees through gain-sharing and profit-sharing bonuses. This amount represents 1.5% of the French
subsidiaries’ turnover.
Methods
Estimation model
The estimation model depends closely on the data. The distribution between 2003-2007 makes necessary the use
of a panel data estimation model. Because the Hausman test is significant and indicates significant differences
between random-effect and fixed-effect models, we use robust fixed-effect models to test our statistical models.
Dependent variables: withdrawal behaviors
Our study is interested in the relationship between shared capitalism and withdrawal behaviors. To measure
withdrawal behaviors, we use two variables for each subsidiary and for each year: (i) turnover and (ii)
absenteeism. Both variables measure employees’ withdrawal behavior. Staff turnover is measured by counting
voluntary departures over the year, excluding departures due to retirement, the end of a fixed-term contract, the
end of a training course or involuntary causes (illness, death, work accidents in the workplace and occupational
diseases) (Fakhfakh, 2004). Absenteeism is measured by the days of absence for each subsidiary (Brown et al,
1999).
Independent variables: Shared capitalism
6
Our hypotheses suggest that shared capitalism has an impact on withdrawal behaviors. For each subsidiary and
for each year, shared capitalism5 is measured using three variables: (1) employee ownership as the monetary
value of the stocks held by all of the employees in a given subsidiary; (2) profit sharing as the annual monetary
value of profit-sharing bonuses granted by the subsidiary to all of its employees; and (3) gain sharing as the
annual monetary value of gain-sharing bonuses paid by the subsidiary to all of its employees.
Control variables
We include several control variables that affect withdrawal behaviors in the subsidiaries. Wilson and Peel
(1990) and Fakkfakh (2004) state that the variables influencing withdrawal behaviors can be classified into five
groups: the characteristics of the work, the characteristics of the compensation, the size of the company, the
technological characteristics and the economic environment. The characteristics of the work in a given
subsidiary are described in terms of the number of white-collar employees and average seniority. The
characteristics of the compensation are described in terms of the total gross annual salary paid by the subsidiary
to its employees. The subsidiary’s size is measured by the number of employees that it has. The technological
characteristics are described using dummy variables that indicate whether a given subsidiary belongs to one of
the following six sectors: road, concession, energy, construction, real estate and the head office. Each dummy
variable takes a value of one if it belongs to the sector and zero if it does not.
5 Our measure of shared capitalism includes only three shared capitalism arrangements out of the four
mentioned by Kruse et al (2010) because the studied firm does not use broad-base stock options.
7
Table 1. Descriptive statistics
EXPLAINED VARIABLES: WITHDRAWAL BEHAVIORS
Continuous variables
Mean
Minimum
Maximum
Standard
deviation
Median
Withdrawal behaviors
Turnover
74.82
0
17,316
629.32
12
Absenteeism
2,088.86
0
132,119
5,276.21
739
EXPLICATIVE VARIABLES: SHARED CAPITALISM
Employee ownership
(Euros)
1,011,488
0
1,36e+08
3,955,909
213,166.4
Gain-sharing bonuses
(Euros)
47,813.82
0
6916,000
228,697.4
0
Profit-sharing bonuses
(Euros)
92,648.84
0
1,43e+07
431155.7
0
CONTROL VARIABLES
Continuous variables
Mean
Minimum
Maximum
Standard
deviation
Median
Salary before tax (Euros)
3,199,347
1037,43
1,79e+08
8,054,405
1,271,000
Average tenure (years)
10.75
0.5
28
4.03
10,60
#Employees
122.30
1
8,897
330.06
51
#White collars
18.98
0
1,074
47.24
7
Dummy variables
Frequencies
Percentage
Distributorship
102
2.82%
Road
864
23.91%
Energy
1,550
42.89%
Building trade
1,065
29.47%
Headquarters
24
0.66%
Real estate
9
0.25%
8
Table 2. Correlation matrix
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
1
0.66***
1
0.62***
0.56***
1
0.65***
0.52***
0.67***
1
0.77***
0.76***
0.69***
0.60***
1
0.82***
0.71***
0.66***
0.62***
0.64***
1
0.58***
0.46***
0.67***
0.57***
0.44***
0.77***
1
0.04**
-0.03**
0.02
0.01
0.01
0.00
-0.02
1
0.74***
0.77***
0.55***
0.54***
0.55***
0.86***
0.71***
-0.03*
1
0.25***
0.3099***
0.14***
0.14***
0.26***
0.11***
0.05***
-0.07***
0.16***
1
0.08***
-0.03**
-0.02
-0.03**
-0.01
0.02*
-0.05***
0.26***
0.02
-0.12***
1
-0.18***
-0.07***
-0.09***
-0.04**
-0.08***
-0.13***
-0.1***
-0.05***
-0.14***
-0.18***
-0.45***
1
0.04**
0.01
0.04***
0.02
0.01
0.07***
0.12***
-0.16***
0.07***
-0.13***
-0.34***
-0.52***
1
-0.01
-0.01
0.05***
-0.01
-0.01
0.03**
0.02*
0.08***
-0.01
-0.01
-0.04**
-0.06***
-0.04***
1
-0.01
0.00
0.06***
0.08***
0.03**
0.00
0.04**
-0.02
0.00
-0.01
-0.03**
-0.04***
-0.03**
0.00
9
Descriptive statistics
The descriptive statistics and the correlations between the variables included in the regressions are displayed in
tables 1 and 2. Table 1 shows that our sample is heterogeneous. There are large dispersions in staff turnover
(Mean: 74.82, SD: 629.32) and absenteeism (Mean: 2,088.86, SD: 5,276.21). Although the size of some
subsidiaries’ staff approaches that of a large group (Maximum staff: 8,897), some subsidiaries operate more like
sole proprietors. We notice a great variability in gross annual salary (Mean: 3.19 million Euros, SD: 8 million
Euros), profit-sharing bonuses (Mean: 92,648 Euros, SD: 431,155 Euros) and gain-sharing bonuses (Mean:
47,813 Euros, SD: 228,697 Euros). Finally, the employees of the studied company have spent a relatively short
but homogeneous average time with the company (Mean: 10 years, SD: four years).
Table 2 displays the correlations between the variables included in the regression models. We note that the value
of several coefficients is above 0.5. The variables concerned are the profit-sharing bonuses, #Employees and
#White collars. These high coefficients suggest the presence of multicollinearity. The presence of possible
multicollinearity problems among the explanatory variables has been tested in each of the models by means of
variance inflation factors. The variables’ multicollinearity problems can cause instability in the regression
coefficients. The variance inflation factor (VIF) measures the collinearity problem among the variables. In our
case the average VIF is under 3.5. Craney and Surles (2002) consider the multicollinearity problems as arising
when the VIF value is above 10.
RESULTS
Table 3. Relationships between shared capitalism and turnover
Model 1
Model 2
Model 3
Model 4
Employee ownership
-4.43e-05***
-4.63e-05***
(1.40e-05)
(1.22e-05)
Gain-sharing bonuses
-5.42e-05
0.000171**
(0.000108)
(6.74e-05)
Profit-sharing bonuses
-0.000275
-2.52e-05
(0.000424)
(0.000153)
Gross salary
5.33e-06
-1.97e-05
-9.83e-06
3.55e-07
(8.13e-06)
(2.08e-05)
(3.12e-05)
(1.49e-05)
Average tenure
-0.417
-0.725
-1.621
-0.734
(1.352)
(1.242)
(1.732)
(1.436)
#Employees
0.777
0.940***
0.907***
0.823***
(0.0499)
(0.222)
(0.224)
(0.0568)
#White collars
3.068
0.660
0.0578
2.470
(2.229)
(1.586)
(1.696)
(1.835)
Constant
-35.77
21.56
41.26
-19.54
(42.62)
(40.59)
(44.03)
(41.14)
Number of observations
2,887
2,882
2,882
2,877
Number of subsidiaries
840
840
840
840
R-squared overall
0.32
0.44
0.14
0.30
F
64.96***
19.44***
20.25***
85.49***
Notes: Employee ownership, profit-sharing bonuses, gain-sharing bonuses and gross salary are the total
amount spent by a subsidiary in Euros. Average tenure is measured by the average number of years that
employees have spent in a given subsidiary. #Employees and #White collars indicate, respectively, the
numbers of employees and white-collar employees working for the subsidiary. Robust standard errors are
reported in parentheses: * significant at 10%, ** significant at 5% and *** significant at 1%. To improve
clarity and because they remain constant during the five-year period, we do not report coefficients that are
associated with particular sectors.
10
How does shared capitalism affect turnover?
Table 3 displays the results of the regression analyses for the two dependent variables investigated. The aim of
this paper is to study the relationship between shared capitalism and withdrawal behaviors. Models 1 through 4
test the relationship between profit sharing, gain sharing, employee ownership and staff turnover.
We find that employee ownership is negatively and significantly associated with turnover (model 1). Models 2
and 3 show that the coefficients associated with gain sharing and profit sharing are not significant. Model 4
indicates that employee ownership has a significant and negative effect on staff turnover even when it is
combined with the two other forms of shared capitalism. The coefficient associated with gain sharing becomes
significant and positive, whereas the coefficient reported for profit sharing remains not significant. Because the
relation between employee ownership and staff turnover is negative, this first result partially corroborates our
Hypothesis 1.
Table 4. Relationships between shared capitalism and absenteeism
Model 5
Model 6
Model 7
Model 8
Employee ownership
-0.000103*
-0.000116***
(5.52e-05)
(4.29e-05)
Gain-sharing bonuses
-0.00135
-0.000835
(0.000926)
(0.000834)
Profit-sharing bonuses
0.000570
0.00124*
(0.000685)
(0.000740)
Gross salary
0.000352**
0.000338**
0.000265**
0.000333**
(0.000139)
(0.000161)
(0.000124)
(0.000133)
Average tenure
12.85
12.88
13.60
17.53
(23.34)
(23.80)
(23.43)
(21.14)
#Employees
-0.363
-0.392
0.171
-0.461
(0.892)
(1.217)
(1.236)
(0.838)
#White collars
23.83
22.99
18.92
29.76
(20.97)
(22.52)
(20.40)
(23.22)
Constant
509.5
527.9
634.0
340.1
(491.2)
(556.3)
(505.3)
(559.8)
Number of observations
2,793
2,789
2,789
2,785
Number of subsidiaries
816
816
816
816
R-squared overall
0.65
0.64
0.69
0.68
F
3.36**
2.22*
2.25**
2.93***
Notes: Employee ownership, profit-sharing bonuses, gain-sharing bonuses and gross salary are the total
amount spent by a subsidiary in Euros. Average tenure is measured by the average number of years that
employees have spent in a given subsidiary. #Employees and #White collars indicate, respectively, the
numbers of employees and white-collar employees working for the subsidiary. Robust standard errors are
reported in parentheses: * significant at 10%, ** significant at 5% and *** significant at 1%. To improve
clarity and because they remain constant during the five-year period, we do not report coefficients that are
associated with particular sectors.
How does shared capitalism affect absenteeism?
Models 5 through 8 test the relationship between shared capitalism and absenteeism. Employee ownership is
negatively related to absenteeism, but the significance is very low (model 5). Models 6 and 7 show that the
coefficients associated with gain sharing and profit sharing are not significant. Model 8 reports the combined
effects of the three forms of shared capitalism. Employee ownership remains negatively related to absenteeism,
but it has a higher significance. Profit sharing is positively associated with absenteeism, but it has a very low
significance. Gain sharing is not significant. Again, these results partially corroborate our Hypothesis 2. To
complete previous tests, we ran additional models to test the impact of increased participation in an ESPP on
withdrawal behaviors.
11
Additional test: How does an ESPP affect employee withdrawal?
Within the studied company, employees primarily acquire shares through an ESPP. Several factors can
contribute to either encourage or deter employee participation in such a program. In an ESPP, an employer
offers its employees the opportunity to buy company stock at a discounted price. The discount represents a gift
that can be accepted or rejected by each employee. Bryson and Freeman (2012) find that employees who accept
this gift by participating in the ESPP are entering in a gift-exchange relationship. They reciprocate the
employer’s initial gift by adopting more favorable behaviors in the workplace. We investigate this assumption
by testing how ESPP participation affects employees’ withdrawal (models 9 & 10). An additional dummy
variable is created measuring whether the number of shares acquired by the employees through the ESPP
increases or not. The dummy variable takes a value of one if the employees increase the number of their shares;
if the employees do not increase the number of their shares, the dummy variable takes a value of zero. We use
the number of shares instead of the amount of employee ownership to exclude variations among the portfolios
due to increases in stock prices.
With respect to absenteeism, our results confirm the view developed by Bryson and Freeman (2012).
Subsidiaries in which employees have increased their investment in company stocks through the ESPP have
lower absenteeism (model 10). This assumption is not confirmed for turnover (model 9).
Table 5. Relationships between ESPP participation and employees’ withdrawal
Model 9
Model 10
Turnover
Absenteeism
ESPP participation
1.623
-117.0**
(2.088)
(56.82)
Gross salary
-2.15e-05
0.000296**
(2.08e-05)
(0.000136)
Tenure (years)
-0.765
10.41
(1.200)
(24.74)
Employees
0.958***
0.0645
(0.235)
(1.231)
White collars
0.452
17.80
(1.376)
(20.07)
Constant
25.78
748.3
(37.40)
(470.6)
Number of observations
2,887
2,793
Number of subsidiaries
840
816
R-squared overall
0.44
0.120
F
24.30***
2.39**
Notes. ESPP participation takes a value of one if the participation in the subsidiary is positive
and zero if it is not. Gross salary is the total amount spent by a subsidiary in Euros. Average
tenure is measured by the average number of years that employees have spent in a given
subsidiary. #Employees and #White collars indicate, respectively, the numbers of employees
and white-collar employees working for the subsidiary. Robust standard errors are reported in
parentheses: * significant at 10%, ** significant at 5% and *** significant at 1%. To improve
clarity and because they remain constant during the five-year period, we do not report
coefficients that are associated with particular sectors.
To test the sensitivity of our results to the method of estimation, we checked the stability of our results when the
dependent variables were shifted by one year. This shift permits an eventual simultaneity of data bias to be
neutralized. We found that our results remain stable except for the relationship between employee ownership
and turnover, which becomes insignificant. We also replaced the amount of employee ownership with the
number of employee owners for a given subsidiary. This confirms the negative relationship between employee
ownership and absenteeism. The coefficient associated with the number of employee owners is not significant
when turnover is the dependent variable. Another concern is the distribution of the dependent variables. Indeed,
the dependent variables are count variables (specifically, the number of days of absences and the number of
voluntary quits). Poisson regressions are recommended in this instance. We did not find that running all of the
analyses using Poisson regression models affects our results. Only models 5 and 6 (absenteeism) are affected.
12
Employee ownership, which was weakly significant, is no longer significant. Gain sharing becomes significant
at the 10% level.6
DISCUSSION
The aim of this paper is to test the impact of different forms of shared capitalism on withdrawal behaviors. We
find that our research hypotheses are corroborated to a great extent. Shared capitalism is a concept with several
dimensions. We chose to measure three out of the four forms of shared capitalism. Profit sharing and gain
sharing allow us to capture short-term shared capitalism policies, whereas employee ownership is a long-term
shared capitalism policy. Our measure of employee ownership (total amount of employee ownership in Euros)
enabled us to capture both the intensity and the duration of the employees’ investments. The major point of our
study is to note the different impacts of short-term and long-term forms of shared capitalism. Taken together,
our results show that, unlike short-term forms of shared capitalism, employee ownership always has a
significant and negative effect on withdrawal behaviors.
Our overall results are in line with Blasi et al (2010) and Kruse et al (2012) concerning the impact of employee
ownership turnover, but we also find that long-term shared capitalism in the form of employee ownership can
have a significant (and negative) impact on absenteeism.
Our results call for several comments. The results show that employee ownership always has a strong impact on
withdrawal behaviors, from the initial stage of withdrawal to turnover. We test the impact of employee
ownership both separately and combined with other forms of shared capitalism. When all forms of shared
capitalism are combined, our results highlight the contrasting impacts of short-term and long-term forms of
shared capitalism. More precisely, model 4 suggests that employee ownership has a strong and negative impact
on turnover, whereas gain sharing has a small but positive impact on turnover. Model 8 suggests that employee
ownership has a negative impact on absenteeism, but profit sharing has a positive impact. When we test the
isolated impact of profit sharing and gain sharing, we find that they have no significant impact on withdrawal
behaviors. Whatever the specification of our model, the results highlight the significant (and negative) impact of
employee ownership on turnover and absenteeism. This major result shows that, to some extent, long-term
shared capitalism seems to initiate a stronger association between an employer and its employees. By contrast,
our results show that short-term forms of shared capitalism (namely, gain sharing and profit sharing) have no
significant impact on withdrawal behaviors. The literature reports these dissimilar impacts, especially the
difference between the impact of profit sharing and that of employee ownership. For instance, Bryson and
Freeman (2012), Blasi et al (2010), Brown et al (1999) and Fakhfakh (2004) report differences between
employee ownership and profit sharing. This research stream suggests that short-term forms of shared capitalism
have no impact on long-term behaviors such as withdrawal. Because withdrawal behaviors are progressive in
nature, it seems quite logical to find an association only with the long-term form of shared capitalism. Gain-
sharing and profit-sharing bonuses are defined on a short-term horizon. Gain sharing and profit sharing are
yearly programs: they cannot produce a significant impact on withdrawal behaviors, which are more progressive
and could take more than a year. By strongly associating employees with the firm, employee ownership seems
to be an especially accurate method of addressing the problem of withdrawal behaviors.
Our article suggests that the gift-exchange approach (see section 1) is relevant to explain such behaviors. The
gift-exchange approach suggested by Kruse et al (2012), Bryson and Freeman (2012) and Pendleton (2011),
among others, receives strong support from our study. Employee ownership is more complex than gain sharing
and profit sharing, and it allows the firm to build a closer relationship with employees.7 Employees consider the
opportunity of employee ownership (and the associated discount) as a gift and tend to give a reciprocal “gift” to
the firm, translated, for example, into lower turnover and absenteeism rates. In addition, our test of an ESPP’s
impact on withdrawal behaviors gives additional support to this view by suggesting that employees respond to
their employer’s gift of a discount on company stock (or the equivalent in free shares) by agreeing to participate.
In fact, the results from model 10 also suggest that there is a more significant effect on absenteeism when
employee ownership is measured in terms of ESPP participation (table 4 vs table 5). Our interpretation of this
result considers that the decision to increase the employee ownership stake is more important than the total
amount invested. This can be viewed as a gift exchange between employer and employees. Our results suggest,
consistent with Bryson and Freeman (2012), that employees reciprocate the company’s initial gift of a discount
on company stock.
Further, it should be remembered that employee ownership is a collective incentive scheme. Our hypotheses are
corroborated by the amount of employee ownership of the subsidiary. In this respect, it should be made clear
6 The results of all additional analyses are available from the authors on request.
7 It should be noted that there are strong links between gain sharing/profit sharing and employee ownership.
However, our study and the literature show that the longer the form of shared capitalism, the better the results
for firms.
13
that the two dimensions of withdrawal behaviors implicate different phenomena. Mobley (1977) notes that
absenteeism is one of the first phases of a process of progressive withdrawal by the employee, which can have
as a final result his departure on his own initiative. From this point of view, an employee’s withdrawal has
several phases. Absenteeism is one of the first and leaving is the last. This analysis may explain the differences
in the results obtainednamely, that employee ownership has a weaker effect on staff turnover than it does on
absenteeism. From a broader point of view, employee ownership is a powerful means of retaining employees
and increasing the fidelity of human capital, and it acts as a “stabilizing force” (Blair et al, 2000). We choose to
measure employee ownership by the total amount of employee ownership in Euros. This enables us to measure
both the intensity and the duration of the investments the employees made. Replacing this monetary measure of
employee ownership with the number of employee owners affects our results regarding turnover. Our results
also confirm the view that employee ownership should be regarded as a gift exchange. Indeed, the amount
invested reflects both the intensity of employees’ investment in their company and their willingness to engage in
a long-term relationship. The results that we find by analyzing the number of employee owners is different
because the number of employee owners can be very high even though each individual employee may have a
very low stake.
Some limitations of this study include the measures that we used and the characteristics of the data. As far as the
data are concerned, their characteristics make it difficult to generalize our results. One of the specificities of our
sample comes from the sector analyzed. The main activities of the company studied mostly belong to the
construction sector. This sector is characterized by precarious working conditions, strong labor mobility and
weak qualifications. In this context, employee ownership has a different meaning than in other sectors, such as
services or innovating businesses, as noted by Blair et al (2000).
CONCLUSION
This paper studies the relationship between different forms of shared capitalism and employees’ withdrawal
measures. The analyses addressed more than 800 subsidiaries of a French listed company over a five-year
period. We show that employee ownership is negatively and significantly associated with turnover and
absenteeism, whereas gain sharing and profit sharing are not. From a managerial point of view, our results
suggest that companies wishing to promote shared capitalism should first try a long-term form of shared
capitalism and employee investment. In pursuing this goal, however, the risk to the employees of losing their
investments should not be underestimated. Both our contribution and its limits call for new lines of research.
The number of studies on the effects of employee ownership in France is small. However, employee ownership
is encouraged by numerous tax incentives; thus, many companies make important efforts to develop it. One
might have expected that the empirical evidence for its beneficial effects would be more plentiful. Therefore,
these studies must be conducted in different contexts, incorporating particularly the fundamental concept of
employee involvement in decision making. One suitable methodological direction, as suggested by Jones et al
(2006), could be to develop more econometric case studies in order to take advantage of more in-depth research
designs.
14
References
Blair, Margaret M., Kruse, Douglas L. and Blasi, Joseph R. (2000) Employee Ownership: An Unstable Form?
Or a Stabilizing Force?. In Margaret M. Blair and Thomas A. Kochan (eds.), The New Relationship: Human
Capital in the American Corporation. Washington D.C: The Brookings Institution.
Blasi, Joseph R., Conte, Michael, and Kruse, Douglas L. (1996). Employee Stock Ownership and Corporate
Performance Among Public Companies. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 50(1) 60-79.
Blasi, Joseph R., Kruse, Douglas L. and Markovitz, Harry M. (2010). Risk and Lack of Diversification under
Employee Ownership and Shared Capitalism. In Kruse, Douglas L., Freeman, Richard. B., Blasi, Joseph. (Eds),
Shared capitalism at work: employee ownership, profit and gain sharing, and broad-based stock options, NBER
and University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL.
Blasi, Joseph R., Freeman, Richard B., Mackin, Christopher and Kruse, Douglas L. (2010). Creating a bigger
pie: The Eects of Employee Ownership, Profit Sharing, and Stock Options on Workplace Performance in
Kruse Douglas L., Freeman Richard B., Blasi Joseph R. (Eds), Shared capitalism at work: employee
ownership, profit and gain sharing, and broad-based stock options, NBER and University of Chicago Press,
Chicago, IL.
Brown, Sarah, Fakhfakh, Fathi and Sessions, John G. (1999). Absenteeism and Employee Sharing: an Empirical
Analysis Based on French Panel Data, 1981-1991. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 52(2) 234-251.
Bryson, Alex, and Freeman, Richard B. (2012). Company Share Plans - Gift or Incentive? Evidence from a
Multinational Corporation. American Economic Association annual meeting.
Craney, Trevor A. and Surles, James G. (2002). Model-dependent Variance Inflation Factor Cutoff Values.
Quality Engineering, 14(3) 391403.
Engelhardht, Gary V. and Madrian, Brigitte C. (2004). Employee Stock Purchase Plans. National Tax Journal,
57(2) 385-406.
Fakhfakh, Fathi. (2004). The Effect of Profit Sharing and Employee Share Ownership on Quits: Evidence from
a French Panel Firms, Employee Participation, Firm Performance and Survival. Advances in the Economic
Analysis of Participatory and Labor Managed Firms, 8 129-147.
Festing Marion, Groening, Y., Kabst, R. and Weber, W. (1999). Financial Participation in Europe -
Determinants and Outcomes. Economic and Industrial Democracy, 20(2) 295-329.
Freeman, Richard B., Kruse, Douglas L., Blasi, Joseph R. (2010). Worker Response to Shirking under Shared
Capitalism. In Kruse, Douglas L., Freeman, Richard B., Blasi, Joseph R. (Eds), Shared capitalism at work:
employee ownership, profit and gain sharing, and broad-based stock options, NBER and University of Chicago
Press, Chicago, IL.
Hsieh, An-Tien, and Liu, Li-Ling. (2006). The Re-examination of the Relationship Between Employee Stock
Ownership and Voluntary Employer Change Intention in Taiwan. International Journal of Human Resource
Management, 17(1) 174-189.
Jones, Derek C., Kalmi, Panu and Kauhanen, Antti. (2006). Human Resource Management Policy: New
Evidence from an Econometric Case Study. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 22(4) 526-538.
Jones, Derek C., Kalmi, Panu, and Kauhanen, Antti. (2010). How Does Employee Involvement Stack Up? The
Effects of Human Resource Management Policies on Performance in a Retail Firm. Industrial Relations, 49(1)
121.
Kaarsemaker Eric C.A. (2006). Employee Ownership and its Consequences: Synthesis-generated Evidence for
the Effects of Employee Ownership and Gaps in the Research Literature. University of York.
Kruse, Douglas L. (2002). Research Evidence on the Prevalence and Effects of Employee Ownership. Journal of
Employee Ownership, Law and Finance, 14(4) 65-90.
Kruse, Douglas L. and Blasi, Joseph R. (1997). Employee Ownership, Employee Attitudes, and Firm
Performance: A review of the evidence. In Mitchell, Daniel J. B., Lewin, David. and Zaidi, Mahmood (Eds),
Handbook of Human Resource Management, JAI Press.
Kruse, Douglas L., Freeman, Richard B., and Blasi, Joseph R. (2010). Shared capitalism at work: employee
ownership, profit and gain sharing, and broad-based stock options, NBER and University of Chicago Press,
Chicago, IL.
Kruse, Douglas L., Blasi, Joseph R., and Freeman, Richard B. (2012). Does linking worker pay to firm
performance help the best firms to do even better, NBER Working paper n°17745. Cambridge, MA: National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Mobley, William H. (1977). Intermediate Linkages in the Relationship between Job Satisfaction and Employee
Turnover. Journal of Applied Psychology, 62(2) 237-240.
Mobley, William H. (1982). Some unanswered questions in turnover and withdrawal research. Academy of
Management Review, 7(1) 111-116.
Pendleton, Andrew. (2011). Employee Stock Ownership as a Gift Exchange. 2011-2012 Beyster Symposium &
Mid-Year Fellows Workshop in Honor of Louis O. Kelso, 8-11 December.
15
Pérotin, Virginie and Robinson, Andrew. (2003). Employee Participation in Profit and Ownership, European
Parliament, working paper SOCI 109.
Pierce, Jon L., Rubenfeld, Stephen and Morgan Susan. (1991). Employee Ownership: a Conceptual Model of
Process and Effects. Academy of Management Review, 16(1) 121-144.
Rapp, Thomas and Aubert, Nicolas. 2011. Bank Employee Incentives and Stock Purchase Plans Participation.
Journal of Financial Services Research, 40(3) 185-203.
Wilson, Nicholas and Peel, Michael. J. (1990). The Impact on Absenteeism and Quits of Profit-Sharing and
Other Forms of Employee Participation. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 44(3) 454-468.
... According to Kinear and Suthrland (2016), the mobility of knowledge workers is the organization's primary concern in this new economy where organizations can lose their competitive advantage without talent. Therefore, they must prepare a budget to maintain excellent employees in the organization (Aubert & Hollandts, 2015;Cascio, 2015). ...
Article
Full-text available
The purpose of this study was to find out how the effect of the antecedents of intention to leave involve job dissatisfaction and work-related stress in the Small Medium Entreprises (SMEs). The variables were moderated by the perceived alternative job opportunities (PAJO) as Indonesian Migrant Workers. A total of 89 questionnaires were distributed to the employees of SMEs located in Ngunut District, Tulungagung Regency, East Java, Indonesia. The Data were analyzed using the associative descriptive method, using PLS version 3.0 software. The results of the analysis obtained in this study indicate that work dissatisfaction and work-related stress have a positive influence on the intention to leave the SMEs. The perceived of alternative job opportunities as Indonesian migrant workers successfully moderating the effect of employee work-related stress on the intention to leave SMEs in Ngunut District, Tulungagung Regency.
... Le partage d'informations et le souci de protéger le patrimoine des salariés seraient en revanche cruciaux pour maintenir la réciprocité positive. Les travaux empiriques de Bryson et Freeman (2012) et d'Aubert & Hollandts (2014) parviennent à des conclusions similaires confirmant cette approche dans le cadre des augmentations de capital réservées aux salariés (ACRS ou ESPP soit Employee stock purchase plans aux Etats-Unis). Dans le cadre de ces opérations, les salariés se voient proposés d'acquérir des actions de leur entreprise à un prix décoté (20% en France). ...
Chapter
Full-text available
ENGLISH The economist François Perroux analyze employees’ participation in terms of giving and not in terms of market exchange. To the best of our knowledge, this association between gift and participation is the only attempt. We highlight the limits of constraint and exchange identified by Perroux for justifying the use of the gift to better understand the economic realities and more specifically, participation. Since the work of Perroux empirical and experimental studies have examined the issue. Some studies focus on employee financial participation which is a component of participation but not the only one. Participation in decision making is a second part of participation that is not separable from the first. Academic attention for the gift is fairly recent and refer mostly to Akerlof and Mauss. FRENCH L’économiste François Perroux analyse la participation en termes de don et non plus en termes d’échange marchand. Cette tentative d’association est la seule à notre connaissance. Nous revenons sur les limites de la contrainte et de l’échange qui justifient pour Perroux le recours au don pour mieux comprendre les réalités économiques en général et la participation en particulier. Depuis les travaux de Perroux, des travaux principalement empiriques et expérimentaux ont étudié la question. Certains travaux s’intéressent à la participation financière des salariés qui n’est qu’une composante de la participation. La participation à la gestion en est un autre qui nous semble indissociable de la première. L’attention pour le don est plutôt récente et se réfèrent pour la plupart à Akerlof et à Mauss.
Article
Full-text available
p>The purpose of this research was to investigate the effect of organizational citizenship behaviors (altruism, courtesy, sportsmanship, generalized compliance and civic virtue) on employee withdrawal behaviors (turnover, absenteeism and tardiness). Most research in the OCB literature focused on the impact of organizational citizenship behaviors on turnover, with minimal attention directed toward absenteeism and tardiness, as negative employee performance behaviors. Data were obtained from employees (N = 334) at a municipal law enforcement agency with (N = 624) employees resulting in a 53.53% usable response rate. Data analysis indicated that job satisfaction was directly related to organizational citizenship behavior; and organizational citizenship behavior was inversely related to overall employee withdrawal behavior. Study findings did not lend support for organizational commitment being directly related to organizational citizenship behavior. The authors specified study limitations and future research opportunities.</p
Article
Full-text available
Pour l " économisteFrançois Perroux, la contrainte, l " échange et le don sont les trois motifs des actes économiques.Son originalité est d " analyser la participationà la lumière du dernier motif. Il conçoit la participation comme un don à l " oeuvre commune et adopte une vision de la participation ne se limitant pas au seul partage des bénéfices. Sa critique de l " échange libéral et de la contrainte marxiste traduit les angoisses de son temps mais les formes contemporaines de l " échange et de la contrainte rendent actuelles ses analyses. Rapprocher don et participation trouve sa cohérence dans des travaux qui se focalisent sur la participation financière des salariés. Les travaux empiriques les plus récents montrent en effet la pertinence des théories du don et de la réciprocité pour comprendre la participation des salariés.
Article
Full-text available
Employee ownership has attracted attention and interest for a wide variety of reasons. Much of the interest has focused on the potential for better economic performance, particularly through enhanced motivation and commitment from employees who have a direct stake in firm performance. Strong majorities of the public believe that employee-owners work harder and pay more attention to the quality of their work than non-owners, and are more likely than outside shareholders to vote their shares in the long-term interest of the company. 1 There have also been social arguments for employee ownership, based on its potential to broaden the distribution of wealth, decrease labor-management conflict, and enhance social cohesion and equality by distributing the fruits of economic success more widely and equitably (Gates, 1998). The idea of employee ownership has attracted support across the political spectrum, often being seen as a form of economic democracy that complements our political democracy. 2 Along with these positive views, however, there have been many concerns expressed about employee ownership-particularly that it can expose workers to excessive risk and may in some cases increase labor-management conflict and lower economic performance. How much employee ownership exists in the United States, and what are the lessons from the accumulated evidence? There have been over 70 empirical studies on the effects of employee ownership in the past 25 years. These can be categorized into studies of: (a) employee attitudes and behavior; (b) firm performance; (c) employment stability, growth, and firm survival; and (d) employee wealth and wages. The studies have mostly been done on samples of United States firms and employees, although several have been done on firms in other Western industrialized countries. In this testimony, I will first present data on the extent of employee ownership in the United States, and then briefly summarize the results from these studies and discuss some implications for public policy.
Article
Employee share purchase plans (ESPPs) give free or discounted shares of stock to workers who buy shares in the hope that the greater share ownership will retain workers, build loyalty and raise productivity, as in gift exchange models. Using measures of workers’ organizational loyalty and sense of ownership in a multinational firm that puts the ESPP at the heart of its compensation policy, we find that workers who join the ESPP have lower turnover intentions and do less on‐the‐job search than others, motivated in part by gift exchange reciprocity, and also respond to the group incentive of ownership with greater work effort, longer hours, and lower absence rates. Workers in workplaces with high perceived rates of ESPP participation are more likely to intervene against shirkers. The results appear robust to the selectivity of who joins the ESPP. The mix of gifting shares to workers who buy shares and the group incentive of ownership makes ESPPs a unique dual form of compensation.
Article
This study compares the corporate performance in 1990/91 of two groups of public companies: those in which employees owned more than 5% of the company's stock, and all others. The results of the analysis, which looks at profitability, productivity, and compensation, are consistent with neither negative nor highly positive views of employee ownership, but where differences are found, they are favorable to companies with employee ownership, especially among companies of small size. The circumstances in which employee ownership was used - specifically, whether it was part of a wage/benefit concession package and whether it was involved in a takeover threat - do not appear to have had a significant effect on the 1990 performance levels or 1980-90 performance growth of the firms. Although the authors caution that the data do not permit clear tests of causality, these results are broadly consistent with those of past studies.
Article
A model is developed that explicates one process through which employee ownership operates, leading to a set of social-psychological and behavioral effects. Where the formal ownership system is operationalized such that it leads to psychological ownership, a bonding or integration of the employee-owner with the organization occurs. It is through these processes that employee ownership exercises an influence upon group and individual outcomes. A set of antecedent and moderating variables to the operation of the formal ownership system is identified.
Article
Current employee turnover research inadequately addresses several long recognized and important questions. Specifically, where is the process in turnover process research; what are the consequences of turnover and the processes related to these consequences; what is the role of performance in the turnover process; and what are the conceptual and empirical relationships among turnover and other so-called "withdrawal" critera? The importance of these questions and approaches to addressing these questions are discussed.
Article
Although past literature had provided inconsistent conclusions as to whether or not employee stock ownership (ESO) can serve the function of employee retention, this paper proposes that the reason for such inconsistency lies in the inability to clarify ESO characteristics. Therefore, this study examines the relationship between ESO and voluntary employer change intention from the viewpoint of vested and portable characteristics. Study results indicated that vested ESO achieves the function of employee retention. However, when vested ESO is also portable, employees tend to spend more efforts searching for external ESO alternatives, which reinforce their voluntary employer change intention.
Article
This article's objective is to analyse determinants and outcomes of financial participation in Europe. It starts off with a definition of the instruments, a review of the literature in the field of financial participation and a discussion on the relevance of financial participation in selected European countries. Choosing a rather inductive approach, the authors develop a model for financial participation. Based on the Cranfield data, the significance of the variables used in the model is tested. Union density, number of employees, public limited company status, geographical market and policy regarding pay and benefits came out as significant determinants for financial participation at company level. The environment, however, also bears influence. Organizations in Germany, France, Great Britain and Sweden show significantly different practices. Employee share ownership and profit sharing cannot only increase financial performance but also allow for efficient human resource management. Profit sharing increases profits and decreases absenteeism as well as staff turnover. The findings for employee share ownership are not that straightforward.
Article
This paper uses an unbalanced panel of 129 French firms over the period 1981–1991 to test the effects of two participatory schemes – profit sharing and employee share ownership – on voluntary quits. The effects of sharing schemes on productivity are well documented and most studies show positive and significant effects on productivity but their effects on quits have been less studied. This paper is the first French study looking at the effects of profit sharing and employee share ownership on quits. Our empirical investigation shows that employee share ownership reduces voluntary quits significantly whereas pure profit sharing has no significant effect.
Article
When creating designed experiments, it is not always possible to run the experiment at the exact settings required to maintain orthogonal effects. However, this is not measurement error when precise measurements of the settings can be made once the experiment begins. A comparison is made for a 15-run Box–Behnken design using both the intended design settings and the actual design settings. Variance inflation factors are used to measure the induced collinearity in the effects. Two cutoff values are suggested for use to determine when an effect's variance inflation factor is too large to keep that effect in the model.