ArticlePDF Available

Portfolios for Investors Who Want to Reach Their Goals While Staying on the Mean–Variance Efficient Frontier

Authors:
  • LWI Financial Inc. ("Loring Ward")
THE JOURNAL OF WEALTH MANAGEMENT 1
FALL 2011
Portfolios for Investors Who Want to
Reach their Goals While Staying on
the Mean–Variance Efficient Frontier
SANJIV DAS, HARRY MARKOWITZ, JONATHAN SCHEID,
AND MEIR STATMAN
SANJIV DAS
is a professor of finance at
the Leavey School of Busi-
ness, Santa Clara Un iver-
sity, in Santa Clara, CA.
srdas@scu.edu
HARRY MARKOWITZ
is a professor of finance at
the Rady School of Man-
agement, University of
California, San Diego, in
La Jolla, CA.
harryhmm@aol.com
JONATHAN SCH EID
is the president and CIO at
Bellatore Financial, Inc.,
in San Jose, CA.
jscheid@bellatore.com
MEIR STATM AN
is Glenn Klimek Professor
of Finance at the Leavey
School of Business, Santa
Clara University, in Santa
Clara, CA, a nd a visiting
professor at Tilburg Uni-
versit y in the Netherlands.
mstatman@scu.edu
Mental-accounting portfolio
theory is a goal-based port-
folio theory, combining some
of the most appealing features
of Markowitz’s [1952a] mean–variance port-
folio theory and Shefrin and Statman’s [2000]
behavioral portfolio theory.
Mean–variance portfolio theory is a
“production” theory. Investors in that theory
produce portfolios that combine expected
returns and standard deviations of returns at
levels that are best for them. But what do
mean–variance investors want to do with
the money in their portfolios? Do their goals
consist of funding a comfortable retirement
and a modest bequest to children? Do they
consist of a bare-bones retirement and a con-
siderable bequest to charity? The production
of mean–variance efficient portfolios is only
a station on the way to investors’ ultimate
goals, yet mean–variance portfolio theory is
silent about these goals. In contrast, behav-
ioral portfolio theory combines the produc-
tion of optimal portfolios for investors with
the use of the money in investors’ portfolios
to reach their goals.
Mean–variance investors consider their
portfolios as a whole, as depicted in Exhibit 1.
In contrast, behavioral investors begin by
dividing the whole of their portfolios into
mental accounts, each dedicated to a partic-
ular goal and each with its own time horizon.
These are depicted in Exhibit 2. For example,
a $1 million portfolio might be divided into
an $800,000 mental account for a retirement
goal that is 15 years away, a $150,000 mental
account for an education goal that is three
years away, and a $50,000 mental account
for a bequest goal that is 25 years away. Next,
behavioral investors specify threshold levels
they want to reach or exceed for each goal
when t hey arr ive at it s hor i z on. For ex a mp le,
investors might aim to reach or exceed a
$2 million threshold in the mental account
dedicated to the retirement goal, $180,000 in
the mental account dedicated to the educa-
tion goal, and $850,000 in the mental account
dedicated to the bequest goal.
Investors in mean–variance portfolio
theory face a single efficient frontier, con-
sisting of the best feasible combinations of
expected returns and standard deviation of
returns. In contrast, investors in behavioral
portfolio theory face many efficient fron-
tiers, one for each mental account. More-
over, while risk in mean–variance portfolio
theor y is mea s u red by t he st a ndard devia t ion
of return, risk in behavioral portfolio theory
is measured by the probability of failing to
reach the threshold level of a mental account.
Investors in behavioral portfolio theory
choose their best combination on the effi-
cient frontier of expected returns and the
probability of failing to reach the threshold
of each mental account.
JWM_DAS.indd 1JWM_DAS.indd 1 7/1/11 3:24:37 PM7/1/11 3:24:37 PM
Author Draft For Review Only
2 PORTFOLIOS FOR INVESTORS WHO WANT TO REACH THEIR GOALS FALL 2011
The road to behavioral portfolio theory started
more than 60 years ago, when Friedman and Savage
[1948] noted that hope for riches and protection from
poverty share roles in our behavior; people who buy
lottery tickets often buy insurance policies as well. So,
people are risk seeking enough to buy lottery tickets
and risk averse enough to buy insurance. Four years
later, Markowitz wrote two articles that ref lect two
very different views of behavior. In one [1952a], he cre-
ated mean–variance theory, and in the other [1952b],
he extended Friedman and Savages insurance–lottery
framework. People in mean–variance theor y, unlike
people in the insurance–lottery framework, never buy
lottery tickets; they are always risk averse and never risk
seeking.
Friedman and Savage observed that people buy
lottery tickets because they aspire to reach higher social
classes, whereas they buy insurance as protection against
falling into lower social classes. Markowitz [1952b]
clarified Friedman and Savage’s observation by noting
that people aspire to move up from their current social
class orcustomary wealth.” So, people with $10,000
might accept lottery-like odds in the hope of winning
$1 million, and people with $1 million might accept
lottery-like odds in the hope of winning $100 million.
Kahneman and Tversky [1979] extended the work of
Markowitz [1952b] into prospect theory. Prospect theory
describes the behavior of people who accept lottery-like
odds when they are in the domain of losses, such as
when they are below their aspiration levels, but reject
such odd s when they are in the d omain of g a ins, such a s
when they are above their aspiration levels.
Behavioral portfolio theory’s description of port-
folios as collections of mental accounts, or a set of layers
in portfolio pyramids, is part of common investment
advice. The mental account or pyramid structure of
behavioral portfolios is also reflected in the upside-
potential and downside-protection layers of “core and
satellite” portfolios.
One might argue that although the portfolios are
described as layered pyramids, which are consistent with
behavioral portfolio theory, investors actually consider
them as a whole, wh ich i s con sistent with mean–v a r i a n ce
portfolio theory. But the evidence does not support such
an argument. Consider, for example, Question 13 in
the Asset Allocation Planner of Fidelity Investments
[2003]:
If you could increase your chances of improving
your returns by taking more risk, would you:
1. Be willing to take a lot more risk with all your
money?
2. Be w i ll i n g to t a ke a lot more r i s k with some of your
money?
EXHIBIT 1
Mean–Variance Portfolio Theory
Investor s consider the portfolio a s a whole. They want to be on
the mean–variance ef ficient frontier.
EXHIBIT 2
Behavioral Portfolio Theory
Investors divide their portfolios into mental accounting layers
or a portfolio pyram id, whereby each layer is associated with a
particular goal and a particular attitude toward risk.
JWM_DAS.indd 2JWM_DAS.indd 2 7/1/11 3:24:37 PM7/1/11 3:24:37 PM
Author Draft For Review Only
THE JOURNAL OF WEALTH MANAGEMENT 3
FALL 2011
3. Be willing to take a little more risk with all your
money.
4. Be willing to take a little more risk with some of
your money?
5. Be unlikely to take much more risk?
Answers 1 and 3 make sense within mean–variance
theory. In that theory, only the risk of all the money
in the overall portfolio matters. But Answers 2 and 4
make no sense within mean–variance theory because
they assume a segmentation of the portfolio into mental
accounts depending on where investors are willing to
take more or less risk with some of their money. Mean
variance investors have a single attitude toward risk,
not a set of attitudes mental account by mental account.
In contrast, behavioral investors have many attitudes
toward risk, one for each mental account, so they might
be willing to take a lot more risk with some of their
money. Statman [2004] found that the number of inves-
tors who were willing to take a lot mor e risk wit h some of
their money exceeded the number of investors who were
willing to take a little more risk with all their money
by a ratio of approximately 10 to one. Yet taking a lot
more risk with some of our money adds to our overall
portfolio risk about the same as taking a little more risk
with all our money.
Recently, Harry Markowitz joined Das et al.
[2010] in the development of mental accounting port-
folio theory, which combines mean–variance portfolio
theory with several features of behavioral portfolio
theory. These features include the mental accounting
structure of portfolios and the definition of risk as the
probability of failing to reach threshold levels. But mental
accounting portfolio theory does not include two central
features of behavioral portfolio theory. First, investors
in behavioral portfolio theory can be risk seeking in
some of their mental accounts, but risk-seeking pref-
erences are excluded from both mean–variance port-
folio theory and mental accounting portfolio theory.
Second, the optimal securities in behavioral portfolio
theory resemble call options w ith asymmetric distr ibu-
tions of returns rather than securities with symmetric
distributions of returns, such as normal distributions.
We hasten to add that mean–variance portfolio theory
can accommodate many kinds of return distributions,
including asymmetric return distributions.
INVESTOR GOALS AND MENTAL ACCOUNTS
Consider a 50-year-old investor with $1 million in
investable assets. She allocates her money to three mental
account subportfolios, each associated with a goal. She
allocates $800,000 to the retirement account, $150,000
to the education account, and $50,000 to the bequest
account that she hopes to leave for her children. Our
investor has other assets, including a house and future
Social Security payments. Moreover, our investor is still
working and investing her savings. She intends to retire
at 65 and estimates her life expectancy to be 75.
Our investor wants her $800,000 retirement
account to grow to $1,917,247 by the time she is 65,
which implies a compound annualized return of 6%
during the remaining 15 years. Her horizon for the
education account is shorter, only three years, and she
wants that account to grow to $188,957, which implies
a compound annualized return of 8% . Our investor’s
horizon for the bequest account is long—25 years—but
she has an ambitious aspiration; she wants her current
account of $50,000 to grow to $850,003, which implies
a compound annualized return of 12% .
The mean–variance efficient frontier faced by our
investor is determined by the characteristics of avail-
able securities, namely, their expected returns, standard
deviations, and correlations. She creates three mental
account subportfolios associated with her three goals and
will evaluate her progress toward her goals once a year,
adjusting her goals and mental account subportfolios
as necessary. Each mental account subportfolio is opti-
mized by the mean–variance procedure. The optimal
mean–variance subportfolio for the retirement goal is
the one that corresponds to an expected return of 6%.
The 6 % expected ret u r n also deter m ines the ris k of th i s
subportfolio. Mental account subportfolios are created
similarly for the education goal, with its expected return
of 8% , and the bequest goal, with its expected return
of 12% . Exhibit 3 provides a summar y of the mental
account subportfolios and their related return and risk
characteristics.
To keep our example simple, assume there are
only three assets: a bond mutual fund or ETF with an
expected return of 2% a year and a standard deviation
of 5%, a conservative stock mutual fund or ETF with an
expected return of 8% a year and a standard deviation of
20%, and an aggressive stock mutual fund or ETF with
an expected return of 15% a year and a standard deviation
JWM_DAS.indd 3JWM_DAS.indd 3 7/1/11 3:24:42 PM7/1/11 3:24:42 PM
Author Draft For Review Only
4 PORTFOLIOS FOR INVESTORS WHO WANT TO R EACH THEIR GOALS FALL 2011
of 40%. The returns of the bond fund are uncorrelated
with the returns of the two stock funds. The returns of
the two stock funds have a 25% correlation.
Our investor calculates three mean–variance effi-
cient subportfolios corresponding to the three goals.
They are displayed in Exhibit 4 along with the overall
portfolio. The standard deviation of the returns of the
re t i rement su bpor t fol io is t he lowe s t at 10.45 % , fo l lowed
by the 15.23% of the education subportfolio and the
25.28% of the bequest subportfolio. The 6.60% expected
return of the overall portfolio is a weighted average of
the returns of the three mental account subportfolios,
but the 11.85% standard deviation of the overall portfolio
is different from the weighted average of the standard
deviations of the three mental account subportfolios.
Asking our investor to state her preferences for
expected return and standard deviations for each goal
is better than asking her to state her preferences for the
expected return and standard deviation of the overall
portfolio. The latter requires that she aggregate the three
goals in her mind, which is difficult. It is easier to match
low risk tolerance with the retirement subportfolio,
medium risk tolerance with the education subportfolio,
and high risk tolerance with the bequest subportfolio
than to match a weighted-average risk attitude toward
the three goals.
Moreover, since our investor has little sense of her
tr ue attitude toward risk in the overall por tfolio, asking
her to state that risk attitude is likely to result in her
choosing a portfolio on the eff icient frontier that does
not correspond well to her true risk attitude. There is a
loss that comes from choosing the wrong portfolio on
the eff icient frontier, and that loss can range between a
few basis points of annual return to several percentage
points. See Exhibit 5 for a schematic representation of
these losses.
Mental account subportfolios and the overall port-
folio are always on the mean–variance eff icient frontier
when there are no constraints on allocation, such as a
preclusion of short or leveraged positions (see Exhibit 6).
Mental account subportfolios may be a few annual basis
points below the mean–variance efficient frontier when
such constraints are imposed. Yet even such small losses
are rarely incurred in usual practice, as financial advi-
sors rarely recommend overall portfolios with short or
leveraged positions.
EXHIBIT 3
Mental Account Subportfolios and Goals
EXHIBIT 4
Mental Account Subportfolios and the Overall Portfolio
JWM_DAS.indd 4JWM_DAS.indd 4 7/1/11 3:24:42 PM7/1/11 3:24:42 PM
Author Draft For Review Only
THE JOURNAL OF WEALTH MANAGEMENT 5
FALL 2011
The proportion allocated to the bond fund is
highest in the retirement subportfolio, lower in the edu-
cation subportfolio, and lowest in the bequest portfolio.
Arranging the overall portfolio as a set of three mental
account subportfolios does not imply that we need three
“real” accounts for each fund, or one for the bond fund
in the retirement subportfolio, another for the bond
fund in the education subportfolio, and a third for the
bond fund in the bequest subportfolio. Instead, we have
one real bond fund account and three “virtual” bond
accounts listing the allocation in the bond fund of each
subportfolio. Financial advisors can provide portfolio
reports to their clients in two formats—real account
formats for the overall portfolio and virtual account for-
mats for each of the mental account subportfolios (see
Exhibit 7).
The presentation of the overall portfolio as the sum
of the three mental account subportfolios has an advan-
tage over a sole presentation of the overall portfolio.
The mental account subportfolios’ presentation speaks
the language of investors. Investors want to reach their
goals, not have portfolios only on the mean–variance
eff icient frontier. Goal-based mental account subportfo-
lios let investors articulate each goal, the horizon of each
goal, and the attitude toward risk for each goal. Telling
the investor that the expected return of her overall port-
folio is 6.60 % and its standard deviation is 11.85% tells
her little because the overall portfolio combines three
very different goals. Telling her the expected returns
and standard deviations of each subportfolio highlights
her goals.
MEASURING RISK BY THE PROBABILITY
OF LOSSES AND THEIR AMOUNTS
Our investor is better able to convey her prefer-
ences for expected returns and standard deviations asso-
ciated with each goal than her preferences for expected
returns and standard deviations associated with the
overall portfolio. Yet standard deviations have little intu-
itive meaning to most investors who are not schooled in
statistics. Standard deviations can be made more intui-
tive to understand. For example, we can tell our investor
that the 10.45% standard deviation in her retirement
subportfolio implies that she has approximately a two in
three chance that her realized return would be higher
than –4.45% yet lower than 16.45%. The first is the 6%
expected return minus the 10.45% standard deviation,
and the second is 6% plus 10.45%. This explanation helps
convey the facts of risk somewhat more intuitively but
not much more i ntu itively. ( I ndeed , standard deviations
have little intuitive meaning even to investors schooled
in statistics).
Our investor is likely to prefer to express her atti-
tud e toward risk by sp ecif y i n g a pr obab i l i t y of inc u r r ing
a loss and the amount of loss. Referring to the retirement
mental account subportfolios, she might say that she
EXHIBIT 5
Loss in Units of Expected Return from Misestimated
Risk Attitudes
Misestimation of risk attitudes leads to suboptimal portfolios on
the efficient frontier.
EXHIBIT 6
The Mean–Variance Efficient Frontier with Mental
Account Subportfolios and the Overall Portfolio
JWM_DAS.indd 5JWM_DAS.indd 5 7/1/11 3:24:48 PM7/1/11 3:24:48 PM
Author Draft For Review Only
6 PORTFOLIOS FOR INVESTORS WHO WANT TO R EACH THEIR GOALS FALL 2011
does not want too much risk. Specifically, she is willing
to accept no more than a 6.28 % probability of losing
more than 10% of her retirement subportfolio during
the coming year. Our investor is willing to accept con-
siderably more risk in her bequest subportfolio. In that
subportfolio, she is willing to accept a 14.27% prob-
ability of losing more than 15% of her funds during the
coming year.
It turns out that the 10.45% standard deviation
of the retirement subportfolio can be expressed more
intuitively as a probability no higher than 6.28% of
losing more than 10% of her funds in the retirement
subportfolio during the coming year. Similarly, the
25.28% standard deviation of the bequest subportfolio
is expressed more intuitively as a probability no higher
than 14.27% of losing more than 15% of her funds in the
bequest subportfolio during the coming year.
Exhibit 8 compares the mental account subportfo-
lios’ risk with the language of probability.
CONCLUSION
Investors are attracted to Markowitz’s mean–
variance portfolio theory by its logic and practical
application. It seems logical to choose portfolios based
on their overall expected returns and standard devia-
tions of returns. And the mean–variance optimizer is
a practical tool, quick at drawing the efficient frontier
of expected returns and standard deviations of returns.
Yet investors want more than portfolios on the mean
variance efficient frontier. Ultimately, investors want
their portfolios to satisfy goals such as a secure retire-
ment, college education for their grandchildren, or a
bequest for children.
While Markowitz’s mean–variance portfolio
theor y is si l ent a bou t ultimate portfol io goa ls, t hese g o a l s
are central in Shefrin and Statman’s behavioral port-
folio theory. Among other things, investors in behav-
ioral portfolio theory divide their portfolios into mental
account layers of a portfolio pyramid, whereby each layer
EXHIBIT 7
Real Portfolio and Virtual Portfolios
JWM_DAS.indd 6JWM_DAS.indd 6 7/1/11 3:24:53 PM7/1/11 3:24:53 PM
Author Draft For Review Only
THE JOURNAL OF WEALTH MANAGEMENT 7
FALL 2011
is associated with a particular goal and a particular atti-
tude toward risk. Risk in behavioral port folio theory is
the probability of failing to reach the threshold of each
goal, not the standard deviation of the returns of the
overall portfolio. In this article, we combine appealing
features of mean–variance portfolio theory and behav-
ioral portfolio theory in a mental accounting portfolio
theory. Investors divide their portfolios by goals into
mental account layers of a portfolio pyramid, and risk is
the probability of failing to reach the threshold return
of each goal. Yet each mental account is optimized by
the rules of mean–variance portfolio theory.
ENDNOTE
This article is an abbreviated version of “Portfolio
Optimization with Mental Accounts” [Das et al. 2010].
REFERENCES
Das, S., H. Markowitz, J. Scheid, and M. Statman. “Portfolio
Optimization with Mental Accounts.Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis, Vol. 45, No. 2 (2010), pp. 311-334.
Fidelity Investments, “Asset Allocation Planner Question-
naire.” 2003, Available at: ww w.fidelity.com.
Friedman, M., and L.J. Savage. “The Utility Analysis of
Choices Involving Risk.” Journal of Political Economy, 56
(1948), pp. 279-304.
Kahneman, D., and A. Tversky. “Prospect Theor y: An Anal-
ysis of Decision Making under Risk.Econometrica, 47 (1979),
pp. 263-291.
Markowitz, H. “Portfolio Selection.” Journal of Finance, 7
(1952a), pp. 77-91.
——. “The Utility of Wealth.” The Journal of Political Economy,
60 (1952b), pp. 151-158.
Shefrin, H., and M. Statman. 2000. “Behavioral Portfolio
Theory.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, Vol. 35,
No. 2 (2000), pp. 127-151.
Statman, M., and V. Wood. “Investor Temperament.” Journal
of Investment Consulting, Summer (2004), pp. 1-12.
To order reprints of this article, please contact Dewey Palmieri
at dpalmieri@ iijournals.com or 212-224-3675.
EXHIBIT 8
Probability of Return Lower than Threshold Return
JWM_DAS.indd 7JWM_DAS.indd 7 7/1/11 3:24:57 PM7/1/11 3:24:57 PM
Author Draft For Review Only
... Each subportfolio is dedicated to a goal, and individuals care about the expected return of each subportfolio and the probability of underachieving goals. Even though mean-variance portfolio theory and behavioral portfolio theory have foundational differences, Das et al. (2010) show that subportfolios as well as the overall portfolio are mean-variance efficient when returns are assumed to be normally distributed, and MVO is shown to be still relevant when the assumptions are relaxed (Das et al. 2011). Through these developments, forming subportfolios based on distinct goals have become central to formulating portfolio optimization models for individual investors. ...
... Each subportfolio is dedicated to a goal, and individuals care about the expected return of each subportfolio and the probability of underachieving goals. Even though mean-variance portfolio theory and behavioral portfolio theory have foundational differences, Das et al. (2010) show that subportfolios as well as the overall portfolio are mean-variance efficient when returns are assumed to be normally distributed, and MVO is shown to be still relevant when the assumptions are relaxed (Das et al. 2011). Through these developments, forming subportfolios based on distinct goals have become central to formulating portfolio optimization models for individual investors. ...
... An investor with low or moderate risk aversion may build a portfolio falling outside the GMVP equivalent. For example, Das et al. [12,13] illustrated a portfolio pyramid based on different levels of γ, in which the top, middle, and bottom of the pyramid are the mental accounts for bequest (with a low value of γ = 0.8773), education (with a moderate value of γ = 2.7063), and retirement (with a higher value of γ = 3.7950) goals, respectively. These goal-based portfolios have received considerable attention since the 2008-2009 crisis, when investors realized that chasing high returns could negatively impact long-term wealth accumulation. ...
Article
Full-text available
Researchers usually specify risk aversion coefficients from 1 (lowest) to M (highest) for a portfolio to indicate active or passive approaches. How effective is this practice? Recent studies suggest that the global minimum variance portfolio (GMVP) is statistically equivalent to portfolios with extensive risk aversion coefficients (the GMVP-equivalent). Expressing the risk aversion coefficient as a Taylor series of the target return and efficient set constants, we generalize the previous result to the non-GMVP-equivalents and segment mean-variance portfolios according to a hierarchy of risk aversion coefficients. In this paper, we show that hierarchical risk aversion coefficients are superior to isometric attributes.
... For example, Markowitz, himself, discussed how a community of investors can collectively benefit by improving efficiency through MVO and demonstrated how the single-period MVO can be effective in a multi-period investment situation (Markowitz & van Dijk, 2003). Markowitz, along with others, also presented how the theory of MVO can be developed specifically for individual investors that may focus on achieving personal investment goals through mental accounting (Das et al., 2010(Das et al., , 2011. ...
Article
Full-text available
Mean–variance optimization, introduced by Markowitz, is a foundational theory and methodology in finance and optimization, significantly influencing investment management practices. This study enhances mean–variance optimization by integrating machine learning-based anomaly detection, specifically using GANs (generative adversarial networks), to identify anomaly levels in the stock market. We demonstrate the utility of GANs in detecting market anomalies and incorporating this information into portfolio optimization using robust methods such as shrinkage estimators and the Gerber statistic. Empirical analysis confirms that portfolios optimized with anomaly scores outperform those using conventional portfolio optimization. This study highlights the potential of advanced data-driven techniques to improve risk management and portfolio performance.
... This implies the classic statement in investment, the higher the risk, the higher the return. The shape of the efficient frontier plotted here is standard and similar to those plotted in [36][37][38]. The required average return is 5%. ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper studies the portfolio selection problem where tradable assets are a bank account, and standard put and call options are written on the S&P 500 index in incomplete markets in which there exist bid–ask spreads and finite liquidity. The problem is mathematically formulated as an optimization problem where the variance of the portfolio is perceived as a risk. The task is to find the portfolio which has a satisfactory return but has the minimum variance. The underlying is modeled by a variance gamma process which can explain the extreme price movement of the asset. We also study how the optimized portfolio changes subject to a user’s views of the future asset price. Moreover, the optimization model is extended for asset pricing and hedging. To illustrate the technique, we compute indifference prices for buying and selling six options namely a European call option, a quadratic option, a sine option, a butterfly spread option, a digital option, and a log option, and propose the hedging portfolios, which are the portfolios one needs to hold to minimize risk from selling or buying such options, for all the options. The sensitivity of the price from modeling parameters is also investigated. Our hedging strategies are decent with the symmetry property of the kernel density estimation of the portfolio payout. The payouts of the hedging portfolios are very close to those of the bought or sold options. The results shown in this study are just illustrations of the techniques. The approach can also be used for other derivatives products with known payoffs in other financial markets.
Article
Recent work puts forth “net worth optimization” as an extension of asset‐only mean–variance optimization and liability‐relative optimization in which all of the components of an individual's holistic economic balance sheet are included in the optimization. This type of holistic, total portfolio optimization is constrained to include an untradable allocation to two entries in an individual economic balance sheet: the person's human capital and the person's nondiscretionary consumption liability, in which both are modeled as separate personalized combinations of asset classes (and perhaps individual stocks or bonds) based on the expected nature of their cash flow characteristics. In a series of controlled optimizations in which various parameters are varied, we study how changes in human capital modeling (riskiness) and balance sheet strength (funding status) influence the recommended asset allocation for an investor's financial capital asset allocation. Net worth optimization separates an investor's risk tolerance (attitude toward risk) from the investor's ability to take on risk (risk capacity), allowing risk tolerance to serve its original purpose.
Conference Paper
Selection of an efficient portfolio is a sophisticated process assuming decision making on proper distribution of funds based on possible expected rates of return and risk. In general, portfolio theory and relevant topics are among the most investigated issues in economic and financial articles. As a rule, decision maker uses past historical data of financial securities to make assumptions on expected returns and risk. Obviously, investors often deal with imprecise data while making decisions. To overcome such difficulties some researchers, suggest combination of the classic mean variance portfolio model with other approaches. It seems difficult to choose a proper approach to investment portfolio selection problem. The comparison of classic mean-variance model and mean-variance model with combination fuzzy approach performed in this study contributes to actuality of the paper. Modeling of sample investment portfolio is implemented by using statistical data obtained from Yahoo Finance web-platform and expert opinion. In the classic approach MS Excel is used to perform calculations and construct efficient frontier. The software based on C# programming language is developed for defining efficient portfolios and constructing fuzzy efficient frontier in combined approach. The comparison of the two methods shows the efficiency of fuzzy approach. It provides more flexibility to investors and represents an interval within return and risk of efficient portfolios might vary. Investors may choose a portfolio which best suits their return expectation and risk preferences from a given set of efficient portfolios comprising efficient frontier.
Article
Full-text available
Investing in the financial market is a way to grow wealth. This investment undoubtedly generates a return accompanied by a certain level of risk. In finance, risk occupies a crucial place in the stock market. Indeed, it intervenes in the process of choice and selection of the portfolio. Investment decisions can be tricky from time to time and require further thought. The achievement of judicious investment is based on a knowledge of the financial market evolution, the behavior of investors as well as techniques of portfolio management. Multitudes of strategies have been implemented over time to effectively manage the portfolio. Within this framework, various strategies have been implemented such as modern portfolio theory (MPT) and behavioral portfolio theory (BPT). We concentrate on portfolio optimization for two alternative approaches: the MVT and the BPT. This study aims to compare portfolios generated by these two approaches during political and COVID-19 crisis periods using data from the Tunisian stock market exchange for the period 2009 –2022. The results show that in the case of a higher degree of risk aversion induced by investors’ BPT, all the stock is located at the top right of the mean-variance frontier. However, during the crisis, the portfolios selected by rational investors were not systematically selected by irrational investors, even if the optimal portfolio of BPT coincides with the Markowitz efficiency frontier. The results indicate that the crisis induces simultaneously an increase in risk and a sharp decrease in the portfolio return of individuals who follow the mean-variance theory of Markowitz.
Article
We use a large administrative panel data set to study which characteristics are related to households’ investments in socially responsible investing (SRI) mutual funds. To isolate financial and non-financial preferences for SRI investments, we distinguish between two types of SRI funds; ESG and charitable funds. We also analyze to what extent liquid wealth and age play a role in allocation of SRI funds. We find that participation in SRI funds is lower for young and retired investors. Moreover, we find that young adults are more likely to be ESG investors, while retired investors are more likely to participate in charitable funds. Further, liquid wealth is important for SRI participation but becomes less relevant once investors have sufficient liquid wealth. For the exposure to SRI funds, the overall picture is quite different as it is negatively related to wealth, income, risky share, and education. The relationship between investors’ characteristics and the returns on their conventional fund portfolio are similar for conventional and SRI investors. Our analysis indicates that SRI investors might have non-financial objectives for their SRI investments. Finally, on average, SRI investors earn higher returns on their total fund portfolio compared to conventional investors.
Article
Full-text available
We develop a positive behavioral portfolio theory (BPT) and explore its implications for portfolio constrution and security design. The optimal portfolios of BPT investors resemble combinations of bonds and lotterly tickets consistent with Friedman and Savage's (1948) observation. We compare the BPT efficient frontier with the mean-variance efficient frontier and show that, in general, the two frontiers do not coincide. Optimal BPT portfolios are also different from optimal CAPM portfolios. In particular, the CAPM two-fund separation does not hold in BPT. We present BPT in a single mental account version (BPT-SA) and a multiple mental account version (BPT-SA). BPT-SA investors integrate their portfolios into a single mental account, while BPT-SA investors segregate their portfolios into several mental accounts. BPT-SA portfolios resemble layered pyramids, where layers are associated with aspirations. We explore a two-layer portfolio where the low aspiration layer is designed to avoid poverth while the high aspiration layer is designed for a shot at riches.
Article
Full-text available
We integrate appealing features of Markowitz s behavioral portfolio theory (BPT) into a new mental accounting (MA) framework. Features of the MA framework include an MA structure of portfolios, a definition of risk as the probability of failing to reach the threshold level in each mental account, and attitudes toward risk that vary by account. We demonstrate a mathematical equivalence between MVT, MA, and risk management using value at risk (VaR). The aggregate allocation across MA subportfolios is mean-variance efficient with short selling. Short-selling constraints on mental accounts impose very minor reductions in certainty equivalents, only if binding for the aggregate portfolio, offsetting utility losses from errors in specifying risk-aversion coefficients in MVT applications. These generalizations of MVT and BPT via a unified MA framework result in a fruitful connection between investor consumption goals and portfolio production.
Article
Analysis of decision making under risk has been dominated by expected utility theory, which generally accounts for people's actions. Presents a critique of expected utility theory as a descriptive model of decision making under risk, and argues that common forms of utility theory are not adequate, and proposes an alternative theory of choice under risk called prospect theory. In expected utility theory, utilities of outcomes are weighted by their probabilities. Considers results of responses to various hypothetical decision situations under risk and shows results that violate the tenets of expected utility theory. People overweight outcomes considered certain, relative to outcomes that are merely probable, a situation called the "certainty effect." This effect contributes to risk aversion in choices involving sure gains, and to risk seeking in choices involving sure losses. In choices where gains are replaced by losses, the pattern is called the "reflection effect." People discard components shared by all prospects under consideration, a tendency called the "isolation effect." Also shows that in choice situations, preferences may be altered by different representations of probabilities. Develops an alternative theory of individual decision making under risk, called prospect theory, developed for simple prospects with monetary outcomes and stated probabilities, in which value is given to gains and losses (i.e., changes in wealth or welfare) rather than to final assets, and probabilities are replaced by decision weights. The theory has two phases. The editing phase organizes and reformulates the options to simplify later evaluation and choice. The edited prospects are evaluated and the highest value prospect chosen. Discusses and models this theory, and offers directions for extending prospect theory are offered. (TNM)
Investor Temperament
  • M Statman
  • V Wood
Statman, M., and V. Wood. "Investor Temperament." Journal of Investment Consulting, Summer (2004), pp. 1-12.
Asset Allocation Planner Questionnaire
  • Fidelity Investments
Fidelity Investments, " Asset Allocation Planner Questionnaire. " 2003, Available at: www.fidelity.com.