ArticlePDF Available

Abstract

Hyman Minsky pioneered the idea of the financial instability hypothesis to explain how swings between robustness and fragility in financial markets generate business cycles in the economic system. Yet few economists have recognized that this elemental idea originates not only from the financial theory of investment and investment theory of business cycles put forward by John Maynard Keynes, but also in the credit view of money and finance advocated by Joseph Schumpeter. Nevertheless, Minsky described Schumpeter’s business cycle theory as ‘banal’ because it relied on the real economy as Walras represents. The reason was that money was endogenous in Schumpeter’s earlier view, as it emerged out of the credit system, which allowed for a discussion of the relationship between production and finance. This essay will focus on how Minsky related some ideas from Schumpeter’s Theory of Economic Development with those in Keynes’ General Theory Money and finance provide a link between Keynes’ view of the investment decision as a determinant of output and employment with Schumpeter’s view of the investment decision as a determinant of innovation and economic growth.
See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/265334143
Schumpeter, Minsky and the financial instability hypothesis
Conference PaperinJournal of Evolutionary Economics · June 2014
CITATIONS
5
READS
274
1 author:
Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:
R&D internationalization, innovation and after peak-FDI development View project
BERD-Flows “Internationalisation of business expenditures on R&D and analysis of their economic impact (BERD Flows)” View project
Mark Knell
Nordic Institute for Studies in Innovation, Research and Education
58 PUBLICATIONS1,101 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
All content following this page was uploaded by Mark Knell on 04 September 2014.
The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.
!
1
Schumpeter, Minsky and the financial instability hypothesis1
Author: Mark Knell
Draft 25 Apr. 2014
Abstract:
Hyman Minsky pioneered the idea of the financial instability hypothesis to explain how
swings between robustness and fragility in financial markets generate business cycles in the
economic system. Yet few economists have recognized that this elemental idea originates
not only from the financial theory of investment and investment theory of business cycles put
forward by John Maynard Keynes, but also in the credit view of money and finance
advocated by Joseph Schumpeter. Nevertheless, Minsky described Schumpeter’s business
cycle theory as banalbecause it relied on the real economy as Walras represents. The
reason was that money was endogenous in Schumpeter’s earlier view, as it emerged out of
the credit system, which allowed for a discussion of the relationship between production and
finance. This essay will focus on how Minsky related some ideas from Schumpeter’s Theory
of Economic Development with those in Keynes’ General Theory. Money and finance provide
a link between Keynes’ view of the investment decision as a determinant of output and
employment with Schumpeter’s view of the investment decision as a determinant of
innovation and economic growth.
Key Words: economic evolution, financial instability, business cycles, technological
revolutions, innovation, effective demand, Joseph Schumpeter, John Maynard Keynes,
Hyman Minsky.
Mark Knell, NIFU Nordic Institute for Studies in Innovation, Research and Education NIFU,
Wergelandsveien 7, 0167 Oslo, Norway. Email: mark.knell@nifu.no.
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!
1 The author wishes to thank those participating in Kurt’s monthly Kreis-Diskussion in Vienna,
especially Kurt Dopfer, Michael Peneder and Jerry Silverberg. The usual caveats apply.
!
2
Schumpeter, Minsky and the financial instability hypothesis
Mark Knell
1. Introduction
The financial instability hypothesis, pioneered by Hyman Minsky, explains how swings
between robustness and fragility in financial markets generate business cycles in the
economic system. Yet few economists have recognized that the basic idea originates not
only from the financial theory of investment put forward by John Maynard Keynes, but also
from the credit view of money and finance advocated by Joseph Schumpeter. In an essay
written to celebrate the centenary of both Keynes and Schumpeter, Minsky (1986b: 121)
affirmed his desire to integrate Schumpeter’s vision of a resilient intertemporal capitalist
process with Keynes’ hard insights into the fragility introduced into the capitalist accumulation
process by some inescapable properties of capitalist financial structures.” Minsky (1993a:
106) further maintained that, “To understand the short-term dynamics of the business cycle
and the longer-term evolution of economies it is necessary to understand then financing
relations that rule, and how the profit-seeking activities of businessmen, bankers, and
portfolio managers lead to the evolution of financial structures.” For this reason, the financial
instability hypothesis is just as much about evolutionary economics as it is about effective
demand in a monetary economy and the institutional arrangements underlying the financial
system. This paper relates some ideas from Schumpeter’s Theory of Economic Development
with those in Keynes’ General Theory through the eyes of Hyman Minsky.
Born in Chicago on 23 September 1919, Hyman Philip Minsky studied mathematics at
the University of Chicago from 1937 to 1941. After graduation, he began the study
economics at the graduate level at the same university. This interest came mainly from his
social and political views on social democracy. Oscar Lange and Henry Simons had an
important influence in the direction of his studies at this time and one year later Lange
recommended that he join a post-war planning research project under the direction of
Wassily Leontief at Harvard University. Minsky would have likely met Schumpeter at this
time. After serving in the U.S. Army for almost three years plus a few additional months as a
civilian employee in the U.S. Military government for Germany, he decided to return to
Harvard University in 1946 to resume his graduate studies, where he completed a Master of
Public Administration (MPA) in 1947 and Doctorate in 1954.
!
3
Minsky began his doctoral dissertation research under Schumpeter, but finished it in
1954 under the supervision of Leontief after Schumpeter’s untimely death in January 1950.
The reason that Minsky (1992: 354) gave for studying under Schumpeter is that his “vision of
the capitalist process required an integration of financial markets and investment behaviour”
that was similar to the approach taught at Chicago. His thesis, published in 2004 as Induced
Investment and Business Cycles, explored how market structure, financial institutions, the
determinants of effective demand, and business cycle performance related to each other.
After three relatively short appointments, Minsky was appointed Professor of Economics at
Washington University in St Louis in 1965, where he remained until his retirement in 1990.
He was a Senior Scholar at the Levy Economics Institute of Bard College at he time of his
death on 24 October 1996.
The following section summarizes the financial instability hypothesis, which stands at
the centre of Minsky’s many contributions to economics and provides a crucial link between
Schumpeter and Keynes. Minsky learned about the role of banks in financing investment
from Schumpeter, but he followed an approach similar to that of Keynes. Section three
considers some important similarities and differences between the theoretical analyses put
forward by Schumpeter that have direct relevance to the ideas advanced by Minsky. It also
contains a short discussion of the Walrasian foundation of Schumpeter’s thought, and how
he extended this theory to include changing technology and the role of money and finance in
this process. The fourth section contrasts Schumpeter’s theory of innovation with Keynes’
theory of effective demand and employment, with a focus on the role that the investment
decision plays in each theory. Section five considers the important role that Keynes’ theory of
effective demand and the investment decision plays in the financial instability hypothesis.
The sixth section explores some issues related to Schumpeter’s business cycle theory and
financial fragility and financial regulation, including the suggestion by Perez (2002) that this
nexus is also important for long-term “Kondratiev” waves or what were later described as
technological revolutions and techno-economic paradigms. Section seven explores some
fundamental differences between Minsky and Schumpeter on the instability of capitalism. A
final section will provide some concluding comments on the intellectual relationship between
Minsky, Keynes and Schumpeter and what this means for evolutionary theory.
2. The financial instability hypothesis
Hyman Minsky made many important contributions to financial theory, but he was best
known for the financial instability hypothesis. The financial instability hypothesis is derived
from his own interpretation of the General Theory, especially as they relate to Keynes’s ideas
on investment and portfolio decisions and liquidity preference, and the credit view of money
and finance of Schumpeter. He described a situation where an increase in speculative
!
4
investments would lead to over-indebtedness and financial fragility over the course of the
business cycle, which might ultimately lead to an economic environment that is conducive to
high inflations, debt deflations, a collapse of asset values and deep depressions. Minsky
(1992c) had a theory of resource allocation that did not rely on exogenous shocks to
generate cyclical behaviour, and he described the accumulating capitalist economy with
expensive capital assets and a complex sophisticated financial systemthat evolves in real
calendar time.
Instability underlies the appearance of stability of the financial markets. During periods
of stability, when stock prices are rising higher than the interest rate, investors are lured into
taking more risk, which leads them to borrow more and to overpay for assets. Minsky (1980:
215) identified three types of financial postures that contribute to the accumulation of
insolvent debt: (1) hedge finance, in which borrowers can meet all debt payments (interest
and principle) from their cash flows from investment; (2) speculative finance, in which
borrowers can meet their interest payments from investment, but must roll over their debt
over to pay back the original loan; and (3) ponzi finance, when borrowers can neither repay
the interest nor the original debt from the original investment, and rely entirely on rising asset
prices to allow them continually to refinance their debt.
The mix of financial postures determines the overall robustness or fragility of an
economy’s financial structure, ranging from hedge finance providing more robustness and
ponzi finance providing more fragility. The longer the period of economic stability lasts; ponzi
finance tends to become increasingly more prevalent, often resulting in the collapse of some
financial institutions. If the use of ponzi finance is general enough in the financial system, as
might have been the case in the 2008 subprime mortgage crisis, then the collapse of ponzi
finance can also bring down even hedge borrowers, who are unable to find loans despite the
apparent soundness of the underlying investments. Financial institutions often devise ways
of getting around regulations and norms to be able to take on greater risk during periods of
stable growth. These observations lead Minsky (2002) to define two theorems of the financial
stability hypothesis: (1) “the economy has financing regimes under which it is stable, and
financing regimes in which it is unstable”, and (2) “over periods of prolonged prosperity, the
economy transits from financial relations that make for a stable system to financial relations
that make for an unstable system.”
Periodic shifts stability and instability generate endogenous business cycles. Minsky
(1992) maintained that “is that the financial system swings between robustness and fragility
and these swings are an integral part of the process that generates business cycles.” These
business cycles are endogenous to the economic system, and generated, as Minsky (1993b)
pointed out, through “the internal dynamics of capitalist economies, and the system of
!
5
interventions and regulations that are designed to keep the economy operating within
reasonable bounds.” The weight of speculative and Ponzi finance will have a certain barring
on the extent of the recession. Both Schumpeter and Keynes were concerned with business
cycles, but had very different views on how they were generated. Minsky understood these
different visions as two aspects of the same phenomena.
3. Schumpeter and Minsky
Although Minsky was a graduate student of Schumpeter at Harvard University, he later
became known as a devoted proponent of Keynes. At the beginning of the 20th century,
Schumpeter was a student of Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk and Friedrich von Wieser at the
University of Vienna when the “pure logic of choice” and the “temporal nature of production”
where the main issues at the time.2 Schumpeter (1954) considered Wieser (1889) to have
had the most important influence on this thought, mainly because the prominence he placed
on the entrepreneur as an agent of change. Many of his ideas that can be traced to Marx, the
German Historical School and the theory of monopolistic competition, but Schumpeter (1954:
795) believed that the theory of value and distribution provided by Leon Walras was ‘the best
theoretical work of our time’.
Schumpeter’s admiration for Walras appears in his early writings where he claimed that
classical theory lacked a ‘solid theory of price’ and that Walras had provided this theory. This
admiration continued through to his History of Economic Analysis, where he praised him for
being the ‘greatest of all economists’ (Knell, 2012). Schumpeter (1912) began The Theory of
Economic Development by describing the data or independent variables from which Walras
(1873) started with: (1) the initial endowments; (2) the preferences of consumers; and (3) the
technical alternatives from which cost-minimizing producers can choose. He then described
how equilibrium prices of all factors of production and their distribution across different
industries are determined simultaneously and symmetrically when marginal revenue equals
marginal costs when there is free competition. Profits are maximized in equilibrium, since
there would be no economic profits remaining in the economic system. Schumpeter (1912:
62) believed that equilibrium prices, including uniform rates of remuneration for each
particular kind of input (including labour and other material inputs) in the production process,
results from the actions of competitive profit-seeking producers concerned with minimizing
production costs. This process of search and selection by profit-seeking producers explains
how capital and labour moves between enterprises in the absence of significant barriers to
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!
2 Böhm-Bawerk (1884, 1889) introduced the idea intertemporal equilibrium, in which production
became a process whereby capital goods are produced and then used to produce the desired
consumer goods.
!
6
entry and exit. Spontaneous changes to the technical alternatives available to the enterprise
(production function) were the result of the innovation process.
To explain economic development and the business cycle, Schumpeter (1912, 1928,
1939) essentially outlined the “pure theory of production” from a Walrasian point of view, but
assumes that the technical alternatives available to the enterprise change, while the initial
endowments and the preferences of consumers remain constant. He also assigns the
Walrasian entrepreneur with a new function, one that is to carry out ‘new combinations’ of
resources available to the enterprise, or what is more aptly called innovation. Schumpeter
does not consider the entrepreneur as an individual person, but as an agent or instrument of
change assigned with the function of carrying out new combinations of resources available to
the enterprise. These agents of change can earn “entrepreneurial” profits above the normal
rate of return for bringing novelty to the market. Schumpeter considered innovation to be part
of the economic process itself with the actions of cost-minimizing capitalists generating a
tendency toward equilibrium through the search for ‘global’ investment opportunities, and the
actions of profit-seeking entrepreneurs engendering disequilibrium behaviour through the
introduction of new products, markets, methods of products, and new organizational forms.
Schumpeter (1939: 82) considers innovation as an endogenous process “because it is
not implied in, nor a mere consequence of, any other” process. Innovation made it possible
for economic agents to obtain a surplus over costs, or entrepreneurial profit. Schumpeter,
1934: 64) claimed the resulting disequilibrium behaviour “forever alters and displaces the
equilibrium state previously existing.Enterprises compete with one another to gain market
share and improve their ability to increase profit through the use of new technology.
Schumpeter (1934: 59) views on economic dynamics “nearly parallels that of Marx” and his
idea that competition for capital across industries created a tendency toward equilibrium,
whereas competition for capital within an industry created a tendency toward disequilibrium.
One important difference, however, is that he adopts the Walrasian theory of capital
formation under free competition to explain the tendency toward equilibrium, and then
introduces the entrepreneur as innovator to explain the tendency toward disequilibrium.
Minsky was very critical of Schumpeter’s adherence to Walrasian theory in several
papers written around the time of his retirement. In the first paper, written for the Keynes and
Schumpeter centenary, Minsky (1986b: 112) claimed that “the crisis of capitalism evoked a
magnificent theoretical performance from Keynes; [whereas] Schumpeter’s response was
banal.” He was referring to Schumpeter’s Business Cycles, which included a mechanical
threecycle explanation of economic development in which investment behaviour depended
the innovative reactions of entrepreneurs or secondary waves. Minsky (1986b: 121) also
believed that when writing this book “Schumpeter got enmeshed in a Walrasian trap that
!
7
assumed only real things mattered, whereas in his original version [Economic Development]
money mattered”. Still, Schumpeter remained Walrasian throughout his life, including in his
early writings on economic development, but Minsky was concerned with Schumpeter’s
theory of finance, money, and credit. He believed that Economic Development was more
compatible with Keynesmonetary theory than Business Cycles because it considered the
innovation in the context of the monetary production economy.
The point raised by Minsky is important because it relies on chapters in Economic
Development that were often overlooked by other economists.3 Schumpeter considered
money, credit and finance as essential to the innovation process. He began the first edition of
Economic Development, by describing the circulation of money and real goods and services
in terms of a ‘Kreislauf’ or monetary circuit, but alludes to the importance of credit money at
the end of the first chapter. Walrasian equilibrium implies that money is neutral in a simple
monetary circuit without capital, but Walras (1874) also considered money to be analogous
to capital, where its value is determined by the demand for various services of capital (rents,
wages, and interest), or what he termed encaisse désirée. Money produces utility by acting
as an intertemporal reallocation mechanism; an idea that Marget (1931) considered to be
similar to the Cambridge cash-balance approach and Keynes's theory of liquidity preference.
While this theory appears to contradict Walrasian equilibrium, Walras did not expound on the
theory money until after sketched his theory of capital and credit, which Currie and Steedman
(1990) suggest was part of his goal of providing an analysis of a progressive economy.
Schumpeter may have understood Walras’ vision better than Minsky believed, as credit
money was not introduced into the analysis until after the chapter on innovation and
economic dynamics. There was more to Walras than general equilibrium.
Like Walras, Schumpeter (1912) considered money to be analogous to capital, as bank
deposits allow them to give credit to producers for their purchases of circulating capital
goods. Still, Schumpeter (1912: 107) took this idea one step further claiming “credit is
essentially the creation of purchasing power for the purpose of transferring it to the
entrepreneur.” The availability of credit creates allows entrepreneurs to gain access to
investment goods necessary for innovation “before they have acquired the normal claim to
it.Schumpeter (1912) reasoned that money was credit-driven and determined endogenously
by the demand for bank loans by entrepreneurs engaged in innovative activities.4
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!
3 Schumpeter began writing on a book on money in the late 1920s originally entitled Geld und
Wahrung (Money and Currency). The main goal was to develop a new theory of money based on the
credit view of money in the Theory of Economic Development. According to Swedberg (1991), he
attempted to rewrite parts of the book in the ladder years of his life, but never completed it. It is
doubtful that Minsky had seen the manuscript.
4 Bank credit was the driving force of cyclical growth in Schumpeter (1912). His argument followed the
standard loanable-funds approach insofar as he derived the existence of interest rates from temporary
different monopoly rents on innovations, a disequilibrium phenomenon.
!
8
Entrepreneurs not only had an insatiable desire to gain profit through innovation, but the
could finance new innovations through endogenous money creation (Binswanger, 1996).
Minsky (1957a) had a similar view of money, with “profit-seeking activities” driving
evolutionary changes in financial institutions”, which then leads to the endogenous creation
of money.5 The paper claimed that it was almost impossible to control monetary aggregates
because financial innovations, or new financial instruments, could create problems for the
measurement of these aggregates. Later, Minsky (1986b: 120) recapped the origin of this
idea:
The Schumpeterian vision of the experimenting entrepreneur who innovates need but
be extended to financial firms and their clients to explain why portfolios migrate to a
brink at which a shortfall of cash flows or a rise in financing terms may lead to a market
revision of asset values and therefore of investment programmes.
Here Minsky linked Schumpeter’s idea of the innovating entrepreneur with that of financial
innovations produced by financial institutions. In this context, financial innovations became
the source of financial fragility and hence financial crisis and instability. This is in sharp
contrast to Schumpeter who suggested that innovation was the main source of stability. As
Minsky (1990: 52) put it, “new combinations, which result from the outcomes of negotiations
among entrepreneurial business men and financiers, lead to process and product
innovations as well as new financing relations and new financial institutions.” Minsky (1993a)
concluded, “Nowhere is evolution, change and Schumpeterian entrepreneurship more
evident than in banking and finance and nowhere is the drive for profits more clearly a factor
in making for change.”
Financial institutions were essential to both Schumpeter and Minsky. The institutional
arrangements of the advanced market economy provide the setting within which
entrepreneurs use credit to finance innovation and hence claim resources needed to create
‘new combinations’. Although the main function of the central bank was to provide stability,
its regulatory requirements and the incessant creation of new financial instruments created
change (Minsky, 1986). Minsky and Whalen (1996) observed that the financial structure of
the American economy had experienced considerable change over the last hundred years.
The Glass-Steagall Act (1933) contained institutional innovations that avoided a complete
breakdown of the financial system and massive debt deflation by providing a strict separation
between commercial and investment banking. Federal banking regulators allowed
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!
5 Lavoie (1997) maintains that Minsky’s (1957b) idea that an endogenous rise in interest rates is linked
to a lack-of-saving approach. During the expansion, euphoria takes over and the acceptable degree of
leverage increases, so much that banks encourage under-levered firms to go into debt and conform to
the emerging more relaxed standards (Minsky 1980: 517).
!
9
commercial banks to engage in some securities activities in the 1960s, but it was not until the
Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act (1999) eliminated legal barriers between commercial banks,
investment banks, securities firms, and insurance companies (Carpenter and Murphy, 2010).
Debt was increasingly used in the 1970s to acquire existing assets rather than as internal
finance, and firms relied more heavily on banking system short-term finance. Hedge funds,
unconventional mortgages, and securitization of contractual debt were new financial
innovations that led to the current economic crisis (Whalen, 2009).
4. A short digression on Schumpeter and Keynes
In his review of the General Theory, Schumpeter (1936) criticized Keynes for not taking into
account the financing of changes in the production function’, or innovation, in the formation
of expectations under uncertainty, and relates to the marginal propensity to consume,
marginal efficiency of capital, and liquidity preference. Schumpeter (1946) later
acknowledged that Keynes confined his analysis to short-run phenomena, but he continued
to maintain that because of this, Keynes excluded ‘phenomena that dominate the capitalist
processes.’ Keynes excluded these phenomena because he believed that the capital stock
did not reflect the investment patterns in the short run, which meant that uncertainty,
expectations and financial frugality became the central issues and not innovation.
Keynes was fully aware that technology was essential for economic growth. In
Economic Possibilities for our Grandchildren, Keynes (1931: 19-20) pointed out that “the
accumulation of capital which began in the sixteenth century”, and that “the growth of capital
has been on a scale which is far beyond a hundredfold of what any previous age had
known.” Keynes (1930: 85-86) also wrote in the second volume of A Treatise on Money that
Schumpeter’s theory of innovation is the most important explanation for why the rate of
investment fluctuates over time.
Entrepreneurs are induced to embark on the production of fixed capital or deterred
from doing so by their expectations of the profit to be made. Apart from the many minor
reasons why these should fluctuate in a changing world, Professor Schumpeter’s
explanation of the major movements may be unreservedly accepted.
A Treatise on Money contains many of the ideas developed in the General Theory, but
presented from a more dynamic, long-period perspective. Keynes demonstrated in the
Treatise how an initial investment decision normally gives rise to a set of expectations that
may trigger further changes in investment over several periods. Seccareccia (2004) points
out that expectations were endogenous to the wavelike pattern of behaviour inherent to the
logic of the credit cycle in the Treatise, however, the book failed to provide a theory of the
!
10
determination of output and employment as a whole. The General Theory provided the
theory, but this book was basically concerned with Marshallian short-period static analysis,
with expectations based on the idea of the marginal efficiency of capital.6 The independent
role of demand in determining growth and cycles was the central message in this book, not
long-term expectations and innovation. This message encouraged the development of
consumption function models and the IS-LM framework (Minsky, 1975).
Keynes developed his theory of employment and output from the Marshallian short-run
and long-run perspectives, which was very different from Schumpeter’s Walrasian vision
contained in his dynamic analysis of the innovative entrepreneur. Yet, Keynes originally
described the principle of effective demand as an “entrepreneurial economy” in early drafts of
the General Theory, but he later reserved the term entrepreneur to symbolize investment
and production decisions. His idea of “animal spirits” or the “spontaneous urge to action
rather than inaction” gives the appearance that Keynes’ entrepreneur is similar to
Schumpeter’s, as the entrepreneur is internalized into firm’s behaviour much like
Schumpeter’s profit seeking entrepreneur. The main function of the Keynesian entrepreneur
is the decision to invest, irrespective of the drive to innovate.
Schumpeter and Keynes both considered money and financial aggregates not to be
neutral (non-neutrality principle), highlighting the fundamental role of the credit market and of
the banks. Minsky (1993) emphasized that both economists considered the institutional
arrangements of the financial system as essential for the capitalist economy. Banks had the
important function of financing innovation in Schumpeter’s theory as innovating
entrepreneurs need capital to start new production processes and to develop new products,
which results in an expansion in credit and economic growth. Schumpeter’s credit theory of
money is similar to Keynes’s theory of ‘bank money’ described in the Treatise, but his
criticism of money neutrality hinges on money being a means of payment and the desire to
obtain cash (l’encaisse désirée), rather than as a store of value (Messori, 2004). Coming
from the Marshallian perspective, Keynes (1937) emphasized that money was an asset, and
that the demand for liquidity (liquidity preference) depended on the transactions,
precautionary, and speculative motives for holding money. Fundamental uncertainty became
central to the argument, as it did for Minsky.
5. Minsky and Keynes
In his thesis, Minsky (1954) considers business cycle theory and rejects Schumpeter’s (1939)
view that the business cycle is either a purely statistical phenomenon or caused by industrial
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!
6 Expectations also appear arbitrary in the Treatise on Money.
!
11
innovation and embraces Keynes’s view that business cycles connect investment decisions
together finance and the possibility of coordination failures (Toporowski, 2008). Shortly
thereafter Minsky (1957b) provided a rudimentary exposition of the financial instability
hypothesis, where interest rates rise because of the over-indebted of enterprises, which need
to borrow credit-money to finance their investments. Minsky (1978, 1992a) developed his
Keynesian view further by integrating asset values with liquidity preference, investment
decisions with profits and the relation between asset values and current prices, and debt
valuations to profits, which may lead to financial crisis.
Minsky (1975) defended his views on money and finance against the neoclassical
synthesis in his biography of Keynes, which interprets the General Theory as a mechanical
equilibrium model as similar to the theory of Marshall (1890) where money has little
relevance. One ironic twist to the story is that Minsky (1992c) chose not study with Alvin
Hanson while at Harvard because his reading of Keynes was “strangely mechanical” and that
he completely neglected the significance of money, finance and uncertainty in the dynamics
of the capitalist economy. Much his research was aimed at extending the principle of
effective demand to include more complex financial relations, markets, and institutions
(Papadimitriou and Wray, 1998). From this point of view Minsky could be described as post-
Keynesian, but he preferred to be regarded as a financial-Keynesianto single out his debt
to Keynes, as well as to recognize the importance of the institutional arrangements
underlying the monetary economy. Paradoxically, Minsky did not consider Keynes’ (1936)
theory of effective demand as a ‘general theory’, much in the same way that Schumpeter
(1936; 1946) claimed in his writings on Keynes.
Minsky (1975) was highly critical of the consumption function models and the IS-LM
framework in his biography of Keynes and reasserted the centrality of the decision to invest
when there is pervasive uncertainty. Keynes first developed the idea of uncertainty and
decision-making under uncertainty in A Treatise on Probability, but it became central to The
General Theory and also to Minsky’s (1975) financial instability hypothesis. Probability
cannot, in general, be measured when uncertainty is present (Dow, 1995). But Keynes
(1936) suggested that not all decisions were subject to fundamental uncertainty, with
unknown or un-measurable probabilities, but rather consisted of varying degrees of
uncertainty, some with limited knowledge of probabilities. The importance of uncertainty,
Minsky (1975: 64) maintains, is that it “intervenes and attenuates the significance of the
production functions and stable preference functions of conventional theory as determinants
of system behaviour” through “the portfolio decisions of households, firms, and financial
institutions, and in views held by firms, by the owners of capital assets, and by the bankers to
firms as to the prospective yields of capital assets.” Uncertainty propels financial instability.
!
12
The decision to invest becomes the link between finance and the real economy in
Keynes and it becomes the crucial link between Keynes and Schumpeter in Minsky’s vision
of the capitalist economy. In developed vision, Minsky extends Keynes’ determination of the
decision to invest, which was essential to the principle of effective demand. In Keynes the
volume of investment, determines output and employment, which can be volatile, and
through the multiplier this will cause fluctuations throughout the economy. Minsky (1978,
1986) argued that the financial markets can exacerbate these cycles, making instability
endemic since financial fragility tends to grow during boom periods. The basic conclusion of
Minsky was that markets are too unstable to function properly, an idea shared with both
Keynes and Schumpeter.
Long-term expectation of future profitability determines the amount of investment in
new plant and equipment. These expectations can give rise to speculative behaviours related
to the psychology of the market, but are usually dominated by the enterprise’s desire to know
the prospective yield of assets over their whole life. Minsky (1975) claimed that the decision
to invest in equity markets would inevitably lead to speculative behaviours. In chapter 12,
where the valuation of the stock of capital assets is considered, Keynes (1936: 159) argued:
Speculators may do no harm as bubbles on a steady stream of enterprise. But the
position is serious when enterprise becomes the bubble on a whirlpool of speculation.
When the capital development of a country becomes a by-product of the activities of a
casino, the job is likely to be ill-done.
The price of capital assets relative to the price of current output is essential to Minsky’s
financial instability hypothesis. During the upward swings of the business cycle, the
speculative demand form money decreases, as firms shift their portfolios toward a more
debt-financed position. As firms become more indebted, they become more reliant on ponzi
finance, which appear much like the activities of a casino.
Market instability could also come from animal spiritsin addition to speculative
activities. Keynes used the term “animal spirits” to describe the emotions or “spontaneous
optimism” that motivates human behaviour. It is behaviour that is generally perceived as non-
economic and is often associated with ambiguity and uncertainty (Akerlof and Shiller, 2009).
Such optimism “contains the potential for runaway expansion, powered by an investment
boom as Minsky (1975: 11) put it. But it can also “trigger serious financial difficulties” as
consumers spend more and save less and firms rely more on speculative behavior to finance
their debts. This is the main point of the financial instability hypothesis.
!
13
6. Financial instability, business cycles and technological revolutions
Financial fragility makes the most sense when it is placed in the context of macroeconomic
dynamics and the business cycle. Minsky’s business cycle theory is essentially a Keynesian
demand-driven theory that links the price level of current output with the price level of
financial and real assets. Fluctuations are associated with volatility in the decision to invest,
which not only affects aggregate demand and employment as Keynes (1936) suggests, but
also the introduction of new products, processes and new management methods as
Schumpeter (1911) suggests. Schumpeter (1939) describes these fluctuations in more detail
in his Business Cycles, introducing three synchronized cycles, a short-term “Kitchin”
inventory cycle of about 40 months duration that are also related to information asymmetries,
a medium-term investment or “Juglar” cycle involving both the monetary or financial markets,
and a long-term “Kondratiev” cycle capturing the rise and decline of the use of major
technological innovations. Still, Schumpeter (1939: 177) considered the three-cycle schema
as a “convenient descriptive device,with its main purpose to explain cyclical behaviour over
time. By contrast, Minsky (1954) claimed that ‘induced’ expenditures, driven mainly by the
consumption function (behavioural) and the decision to invest (expectations), were essential
to the explanation of short and medium term fluctuations. In other words, Keynes’ principle of
effective demand was necessary for a theory of the business cycle based on Schumpeter.
Schumpeter (1954: 1089) considered Juglar to be “among the greatest economists of
all times.” Nevertheless, Juglar’s (1862) analysis of business cycles based on easy credit
and speculative behaviour was different from Schumpeter’s so-called Juglar cycle, which was
driven mainly by investment and technological innovation (Legrand and Hagemann, 2007).
Schumpeter shares with Juglar the idea that the demand for capital and credit would
generate cyclical fluctuations, but Juglar understood them to be a consequence of excessive
speculative behaviour rather than innovative behaviour. It is somewhat surprising that Minsky
writes little about Juglar cycles except for a joint paper with Gatti et al. (1996). This paper
integrates the intertemporal behaviour of consumers and producers with a multiplier-
accelerator model that also includes the institutional arrangements supporting the financial
system. In the model, profit-seeking agents, together with the fragility of the financial system,
develop innovative ways to finance investment, with the consequence of generating easy
credit and speculative behaviour. Gatti et al. (1996) adds complexity to Schumpeter’s cycle
theory, but also returns to some of the issues initially raised by Juglar.
Minsky’s ideas about financial instability and financial regulation also have important
implications for the long-term “Kondratiev” cycle. Carlotta Perez (2002) describes how certain
relationships within the technologically driven long-waves can bring about financial instability
and result in new financial regulations. In Business Cycles, Schumpeter (1939) described
!
14
how the bunching of major or radical innovations initiate a fundamental change in the way
things are produced, the types of products being produced, how a firm is organized, and the
way people transport things and communicate. Similar to Schumpeter, Freeman and Perez
(1988), Freeman and Louçã (2001) and Perez (2002) describe five such cycles that have
appeared since the 1770s, each occurring in intervals of roughly 50 to 70 years. These
authors consider each cycle or long wave to represent not only a technological revolution but
also a change in the techno-economic paradigm, much like a paradigm shift as described by
Kuhn (1962). Perez (2002: 8) defines each cycle or technological revolution as “a powerful
and highly visible cluster of new and dynamic technologies, products and industries, capable
of bringing about an upheaval in the whole fabric of the economy.” In Schumpeter’s (1912)
theory, bank credit is a necessary requirement for the introduction of the new radical
innovations and subsequent developments within each technological revolution. This could
have the consequence of the financial system having regular intervals of financial
deregulation, followed by instability, and then by a response of reregulation as Perez
suggests.
Financial capital is essential to the first two phases of the technological revolution.
Every long wave contains at least one core product, or “general purpose technology”, as
Lipsey, et al. (2005) put it, that forms a major cluster of interdependent technologies and
interrelated radical breakthroughs in each long wave, all of which require finance. Finance is
an enabling agent for Schumpeter, cutting a path of creative destruction as the new
technologies displace old and mature ones, fostering the movement of finance capital from
less profitable enterprises and industries to more profitable ones (Kregel, 2009). Perez
(2002) identified four distinct phases in each techno-economic paradigm: (1) irruption, when
the new technology is introduced; (2) frenzy, or the period of intense exploration; (3) synergy,
when the technology is diffused throughout the economy; and (4) maturity, as the diffusion
process becomes complete. Both stagnation and dynamic growth appear in the irruption
stage, as old technologies mature and new technologies have not diffused through the
economy. During the frenzy stage, many new opportunities to apply the new technology
open up, leading to the creation of new markets and the revival of old industries. Financial
fragility becomes particularly acute problem during this phase of the cycle. Dynamic
expansion, economies of scale, and diffusion are most common during the synergy phase,
when producers tend to dominate and economic growth is balanced. In the last phase
complacency appears as the technology reaches maturity and diffuses through the economy.
Schumpeter maintained that Juglar and Kitchin cycles could engender financial crisis
and economic recessions at regular intervals during a long-term “Kondratiev” cycle,
suggesting that the periodic crisis could be much worse at the low end of the long wave.
Perez (2002) maintains that finance capital is the main enabling agent during the first two
!
15
phases of the techno-economic paradigm, by overpowering old ideas and creating new ones,
but as the new paradigm moves in the frenzy stage, new speculative financial instruments
are created to make money from money. This is when financial fragility becomes an
especially important issue. Asset values expand far beyond the real values of new
enterprises, encouraging speculation and ponzi finance, culminating in a bubble or casino
economy, much like Keynes and Minsky envisaged. Periodic financial crises occur often, but
ultimately the frenzy period will end in financial collapse and to government re-regulation of
the banking and financial system, and investors engage in less risky behaviour. Still,
investors will not give up this speculative behaviour easily and will resist re-regulation as long
as there is money to be made in the financial markets. After the collapse, production capital
will become as the paradigm enters the deployment period.7
Perez (2009: 780) suggested that financial bubbles and crashes caused by the way
debt markets work were different from those caused by the way that the market economy
absorbs successive technological revolutions. She contended that they are the result of
opportunity pull rather than of easy credit push”. Minsky, however, considered speculative
investment bubbles as endogenous to the financial markets, which in turn depend on the
institutional arrangements supporting these markets. In an earlier paper, Minsky (1964: 324)
maintained that systematic changes in the financial structure occur during the expansion
phase of the long swing and cited the period of 1922 to 1929 as an example (see also
Galbraith, 1955). And while he did not acknowledge each successive long-wave as an
endogenous, systemic event, he did recognize that financial crisis and financial fragility were
cyclical phenomenon that resembled Schumpter’s Juglar cycle, but also followed the long-
term “Kondratiev” cycle through the evolution of the financial structure. Minsky (1975: 11)
emphasized,
Even if policy succeeds in eliminating the waste of great depressions, the fundamental
financial attributes of capitalism mean that periodic difficulties in constraining and then
sustaining demand will ensue.
7. Schumpeter and Minsky on the instability of capitalism
Both Schumpeter and Minsky considered the capitalist system to be inherently unstable, with
the prospect of its eventual collapse if something is not done about it. Yet, Schumpeter’s
(1928, 1934) vision was very different from that of Minsky, as he believed that different forms
of innovation, such as the introduction of a new product, new method of production, or new
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!
7 The difference between finance capital and production capital resembles the difference between the
entrepreneur and financier as two independent agents that drive the innovation process. Both co-exist,
but dominate over each other during different periods of the long wave.
!
16
form of organization, would reduce this instability. Schumpeter (1942: 83) conceives the term
‘creative destruction’ to captured the way industries mutate by “incessantly revolutioniz[ing]
the economic structure from within, incessantly destroying the old one, incessantly creating a
new one.” Innovation may appear destabilizing as it generates disequilibria and intensifies
economic fluctuations, but it also fulfils a kind of "cleansing" operation of the productive
structure, making it possible for everyone to enjoy higher real incomes. Instability is thus
unavoidable and an essential aspect of capitalism. Schumpeter, (1928: 383-384) stressed,
The instabilities, which arise from the process of innovation, tend to right themselves,
and do not go on accumulating. And we may phrase the result we reach in our
terminology by saying that there is, though instability of the System, no economic
instability of the Order.
Schumpeter did not write much about financial instability, but as Leathers and Raines
(2004) point out, in Business Cycles he cited historical examples of ‘reckless finance’ and
speculative excesses, and made the point that a poker game may be preferable to playing in
the equity markets. He also praised legislation aimed at reducing these excesses. Moreover,
he also made some references to innovation in the banking and finance industries, but he did
not see them as the direct cause of instability and financial crisis. Schumpeter explained
instability as the normal consequence of ‘real’ entrepreneurial activity and the accumulation
of capital, without any reference to liquidity preference or effective demand.
By contrast, Minsky followed Keynes and focused on the financial markets as they had
an innate tendency to excess, and believed that the only way to break the pattern of boom
and bust was through public policy, regulation of the financial system, and central bank
action. He maintained that “the financial system swings between robustness and fragility and
these swings are an integral part of the process that generates business cycles.“ Swings in
the credit cycle went through five stages: displacement, boom, euphoria, profit taking, and
panic. The accumulation of debt was the main dynamic that pushed an economy toward
crisis, and the use of more speculative financial postures. Minsky (1986b: 121) clearly
believed that there is a “need to integrate Schumpeter's vision of a resilient intertemporal
capitalist process with Keynes’ hard insights into the fragility introduced into the capitalist
accumulation process by some inescapable properties of capitalist financial structures.”
8. Schumpeter’s influence on Minsky’s vision
Minsky’s vision of money and finance provides the key link between Keynes’ view of the
investment decision as a determinant of output and employment and Schumpeter’s view of
the investment decision as a determinant of innovation and economic growth. Both
!
17
economists described the process of investment as an entrepreneurial decision, but they
grounded the decision invest in different theoretical apparatus. Keynes believed that long-
term expectations and liquidity preference can be highly volatile as expected profitability
depends on the uncertainty of operating costs and sales over the lifetime of the plant and
equipment, and liquidity preference and the decision to invest depend on highly volatile asset
prices. By contrast, Schumpeter believed this volatility to be the normal consequence of ‘real’
entrepreneurial activity and the accumulation of capital, without any reference to liquidity
preference.
The theory of business cycles also provides an important connection between Minsky,
Keynes and Schumpeter, but in ways that may not be appear obvious. Minsky was highly
critical of Schumpeter’s (1939) Business Cycles and subsequent writings because his
argument appeared to have moved away from his credit view of money and finance and
toward a real economy based on the Walrasian theory of value and distribution. Schumpeter
admired Léon Walras throughout his writings, basing his analysis of development and
business cycles on his theory, but he made some important extensions to this theory by
including changing technology, which he called innovation. Endogenously created money
finances the innovation process, which then generations cycles as it diffuses through the
economy. Minsky (1992) also emphasized that his analysis of financial fragility is placed in
historical time in the same way that Keynes’s (1936) theory of investment and the investment
theory of business cycles is “best treated as an analysis of the outcomes of processes that
operate in time.”
Minsky made few references to Schumpeter in his thesis no in his subsequent writings
until the centennial year of the birth of Keynes and Schumpeter. Despite these few
references Minsky (1992c) himself wrote that Schumpeter’s vision of the financial markets
and investment behaviour in the capitalist process were similar to his own view learned while
studying in Chicago. Keynes provided a theory of effective demand and accompanying
monetary theory, but he did not have the dynamics that Schumpeter so aptly described. Still
Schumpeter could not explain why finance might be the source of instability and financial
crisis. Minsky struggled to distance himself from the Walrasian foundations of Schumpeter,
and any implications of market efficiency, by considering uncertainty and expectations and
the resulting overconfidence and panics as an integral part of the market economy.
!
18
Bibliography
Akerlof, G.A. and R.J. Shiller, 2009. Animal Spirits: How Human Psychology Drives the Economy, and Why It
Matters for Global Capitalism, Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Binswanger, M. 1996. Money Creation, Profits and Growth: Monetary Aspects of Economic Evolution, in
Technological Progress and Economic Dynamics: Studies in Schumpeterian Economics, E. Helmstädter
and M. Perlman, eds., Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Böhm-Bawerk, E. von [1884] 1890. Capital and Interest: A Critical History of Economic Theory, trans. W.A. Smart,
London: Macmillan.
Böhm-Bawerk, E. von [1889] 1959. Capital and Interest: Volume II - Positive Theory of Capital, London:
Macmillan.
Carpenter, D.H., and M.M. Murphy, 2010. Permissible securities activities of commercial banks under the Glass-
Steagall Act (GSA) and the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act (GLBA), Congressional Research Service Report
(R41181).
Currie, M. and I. Steedman, 1990. Wrestling With Time: Problems In Economic Theory, Ann Arbor: University of
Michigan Press.
Delli Gatti, D., and M. Gallegati. 1997. At the root of the financial instability hypothesis: 'induced investment and
business cycles', Journal of Economic Issues, 31: 527534.
Delli Gatti, D., M. Gallegati, and H.P. Minsky. 1996. Financial institutions, economic policy and the dynamic
behaviour of the Economy, in Technological Progress and Economic Dynamics: Studies in Schumpeterian
Economics, E. Helmstädter and M. Perlman, eds., Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Dow, S. 1995. Uncertainty about uncertainty, In S. Dow S. and J. Hillard, J. (eds): Keynes, Knowledge and
Uncertainty. Aldershot: Edward Elgar
Freeman, C., and F. Louçã 2001. As Time Goes By. From the Industrial Revolution to the Information Revolution.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Freeman, C., and C. Perez, 1988. Structural crisis of adjustment, business cycles and investment behaviour. In
Technical Change and Economic Theory, ed. G. Dosi, C. Freeman, R. Nelson, G. Silverberg, and L.
Soete, pages? London: Pinter.
Galbraith, J.K. 1955. The Great Crash: 1929. New York: Houghton Mifflin Harcourt.
Juglar, C. 1862. Des crises commerciales et de leur retour périodique en France, en Angleterre et aux États-Unis,
Paris: Guillaumin et Cie, Edition.
Keynes, J.M. 1930 [1971]. A Treatise on Money, in two volumes, Volumes 5 and 6 of The Collected Works of
John Maynard Keynes. London: Macmillan.
Keynes, J.M. 1931 [2008]. Economic Possibilities for Our Grandchildren, in L. Pecchi and G. Piga, eds., Revisiting
Keynes, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Keynes, J.M. 1936 [1973]. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. Volume 7 of The Collected
Works of John Maynard Keynes. London: Macmillan.
Keynes, J.M. 1937. The general theory of employment, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 51: 209223.
Keynes, J.M. 1973. The General Theory and After: Part II Defence and Development. Volume 14 of The Collected
Works of John Maynard Keynes. London: Macmillan.
Knell, M. 2012. Was Schumpeter Walrasian? In C. Gehrke, N. Salvadori, I. Steedman, and R. Sturn, eds.
Classical Economics versus Modern Theories. Essays in Honour of Heinz D. Kurz, Vol. 2, London:
Routledge.
Kregel, J. 2009. Financial experimentation, technological paradigm revolutions and financial crises, in W.
Drechsler, R. Kattel and E.S. Reinert, Techo-Economic Paradigms: Essays in Honor of Carlota Perez,
London: Anthem Press, pp. 203-220.
Kuhn, T.S. 1962. The structure of scientific revolutions. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Lavoie, M. 1997. Loanable funds, endogenous money, and Minsky's financial fragility hypothesis, in, Money,
Financial Institutions, and Macroeconomics, A.J. Cohen, H. Hagemann and J. Smithin, eds., Kluwer
Nijhoff, Boston.
Leathers, C.G. and J.P. Raines, 2004. The Schumpeterian role of financial innovations in the New Economy’s
business cycle. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 28: 667681
!
19
Legrand, M.D.-P. and H. Hagemann, 2007. Business Cycles in Juglar and Schumpeter, The History of Economic
Thought 49:1-18.
Lipsey, R.G., K.I Carlaw and C.T. Bekar, 2005. Economic Transformations: General Purpose Technologies and
Long Term Economic Growth, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Marget, A.W. 1931, Léon Walras and the "Cash-Balance Approach" to the Problem of the Value of Money, The
Journal of Political Economy, 39: 569-600.
Marshall, A. 1890 [1961]. Principles of Economics, 9th Variorum Edition, C.W. Guillebaud editor. London:
Macmillan.
Messori, M. 2004. Credit and money in Schumpeter’s theory, in R. Arena and N. Salvadori, Money, Credit and the
Role of the State: Essays in Honor of Augusto Graziani, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 173-198.
Minsky, H.P. 1954 [2004]. Induced Investment and Business Cycles, edited and with an Introduction, D. B.
Papadimitriou, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.
Minsky, H.P 1957a. Central banking and money market changes, Quarterly Journal of Economics 71: 171187.
Minsky, H.P 1957b. Monetary systems and accelerator models, American Economic Review, 97: 860-883.
Minsky, H.P 1964. Longer waves in financial relations: financial factors in the more severe depressions, American
Economic Review 54(3), Papers and Proceedings of the Seventy-sixth Annual Meeting of the American
Economic Association: 324-335.
Minsky, H.P 1975. John Maynard Keynes. Columbia University Press: New York, 1975.
Minsky, H.P. 1978, The Financial Instability Hypothesis: A Restatement, Thames Papers in Policial Economy,
reprinted in Minsky (1982).
Minsky, H.P. 1980a. Capitalist financial processes and the instability of capitalism, Journal of Economic Issues,
14: 50523.
Minsky, H.P 1980b. Finance and profits: The changing nature of American business cycles, in The Business
Cycle and Public Policy, U.S. Government Printing Office: Washington D.C., pp. 209244. [also in Minsky,
1982]
Minsky, H.P 1982. Inflation, recession and economic policy. Sussex: Wheatsheaf.
Minsky, H.P 1985 [2009]. Beginnings, PSL Quarterly Review, 62: 191-203
Minsky, H.P 1986a. Stabilizing an Unstable Economy, New Haven, Yale Univ. Press.
Minsky, H.P 1986b. Money and crisis in Schumpeter and Keynes, in The Economic Law of Motion of Modern
Society: A Marx-Keynes-Schumpeter Centennial, H.J. Wagener and J.W. Drukker, eds. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Minsky, H.P 1986c. The evolution of financial institutions and the performance of the economy, Journal of
Economic Issues 20: 345-353.
Minsky, H.P 1990. Schumpeter: finance and evolution, in Evolving Technology and Market Structure: Studies in
Schumpeterian Economics, A. Heertje and M. Perlman, eds,. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Minsky, H.P 1992a. The financial instability hypothesis, Working paper No. 74, The Jerome Levy Economics
Institute of Bard College, New York. Published in P. Arestis and M. Sawyer, eds., Handbook of Radical
Political Economy, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 1993.
Minsky, H.P 1992b. The Capital Development of the Economy and The Structure of Financial Institutions,
Working paper No. 72, The Jerome Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, New York.
Minsky, H.P. 1992c. Hyman P. Minsky, in P. Arestis and M. Sawyer, A Biographical Dictionary of Dissenting
Economists, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Minsky, H.P 1993. Schumpeter and finance, in S. Biasco, A. Roncaglia, and M Salvati eds., Market and
Institutions in Economic Development: Essays in Honour of Paulo Sylos Labini, New York: St. Martin’s
Press, pp. 103115.
Minsky, H.P 1996. Uncertainty and The Institutional Structure of Capitalist Economies, Jerome Levy Institute ,
Working Paper 155.
Minsky, H.P. and C.J. Whalen, 1995. Economic insecurity and the institutional prerequisites for successful
capitalism, Journal of Post-Keynesian Economics, 19: 155-170.
Papadimitriou, D.B. and L.R. Wray, 1998. The Economic Contributions of Hyman Minsky: varieties of capitalism
and institutional reform, Review of Political Economy, 10: 199225.
!
20
Perez, C. 2002. Technological revolutions and finance capital: The dynamics of bubbles and golden ages.
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Perez, C. 2009. The double bubble at the turn of the century: technological roots and structural implications,
Cambridge Journal of Economics 33: 779805.
Schumpeter, J.A. 1909. On the concept of social value, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 23: 21332.
Schumpeter, J.A. 1910. Über das Wesen der Wirtschaftskrisen, Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft, Socialpolitik und
Verwaltung 19: 271325
Schumpeter, J.A., [1912] 1934. Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung, Leipzig, Verlag von Duncker & Humblot.
Third edition translated by R. Opie as The Theory of Economic Development, Cambridge: Harvard
University Press.
Schumpeter, J.A. [1914] 1954. Economic Doctrine and Method, New York: Oxford University Press. Translated by
R. Aris. Original edition, Epochen der Dogmen und Methodengeschichte, Tübingen: Mohr.
Schumpeter, J.A. 1928. The Instability of Capitalism, Economic Journal, 38: 361386.
Schumpeter, J.A. [1932] 2005. Development, translated by M.C. Becker and T. Knudsen, Journal of Economic
Literature XLIII: 108-120.
Schumpeter, J.A. 1936. Review of Keynes’s General Theory, Journal of the American Statistical Association, 791-
795.
Schumpeter, J.A., 1939. Business Cycles: A Theoretical, Historical, and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist
Process, New York: McGraw-Hill.
Schumpeter, J.A. 1942. Capitalism, socialism and democracy. New York: Harper and Brothers.
Schumpeter, J.A. 1946. John Maynard Keynes 18831946, American Economic Review 36: 495518.
Schumpeter, J.A. 1947. The creative response in economic history, Journal of Economic History 7:149-159.
Schumpeter J.A. 1954. History of Economic Analysis. E. Boody, editor. New York: Oxford University Press.
Seccareccia, M. 2004. :Aspects of a new conceptual integration of Keynes’s Treatise on Money and the General
Theory: Logical time units and macroeconomic price formation”, in Money, credit and the role of the state:
essays in honour of Augusto Graziani, R. Aréna, and N. Salvadori, eds., Aldershot, U.K.: Ashgate
Publishing.
Swedberg, R. 1991. Introduction to Joseph A. Schumpeter, Money and Currency, Social Research, 58: 1.
Toporowski, J. 2008. Minsky’s ‘induced investment and business cycles, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 32:
725-737.
Walras, L. [1874] 1954. Éléments d’Économie Pure, Corbaz, Lausanne, definitive edition 1926. Translated as
Elements of Economics, London: George Allen and Unwin.
Whalen, C.J. 2001. Integrating Schumpeter and Keynes: Hyman Minsky’s theory of capitalist development,
Journal of Economic Issues, 35: 805823.
Whalen, C.J. 2009. A Minsky perspective on the global recession of 2009, Research on Money and Finance
Discussion Paper No. 12, Department of Economics, SOAS.
Wieser, F. von [1889] 1893. Der natürliche Werth, Hölder, Vienna. Translated as Natural Value, Lon-don:
Macmillan.
View publication statsView publication stats
... Conversely, as steps have been taken in the application of neo-Schumpeterian insights on the financial system, Minsky's financial interpretation of capitalism offers important intuitions for the analysis of the economy as a system in evolution (Knell 2015). Nonetheless, for sake of clarity, it is important to recall the main features of the FIH. ...
... Minsky (1993:106) argued that a prerequisite to grasping the dynamics of the business cycle and the structural evolution of economic systems is the understanding of "the financing relations that rule, and how the profit-seeking activities of businessmen, bankers, and portfolio managers lead to the evolution of financial structures." For this reason, it can be argued that the FIH is just as much about economic evolution as it is about effective demand in a monetary economy (Knell 2015). Moreover, relying on a slavish reading of the FIH to explain the GFC introduces some difficulties: neither the crisis can be simply read as the result of excessive loans granted to traditional firms to finance their investment decisions, nor the taxonomy of financial position applies to the households' sector without due adaptations (Pressman and Scott 2018). ...
Article
Full-text available
Our paper explains the 2007-8 financial crisis by drawing on a financial reading of Schumpeter’s and Minsky’s contributions, in particular using an adapted version of Minsky’s financial instability hypothesis that is consistent with the key features of a financialized monetary theory of production. We argue that the pathogens that led to the crisis were inherent in the specific innovative form that US capitalism assumed since the early 1980s. Our interpretation of the crisis can be summarized as the description of a ‘financial demand-driven macro-dynamics’. The voracious demand for securities by the actors involved in the securitization process triggered an explosive production of structured financial products, for which the condition of chronic indebtedness of the household sector was the fundamental raw material.
... To understand a given economic and social phenomenon, one has to understand first how the phenomenon is formed and developed, how it becomes what it is (Coriat & Dosi, 2002). However, even though some institutionalist studies develop specific analyses of the financial dynamics-real dynamics-instability nexus (Knell, 2015;Callegari, 2018), a comprehensive theoretical framework for financial innovations and instability is not yet provided within the evolutionary and institutionalist literature. In order to partly fill this gap, this article specifically focuses on the dynamics of financial innovations. ...
... This is the financial instability hypothesis (Minsky, 1982) that maintains that economic fragilities often have endogenous causes. This is a convergent statement in Schumpeterian and Minskyian institutionalist analyses (Knell, 2015). Finance can trigger instability through innovations that lead to more complex and volatile financial markets, which in turn generate challenges for the industry and lead to permanent structural modifications (Schwarcz, 2009, p. 213). ...
Article
Full-text available
This article is a theoretical and conceptual exploration into the study of the dynamics of financial innovations and their consequences in market economies. Drawing upon the works of Schumpeter and Minsky in an institutionalist and evolutionary tradition, the article puts forward the monetary and financial features of the 21st century economies and the recurrent systemic financial instabilities generated within the context of the financialization process. It then calls for alternative regulatory reforms capable of leading to sustainable economic development. The originality of the analysis lies in the fact that the micro-dynamics of innovations may result in both creative and destructive outcomes since there are some crucial differences between entrepreneurial innovations à la Schumpeter as the positive force in economic development, and financial innovations à la Minsky as the source of instabilities. The article then focuses on the weaknesses and inconsistencies of loosely regulated financial markets and suggests a few principles for relevant financial regulation in an endogenously unstable economy. The main contribution of the article is that financial stability must be regarded as a public good to be provided by an economy-wide regulatory framework under the supervision of a visible public hand. The study of the conditions of financial stability proves to be a matter of a specific social dilemma—opposition between private and public interests—that concerns the organisation and management of financial markets at the macroeconomic level. Such a dilemma leads to the ultimate regulatory issue of spurring the innovation dynamics of financial markets while ensuring systemic stability and sustainability through an appropriate regulatory and supervisory environment.
... Ponzi finance tends to become more prevalent as economic stability continues, usually resulting in the collapse of some financial organizations. If the use of Ponzi finance is sufficiently pervasive in the financial system, as it may have been in the case of the 2008 subprime mortgage crisis, then the collapse of fragile Ponzi schemes can also affect hedge borrowers, who are unable to secure loans despite the apparent soundness of the underlying investments (Knell, 2015). When speculative and Ponzi financing units get so indebted that they cannot continue borrowing, they are compelled to sell off assets to pay interest, which leads to an excess of assets that are then put up for sale. ...
Article
Full-text available
Purpose: Pervasive impact of uncertainty necessitates relooking at the traditional empirical approaches to gauge the nexus between the real economy and the financial market, especially after the 2008 financial meltdown. The recent pandemic and ongoing geo-political tension across the globe further emphasized the need for augmentation of the existing analytical framework to address the prime importance and influence of uncertainty on the real economy and financial market. This is why, in this paper, we empirically attempted to calculate the connectedness among the business cycle, financial cycle, and economic policy uncertainty in India. The major contribution of this work can be attributed to the TVP VAR model-based empirical investigation of time-varying connectedness among the aforementioned three variables for the Indian economy from January 1997 to May 2022. Unlike erstwhile works, the paper assesses the net transmitter and receiver of shocks in the multivariate framework too. Design/methodology/approach: To estimate the dynamic connectedness among business cycle, financial cycle, and economic policy uncertainty, this paper integrates Diebold and Yilmaz's (2014) connectedness technique with Antonakakis and Gabauer's (2017) TVP-VAR methodology. Findings: We found that the business cycle and financial cycle are the primary receivers of shocks whereas policy uncertainty is the primary transmitter of shocks. Originality/value: To the best of our knowledge, this is the first empirical attempt to use such a technique in the Indian business cycle literature. Practical implications: The findings of the paper suggest the need to augment the existing policy framework by incorporating the economic uncertainty component. A stable economic environment is congenial to promote investment and garner consumers' confidence to boost growth in developing nations like India.
... Furthermore, owing to the interconnectedness of financial system compartments and the impact of emotional behavior on stock market volatility and crashes, scholars are becoming increasingly interested in financial cycles in order to better understand the relationship between sentiment and systemic risks following the global financial crisis of 2008 (Osina, 2019;Chen et al., 2021;Petropoulos and Siakoulis, 2021). In this context, the phenomenon of financial instability has mainly been identified as a persistent lack of stability in the overall financial system when it fails to develop the real economy, cope with risks and mobilize and allocate savings efficiently, resulting in an early indicator of financial crises (Hakkio and Keeton, 2009;Knell, 2015;Ramiah and Moosa, 2015;Gaies et al., 2020). From an empirical perspective, still little is known about the predictive power of sentiment regarding financial instability, although some studies have identified the "usual suspects" such as liquidity, financial and real cycles. ...
Article
This paper examines the relevance of sentiment in predicting overall financial system instability using long-run short-term memory networks. Weekly data on the US financial system, consumer sentiment, producer sentiment, and investor sentiment is collected from 21 January 1994 to 27 December 2019, and different models are developed to predict the one-week-ahead levels of financial stress in the US financial system. We find that models using sentiment indices outperform those relying solely on historical financial stress and risk data. This result is robust to comparisons with an alternative deep learning method and out-of-sample predictions. It constitutes an argument in favor of behavioral finance and Minsky’s (1975) financial instability hypothesis against the Efficient Market Hypothesis. As it concretely identifies the main indicators for predicting US financial stress one week in advance, the study provides relevant recommendations for policymakers and investors in terms of macroprudential policies and portfolio management.
... Sobre la base de esta afirmación, Schumpeter señaló que la estructura económica se encuentra en un proceso de constante innovación. Minsky extrapoló estas ideas y postuló que el mercado financiero tiene cambios y atraviesa por diferentes etapas hasta llegar a un momento de crisis (Knell, 2015). ...
Article
Full-text available
Episodios recientes han evidenciado la gran fragilidad del sistema financiero, la cual podría desembocar en profundas recesiones económicas. Con respecto a esto, Hyman Minsky propuso la hipótesis de la inestabilidad financiera, que explica cómo el sistema atraviesa tres momentos. Estos se conocen como: cobertura, especulativo y Ponzi; y sostiene que las crisis se generan de manera endógena. Por tanto, Minsky defen­dió el rol de la regulación del gobierno, puesto que las instituciones financieras no logran preservar su estabilidad. Considerando lo anterior, evaluamos cuatro críticas realizadas a esta visión desde la perspectiva de la teoría austriaca, la política económica, la hipóte­sis de los mercados eficientes y el problema del Gran Gobierno. La validez de la hipótesis de Minsky se analizó con evidencia empírica y argumentos teóricos. Encontramos que la hipótesis de la inestabilidad financiera contribuye significativamente a la comprensión de la tendencia de los mercados financieros a las crisis; y cómo el sistema puede estabi­lizarse a través de la regulación.
Article
El trabajo de investigación que se presenta a continuación aborda la posible preocupación de la independencia del Banco Central a través del desarrollo y aplicación de modelos econométricos. La complejidad de la modelización ha permitido ir un paso más allá al corroborar que la independencia financiera no sólo está ligada a los nombramientos y presiones de los estados en torno a su política económica sino también al papel que juegan los mercados financieros al actuar como una fuerza que dicta y contamina las decisiones de los Bancos Centrales. En este sentido, el trabajo propone una base teórica de recomendaciones sobre la aplicación de la nueva política monetaria en un entorno más complejo, tanto por la pandemia que azota al mundo como por el abultado endeudamiento que arrastran los países. El documento concluye con una serie de medidas y consejos que podrían ser abordados por los hacedores de política monetaria dada la necesaria, pero no fácil, "normalización" de la política monetaria que se requiere a nivel global.
Article
Full-text available
عندما يتحدث الناس اليوم عن العولمة أو"الاقتصاد الجديد"، فإن جزءً كبيرًا منهم يتحدثون عن "الأمولة" أو الحجم المتزايد والترابط بين أسواق رأس المال (السندات والأسهم والعملات الأجنبية والمشتقات المالية) والوسطاء الماليون (المصارف، مصارف الاستثمار، صناديق الاستثمار، شركات التأمين، وشركات التقاعد) داخل البلدان وفي جميع أنحاء العالم. وإنه لمن الغريب أن يتم تجاهل التمويل في أبحاث الدورة الاقتصادية لأنه ومنذ عام 1900، ارتبطت كل أزمة اقتصادية كبرى في جميع أنحاء العالم بأزمة مالية (Knoop, 2010). لذلك فعندما يفكر الناس في أسباب الأزمات الاقتصادية الكبرى مثل الكساد الكبير أو أزمة شرق آسيا أو الأزمة العالمية لعام 2008، فإن الأسواق المالية هي أول ما يتبادر إلى أذهان معظم الناس، ومن هنا ظهرت أهمية فهم العلاقة بين الائتمان المصرفي والدورات الاقتصادية من خلال استقراء الأدبيات الاقتصادية في موضوع البحث.
Article
Full-text available
Bu çalışma, kapitalizmin krizlere içkin yapısının finansallaşma ile beraber geçirdiği dönüşümü ve finansal krizlerin arkasındaki işleyişi incelemektedir. Kapitalist iktisadi yapının koşullara göre değişim gösteren dinamik yapısı, tarihsel süreç içerisinde farklı aşamalarda ortaya çıkmaktadır. Bu dinamik yapının temel hareket noktası sermaye birikim sürecinin devam etmesidir. Sermayenin kaçtığı son alan ise finansallaşmadır. Finansallaşma, kapitalizmi yeni bir dönüşümün eşiğine getirirken aynı zamanda krizlerin biçimini de değiştirmektedir. Böylelikle krizler kendini finansal piyasalarda göstermekte, süresi ve etkisi de çok daha derin hissedilmektedir. Çalışmada, finansal krizlerin açıklanmasında Minskyen bir yaklaşım kullanılarak, istikrarın istikrarsızlık yaratmasının altındaki nedenler üzerinde durulmaktadır. Özellikle, krizlerin arkasındaki kapitalist eğilimler ve ideoloji-iktisat ilişkisi ön plana çıkarılmaktadır. Çalışmada bu bağlamda kalınarak; kapitalizmin krizleri ve finansallaşması, Glass-Steagall Yasası ve Minsky Anı incelenmektedir.
Article
Full-text available
Innovation studies rarely incorporate finance in their analysis, although productive innovation and economic development require efficient allocation of financial resources. Complex financial vehicles other than banks increasingly fund global economic activity. These innovative, yet ‘dark’ financial entities service the shielding of private – not public – wealth, and challenge the positive notion of financial innovation as they help cement socio-spatial inequalities. We illustrate how legal structuring benefits (from) the commercialization of state sovereignty and the finetuned work of finance-cum- law that have long shaped the business model of leading financial centres; a legacy difficult to disengage from in times of financial sustainability imperatives.
Article
Full-text available
This research focused on the imperative of financial management innovations to sustainable economic growth in Nigeria. While reviewing the extant literature on financial innovations, this study specifically sought to unearth the positive and negative dimensions of the discourse. Findings were seen from two angles. One of the positive contributions of financial innovation is it remains adaptable to suit different conditions or purposes. It also promotes business activities of a country. On the negative side, financial innovations orchestrated some cyber related crimes exemplified by ponzi schemes, 'yahoo boys' phenomenon, and the likes; all targeted at swindling unsuspecting persons. It was concluded that in spite of complexity of technology induced contemporary illegalities, financial innovations had impacted positively and significantly on the global financial system. It therefore called for shrewdness among owners and managers of financial institutions to encourage competitiveness in the financial sector, and to invest in growth-enhancing innovations.
Book
This book was originally published by Macmillan in 1936. It was voted the top Academic Book that Shaped Modern Britain by Academic Book Week (UK) in 2017, and in 2011 was placed on Time Magazine's top 100 non-fiction books written in English since 1923. Reissued with a fresh Introduction by the Nobel-prize winner Paul Krugman and a new Afterword by Keynes’ biographer Robert Skidelsky, this important work is made available to a new generation. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money transformed economics and changed the face of modern macroeconomics. Keynes’ argument is based on the idea that the level of employment is not determined by the price of labour, but by the spending of money. It gave way to an entirely new approach where employment, inflation and the market economy are concerned. Highly provocative at its time of publication, this book and Keynes’ theories continue to remain the subject of much support and praise, criticism and debate. Economists at any stage in their career will enjoy revisiting this treatise and observing the relevance of Keynes’ work in today’s contemporary climate.
Book
"Today, Mr. Minsky's view [of economics] is more relevant than ever."- The New York Times "Indeed, the Minsky moment has become a fashionable catch phrase on Wall Street."-The Wall Street Journal John Maynard Keynes offers a timely reconsideration of the work of the revered economics icon. Hyman Minsky argues that what most economists consider Keynesian economics is at odds with the major points of Keynes's The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. Keynes and Minsky refuse to ignore pervasive uncertainty. Once uncertainty is given center stage, recurring episodes of financial system crises are all but inescapable. As Robert Barbera notes in a new preface, "Benign economic circumstances!invite increasingly aggressive financial market wagers. Innovation in finance is a signature development in a capitalist economy. Once leveraged wagers are in place, small disappointments can have exaggerated consequences." Thus for Minsky economic calm on Main Street engenders financial system fragility which, in turn, ensures a perpetuation of boom and bust cycles. Minsky colleagues Dimitri B. Papadimitriou and L. Randall Wray write in a new introduction, "We offer this new edition, in the hope that it will contribute to the reformation of economic theory so that it can address the world in which we actually live-the world that was always the topic of Minsky's analysis."
Chapter
We are suffering just now from a bad attack of economic pessimism. It is common to hear people say that the epoch of enormous economic progress which characterised the nineteenth century is over; that the rapid improvement in the standard of life is now going to slow down—at any rate in Great Britain; that a decline in prosperity is more likely than an improvement in the decade which lies ahead of us.