ArticlePDF Available

Abstract and Figures

We investigate the existence and stability of sexual strategies (sequential hermaphrodite, successive hermaphrodite or gonochore) at a proximate level. To accomplish this, we constructed and analyzed a general dynamical game model structured by size and sex. Our main objective is to study how costs of changing sex and of sexual competition should shape the sexual behavior of a hermaphrodite. We prove that, at the proximate level, size alone is insufficient to explain the tendency for a pair of prospective copulants to elect the male sexual role by virtue of the disparity in the energetic costs of eggs and sperm. In fact, we show that the stability of sequential vs. simultaneous hermaphrodite depends on sex change costs, while the stability of protandrous vs. protogynous strategies depends on competition cost.
Content may be subject to copyright.
1 23
Journal of Mathematical Biology
ISSN 0303-6812
J. Math. Biol.
DOI 10.1007/s00285-015-0866-3
Understanding hermaphrodite species
through game theory
Amira Kebir, Nina H.Fefferman &
Slimane BenMiled
1 23
Your article is protected by copyright and
all rights are held exclusively by Springer-
Verlag Berlin Heidelberg. This e-offprint is
for personal use only and shall not be self-
archived in electronic repositories. If you wish
to self-archive your article, please use the
accepted manuscript version for posting on
your own website. You may further deposit
the accepted manuscript version in any
repository, provided it is only made publicly
available 12 months after official publication
or later and provided acknowledgement is
given to the original source of publication
and a link is inserted to the published article
on Springer's website. The link must be
accompanied by the following text: "The final
publication is available at link.springer.com”.
J. Math. Biol.
DOI 10.1007/s00285-015-0866-3
Mathematical Biology
Understanding hermaphrodite species through game
theory
Amira Kebir ·Nina H. Fefferman ·Slimane Ben Miled
Received: 30 May 2014 / Revised: 15 January 2015
© Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2015
Abstract We investigate the existence and stability of sexual strategies (sequen-
tial hermaphrodite, successive hermaphrodite or gonochore) at a proximate level. To
accomplish this, we constructed and analyzed a general dynamical game model struc-
tured by size and sex. Our main objective is to study how costs of changing sex and
of sexual competition should shape the sexual behavior of a hermaphrodite. We prove
that, at the proximate level, size alone is insufficient to explain the tendency for a pair
of prospective copulants to elect the male sexual role by virtue of the disparity in the
energetic costs of eggs and sperm. In fact, we show that the stability of sequential
vs. simultaneous hermaphrodite depends on sex change costs, while the stability of
protandrous vs. protogynous strategies depends on competition cost.
A. Kebir
Université de Tunis, Tunis, Tunisia
e-mail: amira.kebir@gmail.com
A. Kebir ·S. Ben Miled (B)
ENIT-LAMSIN, Université de Tunis el Manar,
Tunis, Tunisia
e-mail: slimane@ipeit.rnu.tn
N. H. Fefferman
Department of Ecology, Evolution, and Natural Resources,
Rutgers University, New Brunswick, NJ, USA
N. H. Fefferman
The Center for Discrete Mathematics and Theoretical Computer Science,
New Brunswick, NJ, USA
e-mail: fefferman@aesop.rutgers.edu
S. Ben Miled
Institut Pasteur de Tunis, Tunis, Tunisia
123
Author's personal copy
A. Kebir et al.
Keywords Hermaphrodite strategies ·Replicator equation ·Instantaneous
reproductive success ·Energy loss ·Stability
Mathematics Subject Classification 92D25 ·92D50 ·91A06 ·91A25
1 Introduction
Sex allocation theory (Charnov 1982) explains the way in which organisms allo-
cate resources to male versus female function. The size-advantage hypothesis (SAH)
describes sex change when fitness changes with individual size (Ghiselin 1969;Warner
1988). In case of variances in fitness for male or female roles, we would expect that
an individual chooses the sexual role that will maximize its fitness (Charnov 1979;
Fischer 1988).
Theory has been developed along two main directions, one specific to simultaneous
hermaphrodites—in which sex is viewed as a quantitative parameter (numbers of male
and female gametes)—and another specific to sequential hermaphrodites—in which
sex is viewed as a qualitative parameter (male or female).
Many hermaphrodite species show intermediate patterns between sequential and
simultaneous hermaphroditism. In this case, sex allocation appears as a phenotypically
plastic response to proximate parameters, such as local mate or local resource compe-
tition, group size, sex-ratio, or local social dominance hierarchy (see St Mary 1994;
Brauer et al. 2007;Hardy 2009;Kebir et al. 2010 for simultaneous hermaphrodites
and Zabala et al. 1997;Okumura 2001;Munday et al. 2006a;Ben Miled et al. 2010 for
sequential hermaphrodites). For sequential hermaphrodites, Okumura (2001)showed
the presence of both male and female gametes in Epinephelus akaarai gonadal tis-
sue, confirming that sex reversal goes in both directions. Nakamura et al. (2003)
demonstrate the role estrogens play in sex differentiation underling the mechanism of
phenotypic plasticity in fishes. Simultaneous hermaphrodites also show a plastic sex
allocation response; St Mary (1994) demonstrates that, depending on social environ-
ment, Lythrypnus dalli individuals behave as male or female only and maintain only
one active gonadal tissue.
The ability to choose the sexual role at any time induces a gender conflict [called
also Hermaphrodite dilemma by Leonard (1990)]—i.e., the tendency for a pair of
prospective copulants to elect the less expensive role (DeWitt 1996;Wethington et al.
1996). Assuming this conflict, our aim is to prove that sexual types (simultaneous
or sequential hermaphrodites) can be a stable equilibrium point of a time and size
structured model at a proximate scale.
At the individual level, gender conflict can be viewed as a game whose payoff
depends on reproductive success, sexual competition cost and/or sex change cost (St
Mary 1997;Angeloni et al. 2002;Angeloni 2003;Brauer et al. 2007). Leonard (1990)
and Wethington et al. (1996) suggested classical game models to analyze how egg-
trading can solve gender conflict. In their games, each player is assigned two strategies:
to cooperate (mate sequentially in both roles) or to defect (mate according to the most
beneficial role). However, their models are static and the payoff is independent of
individual size. Moreover, as we noticed before, individual sexual choices depend on
123
Author's personal copy
Understanding hermaphrodite species through game theory
the population. Therefore dynamical games (Hofbauer and Sigmund 1998) are more
appropriate, enabling us to move from the already-explored static approach to instead
capture changes as both individuals and their environments change.
We propose to generalize (Leonard 1990;Wethington et al. 1996) models by assum-
ing that during reproductive period, the sex role is the result of a size dependent
dynamical game, with four sexual strategies—cooperative female, non-cooperative
female, cooperative male and non-cooperative male—and with a payoff matrix that
depends on gamete production number, sexual competition cost, and sex change cost.
Individuals then change their strategy according to replicator equations in anticipation
of the next reproductive period.
It is to maintain this scale of biological focus that we restrict these investigations to
the proximate level of influential factors. While evolutionary forces should shape the
way in which individuals make decisions about sexual roles in hermaphroditic mating
systems, these decisions are made by those individuals based on local observations of
self, potential partners, and their environment. There is therefore the potential for large
disparity between strategies that maximize lifetime fitness and those that maximize
the fitness benefits from a single, local choice (i.e., make a choice based on a greedy
algorithm). For this reason, it is important to build models that focus on stable strategies
for iterated single-round games. These can then be compared with stable strategies
for global success in lifetime games, for which the payoff is only calculated at the
conclusion of many rounds of play. While in this paper we focus on this proximate
level, future efforts to develop these dynamical game formulations for entire lifetime
games will enable us use the comparison of the two to make biologically realistic
interpretations of hermaphroditic behaviors in ways that have not previously been
accessible.
In Sect. 2, we introduce and analyze a general game theoretical model with four
strategies and a size dependent payoff. We prove, in Theorem 2.1, that the Heaviside
function is an equilibrium state and find a sufficient condition for its local asymptotic
stability. In Sect. 3, using the result of Sect. 2, we define and study a game for her-
maphroditic species and find, by numerical analysis, conditions for which different
kinds of hermaphroditism should exist. Finally, in Sect. 4, we discuss these results and
propose a few concluding thoughts.
2 Analysis of general game theory model
We consider a size-structured population over a finite set, S={s0,...,smax}, (with
s0and smax respectively the initial and maximum size of fertility) playing a game
with four strategies i∈{1,2,3,4}. We assume that the game occurs in a population
with a stable size distribution—i.e., total number of individuals for each size sis
constant—while the proportion of individuals adopting each strategy changes. Let
X(s,t)=(x1(s,t), x2(s,t), x3(s,t), x4(s,t))tbe the vector of frequencies of players
for each strategy for the population of size sat time t(i.e., ixi(s,t)=1 for each s
and t).
The game is a represented by a payoff matrix P(s,s)in M4(R), where for all
(s,s)S2and i,j∈{1...4},Pi,j(s,s)is the payoff of the strategy iat size s
123
Author's personal copy
A. Kebir et al.
playing with the strategy jat size s. Then the game dynamics are represented by the
following replicator equations, for all sSand t∈[0,+∞[:
xi
t(s,t)=xi(s,t)( fi(s,X(s,t)) ¯
f(s,X(s,t))), i∈{1,2,3,4}(1)
with fi(s,X(s,t)) =sS(P(s,s)X(s,t))i, the fitness of the strategy iand
¯
f(s,X(s,t)) =sSXt(s,t)P(s,s)X(s,t), the mean fitness of population of size
sat time t. The solutions of replicator equations, X:S×RR4,areC1(R,R4)
relative to t.
In next theorem, we prove that characteristic functions are equilibrium points of
the system (1) and find conditions for their local asymptotic stability.
Theorem 2.1 For all i ∈{1,2,3,4},letA
ibe a subset of S and 1Aiits associated
characteristic function.
If {Ai,i∈{1,2,3,4}} is a partition of S then X =(1A1,1A2,1A3,1A4)is an
equilibrium point of the system (1). Moreover, if, i∈{1,2,3,4}:
(fjfi)(s,X(s)) < 0,j∈{1,2,3,4}\iand sAi(2)
then Xis locally asymptotically stable.
The proof is left in Appendix.
Remark 1 We should note here that if i{1...4}such that:
sAiand j∈{1,2,3,4}\i,(fjfi)(s,X(s)) > 0.(3)
then the equilibrium Xis unstable.
In biological application of the previous theorem, we analyze the effects of sexual
competition, sexual inversion cost, and gametes costs on the stability of different kinds
of hermaphroditism.
3 Application to a hermaphrodite population
We model here the sexual behavior of hermaphroditic species (sequential her-
maphrodites and simultaneous hermaphrodites) during reproduction through a game
between two protagonists. The change over time of the different strategies is repre-
sented by the replicator equations defined in the previous section.
More precisely, we consider a stable size-structured population of individuals where
mating is considered as a game. We assume that individuals are able to change sex
at each mating i.e., an instantaneous sex changing mating, and do so depending on
the payoff of the game matrix. This flexibility allows us to define four kinds of sexual
strategies corresponding to four categories of players: strategy 1, cooperative female,
noted by FM,—i.e., female that changed to a male, knowing that male is the present
status—strategy 2, pure or non-cooperative female, noted by F—i.e., female that
123
Author's personal copy
Understanding hermaphrodite species through game theory
stayed female knowing that female is the present status—strategy 3, cooperative male,
noted by MF—i.e., male that changed to a female knowing that female is the present
status—and strategy 4, pure or non-cooperative male, noted by M—i.e., male that
stayed male, knowing that male is the present status.
As previously defined, let Sbe the set of sizes and for each i∈{1...4},letxi(s,t)
be the proportion of individuals of the strategy iat size sSand t∈[0,+∞[.
Through the value of each xiwe define the different kinds of sexual states, as
following:
Gonogoristic pure female (resp. gonogoristic pure male) state is where the density
of the pure female (resp. male) strategy is x2(s,t)=1 (resp. x4(s,t)=1) and thus
x1(s,t)=x3(s,t)=x4(s,t)=0 (resp. x1(s,t)=x2(s,t)=x3(s,t)=0), for all
t0 and sS.
pure protogynous (resp. protandrous)hermaphrodite state is where it exists, sS
such that x2(s,t)=1s<s(resp. x2(s,t)=11s<s), x4(s,t)=1x2(s,t)and
x1(s,t)=x3(s,t)=0,for all t0 and sS.
Sequential hermaphrodite state is a state with almost only non-cooperative individ-
uals and rare cooperative individuals, i.e., we assume here that x1(s,t)=x3(s,t)=
0,sSand t0.
Simultaneous hermaphrodite state is a state with almost only cooperative individuals
and rare non-cooperative individuals, i.e., we assume here that x2(s,t)=x4(s,t)=
0,sSand t0.
We assume using the Eq. (1) that the density of each sexual role may not be as
important as the number of mates available. Otherwise, in application to systems
where mating is strictly density dependent, the vector Xshould be normalized by
space to provide population densities rather than frequencies.
3.1 Game matrix
To describe the payoff matrix, we divide it into a gain matrix, G—defined by the
normalized fitness of a strategy comparing to the female fitness—and a loss matrix,
L—defined by the normalized loss of energy for reproduction comparing to the energy
used by a female. The total payoff matrix is P=GL. We use two different constants
of normalization because the two matrix have different units.
Gain matrix We define the fitness of both mating partners as the number of fertilized
eggs produced by the partner playing the female role. Therefore, let Fiti,j(s,s)the
fitness of two protagonists playing respectively strategy i∈{1,...,4}at size sand
strategy j∈{1,...,4}at size s.Wehave,
Fiti,j(s,s)=Fitj,i(s,s).
Fiti,j(s,s)=0ifi=j, the fitness of two individual adopting the same sexual
strategy is always equal to 0.
We assume that the number of fertilized eggs is equal to the number of eggs produced
by a female, while, spermatozoa quantity is not a limiting factor for the fitness. The
123
Author's personal copy
A. Kebir et al.
number of eggs depends on the energy allocated by the female for reproduction. Thus,
if (i,j)∈{(2,1), (2,4), (3,4)}(i.e., {(F,FM), (F,M), ( M,MF)}), the fitness of
the mating is,
Fiti,j(s,s)=Fitj,i(s,s)=ei(s)
with ei(s)the female clutch size of the strategy i.
Let R:SR+be the energy allocated in reproduction by a female through size
(Ris strictly monotonic function). We have,
ei(s)=R(s)
cFif i=2
R(s)RMF
cFif i=3
with cF, female gamete energy cost and RFM and RFM the sex change cost parameters,
describing respectively the amount of a reproductive resource needed for the sex
change from female to male and inversely. All quantities are considered positives. Sex
change cost include energy and time required to convert their gonads and therefore can
be substantial (Charnov 1982). On the other hand, for simultaneous hermaphrodites
the cost might be minimal, because they maintain mature gonads of both sexes and
need to change only their behavior. As, one of our goal is to prove that hermaphrodite
type can be the result of sex changing cost, we suppose that it can be either positive
(taking into account former case) or zero (for the latter case).
The fitness of a mating between a cooperative female, i=1, and a cooperative
male j=3, is defined as following: we suppose that the individual in a cooperative
role divides its resource between the first and second roles. Let p∈]0,1[the fraction
of sex allocation energy assigned to female role (respectively 1 pfor male role),
so:
Fit1,3(s,s)=R(s)p
cF+R(s)pRMF
cF.
We assume here that both partners play twice and both win through the female role of
each round. And finally for the rest we have Fiti,j(s,s)=0. Indeed, we assume
in this model that sex change cost for the two directions can have different val-
ues, otherwise there is no need to divide the cooperative strategy into two groups.
This subdivision induces different strategies for each kind of cooperative individual.
It is for this reason that we define FM individuals as the ones that prefer chang-
ing from female to male and that they prefer playing with cooperative individuals
with opposite strategy and pure female (inversely for MF). We can notice that if
the sex changing costs are equal to zero for both strategies then they win exactly
the same gain and include all the possible games that cooperative individuals can
play.
123
Author's personal copy
Understanding hermaphrodite species through game theory
To conclude, the gain matrix is defined as following,
FM(s)F(s)MF(s)M(s)
FM(s)0R(s)
cF
R(s)p
cF+R(s)pRMF
cF0
F(s)R(s)
cF00 R(s)
cF
MF(s)R(s)p
cF+R(s)pRMF
cF00
R(s)RMF
cF
M(s)0R(s)
cF
R(s)RMF
cF0
(4)
and the dimensionless gain matrix, obtained by dividing the gain matrix by R(s)/cF
(cF= 0) is:
G(s,s)=
FM(s)F(s)MF(s)M(s)
FM(s)0R(s)
R(s)
R(s)p
R(s)+pRMF
R(s)0
F(s)100 1
MF(s)R(s)p
R(s)+pRMF
R(s)001RMF
R(s)
M(s)0R(s)
R(s)
R(s)RMF
R(s)0
(5)
Loss matrix The loss for each kind of player corresponds to the energy used for
reproduction or the energy used for sex change cost, RMF or RFM .
Sexual competition involves extra cost in the evaluation of investment in reproduc-
tion. This cost can explain size dimorphism between males and females. To understand
its effect on the type of hermaphroditism, we introduce cost of sexual competition,
C(s,s), between males of size sand s, we suppose that C:S2R+. This cost can
be either 0—in no competition case—or positive.
The loss matrix is,
FM(s)F(s)MF(s)M(s)
FM(s)RFM RFM +(1p)(R(s)RFM)R(s)RFM
F(s)R(s)00R(s)
MF(s)R(s)RMF RMF R(s)
M(s)0(1p)R(s)(1p)R(s)C(s,s)
(6)
We note that, in this formulation, the female uses all its sex allocation energy for
reproduction, which is not the case for the male. While this may not be representative of
all species, it can be easily relaxed for species in which both sexes are known to compete
for mates, or in which competition is uniquely female. The normalization in this
case is defined as the outgoing energy during reproduction being divided by the total
reproductive resources R(s)for each player. After simplification, the dimensionless
payoff loss matrix is defined as following:
L(s,s)=
FM(s)F(s)MF(s)M(s)
FM(s)RFM
R(s)1p1RFM
R(s) 1RFM
R(s)
F(s)1001
MF(s)1RMF
R(s)
RMF
R(s)1
M(s)0(1p)(1p)CR(s,s)
(7)
123
Author's personal copy
A. Kebir et al.
Where CR(s,s)=C(s,s)
R(s).
Now, we are able to define the total payoff matrix for the matrix, P(s,s)=
G(s,s)L(s,s):
RFM
R(s)R(s)
R(s)+p1RFM
R(s)1p1+R(s)
R(s)RMF
R(s)1RFM
R(s)
0000
p1+R(s)
R(s)RMF
R(s)1RMF
R(s)RMF
R(s)RMF
R(s)
0R(s)
R(s)+p1R(s)
R(s)+pRMF
R(s)1CR(s,s)
(8)
Remark 2 The normalization enable us to compare the payoff of different strategies,
relative to that of the pure female one. since offspring production is always proportional
to female production of gametes. While this simplification leads to some odd-seeming
zeros in our matrices, it is important to remember that they do not reflect the actual
evolutionary fitness associated with the behavior, but instead merely indicate that there
is no difference in payoff relative to the female fitness. By focusing on the relative
benefits, rather than absolute changes in fitness, we can more directly interpret the
results of the game as metrics for decision-making in each reproductive round.
3.2 Application of Theorem 2.1
Let’s study the stability of the knowing strategies, gonogoristic, sequential and simul-
taneous hermaphrodites strategies, using Theorem 2.1. Applying matrix 8to an equi-
librium X=(1Ai)i=1,2,3,4, where {Ai}i=1,2,3,4is a partition of S,wehaveforall
sS:
(f1f2)(s,X)=|S|
R(s)(RA2ρA2+pRA3ρA3RFM(pρA2+ρA1+ρA4)
(1p)R(sA2(pRMF +(1p)R(s))ρA3)
(f3f2)(s,X)=|S|
R(s)(pRA1ρA1RMF(1+(p1A1)(1p)R(sA1)
(f4f2)(s,X)=|S|
R(s)(C(s)A4ρA4+RA2A3ρA2A3RMFρA3
(1p)R(s)(ρA2+ρA3))
where, |X|=card(X), RX=sXR(s)
|X|,C(s)X=sXC(s,s)
|X|and ρX=|X|
|S|,for
all subset Xof S. Then we have the following corollaries:
Corollary 1 Gonogorostic pure male, A2=S and gonogorostic pure female strate-
gies A4=S are unstable strategies.
Proof 1. Pure female strategy corresponds to an equilibrium state of the game (8)
where x
2(s)=1Sand x
1(s)=x
3(s)=x
4(s)=0,sSand thus A2=Sand
A1=A3=A4=∅. In this case, we notice that there exists sSsuch that
123
Author's personal copy
Understanding hermaphrodite species through game theory
R(s)=minsSR(s)and then we have (f4f2)(s,X)=|S|
R(s)(RS(1
p)R(s)) > 0 since RSR(s)and 0 <p<1. We conclude using Remark 1.
2. Pure male strategy corresponds to an equilibrium state for the game where x
4(s)=
1Sand x
1(s)=x
2(s)=x
3(s)=0,sSand thus A4=Sand A1=A2=
A3=∅. In this case, we notice that (f2f4)(s,X)=|S|
R(s)(C(s,.)
S)>0. We
conclude using Remark 1.
We note that, obviously, a population with only a pure male or female strategy is
unstable as with only one pure strategy, reproduction is impossible.
Corollary 2 Sequential hermaphrodite strategies (A1=A3=∅,A2=∅and A4=
), like protandrous or protogynous, are locally asymptotically stable for the game if
ρA4
ρA2
sup
sA4
C(s)A4+(1p)sup
sA4
R(s)
<RA2<ρA4
ρA2
inf
sA2
C(s)A4+(1p)inf
sA2
R(s), (9)
RA2<RFM p+ρA4
ρA2+(1p)inf
sA2
R(s), (10)
and
sup
sA4
C(s)A4<ρA2
ρA4
p+1RMF (11)
Proof Sequential hermaphrodite strategy corresponds to an equilibrium state of the
game where, x
2(s)=1A2(s),x
4(s)=1A4(s)and x
1(s)=x
3(s)=0,sS, thus
A1=A3=∅,A2=∅and A4=∅. Therefore, by Theorem 2.1, the sequential
strategy is stable if
(f1f2)(s,X)<0,(f3f2)(s,X)<0,(f4f2)(s,X)<0,sA2
(f1f4)(s,X)<0,(f2f4)(s,X)<0(f3f4)(s,X)<0,sA4
We have,
1. (f1f2)(s,X)=|S|
R(s)(RA2ρA2RFM(pρA2+ρA4)(1p)R(sA2), s
A2, then:
(f1f2)(s,X)<0,sA2
RA2<RFM p+ρA4
ρA2+(1p)R(s), sA2.(12)
123
Author's personal copy
A. Kebir et al.
2. (f4f2)(s,X)=|S|
R(s)(RA2ρA2CA4ρA4(1p)R(sA2), then:
(f4f2)(s,X)<0,sA2
RA2<C(s)A4ρA4
ρA2
+(1p)R(s), sA2,(13)
and,
(f4f2)(s,X)>0,sA4
RA2>C(s)A4ρA4
ρA2
+(1p)R(s), sA4.(14)
3. (f3f2)(s,X)=−RMF |S|
R(s), then (f3f2)(s,X)<0,sS.
4. (f3f4)(s,X)=(f3f2)(s,X)+(f2f4)(s,X)and we have (f3
f2)(s,X)<0,sSthen if (14) is true, we have (f3f4)(s,X)<0,sA4.
5. (f1f4)(s,X)=|S|
R(s)(RFM(pρA2+ρA4)+C(s)A4ρA4). Then (f1
f4)(s,X)<0(11) is satisfied.
Therefore, sequential hermaphrodite strategies (A1=A3=∅,A2=∅and A4=
) are locally asymptotically stable for the local game if (9)–(11) are satisfied.
Now we analyze the stability of cooperative strategies:
Corollary 3 If RFM = 0and RMF = 0then respectively only the cooperative female
strategy F M (i.e., A2=A3=A4=∅)and only the cooperative male strategy M F
(i.e., A1=A2=A4=∅)are unstable.
Proof 1. The cooperative female strategy, FM, corresponds to an equilibrium state
for the game where x
1(s)=1Sand x
2(s)=x
3(s)=x
4(s)=0,sS
and thus A1=Sand A2=A3=A4=∅. We notice that if RFM = 0 then
(f2f1)(s,X)=RFM |S|
R(s)>0,sSand thus by Remark 1this strategy is
unstable.
2. The cooperative male strategy, MF, corresponds to an equilibrium state for the
game where x
3(s)=1Sand x
1(s)=x
2(s)=x
4(s)=0,sSand thus A3=S
and A1=A2=A4=∅. We notice that if RMF = 0 then (f2f3)(s,X)=
RMF |S|
R(s)>0,sSand thus by Remark 1this strategy is unstable.
3.3 Numerical analysis
The aim of this section is to understand how the different types of hermaphroditism
(sequential hermaphrodite, simultaneous hermaphrodite) exhibited depend on sex
change and competition costs. For that, we fix the two functions R(s)and C(s,s)as
following:
123
Author's personal copy
Understanding hermaphrodite species through game theory
We assume that the resources allocated to reproduction, R(s), are a power function
of s(Cadet et al. 2004),
R(s)=ρRsγR
where ρR0 and γRRare constants.
We assume that energy spent for competition is asymmetric when male size are
different (see Fig. 1). Precisely, energy spent for the competition is a continu-
ous function symmetrical by the first bisect (i.e., C(s,s)=C(s,s), (s,s)
[smin,smax]2), and such as for all s∈[smin,smax],
C(s,s)=ρCsγCand C(s,smax s)=ρCsσC,
where ρC0, γCRand σCRare constants.
We show that hermaphroditism types depend on both sex change and on competition
costs. We will therefore present our results as a function of these key factors: Sequential
vs. simultaneous is determined by the cost of sex change, protandry vs. protogyny is
determined by the cost of competition; in this case we show how reproductive resource
γRaffects the size of the sexual inversion.
Sequential vs. simultaneous is determined by the cost of sex change In this paragraph,
we analyze how the existence of simultaneous or sequential strategies depend on the
two sex change costs, RFM and RMF.
Sex change is caused by physiological and hormonal complications of restructuring
gonads and reproducing as both sexes (Charnov and Bull 1985;Hoffman et al. 1985).
We understand that these processes are costly and maybe limiting the number of change
sex. For that, we plot the effect of different sex change costs, RFM and RMF,onthe
distribution of strategies (Fig. 2). We observe three main regions (1)–(3). We note that
an increase of RMF moves the population from region (1) containing simultaneous
hermaphrodite (i.e., the two cooperative strategies) and pure male—to region, (2)
containing pure males and pure females (i.e., the two non-cooperatives strategies) and
simultaneous hermaphrodites (i.e., cooperative female)—or region (3) containing only
sequential hermaphrodite (i.e., pure male and female with larger individual are male
a smaller one are female). Moreover, as RFM increases, the population moves from
region (2) to (3). We noted that, in regions (2) and (3) larger individual weights cost
of sex change by gain fitness. Actually, the increase of one of the sex changing cost,
both cooperatives strategies are replaced by non cooperative ones (pure female, pure
male or sequential hermaphrodite). Indeed, individual seems to loose “plasticity” and
adopt a more robust strategy.
Furthermore, we note that the pure (non cooperative) male strategy exists for almost
every value of RFM and RMF. This result is not surprising because pure male is a not
costly strategy (competition cost is weak or zero).
Protandry vs. protogyny is determined by the cost of competition In this paragraph we
analyze the effect of competition cost, γC, and female reproductive resource, γRon
123
Author's personal copy
A. Kebir et al.
4 5 6 7 8 9 10
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
C(s1,s2)
s1
s2
10
15
20
25
30
35
(a) γC=2.
4 5 6 7 8 9 10
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
C(s1,s2)
s1
s2
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
(b) γC=0.
4 5 6 7 8 9 10
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
C(s1,s2)
s1
s2
10
15
20
25
30
35
(c) γC=2.
Fig. 1 Graph of function C(s1,s2)for γC∈{2,0,2},ρC=10 and σC=1.5. aγC=−2. bγC=0. cγC=2
123
Author's personal copy
Understanding hermaphrodite species through game theory
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
Sex chg. cost:
female to male
Sex chg. cost:
male to female
Coop.
female to male
Simul. herm.
with pure female
Mixed 4
strategies
Sequential herm. with
coop. male to female
Simul. herm
Region 3: Sequential hermaphrodite
Region2 : Sequential herm.
with coop. female to
male
Region1 : Simultaneous herm. with male
Fig. 2 Effect of sex change costs on the sex distribution. (With smin =4, smax =10, ρC=10, γC=−1, σC=1.5, ρR=1andγR=2)
123
Author's personal copy
A. Kebir et al.
γC
γR
−4 −3.5 −3 −2.5 −2 −1.5 −1 −0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4
−4
−3.5
−3
−2.5
−2
−1.5
−1
−0.5
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
3
3.5
4
Gonochoristic
Pure Protandrous
Pure Protogynous
Protogynous with
two sexual
inversion
Gonochoristic
Fig.3 Effect of male competition and reproductiveresource on sexual strategy distribution. (With smin =4,
smax =10, ρC=10, σC=1.5, ρR=1andRFM =RMF =15)
the direction of the sexual inversion (protogynous and protandrous) distribution in the
case where costs of sex change are higher (where RFM and RMF areinregion1).For
that, as a first analysis , we plot the direction of sexual inversion (Fig. 3), female to male
(protogynous) or male to female (protandrous), and the number of sexual inversions,
for different values of competition coefficient γC∈[4,4]and reproductive function
exponent γR∈[4,4].
We notice that we have pure strategies (i.e., only one sexual inversion) only
if |γC|>0.2 and |γR|<3.5: For a positive value of γC, competition cost is
size-increasing and thus larger males prefer to become female to avoid competi-
tion cost, thus change sex at a size where payoff becomes negative, and hence
adopt the protandrous strategy. For a negative value of γC, competition cost is
size-decreasing and thus larger males pay less energy for competition than smaller
individuals, and hence adopt the protogynous strategy. Moreover, the transition
from protandrous to protogynous strategies for γC∈[0.2,0.2]is accompa-
nied by an increase in the number of sexual inversions until reaching protogy-
nous region as γCpasses from negative to positive. Moreover, if |γR|>3.5
then the gonogoristic strategy (i.e., male and female without sexual inversion)
exists.
Finally, knowing that protandrous or protogynous strategies depend only on the
sign of the competition coefficient γC, then, in a second analysis, we study how
the reproductive resource γRaffects the size of the sexual inversion for protoge-
neous stage C<0)and protandrous one C>0)in the Fig. 4. In fact when the
reproductive function is a decreasing function R<0), we notice that the size at
sexual inversion increases for protogynous (respectively decreases for protandrous)
as γRincreases, and the reverse happens when the reproductive function increases
R>0).
123
Author's personal copy
Understanding hermaphrodite species through game theory
−3 −2 −1 0 1 2 3 4
4
4.5
5
5.5
6
6.5
7
7.5
8
8.5
γR
size
Fig. 4 Size of sexual inversion for Protogynous scenarios (i.e., Cdecreasing) depending on monotonicity
of the function R. (With smin =4, smax =10, ρC=10, γC=−3.5, σC=1.5, ρR=1andRFM =
RMF =15)
4 Discussion and conclusion
In this work, we developed a size-structured dynamical game model. The main result
is the Theorem 2.1 that was used to understand how the competition and the sexual
inversion costs can influence sexual types.
Our model emphasizes the relationship between reproductive energy and gamete
production cost as SAH models (Cadet et al. 2004;Kazancio˘glu and Alonzo 2009).
However, we suppose that sexual inversion is a proximate behavioral trait that can
change from mating to mating. This approach allows us to prove that sexual types
(simultaneous hermaphrodite, sequential hermaphrodite) are a stable strategy of a
dynamical game and not only the result of a global evolutionary process.
Our results show that size effect alone is insufficient to explain the tendency for
copulants to elect the male role and to solve gender conflict. In fact, the solution
requires an understanding of the effects of competition and sex change costs at two
levels: Simultaneous vs sequential and protogynous vs protandrous.
Simultaneous vs sequential hermaphrodites and sex change cost Sex allocation mod-
els for hermaphrodites assume that the optimal allocation to male and female repro-
duction are expected to depend only on the shapes of fitness gain curves of male and
female function through size or age (Leigh et al. 1976;Cadet et al. 2004;Schärer
2009). However, if sex change cost from female to male is very low, nothing prevents
a female from becoming a male when meeting with a female. We observe that, in our
simulations, for a small value of sex change cost, individuals act as cooperative (male
or female) and reproduce symmetrically—alternate male and female roles and trade
123
Author's personal copy
A. Kebir et al.
eggs or sperm ( i.e., gamete trading). This phenomena was observed in diverse groups
as hermaphroditic sea basses (Axelrod and Hamilton 1981) and polychaete worms
(Sella 1985,1988). If the cost of sex change is higher, larger individuals weight cost
of sex change by gain from gamete production and then behaves as sequential her-
maphrodites.
In a global vision, we can classify species having a single sexual organ (i.e., capable
of producing both male and female gametes) compared to the number of sex changes
they may have. We have shown that if costs of sex change are close to 0, species act as
simultaneous hermaphrodite (i.e., presence of only cooperative strategies) by contrast,
if the costs are high, the number of sex changes decrease to one sex change (i.e.,
sequential hermaphrodites) or zero sex changes (i.e., diocies) (figure not shown here).
This result extends a previous result of (Kazancio˘glu and Alonzo 2009) on whether
costs of changing sex can favor dioecy. They suggest that dioecy is favored only when
costs of changing sex are large. Our results also demonstrate that asymmetry of the
cost of sex change (RMF = RFM)causes an asymmetry in the speed of transition
from one to multiple sex changes.
Protogynous vs. protandrous and competition cost We prove in this part, that male
competition and size-based fecundity skew can strongly affect reproductive pay-offs
as in Munoz and Warner (2003). Sexual competition is linked to two type of costs
acting at different levels: sperm competition—expressed through gamete numbers—
and competition by contact (with asymmetric distributed cost, small individuals pay a
higher cost than larger ones)—expressed through Cfunction. We showed that, when
contact competition cost increases, individual adopts successively protogynous then
protandrous strategies. Moreover, in the case of higher competition cost, individual
changes sex at most once. For example, in the protogynous hermaphrodite Serenade,
as Epinephelus marginatus grouper, sex change occurs ones at a fixed size (Bruslé
1985;Marino et al. 2001;Renones et al. 2007). For this species, during mating, we
observed that dominant males established territories where they behave aggressively
towards neighboring males, suggesting a higher cost of competition by contact (Zabala
et al. 1997) and no sperm competition (Marino et al. 2001). While at low population
density, this species is able to sex reverse.
Our results support the idea that sex dimorphism is a consequence of size dependent
contact competition: large males suffer less from competition than small ones. The
same mechanism may lead, in the evolutionary case, to a progressive increase of male
size and explain why in some species the males are much larger than females ((Parker
1983) for haploid reproduction and (Smith and Brown 1986) diploid reproduction).
Our model and Parker (1983) and Smith and Brown (1986) models have similar con-
clusions: when stability is reached, a polymorphic distribution is obtained for the male
trait. This stability is more likely to be reached as the cost of competition between
males having same size increases.
As noted by Brauer et al. (2007), there are three different levels at which sex
allocation can be adjusted. In the first level, the allocation strategy can be the result
of selection and evolution, and thus be an adaptation to the average mating group
size over several generations. In the second case sex allocation is not or not strictly
fixed genetically but is set during ontogeny and therefore influenced by environmental
123
Author's personal copy
Understanding hermaphrodite species through game theory
conditions such as population density (developmental plasticity). Finally, in the third
level sex allocation is not fixed neither during evolution nor ontogeny but evolves
throughout adult life and is adjusted to environmental conditions. In our work we
consider the plasticity of the sex allocation as an Evolutionary Stable Strategy or a
developmental process facilitating evolution (West-Eberhard 2003) (this corresponds
to the third level). This phenotype is generally linked to fluctuating environment (West -
Eberhard 2003) and thus unstable size-structured populations. In this case, Anthes et al.
(2006) and Orr (2007) showed that individuals adopt a short term strategy and optimize
instantaneous reproductive success (e.g., at mating period time scale). Moreover, at
this time scale, the stable size distribution assumption is satisfied.
Our model showed that a dynamic approach that incorporates this type of local social
behavior is more suitable to explain the details of sex changes, and corresponds to those
observed in animal social systems Munday et al. (2006b). The dynamic game approach
was able to reveal more about the dynamic of sex change than purely demographic
models as confirmed by Warner and Munoz (2007). Moreover, model of (Warner and
Munoz 2007) was unable to fit some hermaphrodites species. Their model takes into
account only fecundity differences and sperm competition, and [as seen in Clifton
and Rogers (2008)] those parameters were insufficient to explain some sex inversion
behaviors. We here proved that sex change costs are another factor that can play an
important role in sex change decisions. It should be noted that Clifton and Rogers
suggest that differential mortality may also be an important factor. A natural question
arises then, which one of our results persists at evolutionary time scale? The answer to
this question can be made by integrating demography in our game model and defining
the payoff as a life reproductive success. This question is the aim of our future work.
Acknowledgments AK would like to thank DIMACS at Rutgers University, where most of this work was
done. SBM would like to thank Fulbright program for financial support. The authors would like to thank
the editor and the reviewers for their helpful comments that improve the quality of the manuscript.
Appendix: Proof of Theorem 2.1
Let X=(x
1,...,x
4)an equilibrium point of (1). As for all sS,ix
i(s)=1,
then at equilibrium and for all sSthe system (1) is equivalent to:
x
1(s)((1x
1(s)) f1,4(s,X(s))x
2(s)f2,4(s,X(s)) x
3(s)f3,4(s,X(s))) =0
x
2(s)((1x
2(s)) f2,4(s,X(s))x
1(s)f1,4(s,X(s)) x
3(s)f3,4(s,X(s))) =0
x
3(s)((1x
3(s)) f3,4(s,X(s))x
1(s)f1,4(s,X(s)) x
2(s)f2,4(s,X(s))) =0
(15)
where fi,4=(fif4), i{1...3}.
Now, let {Ai}i=1...4a partition of Sand let x
i(s)=1Ai(s), i∈{1,...,4},we
have then sS:
x
1(s)x
2(s)=x
1(s)x
3(s)=x
2(s)x
3(s)=0,
x
1(s)(1x
1(s)) =x
2(s)(1x
2(s)) =x
3(s)(1x
3(s)) =0 and
x
1(s)+x
2(s)+x
3(s)+x
4(s)=1 (16)
123
Author's personal copy
A. Kebir et al.
Using latter Eq. (16), we can easily prove that for all sS,X(s)satisfies (15)
and that the Jacobian matrix, J, of the system (1) at the equilibrium point Xis:
J(X)=
j(X(s0)) 0··· 0
0.......
.
.
.
.
.......0
0··· 0j(X(smax))
(17)
Where sS,
j(X(s)) =
λ1(s)x
1(s)f2,4(s,X(s)) x
1(s)f3,4(s,X(s))
x
2(s)f1,4(s,X(s)) λ2(s)x
2(s)f3,4(s,X(s))
x
3(s)f1,4(s,X(s)) x
3(s)f2,4(s,X(s)) λ3(s)
(18)
and
λ1(s)=(12x
1(s)) f1,4(s,X(s)) x
2(s)f2,4(s,X(s)) x
3(s)f3,4(s,X(s))
λ2(s)=(12x
2(s)) f2,4(s,X(s)) x
1(s)f1,4(s,X(s)) x
3(s)f3,4(s,X(s))
λ3(s)=(12x
3(s)) f3,4(s,X(s)) x
1(s)f1,4(s,X(s)) x
2(s)f2,4(s,X(s))
Therefore, the characteristic polynomial of (18)is,
det(J(X(s)) λI)=
sS
det(j(X(s)) λ(s)I3)=0.
and then sS,λ1(s), λ2(s)and λ3(s)are the eigenvalues of the matrix (17).
Finally, by following we replace the value of Xand we show that i
{1,...,4}and sAi:
{λj(s), j∈{1,2,3}} = {(fjfi)(s,X(s)), j∈{1,2,3}\i}
which prove the result in Theorem 2.1.
References
Angeloni L (2003) Sexual selection in a simultaneous hermaphrodite with hypodermic insemination: body
size, allocation to sexual roles and paternity. Anim Behav 66(3):417–426
Angeloni L, Bradbury JW, Charnov EL (2002) Body size and sex allocation in simultaneously her-
maphroditic animals. Behav Ecol 13(3):419–426
Anthes N, Putz A, Michiels NK (2006) Sex role preferences, gender conflict and sperm trading in simulta-
neous hermaphrodites: a new framework. Anim Behav 72(1):1–12
Axelrod R, Hamilton WD (1981) The evolution of cooperation. Sci New Ser 211(4489):1390–1396
Ben Miled S, Kebir A, Hbid ML (2010) Individual based model for grouper populations. Acta Biotheor
58(2–3):247–64
Brauer VS, Schärer L, Michiels NK (2007) Phenotypically flexible sex allocation in a simultaneous her-
maphrodite. Evolution 61(1):216–222
123
Author's personal copy
Understanding hermaphrodite species through game theory
Bruslé J (1985) Synopsis of biological data on the groupers epinephelus aeneus (geoffrey saint hilaire,
1809) and epinephelus guaza (linnaeus, 1758) of the atlantic ocean and mediterranean sea. FAO Fish
Synop 129:1–69
Cadet C, Metz JAJ, Klinkhamer PGL (2004) Size and the not-so-single sex: disentangling the effects of
size and budget on sex allocation in hermaphrodites. Am Nat 164(6):779–792
Charnov EL (1979) Simultaneous hermaphroditism and sexual selection. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA
76(5):2480–2484
Charnov EL (1982) The theory of sex allocation. In: Monogr popul biol, vol 18. Princeton University Press,
Princeton
Charnov EL, Bull JJ (1985) Sex allocation in a patchy environment: a marginal value theorem. J Theor Biol
115(4):619–624
Clifton KE, Rogers L (2008) Sex-specific mortality explains non-sex-change by large female Sparisoma
radians. Anim Behav 75(2):e1–e10. doi:10.1016/j.anbehav.2007.06.025
DeWitt TJ (1996) Gender contests in a simultaneous hermaphrodite snail: a size-advantage model for
behaviour. Anim Behav 51(2):345–351
Fischer EA (1988) Simultaneous hermaphroditism, tit-for-tat, and the evolutionary stability of social sys-
tems. Ethol Sociobiol 9(2–4):119–136
Ghiselin MT (1969) The evolution of hermaphroditism among animals. Q Rev Biol 44:189–208
Hardy ICW (2009) Sex ratios: concepts and research methods. Princeton University Press, Princeton
Hofbauer J, Sigmund K (1998) Evolutionary games and population dynamics. Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge
Hoffman SG, Schildhauer MP, Warner RR (1985) The costs of changing sex and the ontogeny of males
under contest competition for mates. Evolution (NY) 39(4):915–927. doi:10.2307/2408690
Kazancio˘glu E, Alonzo SH (2009) Costs of changing sex do not explain why sequential hermaphroditism
is rare. Am Nat 173(3):327–36
Kebir A, Ben Miled S, Hbid ML, Bravo de la Parra R (2010) Effects of density dependent sex allocation
on the dynamics of a simultaneous hermaphroditic population: modelling and analysis. J Theor Biol
263(4):521–9
Leigh EG, Charnov EL, Warner RR (1976) Sex ratio, sex change, and natural selection. Proc Natl Acad Sci
USA 73(10):3656–3660
Leonard JL (1990) The Hermaphrodite’s Dilemma. J Theor Biol 147(3):361–371
Marino G, Casalotti V, Azzurro E, Massari A, Finoia MG, Mandich A (2001) Reproduction in the dusky
grouper from the southern Mediterranean. J Fish Biol 58(4):909–927
Munday PL, Buston PM, Warner RR (2006a) Diversity and flexibility of sex-change strategies in animals.
Trends Ecol Evol 21(2):89–95
Munday PL, Wilson WJ, Warner RR (2006b) A social basis for the development of primary males in a
sex-changing fish. Proc Biol Sci 273(1603):2845–2851
Munoz RC, WarnerRR (2003) A new version of the size-advantage hypothesis for sex change: incorporating
sperm competition and size-fecundity skew. Am Nat 161(5):749–761
Nakamura M, Bhandari R, Higa M (2003) The role estrogens play in sex differentiation and sex changes
of fish. Fish Physiol Biochem 28(1–4):113–117
Okumura S (2001) Evidence of sex reversal towards both directions in reared red spotted grouper
Epinephelus akaarai. Fish Sci 67(3):535–537
Orr HA (2007) Absolute fitness, relative fitness and utility. Evolution 61(12):2997–3000
Parker G (1983) Arms races in evolution—an ESS to the opponent-independent costs game. J Theor Biol
101(4):619–648
Reñones O, Grau A, Mas X, Riera F, Saborido-Rey F (2010) Reproductive pattern of an exploited dusky
grouper Epinephelus marginatus (Lowe 1834) (Pisces: Serranidae) population in the western Mediter-
ranean. Sci Mar 74(3):523–537. doi:10.3989/scimar.2010.74n3523
Schärer L (2009) Tests of sex allocation theory in simultaneously hermaphroditic animals. Evolution
63(6):1377–405
Sella G (1985) Reciprocal egg trading and brood care in a hermaphroditic polychaete worm. Anim Behav
33(3):938–944
Sella G (1988) Reciprocation, reproductive success, and safeguards against cheating in a hermaphroditic
polychaete worm, Ophryotrocha diadema Akesson, 1976. Biol Bull 175(2):212–217
Smith JM, Brown RL (1986) Competition and body size. Theor Popul Biol 30(2):166–179
123
Author's personal copy
A. Kebir et al.
St Mary CM (1994) Sex allocation in a simultaneous hermaphrodite, the blue-banded goby (Lythrypnus
dalli): the effects of body size and behavioral gender and the consequences for reproduction. Behav
Ecol 5(3):304–313
St Mary CM (1997) Sequential patterns of sex allocation in simultaneous hermaphrodites: do we need
models that specifically incorporate this complexity. Am Nat 150(1):73–97
Warner RR (1988) Sex change and the size-advantage model. Trends Ecol Evol 3(6):133–136
Warner RR, Munoz RC (2007) Needed: a dynamic approach to understand sex change. Anim Behav
75(2):11–14. doi:10.1016/j.anbehav.2007.10.013
West-Eberhard MJ (2003) Developmental plasticity and evolution. Oxford University Press, New York
Wethington AR, Dillon J, Robert T (1996) Gender choice and gender conflict in a non-reciprocally mating
simultaneous hermaphrodite, the freshwater snail, Physa. Anim Behav 51(5):1107–1118
Zabala M, Louisy P, Garcia-Rubies A, Gracia V (1997) Socio-behavioural context of reproduction in the
mediterranean dusky grouper epinephelus marginatus (lowe, 1834) (pisces, serranidae) in the medes
islands marine reserve (nw mediterranean, spain). Sci Mar 61(1):65–77
123
Author's personal copy
... Therefore, here, using game theory, we investigate the origin of stability of different kinds of hermaphroditism in general, such as sequential and simultaneous hermaphrodites. In our previous study ( Kebir et al., 2015 ), we constructed and analyzed a general dynamical game model structured by size and sex that we refer to as the instantaneous game (IG) model. The main objective is to study how and when sexual strategies ( i.e. a sequential hermaphrodite or simultaneous hermaphrodite) are stable when sex is viewed as a flexible function. ...
... A behavior decision depends on direct cues in the environment ( i.e. decisions based on local information) or instead depends on long-term fitness, even if each independent decision does not maximize fitness within the immediate environmental context ( i.e. choices made to maximize long-term payoffs, focusing on global system outcomes). To this end, we contrast the analysis of the already-presented IG model ( Kebir et al., 2015 ) with the formulation of a new model called the residual game (RG) model. Our goal is to determine how these types of fitness shape the evolutionary stability of hermaphroditic species. ...
... On the basis of these concepts, we present a new model called the residual game (RG) model, where payoffs are based on an evaluation of mean fitness: precisely the potential reproductive value, RV ( Keyfitz and Caswell, 2005 ). We assess the potential reproductive value through "instantaneous fitness"-that takes into account sexual competition cost and/or sex change cost-defined in ref. ( Kebir et al., 2015 ) via the instantaneous game (IG) model. ...
... This section is concerned with hermaphrodites, where the way of expressing the reproductive role can vary. For instance, males can change to females (protandry) or females can change to males (protogyny), as stated in [38][39][40]. The clownfish (genus Amphiprion) is an example of a colourful reef fish that lives in a symbiotic relationship with sea anemones, while wrasses (Family Labridae) are a type of reef fish where protogyny is prevalent. ...
... Sequential hermaphroditism is when organisms experience multiple sex changes throughout their lifetime [39,40]. For instance, the California sheephead wrasse is a coral reef fish that can change from male to female if they are unsuccessful in reproduction and from female to male to maintain flexibility when they exhibit submissive behaviour. ...
Article
Full-text available
Small factors are the biggest contributors to the biggest changes in an ecosystem which may lead to its demise. Simple things such as tweaking the humidity or tampering with the temperature can be the downfall of the habitants and the ecosystem itself. These changes can be observed right now with the consistent temperature increase on Earth along with the slew of issues that come with global warming. A small change in a few degrees in temperature can perish an entire food supply and the habitat of many already endangered beings forcing them to either adapt or die. Within such an ecosystem the main reason it withstands the test of time boils down to one simple thing; reproduction. This creates the natural question of asking oneself: How does an ecosystem replenish itself and is able to resist collapsing? To even begin considering this thought, one must realise that the size of the population is the key to gaining a deeper understanding as two constituents that are important from evolutionary theory are survival and reproduction. The case of asexual reproducers, it is not difficult to see any alterations that can be introduced to increase reproductivity. Meanwhile, for sexual reproducers, the evolution to increase reproductivity can be observed by looking into the generational data of the species. A certain group of time-based dynamic systems that are connected to a sexual system are the point of contention. The suggested model is a dynamic representation of a hermaphrodite population which is explored using F-quadratic stochastic operators. The key findings offer fresh insights into the future of hermaphrodite populations, that is perhaps a probable solution to prevent the decline of endangered or at-risk species.
... We then calculated MSY, B MSY , and male/female ratios for a protogynous stock using the same population model described above, but also allowing females to change sex. Sex change occurred according to a game theoretic payoff defined by the fitness and energy loss associated with the decision to change sex or not following a size dependent dynamical game (Kebir et al., 2015). We are focused on protogynous species; therefore size is used as a proxy for reproductive value as size is strongly related to male reproductive value in protogynous species (e.g. ...
... Hamaguchi et al., 2002). Kebir et al. (2015) showed that size dependent models of sex change alone may not be sufficient to accurately characterize the timing of sex change, and that the penalty of changing sex must be included. Therefore, sex change will occur, or not, based on the reproductive output at her current size rather than her size in the next year. ...
Article
Full-text available
Sex change has been widely documented in many commercially and recreationally important fish species, yet the implications of this life history trait are not considered in most stock assessments. This omission can lead to poor estimates of parameters vital to understanding the health of sequentially hermaphroditic stocks. Here, we present a game theoretic approach to model the sex changing behaviour of a stock of protogynous (female first) hermaphroditic fish and produce estimates of maximum sustainable yield (MSY), equilibrium biomass at MSY (B MSY) and sex ratio, then compare these reference points to those from an otherwise identical gonochoristic (non-sex changing) stock. We tested each stock at varying levels of exploitation and with a range of assumptions about how sex ratio impacts fertilization rate. We show that a protogynous hermaphroditic stock with flexible timing of sex change produces similar MSY and slightly higher B MSY than a gonochoris-tic stock with otherwise identical vital rates. Sex changing stocks were also able to maintain a higher proportion of males in the population than did non-sex changing stocks as exploitation increased. Although sex changing stocks were able to maintain their sex ratio, the age at which females changed sex decreased with increased exploitation, suggesting smaller body size, and presumably lower fecundity, for females in heavily exploited sex changing stocks. Our game theoretic approach to evaluating hermaphroditic stocks can accommodate a wide variety of sex changing cues and behaviours and allows a flexible model for understanding the effects of exploitation on hermaphroditic stocks.
... If a pair has the same gender, the benefits of mating will be zero. Researchers have developed two game models, the Instantaneous Game (IG) model (Kebir et al. 2015) and the Residual Game (RG) model, to study the problem of sex reversal in hermaphroditic fish during mating. It has been confirmed that pure strategies and cooperative strategies depend on fitness evaluation. ...
... A rigorous mathematical analysis of equilibrium states in infinite populations can be found in Cushing (1998). See also Kebir et al. (2010Kebir et al. ( , 2015 for the role of life-history parameters on sex allocation in hermaphroditic species. Notice that aggregation methods to take into account two timescales have been applied to infinite age-structured populations in a patchy environment with a migration process assumed to be fast in comparison to the demographic process [see Auger et al. (2008) and references therein, and also Marvà and San Segundo (2018)], and in a game-theoretic framework with the game dynamics assumed to be faster than the demographic dynamics (Marvà et al. 2013). ...
Article
Full-text available
In this paper, we ascertain the validity of a diffusion approximation for the frequencies of different types under recurrent mutation and frequency-dependent viability and fertility selection in a haploid population with a fixed age-class structure in the limit of a large population size. The approximation is used to study, and explain in terms of selection coefficients, reproductive values and population-structure coefficients, the differences in the effects of viability versus fertility selection on the fixation probability of an advantageous mutant.
... Nous supposons dans notre modèle que la femelle ne peut se reproduire qu'avec un mâle plus gros qu'elle, exprimant un mécanisme bien connu dans les types d'accouplement de harem chez les poissons [Munday et al., 2006]. Nous notons que des modèles plus sophistiqués ont été utilisés par [Munoz and Warner, 2003] pour le type d'accouplement de harem et par [Kebir et al., 2015] pour le système d'accouplement de lekking. ...
Thesis
Full-text available
The objective of this thesis is to propose an approach for coupling metabolic and ecological levels in a complex biological system. This approach is presented as formal model describing the organism metabolism , which, thanks to DEVS formalism (Discrete Event System Specification), allows a coupling with models of interaction between organisms and between organisms and their environment. A study of the different modeling paradigms allowed us to identify, on the one hand the appropriate paradigm for each level and on the other hand the coupling factors formed by the variables at the interface of individual's internal and external worlds. This coupling explores the effect of lower-level dynamics on the emergence of higher-level characteristics. Two multiagent models, the first on sexual allocation and the second on optimal foraging, concretize the physiology/ecology coupling and show that this coupling makes it possible to connect the individual's internal world with its external world. The strong coupling, in the sense of model integration, explored in a first phase, was improved by the proposal of a formal model, called DEB-DEVS, of the metabolic model (of the Dynamic Energy Budget Theory (DEB)) common to the previous models. This proposal is the result of a reflection on the representation of internal dynamics of agents in ecological models. DEB-DEVS has been illustrated by two classical models of theoretical ecology.
... Local stability analyses were also used, e.g., in Kebir et al. (2010) to study a mathematical model describing the dynamics of a hermaphroditic species where sex allocation is density-dependent so that the fractions of immature individuals acquiring male and female sexual roles as adults depend on current environmental conditions. In a follow up paper (Kebir et al. 2015), the stability of sexual strategies of a hermaphrodite (simultaneous or sequential, protandrous or protogynous) in a stable size-structured population distributed over a finite set of sizes is analyzed taking into account the effects of costs due to sexual competition and sex change. Notice, however, that matrix models for size-structured populations have been criticized because their outputs, and in particular the population growth rate, are sensitive to the dimension of the matrix or, equivalently, to the class width (Picard and Liang 2014). ...
Article
Full-text available
In this paper we consider class-structured populations in discrete time in the limit of weak selection and with the inverse of the intensity of selection as unit of time. The aim is to establish a continuous model that approximates the discrete model. More precisely, we study frequency-dependent growth in an infinite haploid population structured into a finite number of classes such that individuals in each class contribute to a given subset of classes from one time step to the next. These contributions take the form of generalized fecundity parameters with perturbations of order 1 / N that depends on the class frequencies of each type and the type frequencies. Moreover, they satisfy some mild conditions that ensure mixing in the long run. The dynamics in the limit as NN \rightarrow \infty with N time steps as unit of time is considered first in the case of a single type, and second in the case of multiple types. The main result is that the type frequencies as NN \rightarrow \infty obey the replicator equation with instantaneous growth rates for the different types that depend only on instantaneous equilibrium class frequencies and reproductive values. An application to evolutionary game theory complemented by simulation results is presented.
Article
Size-advantage hypothesis models (SAH) allow an understanding of which sex occurs first and when the sex is changed in hermaphrodite species, through the optimal allocation of energy in terms of male versus female roles. Whereas sex allocation depends directly on how an organism allocates energy throughout its lifetime, the dynamic energy budget theory (DEB), describes the uptake and use of energy and nutrients, as well as the physiological organization throughout an organism’s life cycle, including growth, maintenance, reproduction, and aging. We propose an evolutionary individual-based model to bridge the gap between metabolic models and the sexual allocation model. In this paper, we describe an individual-based model used to study the size at the time of a sex change/maximum size, i.e., Lratio and the most important physiological factors influencing size at the time of a sex change, Lchangei. We show that the fraction that determines how much to invest in somatic maintenance and growth, κ, the cost of the structure relative to the energy allocated to the soma, and the somatic maintenance rate coefficient are the most influential factors. We also show that the ratio between male and female gamete costs has very little influence on Lchangei and Lratio.
Conference Paper
A major challenge in ecological modeling of complex living system, is the integration of different models that describe the same phenomenon at different levels (physiological and ecological levels). The multi-agent paradigm provides an intuitive approach to model and simulate individual metabolism (Dynamic Energy Budget (DEB) model) and sexual behavior (Sex allocation model) and connect them to population-level proprieties. In this work, we model the energetic and sexual behavior of hermaphrodite species to determine the optimal size of sex change. For this purpose, we consider population dynamics and individuals evolutionary traits. Sex change size is seen as an emerging traits from both the set of intra-individual physiological traits, and inter-individual interactions. We develop an evolutionary individual-based model implementing these two models with a simple genetic algorithm to determine the optimal sex change size. The model description follows the ODD (Overview, Design concepts, Details) protocol, it is simulated with NetLogo platform and it is parametrized for Dusky grouper (Epinephelus marginatus). For this hermaphrodite species, both growth and maturation predicted by the model fit well with field observations.
Article
Full-text available
Spawning of the Mediterranean dusky grouper Epinephelus marginatus (Lowe, 1834) was observed for the first time in summer 1996 during scuba diving surveys in the Medes Islands Marine Reserve (NW Mediterranean). Ten spawning events were observed, which occurred at sunset, in the evenings around the new moon of August. A mature female (usually between 50 and 75 cm TL), in the standard mottled colour pattern, and a larger (more than 100 cm long) dominant male, in a conspicuous silver streaked colour-pattern, ascended up to 12 m side by side, spiralling in an anti-clockwise direction two or three times, from the bottom to shallow warmer waters, where the ova and sperm are released. Some traits of variability over this common pattern of spawning are described. Predation by saddled bream Oblada melanura, which concentrate in great numbers after each spawning suggests a very low survival of the spawned eggs.
Book
The first comprehensive synthesis on development and evolution: it applies to all aspects of development, at all levels of organization and in all organisms, taking advantage of modern findings on behavior, genetics, endocrinology, molecular biology, evolutionary theory and phylogenetics to show the connections between developmental mechanisms and evolutionary change. This book solves key problems that have impeded a definitive synthesis in the past. It uses new concepts and specific examples to show how to relate environmentally sensitive development to the genetic theory of adaptive evolution and to explain major patterns of change. In this book development includes not only embryology and the ontogeny of morphology, sometimes portrayed inadequately as governed by "regulatory genes," but also behavioral development and physiological adaptation, where plasticity is mediated by genetically complex mechanisms like hormones and learning. The book shows how the universal qualities of phenotypes--modular organization and plasticity--facilitate both integration and change. Here you will learn why it is wrong to describe organisms as genetically programmed; why environmental induction is likely to be more important in evolution than random mutation; and why it is crucial to consider both selection and developmental mechanism in explanations of adaptive evolution. This book satisfies the need for a truly general book on development, plasticity and evolution that applies to living organisms in all of their life stages and environments. Using an immense compendium of examples on many kinds of organisms, from viruses and bacteria to higher plants and animals, it shows how the phenotype is reorganized during evolution to produce novelties, and how alternative phenotypes occupy a pivotal role as a phase of evolution that fosters diversification and speeds change. The arguments of this book call for a new view of the major themes of evolutionary biology, as shown in chapters on gradualism, homology, environmental induction, speciation, radiation, macroevolution, punctuation, and the maintenance of sex. No other treatment of development and evolution since Darwin's offers such a comprehensive and critical discussion of the relevant issues. Developmental Plasticity and Evolution is designed for biologists interested in the development and evolution of behavior, life-history patterns, ecology, physiology, morphology and speciation. It will also appeal to evolutionary paleontologists, anthropologists, psychologists, and teachers of general biology.
Article
In its simplest form, the size-advantage hypothesis predicts that individuals should change sex in order to increase their reproductive success. In terms of lifetime expectations, this must be true for the hypothesis to hold. However, as we review here, some loss of reproductive success may occur immediately after sex change. Unavoidable costs (e.g., those resulting from a restructuring of the gonad) have not been adequately distinguished from adaptive allocations of resources which diminish current reproduction in favor of large increases in future mating success. This strategy can become particularly important for species in which a few males monopolize matings. To illustrate this idea, we describe the changes in mating frequency as mature females become sexually active males in three species of protogynous wrasses. In one species, a male defends a permanent, all-purpose territory composed of up to 12 females. When he is removed, a single female changes sex and successfully completes mating sequences with all females in the territory within an average of 5.6 days. This duration roughly corresponds to the time required for functional transformation of gonads; thus, individuals in this species suffer few reproductive losses as a result of changing sex. The largest males in two other species mate with an average of 25 to 50 females per day, but only by successfully defending reproductive territories. In one of those species, individuals that changed sex mated infrequently over a two-year period after sexual transformation and, by the end of the study, were still well below the average size of males that consistently obtained territories. Sex-changed individuals in the other species had very low reproductive success for up to 45% of the maximum lifespan as a male. It is improbable that the substantial cost of changing sex in the latter two species results from gonad restructuring or from mistakes due to imprecise cues for sex change. Instead, the cost appears to represent an investment in growth rather than current reproduction as a means of rapidly attaining a size advantage when individuals face intense competition for extraordinarily successful mating territories.
Article
Adaptive gender expression in simultaneous hermaphrodites will reflect the relative costs and benefits of each sexual function. The net gain through either or both functions may vary with body size. Shell length measurements of Physa gyrina and P. heterostropha in the laboratory and P. heterostropha in the field revealed that successful mating generally involved smaller sperm donors and larger recipients. In contrast, attempts by larger snails to donate sperm were contested by smaller snails. These data suggest substantial plasticity in gender expression in accordance with a game-theoretic extension of Ghiselin's (1969, . Rev. Biol., 44, 189-208, 1974; The Economy of Nature and the Evolution of Sex) size-advantage model. Specifically, the larger of two interacting snails is more fecund, so the smaller snail has more to gain by donating sperm. This asymmetry creates a contest in which the smaller snail can afford to escalate the contest more and still profit, so long as escalation costs are not greater for the smaller snail. In the present study, the usual form of contest escalation was a visually obvious shell-swinging display, which attracts predators. Thus, the smaller of two contestants can use the risk of predation as a weapon in Contest escalations (i.e. a game of chicken), rather than using a purely physical contest that might favour the larger contestant. (C) 1996 The Association for the Study of Animal Behaviour
Article
Like freshwater pulmonate snails in general, mature Physa heterostropha pomilia (Say) are hermaphroditic but cannot reciprocally inseminate each other simultaneously. One member of a pair assumes the male role and the other the female, after which swapping may occur. The tendency for a pair of prospective copulants to elect the same sexual role was defined as gender conflict, and distinguished from sexual conflict, the more widely noted tendency for females to reject low-quality males. Experiments assessed whether previous reproductive history affected the likelihood of mating and the sexual role assumed and evaluated the strength of gender and sexual conflicts. Snails were selected from isofemale lines fixed for albinism at two complementary loci. Ten pairings were made involving all combinations of four categories of reproductive history: previously selfing virgin, not previously selfing virgin, previously selfing mated, and not previously selfing mated. Encounter times, evasive behaviours, and polarity of mating were recorded. Results suggested that the probability of initiating copulation as male in any encounter increased with autosperm store, and that snails mounted as female may decrease the overall probability of mating by rejective behaviour when their reserves of allosperm are high. There was no evidence that snails ever use any mechanism to increase their likelihood of being mounted as female. Evasive behaviours observed in encounters between virgin snails were best attributed to male-male gender conflict, but such behaviour patterns seemed to derive from sexual conflict when virgin snails encountered previously mated snails. Male-male gender conflict did not, however, detectably lengthen contact times, lead to bouts of sperm trading or ultimately lower mating success. (C) 1996 The Association for the Study of Animal Behaviour.
Article
Adaptive gender expression in simultaneous hermaphrodites will reflect the relative costs and benefits of each sexual function. The net gain through either or both functions may vary with body size. Shell length measurements ofPhysa gyrinaandP. heterostrophain the laboratory andP. heterostrophain the field revealed that successful mating generally involved smaller sperm donors and larger recipients. In contrast, attempts by larger snails to donate sperm were contested by smaller snails. These data suggest substantial plasticity in gender expression in accordance with a game-theoretic extension of Ghiselin’s (1969,Q. Rev. Biol.,44,189–208, 1974;The Economy of Nature and the Evolution of Sex) size-advantage model. Specifically, the larger of two interacting snails is more fecund, so the smaller snail has more to gain by donating sperm. This asymmetry creates a contest in which the smaller snail can afford to escalate the contest more and still profit, so long as escalation costs are not greater for the smaller snail. In the present study, the usual form of contest escalation was a visually obvious shell-swinging display, which attracts predators. Thus, the smaller of two contestants can use the risk of predation as a weapon in contest escalations (i.e. a game of chicken), rather than using a purely physical contest that might favour the larger contestant.