ArticlePDF Available

Paying for nature: What every conservationist should know about political economy

Authors:
  • St. Catharine's College, University of Cambridge

Abstract

Global conservation policy and global capitalism have become increasingly intertwined over the last decade. The move towards ‘green capitalism’ has manifested itself in diverse ways, most notably in the expansion of payments for environmental services and attempts to commodify nature. However, there are concerns that prioritizing the financial value of nature could undermine efforts to conserve biodiversity. One particularly strong set of critiques has emerged from political economy. While providing rich theoretical and empirical insights into the potential downsides of green capitalism, the literature is often dense and difficult for non-specialists to navigate. Here I review and translate its main concepts and critiques for a conservation audience. I begin by exploring the basic process of commodity exchange. I then consider nature as a reluctant and uncooperative commodity that often requires new institutions and technologies to be commodified. This means conservation organizations play a key role in green capitalism's political economy. These developments are likely to have considerable social and environmental impacts, with a highly uneven distribution of costs and benefits.
http://journals.cambridge.org Downloaded: 01 Apr 2015 IP address: 128.232.239.148
Paying for nature: what every conservationist should
know about political economy
IVAN R. SCALES
Abstract Global conservation policy and global capitalism
have become increasingly intertwined over the last decade.
The move towards green capitalismhas manifested itself in
diverse ways, most notably in the expansion of payments for
environmental services and attempts to commodify nature.
However, there are concerns that prioritizing the nancial
value of nature could undermine eorts to conserve
biodiversity. One particularly strong set of critiques has
emerged from political economy. While providing rich
theoretical and empirical insights into the potential down-
sides of green capitalism, the literature is often dense and
dicult for non-specialists to navigate. Here I review and
translate its main concepts and critiques for a conservation
audience. I begin by exploring the basic process of
commodity exchange. I then consider nature as a reluctant
and uncooperative commodity that often requires new
institutions and technologies to be commodied. This
means conservation organizations play a key role in green
capitalisms political economy. These developments are
likely to have considerable social and environmental
impacts, with a highly uneven distribution of costs and
benets.
Keywords Environmental values, green capitalism, market
environmentalism, neoliberal conservation, payments for
environmental services
Introduction
Inaneort to address conicts between economic growth
and the maintenance of biological diversity, global
conservation policy and global capitalism have become
increasingly intertwined over the last decade. The idea that
capitalism can and should help conservation is now
mainstream (Brockington & Duy, 2010). This trend has
manifested itself in diverse ways, including partnerships
between conservation non-governmental organizations
(NGOs) and large corporations to help reduce and oset
the environmental impacts of their activities (Burgin, 2008;
Seagle, 2012), conservation NGOs playing a key role in the
expansion of payments for environmental services such as
carbon sequestration (McGregor, 2010; Fisher, 2012), and
NGOs promoting and managing ecotourism as a way of
generating funds for conservation (West & Carrier, 2004;
Duy, 2006).
These developments can be seen as part of a broader
trend of trying to greencapitalism (Prudham, 2009; Igoe
et al., 2010). Green capitalism is based on the belief that
environmental degradation is largely the result of the failure
of markets to reect the environmental costs of production
and consumption and the value of natural capital. Following
on from this, private property and the assignment of
economic values to the environment are seen as the best
way to manage natural resources (Anderson & Leal, 2001;
Farber et al., 2002). Green capitalist policies are presented
as winwin solutions, with the potential to create oppor-
tunities for economic growth, incentives for the mainten-
ance of biological diversity, and nancial support for
conservation activities (Ferraro, 2011). Placing an emphasis
on the economic value of nature is often put forward as
the only realistic and pragmatic way of explaining
the importance of conservation to policy-makers and
business leaders and achieving conservation goals (Igoe
et al., 2010).
The implicit assumption behind capitalism generally,
and green capitalism more specically, is that it is the system
best suited to the real world of scarce natural resources and
unlimited human wants (Gowdy et al., 2010). This argument
is based on the presumption that only through pricing
will people understand the value of nature and therefore
act responsibly (Roberts, 2008). These ideas have resulted in
growing eorts to commodify nature (Igoe et al., 2010;
Fairhead et al., 2012).
The increasingly close relationship between conservation
and capitalism has led to growing concerns among some
conservationists that conservation is selling out on nature
(McCauley, 2006). There are worries that important
intrinsic and cultural dimensions of nature are being lost
in the rush for utilitarian economic solutions (Collar, 2003;
Pyle, 2003; Clements et al., 2010). Although important, these
arguments have been well rehearsed. My aim here is to
show there are more radical critiques that conservation
researchers and practitioners should be aware of, and to
make them accessible to a conservation audience. I do so
in response to calls for conservation research and practice
to be more interdisciplinary, as well as to comments that
dierences in language and concepts often make this
IVAN R. SCALES St Catharines College, University of Cambridge, Trumpington
Street, Cambridge, CB2 1RL, UK. E-mail irs28@cam.ac.uk
Received 29 August 2013. Revision requested 8October 2013.
Accepted 7January 2014. First published online 29 April 2014.
Oryx
, 2015, 49(2), 226–231 ©2014 Fauna & Flora International doi:10.1017/S0030605314000015
http://journals.cambridge.org Downloaded: 01 Apr 2015 IP address: 128.232.239.148
dicult (Campbell, 2005; Balmford & Cowling, 2006;
Fox et al., 2006). With this in mind, I review and translate
recent research by scholars in the social sciences on the
political economy of conservation. Broadly speaking,
political economy pays close attention to the role of political
institutions and power in economic systems (Johnston et al.,
2001). The fundamental questions of political economy are:
(1) who does what in an economic system, (2) who owns
what, (3) who gets what, and (4) what do they do with it
(Bernstein, 2010)?
Given the volume and theoretical complexity of the
literature, I concentrate on a small number of core concepts,
mainly from Marxian political economy, as well as specic
case study examples, primarily from low-income nations.
I begin by exploring the basic process of commodity
exchange under capitalism. I then consider nature as a
reluctant and uncooperative commodity that often requires
new institutions and technologies to be commodied. This
means conservation organizations play a crucial role in the
commodication of nature and have moved from the critical
margins of global capitalism to playing a key role in green
capitalisms political economy. These developments are
likely to have signicant social and environmental conse-
quences, with a highly uneven distribution of costs and
benets.
Capitalism and commodities
At its most basic, capitalism can be described as a system for
organizing production (a mode of productionin Marxian
terminology) based on private ownership, the exchange and
distribution of goods and services through markets, and
driven by the prot motive (Bowles, 2007). It is a distinct
and increasingly pervasive way of making, moving and
selling all manner of goods and services(Castree, 2003,
p. 274). As a mode of production it places considerable
emphasis on commodities.
A commodity can be dened as something that is
produced for the purpose of exchange (Kosoy & Corbera,
2010). So when conservation policy attempts to place an
economic value on the environmental services provided by
nature and promotes or facilitates the exchange of these
services for money, it can be said to be commodifying
nature. In other words, commodication is the process
whereby goods formerly outside marketised spheres of
existence enter the world of money(Bakker, 2005,p.545).
The concept of a commodity has a central role in political
economy, since it plays a crucial part in shaping social
relations and the relationship between humans and the
material world around them.
The simplest form of commodity exchange involves
bartering. We can represent this form of exchange as
Commodity to Commodity, or CC. The point is that
commodities are exchanged because of their use values.
As well as bartering, money can be used as a form of mobile
value. This commodity exchange can be represented as
CommodityMoneyCommodity, or CMC. This allows a
commodity to be exchanged for money in one place, the
value stored or moved and then exchanged for another
commodity. The important point is that this doesnt
necessarily change the purpose of the exchange, which
emphasizes the use value of that commodity.
There is considerable variation between societies (his-
torically and geographically) in what is considered to be
private property and what is exchanged as commodities
(Bowles, 2007). Under certain modes of production
commodities become a vehicle for prot and capital
accumulation; i.e. money is invested for the sole purpose
of making prot. This form of exchange is represented as
MCM. The emphasis here is not on what the commodity
can be used for but what it can be exchanged for: its
exchange value is prioritized over its use value. While
capitalism is by no means the only mode of production that
involves transactions based on exchange value, it makes
it a core principle. Capitalism is driven by competition,
wealth accumulation and an increase in the productive and
consumptive capacity of society. The logic of capitalism thus
dictates that capital continually searches for investment
opportunities and sources of continued economic growth;
i.e. new protability frontiers. Because capitalism needs new
protability frontiers, it must always be in search of new
objects and processes to commodify (Harvey, 2005). The
relentless quest for growth and prots has thus seen an ever
greater number and range of objects, assets and processes
come under private ownership and market exchange
(Watts, 1994; Harvey, 2003).
The most recent phase of global capitalism, emerging in
the late 1970s, is described as neoliberal. Broadly speaking,
neoliberalism can be described as a set of policy measures
informed by a distinct world-view that places emphasis on
individual liberty and freedom, minimal involvement of
the state, and free markets as the best way to coordinate
the diverse needs of people (Castree, 2003,2010; Harvey,
2005; Igoe et al., 2010; Peck, 2010). In terms of policy,
neoliberalism tends to promote the privatization of state
assets and common pool resources, clear property rights,
and the deregulation of markets to allow maximum
entrepreneurial freedom (Harvey, 2005; Castree, 2008;
Peck, 2010). Under green capitalism, previously uncommo-
died aspects of the natural world are becoming part of
capitalismsprotability frontier. This is interpreted by
some scholars as the neoliberalization of conservation
(Igoe et al., 2010; Fletcher, 2012). The important question is
how the greater commodication of nature under green
capitalism might alter social and environmental relations.
From the perspective of political economy the answer to this
question depends on how nature behaves as a commodity.
Paying for nature 227
Oryx
, 2015, 49(2), 226–231 ©2014 Fauna & Flora International doi:10.1017/S0030605314000015
http://journals.cambridge.org Downloaded: 01 Apr 2015 IP address: 128.232.239.148
Nature as a reluctant and uncooperative
commodity
The problem with treating nature as a commodity is that it
is not produced specically for the purpose of exchange.
Like land and labour, nature is a ctitious commodity
(Polanyi, 1944) and must be commodied through the
creation of new institutions and technologies (Harvey,
2005). However, nature can be a reluctant commodity and
hard to commodify. The neoclassical economic denition of
a commodity is based on the idea of a standardized good or
service, with interchangeable units and a price determined
through market exchange (Bakker, 2005). A good com-
modity (i.e. something that is straightforward to exchange)
has clear values, boundaries and property rights (Kosoy &
Corbera, 2010). This is the opposite of most ecosystems and
landscapes: their values are multiple, complicated and dier
between people and cultures, with often unclear and
contested ownership rights (Bakker, 2005; Carrier, 2010;
Castree, 2010).
Bakkers(2005) research on the privatization of water
supply and management in England and Wales shows just
how uncooperative nature can be as a commodity. Water is
dicult to own, manage privately and commodify. Firstly,
its provision and use involves a set of complex and diuse
biophysical processes: from precipitation to surface ow,
river ow and storage. Secondly, its provision is dependent
on major infrastructure that requires considerable invest-
ment and therefore favours monopoly control rather than
competing providers in a free market. Thirdly, ows of
water cut across political and economic boundaries at vari-
ous spatial levels, leading to complex politics of ownership
and control. Finally, water involves a diverse set of users
with dierent and sometimes conicting priorities. Its priva-
tization and commodication has thus been both partial (i.e.
only part of the process can be privatized and commodied)
and highly contested (Castree, 2003; Bakker, 2005; Roberts,
2008). As I discuss in the next section, these factors have
often led to an uneven distribution of costs and benets.
Because ecosystems and the services they provide are
complex, most conservation policy eorts to commodify
nature tend to focus on one or two specic services and also
simplify those services as much as possible. Looking at
carbon osets for example, for the sake of simplicity and
ecacy, schemes tend to treat carbon as fungible; i.e.
dierent forms of carbon, locked up in dierent forms of
biomass and released through diverse processes, become
mutually substitutable. Carbon is thus converted into a
uniform commodity and separated from both its social and
ecological context so that it can be traded on global carbon
markets (van der Horst & Evans, 2010; Bumpus & Liverman,
2011). This is likely to lead to a narrowing of vision when
it comes to environmental policy, so that other values and
issues are crowded out.
In the context of climate change, the worlds forests are
increasingly seen through the lens of carbon sequestration.
The current priority is to reduce carbon in the atmosphere,
through whatever means: renewable energy, energy
eciency or carbon osets. Osetting carbon by paying
low-income nations to maintain tropical forest cover
through avoided deforestation is seen as a cheap way of
doing this (Kindermann et al., 2008; Bumpus & Liverman,
2011). However, in privileging carbon, other social and
environmental concerns risk being forgotten. The focus on
carbon has already led to the planting of certain tree species
over others because of their high carbon content and rapid
growth rates, and could encourage investment in planta-
tions instead of work on restoring complex ecosystems or
maintaining biodiversity (Kosoy & Corbera, 2010).
The power relations behind the commodification
of nature
Given the fact that nature is often an uncooperative
commodity, the process by which it is commodied, and
its power relations, deserve special attention. Dealing rst
with the question of who does what(Bernstein, 2010)ina
green capitalist mode of production, the commodication of
environmental services is based on its own distinctive
division of labour and elites. Given their largely ctitious
character, the commodities traded under green capitalism
rely on particular individuals and institutions to create and
maintain them. They also require new ways to quantify and
measure the services provided. Looking at regulating
services such as carbon sequestration for example, these
require complex scientic measurements and nancial
mechanisms (Kosoy & Corbera, 2010). The elites in this
mode of production are the scientists who facilitate the
measurements of carbon, the consultants and organizations
who advise on carbon-oset projects, and the nancial
experts and institutions who sell credits on carbon markets
(Bumpus & Liverman, 2008,2011). Looking at biodiversity
osets, these also depend on the scientic and policy
mechanisms and institutions that measure and prioritize
biological diversity (MacDonald & Corson, 2012). The
result is likely to be unequal bargaining power between the
various actors (buyers, sellers and intermediaries), with
global buyers beneting from greater experience, knowledge
and buying power (Karsenty, 2007; Bumpus & Liverman,
2008).
Conservation NGOs play a key role in the commodica-
tion of nature. They have positioned themselves as gate-
keepers between capital and nature and have sought to
increase their inuence by providing authoritative knowl-
edge on ecosystem function and management (MacDonald,
2010). Conservation organizations and the environmental
movement more generally have thus moved from being
228 I.R. Scales
Oryx
, 2015, 49(2), 226–231 ©2014 Fauna & Flora International doi:10.1017/S0030605314000015
http://journals.cambridge.org Downloaded: 01 Apr 2015 IP address: 128.232.239.148
critical voices on the margins of capitalism to playing a
central role in creating new protability frontiers and
enabling capital to expand into new areas (Fairhead et al.,
2012). In Madagascar, for example, a group of conservation
NGOs has formed a partnership with Rio Tinto/QMM,
providing advice on the environmental impacts of ilmenite
mining and helping to negotiate biodiversity osetting,
receiving funding for conservation activities in the process
(Seagle, 2012).
Dealing with questions of ownership and distribution
(i.e. who owns what, who gets what, and what do they do
with it; Bernstein, 2010) there is concern that the
commodication of nature will result in an uneven
distribution of costs and benets, with some even losing
access to natural resources. Research on the commodica-
tion of water has shown what can happen when economic
eciency is prioritized over social and environmental
equity. While in many cases the privatization of water has
resulted in an overall improvement in water supply, this is
usually accompanied by a large increase in costs for
consumers (Bakker, 2005; Roberts, 2008). This can have
serious socio-environmental impacts. In South Africa
privatization led to signicant price hikes and resulted
in poor households being disconnected from the water
supply between 1994 and 2002 (Bond, 2004). In Kwazulu-
Natal this forced the poorest residents to access water from a
polluted river, leading to a cholera outbreak that killed
hundreds and infected thousands more (Bond, 2004;
Roberts, 2008).
Critics of green capitalism see a strong potential for so-
called green grabbing: the appropriation of land and natural
resources by elites both for environmental ends and to allow
further accumulation of wealth (Bumpus & Liverman, 2008;
Fairhead et al., 2012). It is likely that in low-income nations,
in particular, the potential wealth to be gained from
commodied environmental services will lead to a strong
incentive for elites (local, national and international) to take
control of natural resources (Sandbrook et al., 2010). Green
grabs could thus mirror the spate of recent agricultural land
grabs, which have seen a range of corporate and state
interests securing access to land for the cultivation of food
crops and biofuels, dispossessing rural households in the
process (Cotula & Vermeulen, 2009; Demirbas, 2009; White
et al., 2012). Green grabs have already been documented in a
number of dierent contexts and geographical locations. In
Tanzania and Colombia the desire to secure the cultural
environmental services that bring western ecotourists has
led to the enclosure of land and the redenition of rights to
use natural resources, with communities excluded from
their previous livelihood activities (Benjaminsen &
Bryceson, 2012; Ojeda, 2012). In Madagascar protected
areas have been expanded to accommodate biodiversity
osets related to mining operations, limiting local access to
forests (Seagle, 2012). In Uganda, households have lost
access to land acquired by a Norwegian company for carbon
forestry (Nel & Hill, 2013).
Dispossession doesnt necessarily have to include
outright land grabs and the alienation of existing claimants,
but may also occur through the restructuring of rules that
govern access to and use of natural resources (Fairhead et al.,
2012). In the State of Chiapas in Mexico there is evidence
that smallholder farms are changing land-use strategies and
planting carbon sequestering trees as a new source of
income (Osborne, 2011). While in this case tree planting has
helped many households to secure land rights and generated
alternative sources of income, there have been important
dierences in the distribution of costs and benets between
and within households. To benet from carbon oset
payments, households have had to shift from short-term
food production (for subsistence and cash) to managing
longer-term forestry-based income. However, poorer
households have been unable to give up short-term food
supply and many have complained about the insuciency
of carbon payments in relation to the considerable labour
requirements. In some cases, the shift in balance away from
short-term food supply has resulted in tensions within
households (largely between men and women) about
livelihood priorities (Osborne, 2011).
Such arguments have been made before in relation to
community-based conservation (Hulme & Murphree,
2001). Although some households may benet from new
sources of income (especially those that can aord to
abandon short-term subsistence activities), poorer house-
holds are often the most directly dependent on access to
natural resources such as forests and thus stand to lose the
most from any schemes that redene resource use and
prioritize environmental services over other livelihood
options. It is likely that many attempts to commodify
environmental services will keep some individuals, house-
holds and communities in poverty traps as they are forced to
forgo more lucrative activities in order to protect environ-
mental services (Karsenty, 2007). These previous experi-
ences together with more recent case studies should serve as
a reminder of the complex multi-scalar political economy of
green capitalism. They suggest that winners and losers are
likely to be at multiple spatial levels, with uneven outcomes
within households, between households, between com-
munities, up to the international level.
Conclusion
Green capitalism is increasingly seen by many as the only
realistic way of achieving conservation goals. The expansion
of green capitalism has seen a proliferation of attempts to
commodify nature. For scholars drawing on political
economy, this is part of a long historical process of capitalist
expansion and the search for new protability frontiers.
Paying for nature 229
Oryx
, 2015, 49(2), 226–231 ©2014 Fauna & Flora International doi:10.1017/S0030605314000015
http://journals.cambridge.org Downloaded: 01 Apr 2015 IP address: 128.232.239.148
This has often been achieved by moving assets from the
public domain to the private sphere, a process that Harvey
(2005) labeled accumulation by dispossession. However,
green capitalism diers in important ways from previous
waves of capitalist expansion.
The rst signicant dierence is in the types of objects
and processes being commodied. The greening of
capitalism involves commodifying aspects of nature that
have never previously been commodities, for example
carbon sequestration and other ecosystem functions. The
second dierence is in the diversity of actors and the role
played by conservation organizations. Whereas in previous
forms of commodity expansion conservation NGOs were
absent or only on the periphery, and often critiqued
business practices and relentless economic growth, many
have moved closer to those at the heart of the process
(Fletcher, 2012). Conservation NGOs are acting as media-
tors, facilitators and expert consultants in the commodica-
tion of nature (Bumpus & Liverman, 2008; Brockington &
Scholeld, 2010; Fairhead et al., 2012). Finally, green
capitalism diers in the speed of change. The last decade
has seen an expansion in the aspects of social and natural life
that are treated as commodities. As Karl Polanyi (1944)
argued, it isnt just the direction and extent of social change
that is important but the rate of change, since it inuences
whether and how societies can adapt or push back against
such changes. Green capitalism proposes signicant and
rapid changes in the relationship between society and
nature, seeking to mediate it principally through com-
modity exchange and market forces. The danger is that in
the rush to commodify nature, conservation serves the
interests of capital, rather than markets serving the interests
of biodiversity conservation. Perhaps it is time to slow down
and start asking questions.
The dierences in the types of objects and processes
being commodied, the role of the various actors involved
and the speed of change under green capitalism ultimately
raises questions about the power relations at the heart of
green capitalism. Who will be the winners and losers and
who will decide? Green capitalism is likely to have its own
distinct political economy, with its own divisions of labour
and elites, raising questions that need to be addressed
urgently. For example, how is property being restructured
under green capitalism and to what extent does restructur-
ing lead to dispossession? How are costs and benets
distributed at dierent points of the commodity chain,
between dierent stakeholders and at dierent spatial levels?
Who exercises power in a green capitalist mode of
production and how?
These questions point to a bigger question. As Michael
Sandel (2012,p.1011) has argued, without quite realizing it,
without ever deciding to do so, we drifted from having a
market economy to being a market soc iety.. . The great
missing debate in contemporary politics is about the role
and reach of markets. Political economy reminds us
that particular modes of production are not inevitable.
The question shouldnt be whether we can place a nancial
value on nature, as if there is no other choice. The question
is should we?
References
ANDERSON,T.&LEAL,D.(2001)Free Market Environmentalism.
Palgrave MacMillan, New York, USA.
BAKKER,K.(2005) Neoliberalizing nature? Market environmentalism
in water supply in England and Wales. Antipode,95,542565.
BALMFORD,A.&COWLING, R.M. (2006) Fusion or failure? The future
of conservation biology. Conservation Biology,20,692695.
BENJAMINSEN, T.A. & BRY CESON,I.(2012) Conservation, green/blue
grabbing and accumulation by dispossession in Tanzania. Journal of
Peasant Studies,39,335355.
BERNSTEIN,H.(2010)Class Dynamics of Agrarian Change. Kumarian
Press, Halifax, USA.
BOND,P.(2004) From racial to class apartheid: South Africas
frustrating decade of freedom. Monthly Review,55,4559.
BOWLES,P.(2007)Capitalism. Pearson, Harlow, UK.
BROCKINGTON,D.&DUFFY,R.(2010) Capitalism and conservation:
the production and reproduction of biodiversity conservation.
Antipode,42,469484.
BROCKINGTON,D.&SCHOLFIELD,K.(2010) The conservationist
mode of production and conservation NGOs in sub-Saharan Africa.
Antipode,42,551575.
BUMPUS, A.G. & LIV ERMAN, D.M. (2008) Accumulation by
decarbonization and the governance of carbon osets. Economic
Geography,84,127155.
BUMPUS, A.G. & LIVE RMAN, D.M. (2011) Carbon colonialism? Osets,
greenhouse gas reductions, and sustainable development. In Global
Political Ecologies (eds R. Peet, P. Robbins & M. Watts), pp. 203224.
Routledge, London, UK.
BURGIN,S.(2008) BioBanking: an environmental scientists view of the
role of biodiversity banking osets in conservation. Biodiversity and
Conservation,17,807816.
CAMPBELL, L.M. (2005) Overcoming obstacles to interdisciplinary
research. Conservation Biology,19,574577.
CARRIER, J.G. (2010) Protecting the environment the natural way:
ethical consumption and commodity fetishism. Antipode,42,
672689.
CASTREE,N.(2003) Commodifying what nature? Progress in Human
Geography,27,273297.
CASTREE,N.(2008) Neoliberalising nature: the logics of deregulation
and reregulation. Environment and Planning A,40,131152.
CASTREE,N.(2010) Neoliberalism and the biophysical environment: a
synthesis and evaluation of the research. Environment and Society:
Advances in Research,1,545.
CLEMENTS, T., JOHN , A., NIELS EN, D., AN, D., T AN,S.&MILNER-
GULLAND, E.J. (2010) Payments for biodiversity conservation in the
context of weak institutions: comparison of three programs from
Cambodia. Ecological Economics,69,12831291.
COLLAR, N.J. (2003) Beyond value: biodiversity and the freedom of the
mind. Global Ecology and Biogeography,12,265269.
COTULA,L.&VERMEULEN,S.(2009) Deal or no deal: the outlook for
agricultural land investment in Africa. International Aairs,85,
12331247.
DEMIRBAS,A.(2009) Political, economic and environmental impacts
of biofuels: a review. Applied Energy,86,108117.
230 I.R. Scales
Oryx
, 2015, 49(2), 226–231 ©2014 Fauna & Flora International doi:10.1017/S0030605314000015
http://journals.cambridge.org Downloaded: 01 Apr 2015 IP address: 128.232.239.148
DUFFY,R.(2006) Global environmental governance and the politics of
ecotourism in Madagascar. Journal of Ecotourism,5,128144.
FAIRHEAD, J., LEACH,M.&SCOONES,I.(2012) Green grabbing: a new
appropriation of nature. Journal of Peasant Studies,39,237261.
FARBER, S.C., COSTANZA,R.&WILSON, M.A. (2002) Economic and
ecological concepts for valuing ecosystem services. Ecological
Economics,41,375392.
FERRARO, P.J. (2011) The future of payments for environmental
services. Conservation Biology,25,11341138.
FISHER,J.(2012) No pay, no care? A case study exploring motivations
for participation in payments for ecosystem services in Uganda.
Oryx,46,4554.
FLETCHER,R.(2012) Using the masters tools? Neoliberal conservation
and the evasion of inequality. Development and Change,43,295317.
FOX, H.E., CHRISTIAN , C., CULLY NORDBY, J., PERGAMS, O.R.W.,
PETERSON, G.D. & PYKE, C.R. (2006) Perceived barriers to
intergrating social science and conservation. Conservation Biology,
20,18171820.
GOWDY, J., HALL, C., K LITGAARD,K.&KRALL,L.(2010) What every
conservation biologist should know about economic theory.
Conservation Biology,24,14401447.
HARVEY,D.(2003)The New Imperialism. Oxford University Press,
Oxford, UK.
HARVEY,D.(2005)A Brief Introduction to Neoliberalism. Oxford
University Press, Oxford, UK.
HULME,D.&MURPHREE,M.(2001)African Wildlife and Livelihoods:
The Promise and Performance of Community Conservation. James
Currey, Oxford, UK.
IGOE, J., NEVES,K.&BROCKINGTON,D.(2010) A spectacular
eco-tour around the historic bloc: theorising the convergence of
biodiversity conservation and capitalist expansion. Antipode,42,
486512.
JOHNSTON, R.J., GREGORY, D., PRATT,G.&WATTS, M. (eds) (2001)
The Dictionary of Human Geography. Blackwell Publishing, Oxford,
UK.
KARSENTY,A.(2007) Questioning rent for development swaps: new
market-based instruments for biodiversity acquisition and the
land-use issue in tropical countries. International Forestry Review,
9,503513.
KINDERMANN, G., OBERSTEINER, M., S OHN GEN, B., SATHAYE, J.,
ANDRASKO, K., RAMETSTEINER, E. et al. (2008) Global cost
estimates of reducing carbon emissions through avoided
deforestation. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the
United States of America,105,1030210307.
KOSOY,N.&CORBERA,E.(2010) Payments for ecosystem services as
commodity fetishism. Ecological Economics,69,12281236.
MACDONALD, K.I. (2010) The devil is in the (bio)diversity: private
sector engagementand the restructuring of biodiversity
conservation. Antipode,42,513550.
MACDONALD, K.I. & CORSON,C.(2012)TEEB Begins Now: a virtual
moment in the production of natural capital. Development and
Change,43,159184.
MCCAULEY, D.J. (2006) Selling out on nature. Nature,443,2728.
MCGREGOR,A.(2010) Green and REDD? Towards a political ecology
of deforestation in Aceh, Indonesia. Human Geography,3,2134.
NEL,A.&HILL,D.(2013) Constructing walls of carbonthe
complexities of community, carbon sequestration and protected
areas in Uganda. Journal of Contemporary African Studies,31,
421440.
OJEDA,D.(2012) Green pretexts: ecotourism, neoliberal conservation
and land grabbing in Tayrona National Natural Park, Colombia.
Journal of Peasant Studies,39,357375.
OSBORNE, T.M. (2011) Carbon forestry and agrarian change: access and
land control in a Mexican rainforest. Journal of Peasant Studies,38,
859883.
PECK,G.(2010)Constructions of Neoliberal Reason. Oxford University
Press, Oxford, UK.
POLANYI,K.(1944)The Great Transformation. Rinehart, New York,
USA.
PRUDHAM, W.S. (2009) Pimping climate change: Richard Branson,
global warming, and the performance of green capitalism.
Environment and Planning A,41,15941613.
PYLE, R.M. (2003) Nature matrix: reconnecting people and nature.
Oryx,37,206214.
ROBERTS,A.(2008) Privatising social reproduction: the primitive
accumulation of water in an era of neoliberalism. Antipode,40,
535560.
SANDBROOK, C., NELSON, F., ADAM S, W.M. & AGRAWAL,A.(2010)
Carbon, forests and the REDD paradox. Oryx,44,330334.
SANDEL,M.(2012)What Money Cant Buy: The Moral Limits to
Markets. Allan Lane, London, UK.
SEAGLE,C.(2012) Inverting the impacts: mining, conservation
and sustainability claims near the Rio Tinto/QMM ilmenite
mine in Southeast Madagascar. Journal of Peasant Studies,39,
447477.
VAN DE R HORST,D.&EVAN S,J.(2010) Carbon claims and energy
landscapes: exploring the political ecology of biomass. Landscape
Research,35,173193.
WATTS,M.(1994) Development II: the privatization of everything.
Progress in Human Geography,18,371384.
WEST,P.&CARRIER, J.G. (2004) Ecotourism and authenticity: getting
away from it all? Current Anthropology,45,483498.
WHITE, B., BORRAS, S.M., H ALL, R., S COONES,I.&WOLFORD,W.
(2012) The new enclosures: critical perspectives on corporate land
deals. Journal of Peasant Studies,39,619647.
Biographical sketch
IVAN SCALES is a geographer specializing in environment and
development issues, mostly in sub-Saharan Africa. His research
emphasizes the role of political, cultural and economic factors in
shaping the way natural resources are used and contested. Current
research projects investigate the diversity of environmental values,
agriculture and food security, tropical deforestation, and community-
based approaches to conservation.
Paying for nature 231
Oryx
, 2015, 49(2), 226–231 ©2014 Fauna & Flora International doi:10.1017/S0030605314000015
... geography, but also in ecological economics and political ecology, the acceleration of commodification and privatization processes and their potentially negative social-ecological consequences are subject of critical debates (Smessaert et al., 2020). In this context, terms such as market environmentalism (Bakker, 2005;, neoliberal conservation , green capitalism (Prudham, 2009;Scales, 2014), neoliberal environmentality (Fletcher, 2010), and liberal environmentalism (Dempsey, 2016) is based on the paradigm that economic incentives are particularly effective in guiding human behavior (Allen, 2018;Fletcher, 2010). ...
... In this context, contentious debates revolve around the potential negative social and ecological consequences that arise when more market-based ES policies prioritize exchange values (the market-determined relative value of an ES based on supply and demand) over use values (the inherent utility of an ES to individuals or society at large) (e.g. Kallis et al., 2013;Scales, 2014). The prioritization of exchange values over use values is also seen as an important component of commodification processes, as ES are broken down into separate units to be transferred in a market-like exchange Kallis et al., 2013;. ...
... Furthermore, trading these ES as exchangeable commodities is seen critically, as it is often difficult to assign clear boundaries, values, and property rights to ES, which is particularly due to their physical characteristics and, thereby, their common-or public-good character (Bakker, 2004;Farley & Costanza, 2010;McElwee, 2012). Thus, it is argued that PES run into danger of focusing on easily commodifiable ES, instead of targeting complex bundles of ES at the landscape scale (Corbera et al., 2007;Ghazoul et al., 2009;Robertson, 2006;Scales, 2014). Opponents of PES also fear potentially negative social implications of PES-related commodification trends (Fletcher & Büscher, 2017;McElwee, 2012). ...
Thesis
Full-text available
As ecosystems around the world continue to degrade, the implementation of ecologically effective and socially just conservation instruments is critical. Payments for ecosystem services (PES) are an increasingly popular tool. PES are voluntary and conditional incentives for the provision of ecosystem services, rewarding landowners for their conservation efforts. Some PES programs target local communities that collectively meet contractual obligations (collective PES, C-PES). Proponents see C-PES as a promising tool for successful nature conservation, while critics argue that the introduction of market principles into areas not previously characterized by them can have negative effects, such as the erosion and replacement of well-functioning local community institutions and the crowding out of intrinsic conservation motivations. Against the background of these controversies, this dissertation aims to contribute to answering the question of how paying local communities for their conservation efforts supports or hinders the social-ecological transformation towards sustainability. Paper I reviews definitions and systematizations of program-related commodification processes and local land tenure structures, and their links to social-ecological program outcomes. Based on a framework developed in the first paper, Paper II examines 29 C-PES programs worldwide regarding their ES-related degree of commodification. Paper III focuses on human-environment conflicts in the context of conservation performance payments for wolverines and lynxes in Sweden, which are made to indigenous Sámi communities. Overall, the findings of the three papers suggest that C-PES programs do not in themselves address leverage points for a sustainability transformation, but can only be fully effective when implemented in a careful and inclusive manner, ensuring that they contribute to a larger institutional change across scales and when they support closer connections between people and nature.
... Many scholars have a rather skeptical view on PES or even deny the effectiveness of this conservation instrument. For example, some authors criticize that PES potentially downplay the complexity of ecosystems because of the commercialization and commodification tendencies that are often associated with this instrument (Norgaard 2010, Büscher et al. 2012, Scales 2015. Furthermore, the pure focus on monetary exchange values arguably hides the existing plurality of values (Vatn 2010). ...
... Environmental economics provide the theoretical grounding for the PES approach. This school of thought is strongly influenced by neoclassical theory and follows the assumption that environmental degradation is a result of market failures, namely the exclusion of environmental costs in product prices (Scales 2015). Hence, environmental economists recommend the implementation of valuation and commodification techniques to internalize externalities (Perman et al. 2011). ...
... Monetary valuation is only one of many types of valuation. Scholars criticize that monetary valuations follow a market thinking, which is based on the prioritization of exchange values over use values (Scales 2015), thereby following an understanding of weak sustainability in which ecosystem services and functions can be substituted with other ES or even human-made capital (Biely et al. 2018). Following this line, critics argue that monetization supports a utilitarian rationality and a pure interest in profit-maximization, which abets the view on economic agents as "homo economicus" (McAfee 2012, Kull et al. 2015, Van Hecken et al. 2018). ...
Article
Full-text available
The economic conservation instrument of payments for ecosystem services (PES) enjoys an increasing popularity among scientists, politicians, and civil society organizations alike, while others raise concerns regarding the ecological effectiveness and social justice of this instrument. In this review article, we showcase the variety of existing PES definitions and systematically locate these definitions in the range between Coasean conceptualizations, which describe PES as conditional and voluntary private negotiations between ES providers and ES beneficiaries, and much broader Pigouvian PES understandings that also assign government-funded and involuntary schemes to the PES approach. It turns out that the scale at which PES operate, having so far received very little attention in the literature, as well as critique of PES must be considered in the context of the diversity of definitions to ensure the comparability between studies researching PES programs. Future research should better target linkages between global, regional, and local scales for the development of PES programs, while taking local collective governance systems for a sustainable use of resources into account more seriously.
... Ideally, PES schemes promote development projects that address serious environmental concerns while lifting individuals and communities out of poverty. Yet, this neoliberal logic is implicated in several social and environmental injustices, such as changing human-environment relationships through the commodification and instrumentalization of nature (Goldman 2005), disrupting traditional livelihoods, removing Indigenous and other long-tenured groups from lands (Lyons and Westoby 2014;Scales 2015), and incentivizing behaviors that lead to further habitat loss and environmental degradation (Matulis 2013;Spash 2015). The second critique focuses on issues around the monetary valuation and commodification of nature (Kaiser et al. 2021;Brockington 2017). ...
... E.S. quantification creates new socionatures that fundamentally reshape how humans perceive nature and natural resources (Spash 2015). Valuation processes that determine which resources are worthy of preservation and how preservation should be accomplished is often framed in purely instrumental terms, determined by technocrats and experts and enforced via laws or violent coercion (Bigger & Robertson 2017;Scales 2015). As such, valuation techniques and markets created especially for buying and selling natural capital open new accumulation frontiers (Knuth 2015;Sullivan 2013). ...
Chapter
Full-text available
Payments for ecosystem services (PES) schemes have become a widely used policy instrument for states to incentivize desirable environmental behaviors to meet conservation and preservation goals. However, many studies have shown that market-based regulatory mechanisms may change human-environment relationships, generating the commodification of natural resources and environmental inequalities. Our case study of an extensive grassland PES scheme in the Inner Mongolia Autonomous Region of China demonstrates that implementation is highly contingent upon existing state structures, political ideologies, national economic imperatives, and the ability of PES designers to account for the complexity of human-environment interactions. The state's conflicting mandates to provide environmental protection and facilitate economic growth have undermined conservation and worsened environmental inequality in the region. Our chapter contributes a more nuanced understanding of how normative functions of state-led ecosystem valuation and environmental interventions in an illiberal context may lead to the overutilization of natural resources that exacerbates stratification and injustice in top-down, centralized environmental governance models.
... Madagascar's distinctive biodiversity is part of the global heritage. But who really pays for its conservation [72][73][74]? At this point in time, when most resources are being consumed by the wealthy 10% minority of the global population, it is patently unreasonable to expect that the often vastly poorer majority effectively has to pay for basic ecosystem services which benefit all of humanity. ...
Article
Full-text available
Ecotourism is widely considered a strong mechanism for the sustainable funding of protected areas (PAs). Implemented during the 1990s in Madagascar, nature-based tourism experienced positive growth over the last 30 years with increasing numbers of visits to the parks and reserves. Revenue earned from entrance fees to the network of PAs managed by Madagascar National Parks has never been sufficient to finance their management. Political crises and the COVID-19 pandemic in particular, have highlighted for park managers, the risk of relying on such earnings when they covered just 1% of the required funding in 2021. Alternative mechanisms of funding are analysed for all of Madagascar’s PAs with a view to facilitating sustainable conservation of the localities and protection of the island’s biodiversity.
... Several scholars have highlighted the potential negative social and ecological impacts of PES-related commodification processes. These include the concealing of ecosystem complexity (Kallis et al., 2013;Kosoy and Corbera, 2010;Norgaard, 2010;Scales, 2014), the application of a logic of substitutability by assigning monetary exchange-values to ES , and the exacerbation of social inequalities both locally and globally (Büscher et al., 2012;Corbera, 2012;Kosoy and Corbera, 2010;McAfee, 2012;McElwee et al., 2014). However, in-depth case studies that directly investigate the influence of commodification processes on social-ecological PES outcomes are rare Osborne and Shapiro-Garza, 2018). ...
Article
Full-text available
This study provides a novel framework for analysing PES-related degrees of ES-commodification. The framework differentiates PES programs by the extent to which ES are traded in a market-like exchange in terms of four PES design components. We apply this framework to a newly compiled global dataset of collective PES programs (C-PES). C-PES address communities and groups instead of individuals and private entities and provide voluntary, conditional incentives for ES protection. Many conservationists see potentials for supporting participation and cooperation when linking common land titles with the PES approach instead of strengthening private land tenure regimes. We identified 29 C-PES cases with clusters in Central and Southeast Africa, Central America, and Southeast Asia. Particularly C-PES programs focusing on carbon or wildlife ES reach medium to high degrees of commodification, whereas schemes targeting biodiversity, watershed, or bundled ES show rather low to medium degrees of commodification. Our framework allows for a more nuanced study of the pluralism of PES designs and lays the foundation for further research on the differentiated role of ES-commodification for social-ecological outcomes.
... Already Karl Polanyi (1957) stressed the increasing marketability of land accompanied by the rise of capitalism when he shaped the term "fictitious commodity." Alienation rights economically mobilize land and can in some cases be a door-opener for international companies to acquire land titles, which can facilitate land and "green grabbing" (Fairhead et al. 2012, Scales 2015 when these alienation rights are strongly deregulated, as also discussed in the context of PES in countries of the Global South (Vatn 2010). However, it cannot be concluded that common/ collective or state property would necessarily lead to a more sustainable use of resources, as our review about the complexity and diversity of property regimes shows. ...
Article
Full-text available
Payments for ecosystem services (PES) gained an increasing importance in science and politics within the last decades. Although the enthusiasm about PES is particularly high in Environmental Economics, opponents criticize the market-based character of PES and the associated commodification as well as privatization trends. By means of a systematic literature review we aim at shedding light on the complex and controversial debate about how to define commodification and related privatization processes and how they are linked to PES outcomes. We do so by setting a particular focus on the potentials and challenges of community-based and collective PES (C-PES), also in contrast to PES targeting land under private land tenure (P-PES). Our results reveal that C-PES show promising results when targeting local communities with a high level of social capital. However, there is a lack of studies that systematically assess the relations between different degrees of commodification and the ecological and social outcome of PES programs. For this reason, we provide a new conceptual framework of commodification by highlighting two interrelated spheres, where PES-related commodification processes take place: The first sphere relates to the commodification of ES-providing land, which greatly depends on the land tenure regime in place. The second sphere addresses the commodification of ecosystem services (ES). Our review indicates that C-PES show rather low degrees of commodification in the first sphere because the ES-providing land is often less embedded into private land markets. This is due to often missing alienation rights, more complex decision-making processes, and a potentially lower profit-orientation of the landowners. Empirical long-term studies are needed to investigate changes in both spheres of commodification over time, their potential interactions, and how they affect the outcome of C-PES and P-PES programs.
Article
Full-text available
The Rhino Bond is the first financial instrument dedicated to protecting a species. The Bond allows investors to invest in the conservation of the black rhinoceros Diceros bicornis , with the amount of money returned by the investment depending on whether rhinoceros numbers increase (and by how much). In this paper we focus on how the Bond was brought into being. We draw on an analysis of organizational reports along with data collected from interviews with key informants to investigate the roles of the various stakeholders in the Bond, how species and sites were selected, the motivations and experiences of the stakeholders and the involvement of stakeholders in decision-making. We found that although conservation actors are attracted by the potential for new funding, they have experienced challenges navigating complex financial instruments. The needs of financial actors often dictated decision-making, with implications for the species and sites chosen for the Bond. As profits are tied to an increase in population size of a specific species (which needs to be monitored), the instrument has favoured large and easily counted species and populations. Only some sites were able to meet the stringent conditions of financial instruments, including metrics on financial sustainability. We argue that the dominance of financial principles and motives means that not all species or sites will be viable candidates for investment and that conservation finance should not be seen as a panacea.
Article
In 2005 Milan Municipality launched the “Adopt a green spot” model initiative, to restore and maintain scattered and marginal green areas, following a Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES) scheme. The PES scheme was designed in the form of two standardized typologies of voluntary agreements – sponsorship and collaboration - allowing flexibility in the commitment of involved private stakeholders, including condominiums, NGOs, and the business. 502 agreements, for a total surface of 265.398 m2, have been signed up to now. The paper analysis the design components of the PES scheme which determines its capacity to be replicated in different contexts involving a variety of stakeholders. The main elements enabling the success of the PES scheme are i) the flexibility of the voluntary agreements designed to meet the needs of various stakeholders; ii) the variety of green areas included in the initiative; iii) public recognition which makes it possible to attract firms iv) low transaction costs borne by the stakeholders. The financial resources committed, even if representing a small portion of the total social benefit generated, are sufficient to ensure an adequate requalification and maintenance of small green areas, often neglected because of scarcity of public financing. The replication capacity of this PES scheme makes it a model initiative. Given its characteristics and flexibility, it has been used for the definition of more than 500 agreements with different stakeholders, and for these reasons the policy design approach can be suitable for the replication in other urban contests.
Article
Full-text available
Carbon forestry represents a degree of continuity and discontinuity with traditional conservation practices, rescripting forestry management/governance and land access through projects on the ground in variegated, context-dependent ways. Utilising the comparative lens of two distinct projects operating on state-led protected areas in the east of Uganda, and focusing on their contested boundaries, this paper reflects on these dynamics and tries to make sense of the implications for the rural communities within the project vicinities. The projects and their framings reassert the claims to territory of the state in different ways which are contingent upon and emergent from the local institutional and historical context, or ‘legacies of the land’, which can be seen in context to be disputed and contested. Whilst it must be said that there can be selectively progressive elements within carbon forestry initiatives, it can be observed that techno-centric interventions, which depoliticise their local contexts and selectively transnationalise access to land and forestry resources, can further marginalise local communities in the process.
Book
People around the world are confused and concerned. Is it a sign of strength or of weakness that the US has suddenly shifted from a politics of consensus to one of coercion on the world stage? What was really at stake in the war on Iraq? Was it all about oil and, if not, what else was involved? What role has a sagging economy played in pushing the US into foreign adventurism? What exactly is the relationship between US militarism abroad and domestic politics? These are the questions taken up in this compelling and original book. In this closely argued and clearly written book, David Harvey, one of the leading social theorists of his generation, builds a conceptual framework to expose the underlying forces at work behind these momentous shifts in US policies and politics. The compulsions behind the projection of US power on the world as a "new imperialism" are here, for the first time, laid bare for all to see.
Article
The United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and Degradation (REDD) programme is poised to radically restructure forest management and politics. The programme will eventually provide $30 billion a year in grant and market finance to prevent carbon emissions caused by forest conversion in non-Annex 1 countries. As a consequence new carbon networks involving investment agencies, carbon traders, government departments and NGOs are forming to profit from the programme. This paper analyses the ongoing evolution of REDD from four perspectives drawn from political ecology – classic political ecology, eco-governmentality, eco-dependence, and environmental justice. I argue that both the dominant global managerialist perspective, that sees REDD as an apolitical technical and programmatic challenge, and the oppositional populist response, that sees REDD as a form of neo-liberal expansionism infringing on forest people's rights, gloss over the importance of place. Drawing from the experiences of two advanced REDD pilot projects located in the Indonesian province of Aceh, I explore the particularities of place in shaping how REDD is unfolding. Rather than rejecting, or uncritically accepting, this new form of green neo-liberalism I argue for more contextualised responses that maximise the social and environmental gains that can be made, while also highlighting the negativities involved.
Chapter
https://www.routledge.com/Neoliberal-Environments-False-Promises-and-Unnatural-Consequences/Heynen-McCarthy-Prudham-Robbins/p/book/9780415771498
Article
In this essay contemporary Marxist writings on the commodification of nature in capitalist societies are reviewed systematically. Recent research on commodities in human geography, cultural studies and related fields have been largely post or non-Marxist in tenor and have paid relatively little attention to the ‘natural’ dimensions of commodities. By contrast, recent Marxist writings about capitalism-nature relations have tried to highlight both the specificity of capitalist commodification and its effects on ecologies and bodies. This fact notwithstanding, it is argued that the explanatory and normative dimensions of this Marxist work are, respectively, at risk of being misunderstood and remain largely implicit. On the explanatory side, confusion arises because the words ‘commodification’ and ‘nature’ are used by different Marxists to refer to different things that deserve to be disentangled. On the normative side, the Marxian criticisms of nature's commodification are rarely explicit and often assumed to be self-evident. The essay offers a typology of commodification processes relating to specific natures with specific effects to which a variety of criticisms can be applied. Though essentially exegetical rather than reconstructive, the essay tries to pave the way for a more precise sense of how the commodification of nature in capitalist societies works and why it might be deemed to be problematic.