Content uploaded by Monika Poettinger
Author content
All content in this area was uploaded by Monika Poettinger on Dec 14, 2014
Content may be subject to copyright.
XIII Convegno AISPE “Gli economisti e la guerra”
11-13 dicembre 2014 Università di Pisa
Monika Poettinger
Università Commerciale Luigi Bocconi, Milano
Otto Neurath’s War Economics
[Otto Neurath, Modern Man in the Making, London, Secker and Warburg, 1939, p. 87]
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
2
INTRODUCTION
The Viennese Otto Neurath (1882-1945)
1
, once stigmatized as a volcanic revolutionary, poor in theory as
rich in reforming enthusiasm, has only recently been rediscovered as an economist and his economic
writings have been republished and partially translated in English
2
. This paper analyzes the early years of
Otto Neurath’s scientific activity, at the beginning of the twentieth century, when particular attention was
given by him to war economics.
Otto Neurath excluded any kind of ethical prejudice from restricting economic analysis. Acquiring methods
as war and smuggling should, in his view, be studied exactly as market exchange and production. “That
pillage – he wrote – is prohibited by law, should not impede economists from studying it. Why should the
consequences of trade and domestic manufacture be worth to be analyzed, while the effects of smuggling
are ignored? In consequence of such considerations war has been vastly ignored by economists as a form of
acquisition (…)”
3
.
Far away from any interventionist stance, Neurath considered the Balkan wars and WWI as an
extraordinary occasion to gather information
4
about the emerging of barter trade, even at international
level
5
, the centralized administration of production, the controlled distribution of consumption goods and
the destabilizing or even vanishing of financial systems. His extraordinary efforts in this field were
recognized not only with a Carnegie Endowment for International Peace and an official commendation
from the Austrian government, but also with the appointment as director of the Museum of War Economy
in Leipzig in 1916
6
.
Above all, studying a war economy in its development meant, for Neurath, the possibility to demonstrate
that a certain grade of administrative control over the economy, based on a general system of in-kind
1
A complete biography of Otto Neurath is to be found in: Enza L. Vaccaro, Vite da naufraghi. Otto Neurath nel suo
contesto, Tesi di Dottorato in metodologia delle scienze sociali – ciclo XV – Università La Sapienza Roma; and: Nancy
Cartwright, Jordi Cat, Lola Fleck, Thomas E. Uebel, Otto Neurath: Philosophy Between Science and Politics, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press, 2008. The most recent publication on Otto Neurath is: Günther Sandner, Otto Neurath:
Eine politische Biographie, Vienna, Paul Zsolnay Verlag, 2014.
2
Rudolf Haller and Ulf Höfer (eds.), Otto Neurath. Gesammelte ökonomische, soziologische und sozialpolitische
Schriften, Wien, Hölder-Pichler-Tempsky, 1998; Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath. Economic
Writings: Selections 1904-1945, Dordrect, Springer, 2006.
3
Otto Neurath, Das Begriffsgebäude der Wirtschaftslehre und seine Grundlagen, „Zeitschrift für die gesamte
Staatswissenschaft“, vol. 73, n. 4., 1917, p.493.
4
Otto Neurath, Die Kriegswirtschaftslehre als Sonderdisziplin, „Weltwirtschatliches Archiv“, 1, 1, 1913, p.23.
5
See: Otto Neurath, Grundsätzliches über den Kompensationsverkehr im internationalen Warenhandel,
„Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv“, 13, 2, 1918, pp.23-35.
6
Nancy Cartwright, Jordi Cat, Lola Fleck, Thomas E. Uebel, Otto Neurath: Philosophy Between Science and Politics,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 2008, pp. 19-21.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
3
calculations, could prevent what he considered the worst trait of market economies: economic crises. An
isotype in particular, of his volume of 1939, bears testimony of such stance. The image illustrates a statistic
on coal production in the United States between 1914 and 1936, underlining how in 1917, a year of war,
production steadily remained on its maximum capacity, showing no sign of seasonal or cyclical fluctuation.
As early as 1913, in his essay: Probleme der Kriegswirtschaftslehre
7
, Neurath went a step further: “The
present underemployment of existing forces, that is typical of our Ordnung, incites to war: it is necessary,
for example, to defend oneself from foreign wares and foreign laborers or oblige others to buy our wares
or accept our workers, and all of this because it is not spontaneous to enter in cooperative relations
between states; furthermore it is easy to alleviate the costs of war thanks to reparations; and lastly because
at times war frees productive forces that would otherwise be bound. The uneconomic construction of our
Lebensordnung is the cause why at present war causes lesser evils than in a more economical
Lebensordnung the case would be”
8
.
To eradicate war, in Neurath’s view, mankind had only two alternatives. The first would have been to
render it uneconomical. A second opportunity to foster peace, obviously, would have been to abandon the
present inefficient Lebensordnung for a more effective one. To decide, though, which Lebensordnung to
implement in reality was not the task of an economist. Neurath continued so, instead, to offer to the
attention of politicians economic organizational alternatives to market economy, all the while steadily
collecting statistical data and transforming it in easily understandable isotypes, in order to enable the
largest possible strata of population to decide about their future.
7
Otto Neurath, Probleme der Kriegswirtschaftslehere, „Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswirtschaft“, I, 3, 1913.
8
Otto Neurath, Probleme der Kriegswirtschaftslehere, „Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswirtschaft“, I, 3, 1913, p.500.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
4
WAR ECONOMICS AS A NEW FIELD OF STUDY
“The highest union of individuals under the rule of law which is achieved at present is that of the state and the nation; the highest
imaginable is that of the whole of mankind” (Friedrich List)
9
Otto Neurath has been reevaluated in the 1980s as the empiricist philosopher at the heart of the first
Vienna Circle and for his contribution to epistemology
10
, but he remains largely ignored as an economist,
particularly by historians of economic thought
11
. Merit of Robert Haller and Thomas E. Uebel to have
republished Neurath’s economic writings, even translating a selection of them in English
12
. A complete and
critical appraisal, though, of the role of Neurath in the history of economic ideas is still lacking.
One of the reasons for this misjudgment might have been the negative estimation of Neurath’s economic
writings felled by contemporaries
13
. The holistic approach of Neurath, trying to unify economics long before
his efforts to unify the whole of science, could not be welcomed in an historical moment when taking side
in favor of one of the leading schools of thought was essential in progressing in one’s academic career.
Neurath’s attempt to redefine the content, the scope and the language of economics amidst the most
controversial debates raging between Berlin and Vienna at the beginning of the twentieth century brought
many a mockery and severe critic to his writings. Political coloring and his participation to the Munich
Soviet republic in 1919 also played a part in the rejection of his ideas. Certainly the Bavarian experience
ended his short-lived academic career as professor of economics at Heidelberg, where he had obtained his
habilitation in 1817, but never taught.
9
The quotation from List’s Introduction to his “Nationales System der politischen Ökonomie” was put by Neurath on
top of his article on War Economics published in 1910. Otto Neurath, War Economics, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert
S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, p.153.
10
The most recent account on this philosophical school is: Alan Richardson and Thomas Uebel (eds.), The Cambridge
Companion to Logical Empiricism, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 2007. Thomas Uebel has been throughout
the decisive driving force behind the rediscovering of the Vienna Circle and also the republication of Otto Neurath’s
work. The manifold volumes he edited are extensively quoted in the following.
11
See: Thomas E. Uebel, Neurath’s Economics in Critical Context, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto
Neurath Economic Writings Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, pp.1-108.
12
Rudolf Haller (ed.), Otto Neurath. Gesammelte ökonomische, soziologische und sozialpolitische Schriften, 2 vols.,
Wien, Hölder-Pichler-Tempsky, 1998; Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer.
13
Particularly harsh the opinion of von Mises, who countered many of Neurath’s theses, from the socialist calculation
debate to the problem of homo oeconomicus. Mises, remembering his participation to Böhm-Bawerk’s seminar,
affirmed: “Especially disruptive was the nonsense that Otto Neurath asserted with fanatical force” (Ludwig von Mises,
Memoirs, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2009, p.32). On this also: Heinz D. Kurz, Marginalism, Classicism and Socialism in
German speaking Countries 1871-1932, in: Ian Steedman (ed.), Socialism and Marginalism in Economics 1870-1930,
London, Routledge, 1995, p.13.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
5
The negative perception of contemporaries, however, must not be exaggerated
14
. Neurath’s curriculum in
economics was outstanding. After precocious studies under the guidance of his father, the economist
Wilhelm Neurath
15
, he completed his graduation in Berlin under the supervision of the head of the younger
German historical school, Gustav Schmoller, and the economic historian Eduard Meyer. Between 1905 and
1906, back in Vienna, he then attended the renown economics seminar held by Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk
16
.
Essays by Neurath were printed in Schmoller’s Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik
17
, in Böhm-
Bawerk’s Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft, Sozialpolitik und Verwaltung
18
, and in Weber’s Archiv für
Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik
19
. Neurath also joined the Verein für Socialpolitik and his writings are
present among its published and unpublished proceedings
20
.
Undoubtedly the part of Neurath’s economic thought that gained him ample recognition even among
contemporaries was war economics. His contribution to its definition as an autonomous field of study with
its own rationale and meaningfulness was generally appreciated by fellow economists and intellectuals. His
very reputation as an economists was mainly based on his writings on the issue. Max Weber, in the chapter
on the sociological categories of social action of Economy and Society, discussed at length Neurath’s work
on war economics, by dealing with in-kind calculations as opposed to monetary calculation
21
.
“It is true – wrote Weber - that the problems of a non-monetary economy , and especially of the possibility
of rational action in terms of calculations in kind, have not received much attention. Indeed most of the
attention they have received has been historical and not concerned with present problems. But the World
14
Uebel gives a colorful listing of all negative judgments by contemporaries on Otto Neurath, from Lujo Brentano’s
definition of Neurath as a “romantic economist of the Ancient Egyptian school” to the alternative stigmatizations as a
“bourgeois professor” or as “communist” by Bukharin and Gesell. See: Thomas E. Uebel, Neurath’s Economics in
Critical Context, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings Selections 1904–
1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, pp.75.
15
On the influence of Wilhelm Neurath on the ideas of his son, see: Thomas E. Uebel, Otto Neurath's Idealist
Inheritance: "The Social and Economic Thought of Wilhelm Neurath", „Synthese“, 103, 1, 1995, pp. 87-121.
16
The seminar is justly famous given the participation, next to Neurath, of Otto Bauer, Rudolf Hilferding, Emil Lederer,
Joseph Schumpeter and Ludwig von Mises. On this seminar see: Harald Hagemann, Capitalist Development,
Innovations, Business Cycles and Unemployment, Joseph Alois Schumpeter and Emil Hans Lederer, GREDEG CNRS, 22
November 2012, pp.3-5.
17
Otto Neurath, Zur Anschauung der Antike über Handel, Gewerbe und Landwirtschaft, „Jahrbücher für
Nationalökonomie und Statistik“, III, XXXII, 1906, pp. 577-606; Otto Neurath, Zur Anschauung der Antike über Handel,
Gewerbe und Landwirtschaft, „Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik“, III, XXXIV, 1907, pp. 145-205.
18
Otto Neurath, Nationalökonomie und Wertlehre, eine systematische Untersuchung, „Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft,
Sozialpolitik und Verwaltung“, Vol.20, 1911, pp.52-114.
19
Otto Neurath, Aufgabe, Methode und Leistungsfähigkeit der Kriegswirtschaft, „Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und
Sozialpolitik“, n.44, 1918.
20
The contributions have been republished in English in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath
Economic Writings Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, pp.292-298. For a critical appraisal see: Heino Heinrich
Nau (ed.), Der Werturteilsstreit. Die Äusserungen zur Werturteildiskussion im Ausschuss des Vereins für Sozialpolitik
(1913), Marburg, Metropolis Verlag, 1996.
21
For the English version see: Max Weber, Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretive Sociology, Volume 1,
Berkeley and Los Angeles, University of California Press, 1978, pp.104-107.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
6
War, like every war in history, has brought these problems emphatically to the fore in the form of the
problems of war economy and the post-war adjustment. It is, indeed, one of the merits of Otto Neurath to
have produced an analysis of just these problems, which, however much it is open to criticism both in
principle and in detail, was one of the first and was very penetrating. That “the profession” has taken little
notice of his work is not surprising because until now he has given us only stimulating suggestions, which
are, however, so very broad that it is difficult to use them as a basis of intensive analysis. The problem only
begins at the point where his public pronouncements up to date have left off”
22
.
As Weber credited him, Neurath wrote earliest about war economics. His interest in war economics had
been sparked by his father who, himself had written some unpublished material on the issue. He so
published about Kriegswirtschaft from the very beginning of his brief career as an academic economist, in
1909, up to 1818, when he increasingly became concerned with the problem of socialization, economic
planning and administrative economics. In his articles particular attention was given to the differences
between the economic crisis brought about by war and cyclical crises. Neurath tried to depict a very precise
macroeconomic scenario in which real and monetary consequences of war could be analyzed in their effect
on well-being of people. Great care was taken in comparing such modern scenario with ancient economies
where war was considered just one means of acquisition among many and the differences in the underlying
living order procured completely different results.
His analysis always began with a resume on the history of thought concerning war and economics. It is not
difficult to retrace Neurath’s historical presentation of the problem to the influence of the younger
historical school. In fact he explicitly made reference to Gustav Schmoller
23
, but also to historians like Franz
Oppenheimer
24
and Theodor Mommsen
25
. Looking back in history, it was easy to find a conception of war
completely opposite to the liberalist one. Aristotle would look at war just as a kind of hunt, and many Greek
and Roman authors would see in war a possibly gainful occupation
26
. “In this view, -observed Neurath - war
is a natural source of income just like agriculture, robbery, fishing; by contrast, lending money for interest
and commerce were considered unnatural”
27
.Given these premises, on hand of many contemporary
authors, among them Diodorus, Polybius, Dionysius of Halicarnassus, Plutarch, Livy and Appian, he acutely
22
For the English version see: Max Weber, Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretive Sociology, Volume 1,
Berkeley and Los Angeles, University of California Press, 1978, p.106.
23
Gustav Schmoller, Die geschichtliche Entwicklung der Unternehmung, Leipzig, Duncker & Humblot, 1890.
24
Franz Oppenheimer, Der Staat, Frankfurt am Main, Rutten und Loening, 1907.
25
Theodor Mommsen, Römische Geschichte, vols. 1–3. Leipzig, Weidmann, 1854–56.
26
Otto Neurath, Uneinlösliches Girogeld im Kriegsfalle, „Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung und Volkswirtschaft
im Deutschen Reich“, 33, 1909, p.117. See also: Otto Neurath, Probleme der Kriegswirtschaftslehere, „Zeitschrift für
die gesamte Staatswirtschaft“, I, 3, 1913, p. 440.
27
Ibid.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
7
analyzed the effects of war on the distribution of income in antiquity, in order to draw a comparison with
the present.
Neurath distinguished wars fought by enlisting part of the peasant population and wars waged through
mercenaries. Whenever farmers were concerned, a short war could enrich, through booty, the whole
population, while a long war could damage little proprietors who worked their land by themselves, while
benefiting large landholders who employed slaves. In case of mercenary troops, they could be a vent for
surplus population and constitute a body of future subjects once granted the property of conquered land.
Considering the practices on the distribution of plunder, general consensus in favor of war could be easily
obtained, because positive economic consequences were particularly evident to troops and enlisted
population. In modern times, instead, when no such practices existed, common man could not easily
evaluate the economic effects of warfare as “the ‘warrior used to booty’ whose heroic deeds were
described by the ancient authors”
28
.
In antiquity warfare further procured new areas of production and slave labor. If these effects, though, had
to be considered positive or negative for an economy depended on the changes in comparative advantages
following the new acquisitions and the productivity of slave labor. Merchants usually expected gains from
war, thanks to the removal of competition and the opening of new markets, the same held for money
lenders. Negative consequences for the trading and financial sectors, instead, would be limited in ancient
economies by the small development and impact of these sectors. Generally the positive effects for all
strata of population would so overcome the negative ones, in the victorious country obviously.
“In the Middle Ages – observed Neurath further – and at the beginning of modern times, the same view of
war was held as in antiquity. To the victorious it seemed a blessing, to the defeated it was one of the
greatest scourges. Changing fortunes of war could ravage many countries”
29
. In the centrally ordered
economies of the time, military administrations and market regulations stood on the same plane and were
both controlled by the government. Not everyone approved war as a way of acquisition. That war could be
profitable, though, nobody denied. This view remained prevalent till the colonial wars of the 17th century,
when authors like Caspar Klock
30
extensively discussed the question of war income
31
.
28
Otto Neurath, War Economics, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, p.156.
29
Otto Neurath, War Economics, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, p.157.
30
On the importance of Klock in the history of economic thought see: Bertram Schefold, Einleitung, in: Kaspar Klock,
Tractatus juridico-politico-polemico-historicus De Aerario, Hildesheim, Olms, 2009, vo. 1, pp. V-CXIII.
31
Caspar Klock, Tractatus juridico-, politico-, polemico-historicus de aerario, Nürnberg, 1651.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
8
Neurath was aware that, historically, it had been the spreading of liberalism that had eliminated every
aspect of state administration from the theory of economics, even if the founders of classical political
economy had still been concerned with those issues, along with the prevailing interest in the market
economy. The study of the market economy had had the advantage of allowing a strict theoretical analysis
of specific relationships and problems, but many aspects, as the consequences of war, had so been
completely neglected. Up to the 18th century, on the contrary, war had still been considered one out of
many income sources of wealth, the costs and benefits of which were confronted in order to decide a line
of action
32
. In 1767 Adam Ferguson still entitled a chapter of his An Essay on the History of Civil Society “Of
National Defense and Conquest”
33
, while in 1776 Adam Smith already dedicated a chapter of the fifth book
of The Wealth of Nations to “The Expense of Defense”
34
. It might be concluded that at the end of the 18th
century, the expanding of trade had rendered wars and protectionism more a hindrance than a support to
economic growth. Free traders had further introduced ethical considerations in the economic discourse,
purging it of the notion of wars of aggression. As a result wars were considered only a means of defense
and were evaluated as a cost. “The fact that political economists have given so little consideration to war
within their systems, and that the number of dedicated investigations in no way corresponds to the
importance of the subject, - Neurath stressed - is connected with the great influence the English free
traders still have. They often denied the possibility that a war could enrich people; for them, war was
nothing but a disturbance of commercial economy”
35
.
But as English economic conditions had favored the emergence of free trade theories, so German
circumstances had inspired protectionist theories by Friedrich List and some of his contemporaries
36
.
Friedrich List even suspected a certain malevolence on part of English free traders, bent on excluding other
nations from the development path of their country, by imposing free trade as a universal economic policy.
So long as states did not share the same economic situation, protectionism might be needed to avoid
complete economic subjection of less developed states
37
. List’s voice, though, had remained a fairly isolate
one among the choir of liberalism of the nineteenth century.
32
Otto Neurath, Uneinlösliches Girogeld im Kriegsfalle, „Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung und Volkswirtschaft
im Deutschen Reich“, 33, 1909, p.117.
33
Adam Ferguson, An Essay on the History of civil society, Edinburgh, 1767.
34
Adam Smith, An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, London, Strahan, 1776.
35
Otto Neurath, War Economics, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, p.154.
36
Otto Neurath, Uneinlösliches Girogeld im Kriegsfalle, „Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung und Volkswirtschaft
im Deutschen Reich“, 33, 1909, p.118.
37
Otto Neurath, War Economics, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, pp.159-160.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
9
“When we leaf through the encyclopedic works on economics of the last century – wrote Neurath – as the
Dictionary of Economics or the Paperback Encyclopedia of State Administration, it is useless to look for
articles on war and its consequences. The same happens with treatises and manuals”
38
. An exception were
some empirical studies, related to the Napoleonic Wars, that had tried to quantify and analyze the effects
of warfare on the well-being of the population or the wealth of a state
39
. In this regard Neurath would
often quote Patrick Colquhoun
40
and Joseph Lowe
41
. Particularly interesting the work of Gustav von
Gülich
42
, who tried to construe a complete history of trade characterized by war cycles.
At the bend of the century Neurath noticed that the growing dimension of troops and the related financial
and taxation problems had revived the field of war economics. In 1913, in his brief article on the definition
of war economics as an autonomous discipline
43
, Neurath reviewed such contributions, spanning the first
decade of the twentieth century. He quoted Riesser on the financing problems preceding and following a
war
44
, Jöhr on the specific case of Switzerland
45
and Sombart’s Kriegs und Kapitalismus
46
. In his Die
Kriegswirtschaft
47
he further cited Adolph Wagner
48
and Carl August Struensee
49
.
All these researches analyzed singular problems, but a complete and general study of the issue was still
missing
50
. “In contrast – noted Neurath – to how special problems are treated, questions concerning the
wide-ranging interconnections of the phenomena are usually only hinted at”
51
.
38
Otto Neurath, Die Kriegswirtschaftslehre als Sonderdisziplin, „Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv“, 1, p.345.
39
Otto Neurath, Die Kriegswirtschaftslehre als Sonderdisziplin, „Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv“, 1, pp.343-344.
40
Patrick Colquhoun, A Treatise on the Wealth, Power, and Resources of the British Empire, London: Joseph Mawson,
1814.
41
Joseph Lowe, The Present State of England in Regard to Agriculture, Trade and Finance; With a Comparison of the
Prospects of England and France, London, 1822.
42
Ludwig Gustav von Gülich, Geschichtliche Darstellung des Handels, der Gewerbe und des Ackerbaus der
bedeutendsten handeltreibenden Staaten, Bd. 1–5, Jena, Frommann, 1830–1845.
43
Otto Neurath, Die Kriegswirtschaftslehre als Sonderdisziplin, „Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv“, 1, pp.342-348.
44
Jakob Riesser, Finanzielle Kriegsbereitschaft und Kriegführung, Jena, G. Fischer, 1909.
45
Adolf Jöhr, Die Volkswirtschaft der Schweiz im Kriegsfall, Zürich, Kuhn & Schürch, 1912.
46
Werner Sombart, Krieg und Kapitalismus, München, Duncker & Humblot, 1913.
47
Otto Neurath, Die Kriegswirtschaft, „Jahresbericht der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie“, 16, 1910, pp. 5-54. The
essay was reprinted as Otto Neurath, Durch die Kriegswirtschaft zur Naturalwirtschaft, Munich, Callwey, 1919. The
English translation, based on a draft by Marie Neurath, has been published as: Otto Neurath, War Economics, in:
Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht,
Kluwer, pp.153-199.
48
Adolph Wagner, Finanzwissenschaft, Bd. 1-4, Leipzig, C.F. Winter, 1910.
49
Carl August Struensee von Carlsbach. Über die Mittel, deren ein Staat . sich bedienen kann, um zn seinen
außerordentlichen Bedürfnissen, besonders in Kriegszeiten, nötige Geld zu erhalten, in: Carl August Struensee von
Carlsbach, Abhandlungen über wichtige Gegenstände der Staatswirthschaft, Bd. 1, Berlin, J. F. Unger, 1800, pp.167-
434.
50
Otto Neurath, Uneinlösliches Girogeld im Kriegsfalle, „Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung und Volkswirtschaft
im Deutschen Reich“, 33, 1909, p.118; Otto Neurath, Die Kriegswirtschaftslehre als Sonderdisziplin,
„Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv“, 1, p. 343; Otto Neurath, Probleme der Kriegswirtschaftslehere, „Zeitschrift für die
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
10
Neurath so arrived at the conclusion that a new theory had to be born for which he proposed the
denomination Kriegswirtschaftslehre
52
. He had no doubt: “That a specific theory is needed in relation to
war follows from the fact that a war crisis starkly distinguishes itself from the recurrent crises of our
economic order. While ‘normal’crises, for example, have a slow preparation and constrain the whole
economy to successive liquidations, usually starting in a precise sector and then expanding to others, a war
crisis appears abruptly and concerns all sectors of the economy at once. (…) In this sense it is not enough to
take the peace economy and study how war changes its single components, as the monetary system,
credit, production, etc. It is necessary to study all relationships as a whole, as has not been done for a long
time”
53
. Neurath would so define war economics as the systematic study of the positive and negative
consequences of war
54
, a study that would allow to show, at least schematically “how the economic
situation of specific groups of the population can change during the war”
55
. To this end “a kind of inventory
of real incomes would have to be designed which then could give an approximate survey of the distribution
of pleasures and displeasures”
56
.
The reason why such a theory had not been developed yet was that the existing economic theory would
not allow the analysis of different economic orders, taking for granted that only the market order could and
should exist and be studied. Too much, observed Neurath, had economists looked upon astronomy as the
scientific theoretical model of reference. It was useless to search for a universally valid economic order.
Economic orders, instead should have been studied like different machines capable of performing the same
task, machines as dissimilar as could a steam machine be in respect to an electric engine
57
.
The war economist should so compare, on the base of empirical observations, the economic orders of
singular states in order to reconstruct all interdependencies and evaluate the consequences of war on the
economy in its entirety. Such issues, concluded Neurath, should be researched in depth well before the
reality of a war would constrain to immediate measure taken without the necessary thought
58
.
gesamte Staatswirtschaft“, I, 3, 1913, p. 439; Otto Neurath, Die Naturalwirtschaftslehre und der Naturalkalkul in ihren
Beziehungen zur Kriegswirtschaftslehre, „Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv“, vol.8, 2, p.245.
51
Otto Neurath, War Economics, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, p.153.
52
Otto Neurath, Die Kriegswirtschaftslehre als Sonderdisziplin, „Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv“, 1, pp.342-348.
53
Otto Neurath, Die Kriegswirtschaftslehre als Sonderdisziplin, „Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv“, 1, p.343.
54
Otto Neurath, Probleme der Kriegswirtschaftslehere, „Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswirtschaft“, I, 3, 1913, p. 439.
55
Otto Neurath, War Economics, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, p.153.
56
Ibid.
57
Otto Neurath, Die Kriegswirtschaftslehre als Sonderdisziplin, „Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv“, 1, p.347.
58
Otto Neurath, Uneinlösliches Girogeld im Kriegsfalle, „Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung und Volkswirtschaft
im Deutschen Reich“, 33, 1909, pp.119-121.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
11
FIRST ATTEMPTS TOWARD A MACROECONOMICS OF WAR
“The present time is absorbed by the significance of war for the human kind” (Otto Neurath)
59
In his first essay on Kriegswirtschaft, written in 1909 for Schmoller’s Jahrbuch, Neurath specifically tackled
the problem of convertibility of Girogeld in times of war
60
, studying the monetary consequences usually
associated with a war economy. The views expressed in the article were only reinforced in time and can be
traced in all his subsequent publications on war economy. In nuce they already contained Neurath’s idea
that an in-kind economy would sustain the strains of war much better than a monetary one. A quite
revolutionary thesis that was discussed, during his lifetime, by Arthur Wolfgang Cohn
61
.
In case of war, noted Neurath, the necessity of gold and silver reserves at disposition of the state was
heightened by the imperative to sustain the international financial credibility of the country and to buy
abroad goods that were no longer available inland. Internally precious metals were needed to confront the
frequent runs on banks and the hoarding of reserves by individuals. Neurath considered inevitable to
suspend convertibility and suggested to do so as soon as possible. All reserves should so be put at disposal
of the government to obtain loans from the international market and buy whatever primary necessity
goods were needed to nourish the population or win the war. Internal payments, instead, should be
cleared through giro credit transfers, eliminating money completely from the circulation. Accounts would
be used and needed only for such transfers, while withdrawals would be prohibited
62
. If such measures
would not prove sufficient to guarantee the regular functioning of the economy, the state should switch
toward in-kind payments, both internally and externally.
The sketched schema of Neurath’s first article on war economy was fully developed in 1910 in the lengthier
essay on Kriegswirtschaft, published on the journal of the new trade academy in Wien, where Neurath
taught at the time
63
. The treatise not only elaborated and extended the reasoning lines of the previous one,
59
Otto Neurath, Probleme der Kriegswirtschaftslehere, „Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswirtschaft“, I, 3, 1913, p. 438.
60
Otto Neurath, Uneinlösliches Girogeld im Kriegsfalle, „Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung und Volkswirtschaft
im Deutschen Reich“, 33, 1909, pp.117-121.
61
The most complete analysis of Neurath’s monetary thought is to be found in: Arthur Wolfgang Cohn, Kann das Geld
abgeschafft werden?, Jena, Fisher Verlag, 1920. A more recent appraisal is: Peter Mooslechner, Some Reflections on
Neurath's Monetary Thought in the Historical Context of the Birth of Modern Monetary Economics, in: Thomas E.
Uebel, Neurath’s Economics in Critical Context, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath
Economic Writings Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, pp.101-114.
62
Otto Neurath, Uneinlösliches Girogeld im Kriegsfalle, „Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung und Volkswirtschaft
im Deutschen Reich“, 33, 1909, pp.119-121.
63
Otto Neurath, Die Kriegswirtschaft, „Jahresbericht der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie“, 16, 1910, pp. 5-54. The
essay was reprinted as Otto Neurath, Durch die Kriegswirtschaft zur Naturalwirtschaft, Munich, Callwey, 1919. The
English translation, based on a draft by Marie Neurath, has been published as: Otto Neurath, War Economics, in:
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
12
but added an analysis of the non-monetary consequences of war, in particular those regarding the
distribution of wealth.
Neurath began with an illuminating and provocative statement. He candidly observed that, contrary to the
catastrophic predictions of free traders, “in recent times great wars are not as damaging as might have
been expected, either to the defeated or to the victorious side, and that, on the contrary, something like an
economic boom can be observed during or shortly after the war”
64
. He rejected the idea, though, that this
favorable result would be the consequence of some kind of efficiency effect: “Such deliberations – he
contended – start from the assumption that a fixed amount of economic forces and a fixed amount of
money are available, to be used one way or another, whereas in fact things are much more complicated”
65
.
War as the selection of the fittest also in the economic sphere had no appeal for Neurath. He, instead,
attributed the positive economic consequences of war to an essential characteristic of modern economies:
the underemployment of resources. Neurath’s thesis on this point merits a lengthier quotation.
“As a consequence of our institutions, - he wrote - especially those regulating money, credit and market
affairs, we are forced to restrict our productive capacity to a certain degree. Cartels intentionally bring it
about that less is produced than could be consumed by the population. Even states themselves artificially
try to prevent saturation with all commodities, partly by their destruction, partly by protective tariffs. Since
then we intentionally do not utilize fully or even waste the available manpower and productive capacities,
there are always sufficient reserves. If disturbances of a certain kind occur as, for example, in the case of
war, restrictions can be removed and productive forces are liberated. In the course of this, wealth may rise
far above the pre-war level”
66
.
In the eyes of Neurath, war could so act as a Keynesian policy ante litteram, liberating an economy from an
underemployment equilibrium. War could have, though, a very different economic outcome in case of an
economy already in a full employment situation. “If, however, - noted Neurath – all our powers and means
were already in full operation in peace time, war could cause much more devastation. Even then wounds
may heal quickly; but only in rare cases, for example, if foreign property is seized, could war bring great
Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht,
Kluwer, pp.153-199.
64
Otto Neurath, War Economics, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, p.160.
65
Otto Neurath, War Economics, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, p.162.
66
Otto Neurath, War Economics, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, p.161.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
13
economic advantages; an economic recovery, however, would not be possible during the war, and the
victorious state would more frequently suffer serious harm as well”
67
.
Image 1 Assembling of airplane parts in the Karosseriefabrik in Wien-Favoriten (Source: “Österreichs
Illustrierte Zeitung” 13. August 1916/Copyright Vienna Library in the City Hall)
67
Ibid.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
14
Obviously this line of thought could not be an incitement to wage war in order to obtain full employment.
Neurath used these considerations, on the opposite, to underline the fallacies of the present economic
order and advocate its complete reformation. “Every reform of our economic system – he considered –
which allows all our powers and capabilities to develop more fully, would therefore be in the interest of
world peace”
68
. First step toward such a reform would be to exchange productivity to profitability as
criterion of economic decisions, a feat possible only by switching toward in-kind calculations from
monetary calculation. These hints would be fully developed by Neurath only in further writings. The
remaining part of the essay on Kriegswirtschaft, instead, contained an accurate investigation of the causal
relationships behind the increase in productivity observed in war times
69
.
The first apparent consequence of war detected by Neurath was a general raising of prices, caused by
increased demand of certain goods: foodstuff, weapons and military provisions. The need for some goods,
then, that could not be imported any more, stimulated inland production and speculations. Shortages could
even inspire innovations and technological advancements. At the same time scarcity of labor could result in
wage increases. “The enrichment of some circles of the population, entrepreneurs, speculators and
workers, reasoned Neurath - indirectly means an enrichment of all those who have goods to sell to these
people. The advantages of the war can therefore far exceed its burdens for wide circles of the
population”
70
.
To this positive demand effect Neurath also added a monetary one. The increased circulation of paper
money, in his view, had the effect of a stimulus to production and that of a protective duty, in case a sum
would be charged for exchanging paper money against metal. Industries which had artificially limited their
production could so enlarge it with little costs and great profits. Demand could accelerate the velocity of
circulation too, with an ulterior stimulating effect.
The boom could surely be followed by a crisis, but to eliminate crises war was no solution: “in our economic
order a permanent advance without crises is not possible; but this is true for times of peace as it is for times
of war. These obstructions are not caused by production and consumption, not by the political order or the
68
Ibid.
69
In the opinion of Neurath the only study done with a sufficient measure of completeness on the matter had been
Henry George’s analysis of the effect of the American Civil War on the economy of the American states. See: Henry
George, Social Problems, Chicago and New York, Belford, Clarke and Company, 1883.
70
Otto Neurath, War Economics, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, p.163.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
15
distribution of income, but by the market economy and the credit system”
71
. It would be necessary to
change the existing economic order with an economy in kind to overcame cycles.
Lastly, Neurath tried to ascertain the effect of war on the distribution of income in modern economies.
However the state administration managed war demands in terms of goods, through in kind transfers or
not, the consequences on the income distribution would be mixed and not conducible to a definite
direction. The war demands in terms of money, instead, would decidedly influence income distribution in a
precise way, depending on the financing adopted, through taxes or loans.
In antiquity, noted Neurath, war equipment constituted the way through which everyone contributed to
finance a war and the effect was progressive. Booty, then, granted advantages to all. The alternative use of
treasury for financing war would not increase inequality in a particular way. In modern financial economies,
instead, financing war by taxes could be done progressively, while interests on loans would be paid only to
owners of public debt, so favoring only a very limited part of the population or perhaps even foreigners. As
a consequence it would make sense to favor progressive taxes above loans, whose yield was regressive, to
finance wars.
Nonetheless, also the opposite held if, as Neurath underlined, “raising a loan can lead to making goods
available which a nation’s economy possesses but cannot bring into circulation, because there was not
enough money”
72
. Here again different effects would follow if loans were drawn from hoarded funds or the
circulating money. In the first case the loan would bring into circulation new funds stimulating production,
an effect not dissimilar from absorbing money that could have financed over-speculation. Such a policy
management would not be simple. “The aim of the loan policy – concluded Neurath – as well as that of the
tax policy often is to increase the real income of the population, possibly to change its composition, and
simultaneously to increase money income. It is difficult, however, to achieve these different goals at the
same time”
73
.
As a general rule Neurath held that loans had a much greater stimulating effect than taxes
74
and that inland
war requirements should have been covered through inland loans and external ones through foreign loans.
71
Otto Neurath, War Economics, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, p.163.
72
Otto Neurath, War Economics, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, p.174.
73
Otto Neurath, War Economics, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, p.175.
74
„Experience has shown that use of loans often stimulates enterprise and speeds the movement of goods. The state
can distribute orders in grand style, workers are employed, more taxes can be paid. These beneficial effects have been
noticed particularly in England where it led to the overestimation of loans by many authors. But even disregarding
these favourable effects, loans can mean a much smaller burden on a nation than a tax yielding the same amount”.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
16
Image 2 Advertisement for the subscription of war loans in Austria („Zeichnet 7. Kriegsanleihe“, 1917)
Otto Neurath, War Economics, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, p.176.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
17
Neurath further considered indispensable that a state actively managed its own debt on the market, so as
to control its cost and avoid speculation excesses. “Political economy thereby returns to the view which
ruled in the 18th century under the influence of mercantilism. Measures to influence exchange rates of
money and bonds was at the time equally familiar in practice and in theory. Turning away from extreme
economic liberalism means that old traditions are taken up again, now also in monetary theory”
75
.
Regarding the disturbances that war could cause to the monetary system of the state, Neurath, as in 1909,
suggested to abolish convertibility immediately, in order to salvage reserves and put them at disposition of
the State as its treasure. One last point deserves to be mentioned on the matter, because absent in the
preceding article and of a certain theoretical value. As seen, Neurath considered that an increased
monetary circulation in war could result in increased production depending on the underemployment of
resources. Another condition, though, was necessary for an issue of paper money to result in augmented
production: “the mood of the population”
76
. “Where confidence in the future is strong – wrote Neurath - ,
it is easy for the economy to go on in a lively and prosperous way; but if business is sluggish and speed of
circulation reduced, an increase in money would push the state into repeated issues. There will be no
increase in production, no corresponding increase of tax capacity, no increase of capability to buy bonds –
nothing but a general inflation”
77
. In the case that hyperinflation and severe financial disturbances could
not be controlled the state would have to recur to in-kind payments, of which war history brought ample
proofs.
Neurath concluded: “The main result of our investigation may be expressed as follows: war forces a nation
to pay more attention to the amount of goods which are at its disposal, less to the available amounts of
money than it usually does. (…) Money reveal itself more clearly as only one of the many means to provide
goods. (…) If productive capacity is intact but not money affairs, one last possibility remains – economy in
kind”
78
.
75
Otto Neurath, War Economics, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, pp.178-179.
76
Otto Neurath, War Economics, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, p.190.
77
Ibid.
78
Otto Neurath, War Economics, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, p.193.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
18
THE PRACTICE OF WAR ECONOMICS
“Particularly the field of war, in which we often meet the most extreme form of political calculation – the so called machiavellism –
is the strange crossroad of ancient impulses, traditional behavior and cold blooded reflection” (Otto Neurath)
79
As seen, Neurath defined the task of war economics to divide states in homogenous groups and compare
them in regard to the prevalence of a monetary or an in-kind economic system, the permanence of
Gemeinschaft-like social structures, the distribution of land, property and income, the kind of military
service adopted, constrictive or not, and the grade of employment of resources
80
. Thanks to a research
assigned to him by Eugen von Philippovich and Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk
81
, Neurath had a unique
opportunity to experiment his newly defined science in the reality of the Balkan Wars. He so visited Sofia
and Belgrade during mobilization and at the beginning of hostilities. The study had been financed by a
Carnegie Endowment for International Peace and would be published in 1913 in a series of articles
82
and in
the essay on Serbia’s success in the Balkan War
83
.
Following the interpretative scheme outlined in 1910, Neurath examined in detail Serbia’s economy before
and during the war to ascertain the superiority in armaments, food and transports that had been decisive
for Serbia’s success against Turkey. In his eyes Serbia had profited from the relative backwardness of its
economy. Serbia’s agriculture, with a prevalence of little proprietorship, presented an homogeneous
economic and social structure, characterized by the institution of Zadruga. These informal cooperatives
diffused credit, functioned as educational centers and provided technological help. These traits of Serbia’s
economy, the prevalence of agriculture and the Gemeinschaft-like structure, guaranteed that the negative
effects of war would be limited to a minimum. In the same direction operated the relative homogeneity of
religion and ethnicity of Serbia, both societal stabilizers.
Although the winter harvest after the declaration of war could not be completely saved, the reduction in
production could be contained and both troops and population could be supported through war. The
trading war with Austria had spurned Serbians to look for foreign markets, stimulating entrepreneurship, as
79
Otto Neurath, Probleme der Kriegswirtschaftslehere, „Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswirtschaft“, I, 3, 1913, p. 442.
80
Otto Neurath, Die Kriegswirtschaftslehre als Sonderdisziplin, „Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv“, 1, p.347.
81
See: Thomas Uebel, Vernunftkritik und Wissenschaft. Otto Neurath und der erste Wiener Kreis, Vienna, Springer
Verlag, pp.310-312.
82
Otto Neurath, Kriegswirtschaftliche Eindrücke aus Galizien, „Der Österreichische Volkswirt“, vol. 5, 18, 1913, pp.355-
358; Otto Neurath, Die Ökonomischen Wirkungen des Balkankrieges auf Serbien und Bulgarien, „Jahrbücher der
Gesellschaft österreichischen Volkswirte“, 1913, pp.1-19.
83
Otto Neurath, Serbiens Erfolge im Balkankriege, Vienna, Manz, 1913. For the English version, see: Otto Neurath,
Serbia’s success in the Balkan War, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, pp.200-234.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
19
had the necessity to provide weapons and military provisions. Also the management of reserves, the use of
gold to back up foreign loans, the control over the circulation of money had been sources of success for
Serbia.
Obviously the surprising success of Serbs had also been the result of Turkey’s weakness. “The political
situation – observed Neurath – was extremely favourable” but “in addition their stage of development
allowed them to enjoy the advantages of an agrarian state based mainly on an economy in kind while they
were already drawing some benefit from a money economy since they were able to raise international
loans. The simplicity of its economic conditions strengthened the impact of this peasant democracy.
National and religious factors supported political and military actions in every respect, and helped to create
a general enthusiasm”
84
.
The schema detailed by Neurath in his previous theoretical essays is easily recognizable in the study on
Serbia and the Balkan states. Considering that data were not easily available, Neurath succeeded in
detailing all major points of his theoretical reasoning. Starting with the prevailing agriculture, to the
presence of Gemeinschaft-like structure, to the questions of religion and ethnicity, Neurath correctly
represented the life order of Serbia. He further sketched the capacity of government to administer the
money market and obtain foreign loans, whereas communities and cooperatives maintained the
agricultural activity and managed the distribution of goods. All the while Neurath used whenever possible
in-kind statistics.
The Balkan wars became, so, for Neurath an extraordinary occasion to collect data
85
about the emerging of
barter trade, even at international level
86
, the centralized administration of production, the controlled
distribution of consumption goods and the destabilizing or even vanishing of financial systems. The same
endeavor guided Neurath during WWI.
Ernst Lackenbacher remembered Neurath in 1914 as a the “redbearded giant” that in Galicia entertained
his fellow officers on the field with vivid historical reconstructions
87
; but the engineer Neumann recalled,
instead, how Neurath convinced a General of the Austrian Army to create a special department of the War
Ministry to collect information a and data. “We should found a department for war economy – he
remembered Neurath to have said - and start work seriously. We are learning a lot from successes, even
84
Otto Neurath, Serbiens Erfolge im Balkankriege, Vienna, Manz, 1913. For the English version, see: Otto Neurath,
Serbia’s success in the Balkan War, in: Thomas E. Uebel and Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Otto Neurath Economic Writings
Selections 1904–1945, Dordrecht, Kluwer, p.233.
85
Otto Neurath, Die Kriegswirtschaftslehre als Sonderdisziplin, „Weltwirtschatliches Archiv“, 1, 1, 1913, p.23.
86
See: Otto Neurath, Grundsätzliches über den Kompensationsverkehr im internationalen Warenhandel,
„Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv“, 13, 2, 1918, pp.23-35.
87
Ernst Lakenbacher, Excerpts, in: Marie Neurath, Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Empiricism and sociology, Dordrecht,
Springer, 1973, pp. 12-14.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
20
more from failures, but nobody has time to keep a record of our experiences for the benefit of the future.
Through such neglect, they will all be lost and wasted”
88
.
The Scientific Committee of War Economy was so established in 1916 as part of the Austro-Hungarian
Ministry of War and Neurath was appointed head of the General War and Economics section
89
. In this
position, Neurath dedicated all his efforts to gather as much figures as possible on the war economy, in
form of statistics but also posters, medals and maps that would help analyze how war had changed the
everyday life of common people
90
.
Image 3 Balkan Peasants photographed for the book W. F. Bailey, The Slavs Of The War Zone, London,
Chapman & Hall, 1916
88
G. Neumann, Military Life, in: Marie Neurath, Robert S. Cohen (eds.), Empiricism and sociology, Dordrecht, Springer,
1973, p.10.
89
Nader Vossoughian, The War Economy and the War Museum: Otto Neurath and the Museum of War Economy in
Leipzig c.1918, in: Elisabeth Nemeth, Stefan W. Schmitz, Thomas E. Uebel (eds.), Otto Neurath’s Economics in Context,
Vienna, Springer, 2008, p.133.
90
Otto Neurath, Das wissenschaftliche Kommittee für Kriegswirtschaft des K. und K. Kriegsministerium. Entwurf eines
Arbeitsplanes, Kriegsarchiv, Archiv der Republik, Vienna.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
21
His extraordinary efforts in this field were rewarded not only with an official commendation from the
Austrian government, but also with the appointment as director of the Museum of War Economy in
Leipzig
91
. The museum had as its scope to exhibit to the widest possible public the economic conditions of
Germany during WWI, not only in their monetary form, but also in their informal part. The trading and the
banking sectors would surely be represented through graphs and statistics, but also the innovations
stimulated by shortages and the entire life of single products from production to consumption would be
showed. The expositions should have been interactive, engaging the spectator directly in the
comprehension of the processes through which a peace economy was transformed into a war economy
92
.
The only major achievement of the museum became the exhibition on War Bolckade and War Economy
held in August 1918. The display exactly followed Neurath’s war economics in showing how war had slowly
diffused an in-kind economy at the expense of the monetary economy. As a consequence the
communitarian spirit had been strengthened, the state had increasingly intervened in economic relations,
agriculture had gained importance and all resources had been directed toward Germany’s self-sufficiency.
Shortly after the closing down of the exhibit, war ended and so the experience of Neurath in the museum.
Leipzig, though, was only the first step in Neurath’s career as a museum director
93
. It also represented the
beginning of the development of a universal pictorial language that would result in ISOTYPE
94
.
Isotypes satisfied the enlightenment ideal of Neurath as a universal means of diffusing knowledge,
particularly regarding the economic order. In regard to war economics, Neurath dedicated to it two
silhouettes of Modern man in the making, his book on the economic and social history of mankind through
isotypes. The silhouettes (Image 4) represented, at the eve of WWII, a comparison of different coalitions of
states in terms of in-kind statistics. Instead of evaluating the economic power of the nations through
monetary indexes, Neurath synthetized it in simple and understandable isotypes depicting the availability
of goods.
Such representations might seem a childish result for serious economic research, and Max Weber did not
hesitate to classify Neurath’s in-kind calculations as primitive and short sighted
95
. To their efficacy there is
91
Nancy Cartwright, Jordi Cat, Lola Fleck, Thomas E. Uebel, Otto Neurath: Philosophy Between Science and Politics,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 2008, pp. 19-21.
92
Otto Neurath, Die Kriegswirtschaftslehre und ihre Bedeutung für die Zukunft, „Veröffentlichungen des Deutschen
Kriegswirtschaftsmuseum zu Leipzig“, 4, 1918.
93
In inter-war Vienna Neurath directed the Museum of Town Planning (1919-24), and the Social and Economic
Museum (1924-34). See: Hadwig Kraeutler, Otto Neurath. Museum and Exhibition Work, Frankfurt am Main, Peter
Lang, pp. 101-174.
94
Hadwig Kraeutler, Otto Neurath. Museum and Exhibition Work, Frankfurt am Main, Peter Lang, p.115.
95
For the English version see: Max Weber, Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretive Sociology, Volume 1,
Berkeley and Los Angeles, University of California Press, 1978, p.106.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
22
little to counter: it might be noted that in none of the coalitions examined Germany attained the better
results.
Image 4 Relative economic power of different prospective coalitions in a world war as represented through
isotypes in 1939 (Otto Neurath, De Moderne Mensch Ontstaat, Amsterdam, 1940, pp. 84-85)
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
23
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
24
FROM WAR A NEW ECONOMICS
“History shows well enough the great influence that theories exercise through their capacity to influence the public opinion with
their strictly formulated results” (Otto Neurath)
96
Following the thought of Otto Neurath from 1909 to the end of the experience in the Museum of War
Economy in Leipzig, it is evident how the study of war economy had inspired an entirely new definition of
the economic science
97
. Increasingly in every further articles on Kriegswirtschaft, Neurath expressed his
dissatisfaction with the current economics, all the while introducing a new theoretical framework for
economic research.
“Economics so far – he so wrote in 1916 – is strictly related to the monetary economy and has so almost
completely ignored the natural in-kind economy”
98
. This made necessary to retrieve a conceptual world for
the discipline that allowed to research the monetary economy as the in-kind economy, that comprised
home economy, political economy and market economy. Such conceptual world began with a new object
for the theory and practice of economics: wealth. A wealth defined not through monetary measures but in-
kind
99
.
Starting with this definition Neurath’s economic science could study of the widest possible assortment of
organizational structures and classifying them as to their economy, i.e. their capability to increment the
wealth of mankind. Depending on the group of people the happiness of which was object of study, it could
include family’s economy, political economy and also cosmopolitan economy, all subdivisions that, taken
from Aristotle to Friedrich List, were now granted validity in new fields. Not only past economies, but also
present and future orders of life (Lebensordnungen) possessed the right to be studied and classified as to
their effects on people’s sensations (Lebenstimmungen). Economics became thusly a comparative science
based on empirical data statistically collected, but consisting of an infinite number of models, many of
which with no relation whatsoever to reality. In this sense Neurath excluded any kind of ethical prejudice
from restricting economic analysis. Acquiring methods as war and smuggling should, in his view, have been
96
Otto Neurath, Die Naturalwirtschaftslehre und der Naturalkalkul in ihren Beziehungen zur Kriegswirtschaftslehre,
„Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv“, vol.8, 2, p.245.
97
Otto Neurath, Probleme der Kriegswirtschaftslehre, „Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft“, 69, 1913,
pp.433-501.
98
Otto Neurath, Die Naturalwirtschaftslehre und der Naturalkalkul in ihren Beziehungen zur Kriegswirtschaftslehre,
„Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv“, vol.8, 2, p.246.
99
Otto Neurath, Die Naturalwirtschaftslehre und der Naturalkalkul in ihren Beziehungen zur Kriegswirtschaftslehre,
„Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv“, vol.8, 2, p.246.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
25
studied exactly as market exchange and production, being evaluated, by economists, only in their effect on
people’s Lebenstimmungen.
It comes as no surprise that the most famous image of Neurath, that of the ship, is to be found for the first
time in his essay Probleme der Kriegswirtschaftslehreof 1913. “We are like seamen – wrote Neurath – who
on open sea are constrained to reconstruct their vessel, changing its entire structure, by substituting beam
by beam, with pieces they are carrying along with them or find drifting. They cannot make port so they will
never be able to eliminate the ship entirely and rebuild it completely. The new ship always comes out of
the old one through a continuous restoration“
100
.
Neurath’s images bore a strong message: no science would ever be complete, no science could be rebuilt
from scratch. A statement firstly made, with rhetorical vehemence, discussing war economics. Through it
Neurath attacked the pretense of scientists to produce perfect and complete systems of thought with no
defects or anomalies, allowing no changes or amelioration. Such ‘systematists’ were “born liars” because a
perfect system, in economics as in science, could only remain an eternal aim, never to be attained
101
. Trying
to build such a deceitful system was neither the way of science nor of philosophy: “In logic, or physics,
biology or philosophy we cannot put some undisputable statements on top and then logically derive from
them an entire chain of thought. Inadequacies always contaminate the entirety of this ideal world, starting
from the premises as from later consequences. No precaution can prevent this outcome, nor renouncing all
previous knowledge, starting from a tabula rasa, to achieve a better result”
102
. A clear accusation toward
the systematic turn taken by the Austrian school
103
.
Neurath had identified many cases under which, in a market economy, the results of exchange were sub-
optimal. For example when a consumer had to choose among two identical products with identical prices,
or when limited rationality claimed the scene as with differentials in stock prices
104
. The major distortion to
economy, in terms of Lebenstimmungen, though, was consequent to the widespread adoption throughout
the market economy of a calculation based on prices. Such calculations, along with the institution of credit,
constrained the production to maximize profits, so causing recurrent crises of overproduction. Would the
100
Otto Neurath, Probleme der Kriegswirtschaftslehere, „Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswirtschaft“, I, 3, 1913, p.
457.
101
Otto Neurath, Probleme der Kriegswirtschaftslehere, „Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswirtschaft“, I, 3, 1913, p.
456.
102
Otto Neurath, Probleme der Kriegswirtschaftslehere, „Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswirtschaft“, I, 3, 1913, p.
456.
103
Otto Neurath, Die Naturalwirtschaftslehre und der Naturalkalkul in ihren Beziehungen zur Kriegswirtschaftslehre,
„Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv“, vol.8, 2, p.258.
104
Otto Neurath, Das Begriffsgebäude der Wirtschaftslehre und seine Grundlagen, „Zeitschrift für die gesamte
Staatswissenschaft“, vol. 73, n. 4., 1917, pp. 499.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
26
economy be ruled by the maximization of productivity instead of profitability, crises, for Neurath, would no
longer plague the world.
To the naïve arguments of pacifists, then, Neurath countered that the origin of present wars, wars between
social classes as wars between nations, was to be found in the lack of economic efficiency of the present
economic and life order. He wrote: “The present underemployment of existing forces, that is typical of our
Ordnung, incites to war: it is necessary, for example, to defend oneself from foreign wares and foreign
laborers or oblige others to buy our wares or accept our workers, and all of this because it is not
spontaneous to enter in cooperative relations between states; furthermore it is easy to alleviate the costs
of war thanks to reparations; and lastly because at times war frees productive forces that would otherwise
be bound. The uneconomic construction of our Lebensordnung is the cause why at present war causes
lesser evils than in a more economical Lebensordnung the case would be”
105
.
War could be avoided only by becoming uneconomical. If detrimental to all parties concerned, war would
become an avoidable choice. To this end Neurath considered the best solution to forge broad alliances that
possessed the same economic power, i.e. an equal amount of productive forces
106
. Obviously another
opportunity existed to foster peace: abandoning the present inefficient life order for a more effective one.
From war, from the spreading of in-kind calculations could then emerge an entirely new Weltanschauung
capable of molding the world to diffused wealth and general peace. An utopia that was worth to guide an
economic calculus not just bent on the past but projected toward the future.
105
Otto Neurath, Probleme der Kriegswirtschaftslehere, „Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswirtschaft“, I, 3, 1913,
p.500.
106
Otto Neurath, Probleme der Kriegswirtschaftslehere, „Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswirtschaft“, I, 3, 1913, pp.
465-66.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
27
CONCLUSIONS
Inspired by his father’s critique of modern capitalism, Otto Neurath looked at war as to a sudden and
ubiquitous shock for the present economic order that could reveal and perhaps cure many of its
malfunctions. He so dedicated many writings of his brief academic career, spanning from the beginning of
the twentieth century to 1918, to define a field of study dedicated to war economics. He gained ample
recognition for his efforts, before and during WWI. His writings were published by the main journals of the
time, the most important economists and sociologists discussed his theses. The vehemence of some critics
only demonstrated that Neurath’s outrageous reasoning was felt as threatening by the newly emerging
orthodoxy.
In the first essays on war economics Neurath attempted to sketch a dynamic macroeconomic schema that
could help to evaluate the effects of war on the distribution of wealth in ancient and modern economies. In
doing so he touched many crucial points of economic theorization, from the active management of public
debt to fiscal and monetary stimuli to demand. Unsatisfied by the results obtainable in remaining inside the
fences of an economic system, Neurath further investigated how, through a redefinition of the economic
science as a whole, it would be possible to create a conceptual framework for economics that would allow
to study, along the same lines, war and peace economics, state administration and market order.
As a mechanic who had to compare machines, different as a diesel motor could be in respect to a steam
machine, could recur to PS evaluation to decide which one would be more effective, Neurath opted for a
measurement in terms of wealth creation, to offer a criteria of choice between diverse economic orders.
His economics, born out the acute observation of war conditions, became so the science of collective
wealth, as representative of the individuals’ sensations and measured through in-kind statistics.
Such an economics would encompass all possible life orders, comparing them as to their capacity of
enriching people’s life: a science for dreamers and utopians as much as of bureaucrats and technicians.
Neurath could so dream away economic crises and wars, by simply substituting a criteria of productivity to
the one of profitability, by using in-kind measures instead of prices. A peaceful revolution born out of the
catastrophe of war.
Monika Poettinger Otto Neurath’s War Economics
28
Image 5 People queueing in front of a milk shop in Vienna (Radetzkystraße 27), 1914/1918.
(Photo: R. Bimberg http://kurier.at/kultur/wien-im-ersten-weltkrieg-ausstellung-im-wien-museum)