ChapterPDF Available

Trade unions and the Future of Democratic Capitalism

Authors:
Trade unions and the Future of Democratic Capitalism
Anke Hassel
Hertie School of Governance
2014
In: Pablo Beramendi, Silja Häusermann, Herbert Kitschelt, Hanspeter Kriesi (eds.):
The Politics of Advanced Capitalism. Cambridge University Press. forthcoming
Chapter 9
Trade unions and the future of democratic capitalism
Anke Hassel
During the 20th century, trade unions and employers’ organizations had a firm place
in modern market economies. Union organizations were the counterweight to
business, striving to compensate for the vulnerability of the individual worker to the
risks of the market. As an economic and as a political organization, trade unions could
raise wages, improve working conditions and promote centre-left political parties,
which represented their interests in the political arena. Social insurance and
redistribution, employment protection, health and safety and the expansion of the
middle class over the last 100 years were directly connected to the presence of trade
unions. Their organizations and functions emerged in the process of industrialization
in the late 19th century parallel to employers’ organizations.
From the vantage point of the second decade of the 21
st
century, 20
th
century
industrial organization has been undergoing tremendous change. These developments
have impacted on political parties’ and industrial interest associations’ capacities to
make and affect public policies and ultimately to affect economic outcomes, such as
economic growth, unemployment and inflation. Nevertheless, the stark cross-national
diversity in industrial relations and political mobilization of labour, crystallized
through long struggles, has not simply disappeared without a trace in contemporary
post-industrial capitalism. Some critical elements linger on and separate in particular
the Scandinavian from the Continental European polities, even though they are often
combined under the rubric of “coordinated” market economies. These two, in turn,
are still, in some ways, set apart from both the Anglo-Saxon liberal political
economies, where the decline of organized labour has been most pronounced, as well
as from the Mediterranean “mixed-market” capitalisms, with rather strong state
intervention. As asserted in this book’s introduction, there are common shocks and
directions of change, albeit without entirely removing the cross-national diversity of
industrial relations systems and their capacities to cope with the challenges of market
allocation.
Since the mid-1980s trade unions are rapidly losing members and influence in almost
all industrialized countries. The loss of employment in manufacturing, the rise of
service sector employment, the emergence of global value chains as well as political
and policy changes have altered the way employment is organized in advanced
industrialized economies today. Instead of steady wage gains in line with productivity
increases for the standard worker, wages for the majority of workers are stagnant;
instead of highly regulated employment relationships, labour markets are liberalized,
centralized collective bargaining structures are dismantled and social inequality has
been continuously rising. In many countries trade unions have almost completely
retreated into the public sector.
Only two decades ago, no observer would have expected trade unions to disappear
from the scene. The contribution by Golden, Wallerstein and Lange (1999) in the
Volume on Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Kitschelt et al. 1999)
painted a worried, but still confident, scenario. They nevertheless argued that
persistent diversity between countries would refute any general theory as to why
unions are in decline. This left hope that erosion of union organization was just a
temporary phenomenon. Moreover they stated that: ‘the current weakness of unions
appears, in most countries, to be more a product of sustained unemployment (and
occasional political assault) than an increase of institutional decay’ (Golden,
Wallerstein and Lange 1999, 225). Institutions were found to be significantly more
stable compared to union membership.
However, only two years later, a research report for the Fondazione Rolofe
Debenedetti in 2001 came to a more sceptical conclusion. The authors assumed that
union membership would continue to decline, alongside changes in labour market
institutions. The most likely scenario would be a long-term decentralization of
collective bargaining, which would weaken attempts to coordinate wage bargaining at
a national level. National coordination of bargaining would be replaced by wage
bargaining in large firms, which might or might not transcend national boundaries
(Boeri et al. 2001, 117).
More recent assessments are even more outspokenly pessimistic. Baccaro and Howell
(2011) state that there is a general direction of change in virtually all industrialized
countries towards trade union decline, differentiated collective bargaining and
increasing firm-level diversity. Avdagic and Baccaro argue that the current trends
point to a decrease in the relevance of trade unions everywhere with no credible sign
of reversal in the future (Avdagic and Baccaro 2012). If this assessment is correct –
and there is no reason to fundamentally doubt it – the question arises as to what the
likely implications of these transformations for the future of democratic capitalism
are? How will an on-going decay of labour market institutions and union
representation affect the workings of advanced industrialized economies?
Three theoretical approaches give us some information on the role of trade unions and
labour market institutions in democratic capitalism: power resource, neo-corporatist
and varieties of capitalism theories. Let us consider here what implications they might
have for the development of industrial organization, when exposed to the shocks of
technological change in the occupational structure and globalization experienced by
postindustrial capitalism since the 1980s. How much are the pre-existing industrial
relations organizations of business and labour capable of withstanding the new
shocks? How will their bargaining systems fare—in terms of coverage of wage
earners, centralization and coordination of negotiations? Are these institutional fabrics
still associated with distinctive macro-economic outputs and outcomes?
In the spirit of power resource theory of labour union power (Korpi 1989; Esping-
Andersen 1985; Palme 1990), employers are expected to take advantage of the job
displacements precipitated by external shocks. But where unions are strong, this
theory may expect them to remain tenacious and hold on to some power even under
the impact of shocks. The decline of union organization, as well as the decline of
centralized bargaining, may therefore be directly proportional to the union power at
the beginning of the 1980s.
Two other perspectives, the neo-corporatism theories and varieties of capitalism
theories, may have somewhat different expectations. They stipulate a bifurcation of
viable industrial relations regimes. At one extreme, there are highly organized,
centralized systems of symmetrical power of business and labour associations that are
able to coordinate through elite accommodation (corporatist governance/interest
intermediation, coordinated market economies, CMEs).
1
At the other extreme, there
are less organized, decentralized, divided sectors of economic interest associations
with little capacity to engage in coordinated bargaining (pluralist interest
intermediation, liberal market economies, LMEs).
In general, both neo-corporatist and varieties of capitalism perspectives consider
“pure” cases of either corporatist coordination-centralization or liberal competition-
decentralization as more efficient equilibria than “mixed” cases of partial
centralization and coordination (cf. Calmfors and Driffil 1988; Hall and Gingerich
2009). Whereas the former are likely to sustain a resilient fabric of associations and
associated economic performance, the latter see weak associations further degrade,
but with little harm to economies that are anyway relying on market allocation. A
difficult question is, therefore, what happens to this intermediate group with partially
centralized industrial relations organizations and a lack of coherence of liberal or
coordinated market institutions that encompasses industrial relations, corporate
1
As references for the corporatism literature, see Lange and Garrett 1985, Pizzorno 1978, Schmitter
1974). For the varieties of capitalism literature, see especially Soskice 1999 and Hall and Soskice 2001.
The varieties of capitalism perspective develops out of the corporatism literature, adding onto a close
consideration of firm-level corporate governance and industrial training regimes. The predictions of
both perspectives about the fortunes of industrial interest associations are, therefore, very similar.
governance, occupational training systems, and research and development (Hall and
Soskice 2001)? One might venture a guess that these incoherent sets of political-
economic institutions are particularly hard-hit by the exogenous technological and
globalization shocks. Since it is less costly to let interest associations disintegrate than
to build centralized interest associations, it is likely, therefore, that incoherent systems
converge on the disorganized state of affairs in liberal market economies (LMEs)
through a rapid decline of capital and labour associations and a disintegration of
centralized wage bargaining. They will continue to deliver a worse economic
performance.
In other words, while the power-resource perspective may expect a gradual decline of
interest associations proportional to the peak of mobilization in the 1970s and 1980s,
the corporatist/varieties of capitalism perspective expects a bifurcation: highly
organized corporatist systems stay put, while in intermediate incoherent systems and
in liberal market systems industrial interest associations disintegrate and centralization
as well as coordination of bargaining implodes. In macro-economic terms, the power-
resource perspective makes predictions primarily concerning distributive outcomes
(strong left mobilization leads to more redistribution) and, to a lesser extent, economic
performance. The corporatist/varieties of capitalism perspectives also predict that
“congruent” institutional systems approximating either the coordinated market
economy (corporatist) type or the liberal market economy type, rather than a mix of
the two, perform better.
As a matter of fact, however, the data for the last twenty years show patterns that
imply that a mixture of both theoretical perspectives is at work. National institutional
configurations adjust to new power constellations that derive from economic and
societal changes. Most importantly, the process of the disintegration of organized
economic interests is asymmetrical and multi-dimensional, as discussed in section 9.1.
Apparently consistent with power-resource perspectives, labour organizations decline
more steeply than business associations, and especially where the former were weaker
to begin with.
But wage bargaining coordination and even centralization do not change in lockstep.
The simple dichotomies of the varieties of capitalism literature, and even the addition
of intermediate incoherent cases, do not entirely reflect the diversification of
industrial organization and wage bargaining in the 1990s and 2000s. Consequently, at
the macro-economic level, as discussed in section 9.2.,it has become harder to detect
an impact of the more complicated and multi-dimensional industrial relations regimes
on macro-economic outcomes, such as inflation, growth, and employment.
Nevertheless, as the financial crisis and the crisis of European integration—
particularly in the Euro currency union—since 2007 demonstrate, distinctive
industrial relations regimes plausibly leave some imprint on economic performance,
albeit without validating the old uni-dimensional models and dichotomies.
9.1. The decline and transformation of labour market institutions
Strong labour market institutions dominated much of the western world throughout
the 20
th
century and particularly during the four decades after WW II. National
economies were largely characterized by manufacturing industries, whose workers
were likely to be unionized and whose wages would be set in negotiation with these
unions. Unionized manufacturing firms were trendsetters for wage setting in other
parts of the economy and trade unions played an important role in national politics
and welfare expansion.
In this section, I analyse the changes of key indicators of labour market institutions
over the last three decades, based on aggregate country-level indicators of union
density rates and institutional characteristics of wage-setting, which are the standard
data used to characterize industrial relations systems. They cover the affluent Western
countries of the OECD. In order to sharpen the analysis, in line with theoretical
assumptions about different types of market economies exposed in the introduction to
this volume, I group the countries in the extended VoC framework into Liberal
Market Economies (LMEs) (Australia, Canada, Ireland, New Zealand, the United
States, the United Kingdom), Coordinated Market Economies (CMEs) (Austria,
Belgium, Germany, Luxembourg, the Netherlands), Nordic CMEs (Denmark,
Finland, Norway, Sweden) and Mixed Market Economies (MMEs) (France, Greece,
Italy, Portugal, Spain), a group referred to as state “capture” based political economies
in the terminology of the introduction to this volume. In addition I use data from the
European Social Survey on the composition of union membership.
Following standard VoC arguments, coordinated market economies are defined by
decision-making in key economic activities that are not market-based but rely on
strategic interaction (coordination) of large firms, their interest associations and trade
unions. Nordic CMEs have additional features of coordination, such as a strong public
sector, high levels of centralization and strong institutional support for trade unions.
Liberal market economies primarily rely on market exchanges.
Mixed market economies, as defined by Molina and Rhodes (2007), are characterized
by the central role of the state in facilitating coordination and compensating for the
lack of autonomous self-organization of business and labour. Labour and business
have traditionally used their access to state resources to maintain their position in the
political economy. Mixed market economies can be seen as part of the family of
coordinated market economies, in the sense that the economic actors, trade unions and
business organizations, have similar organizational features to CMEs. Business
organizations often hold monopolies or quasi monopolies over membership domains
and have privileged access to state resources. Unions are frequently politically divided
and compete strongly over political influence. However, the actors do not have similar
capacities to CMEs nor do they use these capacities for autonomous coordination like
CMEs. Rather, organized interests use their resources to lobby the state for protection
or compensation.
9.1.1. Union membership
A quick glance at union membership data reveals the diversity of unionization rates in
Western Europe. The discrepancy between membership rates in different countries is
far more pronounced than, for instance, party affiliations or voting patterns. This
already indicates that there is no ‘natural’ pattern of unionization in advanced
industrialized countries, but that institutional factors shape union organizations to a
great extent. Over time, unionization patterns have not converged, but rather diverged,
even though most followed roughly similar trends of rising membership strength
during the 1970s and decline since the early 1990s.
However, there is a clear and expected trend of declining union density rates across
the OECD (Figure 9.1). Overall density rates declined from 45% (1980s average) to
30% (2000s average) (Table 9.1). A significant difference exists between unions in
Nordic CMEs and all other groups. While the average union density rate in all other
group stands at around 24%, Nordic CME countries still have a density rate of above
70% in the 2000s, mainly because they administratively tie unemployment insurance
coverage to union membership, with this so-called “Ghent system” thus providing an
additional membership incentive (Lind 2009, Rothstein 1992).
“insert Figure 9.1 and Table 9.1 about here”
The strongest decline in unionization took place in LMEs, where union density rates
decreased from 44% to 25% over three decades. In both Continental CMEs and
Mixed Market Economies, where unionization was weaker to begin with (roughly
35% in the 1980s), a drop by about one quarter of union density took place over a 20-
30 year period. In general, this pattern confirms expectations of the power-resource
perspective, but is mildly inconsistent with the other perspectives. The weakest labour
unions in the 1980s took the biggest hit ever. The hit was also pretty substantial in a
number of CMEs, whether coherent or not.
9.1.2. Employers’ organizations and collective bargaining coverage
Collective bargaining coverage and employers’ density rates are highly correlated
(.806**; Table 9.2). This is due to the fact that firms that belong to employers’
organizations participate in collective bargaining that covers the workforce of those
firms. High levels of employers’ density thereby almost automatically translate into
high levels of bargaining coverage. Discrepancies occur when collective agreements
are extended to firms that do not belong to employers’ organizations or when firms
are members of an employers’ organization without participating in collective
bargaining.
2
“insert Table 9.2 about here”
Comprehensive data on employers’ organizations is only available for the most recent
period and, for most countries, no trend can be established. As expected, CMEs have
the highest level of employers’ density: 87%, on average, for the whole period. This
has declined from 96% in the 1980s to 82% in the 2000s. In comparison, the lowest
level of employers’ organization is to be found in LMEs with 51% and – also as
expected – followed by CEE with 60% and MMEs 74%.
As with union density, we find a strong stratification of developments since the 1980s
(table 9.1.). In Nordic CMEs, both employers’ organizational density and bargaining
2
This is a relatively recent phenomenon in Germany, where employers‘ organizations set up
subsidiaries for firms that did not want to be bound by collective agreements: OT (without agreement
status).
coverage have gone up from high levels, while in Continental CMEs they have
maintained the very same high level. Starting from a slightly lower level, they
declined a bit in MMEs, but virtually collapsed in LMEs. This pattern appears to be
most consistent with the corporatist/varieties of capitalism perspective.
The coincidence of an institutional stability of bargaining coverage and employers’
organization with an on-going decline of union density rates in CMEs supports the
assumption that coordination does not depend on trade unions’ power resources but
might be due to employers’ preferences for coordination and a function of the fabric
of political-economist coordination as a whole, as asserted by the varieties of
capitalism perspective.
9.1.3. Wage bargaining centralization and coordination
Theoretically, employers’ density rate or coverage does not predict the centralization
of collective bargaining. Empirically, however, both are significantly correlated
(Table 9.2). Higher levels of employers’ density and bargaining coverage relate
positively to higher levels of wage bargaining centralization.
The country type averages reveal interesting diversity. Starting from low or very high
levels, the drop in collective wage bargaining centralization is precipitous in both
LMEs and Nordic CMEs. It is substantial, but less pronounced, in Continental CMEs
and MMEs have sustained a level of centralization that makes them the set of
countries with the highest average centralization in the 2000s. Wage bargaining
decentralization took place either through pro-active institutional reforms such as in
Sweden, Australia or New Zealand, or it occurred more gradually and informally
through an increasing amount of company level bargaining, which eroded collective
bargaining at a regional or national level.
Wage bargaining coordination may proceed with less than perfect centralization, e.g.,
when companies or sectors take wage leadership. Yet, the last columns of table 9.1.
reveal that coordination fell in roughly similar patterns differentiating the four groups
of countries as far as centralization is concerned: from low levels, the decentralization
is greatest among LMEs, followed by Nordic and Continental CMEs, with MMEs
sustaining rather high levels of coordination.
Overall, the CME category, highlighted in the varieties of capitalism literature, shows
little internal similarity of members. The pressure for decentralization and
liberalization is great in Nordic CMEs, but tempered by continuing high levels of
labour and business organization and collective bargaining coverage. Conversely,
Continental CMEs sustain higher, albeit eroding, levels of coordination, as well as
high coverage, but at lower levels of union and employer density. This may be an
indicator of growing divides between wage bargaining insiders and outsider
companies and wage earner categories. MMEs see declining union and employer
density, yet continued solid collective bargaining centralization and coordination.
Political leverage may have kept unions at the bargaining table, despite declining
leverage, in order to stave off worse outcomes implemented without their
participation.
Taken together, the evidence from macro-level indicators shows that, over time,
unionization rates have significantly declined in all groups of countries. A more
detailed discussion of unionization rates will be provided in the following section.
However, other institutional indicators such as employers’ organizations, collective
bargaining coverage, coordination and centralization have shown a more nuanced
pattern of some resilience in CMEs and MMEs while LMEs and CEEs have drifted
more towards a largely unregulated system of collective bargaining and employers’
coordination and organization.
Institutional resilience can be due to the lack of appropriate indicators to measure
change. Baccaro and Howell have argued that creeping changes of the content of
collective bargaining at a national level might change the dynamic of the system,
while leaving formal institutions intact. These changes cannot be detected by formal
indicators that measure only the predominant bargaining level (Baccaro and Howell
2011).
However, on-going collective bargaining, carried out by highly organized employers’
confederations and covering large numbers of employees, continues to install an
element of harmonization and standardization of pay grades across industries. The
degree of standardization of working conditions that occur in CMEs, and to some
extent MMEs, through wage bargaining should not be underestimated for the
regulation of the labour market. This could imply that coordination persists among
business, while union organization continues to decline. Coordination of business,
therefore, outlives trade union organization and trade union strength.
9.1.4. Unionization of insiders and outsiders
A different aspect of the changing nature of trade unionism points to the increasing
trend towards labour market segmentation. Recent research on dualization has
explored the process in which policies differentiate between rights, entitlements and
services among different groups or categories of entitled citizens. Labour market
insiders are in a secure employment position, while those without or with insecure
employment are labour market outsiders.
3
Dualization occurs when differential
treatment of insiders and outsiders increases, when parts of the insiders are shifted to
become outsiders, and with the development of new institutional distinctions between
different groups of workers (Emmenegger et al. 2012 p.10).
Dualization particularly affects ‘new’ and non-traditional groups entering the labour
market such as women, young employees or migrant workers, who are at risk of being
clustered in the outsider group, as the probability of them entering stable and skilled
standard employment relationships is, by trend, smaller than for older men
(Schwander and Häusermann 2013; Barbieri and Scherer 2009). Until the 1970s, the
precarious situation of women was not visible on a political level, as family and
3
Definitions of insiders and outsiders vary. See Schwander and Häusermann (2013) and Rueda (2007).
marriage policies provided protection. The past few decades have increasingly
politicized this problem. The same also applies to the outsider group of migrant
workers (Emmenegger and Careja 2012), who are considered the overrepresented
group in non-standard, precarious working conditions (ibid p.128).
The emerging increasing cleavage between labour market insiders and outsiders has
accentuated the question how trade unions mediate potential conflicts of interests. In
most of the literature, it is assumed that unions organize labour market insiders
(Becher and Pontusson 2011; Rueda 2007). This implies that union preferences are
dominated by labour market insiders. If unions have to choose between the two
groups, it is likely that they side with that of the insiders, even at the expense of
labour market outsiders.
The data on unionization rates of insiders and outsiders comes from the European
Social Survey (ESS). It includes trade union membership data and some information
on the employment status of the respondent. This includes information of the age,
gender, full-time/part-time employment and income as well as permanent/temporary
employment.
The insider-outsider ratio is the weighted average of density ratios in various
employment segments (gender, age, income, unemployment protection, working
hours, sector). As an example, for the insider-outsider ratio, I calculated the ratio of
trade union density of female over male members, the ratio between members below
the age of 25 and above (25-65), the ratio of trade union members holding a limited
term contract or no contract at all over the ratio of TU members having an unlimited
contract, TU members having a monthly income categorized as lower median over
TU members having an income categorized as upper median, etc. The mean of these
ratios is the io-ratio.
Table 9.3 reports the ESS-based data on the unionization of various subcategories of
workers. Small unionization ratios in table 9.3. indicate a large deficit in outsider
unionization compared to insiders. On the whole, as assumed in the literature, trade
unions in almost all countries are focussed on labour market insiders rather than
outsiders. Unionization rates of those with above- average incomes, standard working
hours, unlimited contracts and a history of steady employment are higher than those
who are part-time, with limited contracts and below average pay. The widest gap is
between younger and older workers.
“insert Table 9.3 about here”
In 2008, in fourteen Western European countries, the unionization rate of young
workers is only one fifth of that of older workers. This is partly due to the
generational difference that young workers combine several factors of labour market
insecurity: they are more likely to be in insecure employment and work in the service
economy, which makes unionization less likely. But it could also be a sign of what the
future of trade unions will look like in two decades: only in Denmark and Finland
were the unionization rates of the under-25-year olds above 20%. In 8 countries,
unionization of young workers was below 10%. Big gaps also exist for part-timers
with less than seventeen hours a week. On average, their unionization rate is only half
that of full-time workers.
The smallest gap is between men and women. In six out of fourteen countries, female
unionization rates are higher than male unionization rates – despite the fact that
women, like young workers, often work in areas of less secure employment and are
often seen, by definition, as labour market outsiders. Gender equality in unionization
is most pronounced in LMEs and Nordic countries. Continental CMEs and MMEs
have larger gender gaps. In other dimensions, notably regarding income,
unemployment and fixed-term contracts, LMEs and MMEs are more segmented in
comparison to CMEs and the Nordic countries, where unionization rates between the
groups differ less. This is, however, partly due to the fact that Belgium shows patterns
of Nordic CMEs when it comes to unionization patterns.
When all employment segments are combined, a pattern of an average unionization
ratio of labour market outsiders versus insiders emerges. We can identify two distinct
groups of countries: those countries where unionization amounts to a significant share
of the overall workforce and those countries where unionization is confined to a
particular segment of the workforce. I label the two groups ‘universalist’ and
‘segmented’ respectively. The first group of countries comprises the Nordic countries
plus Belgium, the second group is made up of all other Western European countries.
All countries with unionization rates above 40%, with the exception of Norway, have
a Ghent system in which trade unions administer state-subsidized unemployment
funds. Only four Western European countries- Sweden, Denmark, Finland and Iceland
- have real Ghent systems. Belgium has a hybrid system; even though unions do in
fact exercise a great deal of administrative control, it is often considered a de facto
Ghent system (Scruggs 2002). All other countries, with the exception of Austria, have
unionization rates of considerably less than 30%.
Belgium turns out to have the most universal union system in Western Europe,
followed by the Nordic countries and then by northern continental Europe, Germany,
the Netherlands, Ireland and France. At the bottom are the UK, Portugal and Spain.
In addition to having higher membership levels overall, universalist trade union
systems are also less exclusionary for labour market outsiders. In other words,
universalist unions attract both a relatively higher share and higher absolute numbers
of labour market outsiders. Figure 9.2 compares unionization rates between insiders
and outsiders. The data again shows that in all countries but Belgium outsiders are
less likely to be union members than insiders.
“insert Figure 9.2 about here”
Segmentalist (insider-focused) unions on the other hand, recruit and reproduce their
membership from existing strongholds. Depending on employers’ attitudes, collective
bargaining institutions and production regimes can either be in manufacturing sectors
or the public sector. There are very few examples of trade union strongholds in private
services industries.
Organizational developments of segmentalist trade unions are,
therefore, more strictly path-dependent and opportunity-driven. These processes are
borne out of the necessity to legitimize the use of membership funds, which restrict
investments in new membership areas, as well as organizational boundaries and the
distribution of power within the organization.
Disaggregated by our four groups of countries, the Nordic CMEs have the least
insider/outsider division, as they include most Ghent systems. They are followed by
the Continental CMEs, the averages of which only look closer to the Nordic countries
because they include Belgium with its Ghent system, while the other Continental
CME countries take a middle position between Nordic countries and MMEs. LMEs
appear to have the greatest insider/outsider division, but we have to warn, that as
protection for labour market insiders is low, the distinction between insiders and
outsiders carries less meaning. The divide between insiders and outsiders thus tends to
be most acute in CMEs and MMEs, both of which still have moderately high levels of
unionization and wage bargaining coordination, but exclude substantial proportions of
the labour market from such representation.
Overall, the traditional liberal market economies constituted one extreme pole of
fragmented, disorganized industrial relations systems in the 2000s, even more so than
ever before. At the same time, however, the identity of coordinated market
economies, or even of a gradation of power-resource across political economies has
broken up to such an extent as to make the existing uni-dimensional theoretical
frameworks for understanding the processes of change more problematic. While there
are correlations between union and employer density, collective bargaining coverage
and wage bargaining coordination and centralization, they are sufficiently loose as to
crystallize subgroups of clusters with rather distinct profiles of industrial relations
systems.
9.2. Industrial relations and economic management and performance
There is a long and rich list of literature on the role of unions and labour market
institutions for economic management and performance. The aim here is not to
summarize all the evidence and literature but to point out some of the recent trends
and the most remarkable developments, as they relate to the changes of industrial
relations in the four groups of countries.
Regarding our theoretical expectations, power resource theory would expect a linear
relationship between the strength of unions and labour market institutions and
outcomes. Weaker unionization and weaker institutions translate into less
involvement for unions in economic decision-making and ultimately greater social
inequality. Neo-corporatism and VoC assumes that particular institutional
configurations have beneficial effects for unions, governments and businesses alike,
which are, in principle, self-sustainable. Higher levels of coordination and
centralization provide opportunities for central decision-making on wages, which can
be traded with policy adjustments. The decline of unions and labour market
institutions, therefore, does not automatically imply a weaker role of unions in
economic management, nor greater wage inequality in itself, but might endanger
central decision making if coverage declines dramatically. The evidence shows that
higher levels of coordination and centralization are still associated with better
economic outcomes. However, as unionization declines, these benefits are
increasingly restricted to specific economic sectors.
9.2.1 Trade unions and economic management
Trade unions played an important role in the Keynesian Welfare State. They were
key-actors in economic management, primarily regarding wage expectation, but also
in a wider sense of political influence over economic policy. Adjustments during the
business cycle were constrained by the fact that nominal wages were rigid rather than
flexible and expansive fiscal policies were used to counteract business downswings.
Deflation or budget balancing on the one hand, generally added to a fall in prices but
not wages; expansive monetary and fiscal policies, on the other, empowered workers
in tight labour markets, who might be tempted to turn their bargaining power into
nominal wages. Therefore, during the 1960s and 1970s, a mechanism was needed that
enabled a macro-economic control over nominal wage developments. Governments
employed various kinds of ‘incomes policies’ to either induce wage restraint or
negotiate it (Hassel 2006; Braun 1975). As labour markets were tight, governments
and businesses did not have any other policy tool to force unions to discipline wage
expectations than to achieve trade union cooperation.
This model of economic management gradually eroded due to slower growth in
advanced industrialized countries during the 1960s, inflationary shocks in the 1970s
and the subsequent liberalization of capital markets. A crucial component of the shift
in economic policy moving away from a ‘mixed economy’, as described by Shonfield,
to an overwhelmingly liberal and private economy, was a new political understanding
that put a premium on market mechanisms in contrast to state correction (Shonfield
1965).
The policy shift also occurred in economic theory, which now claimed that – contrary
to Keynesian assumptions – demand-side policies led to price increases but had no
effect on the real economy. Monetary policy aimed at controlling inflation and not at
accommodating wage expectations by trade unions. Only supply-side policies could
promote economic growth in mature national economies. Supply-side policies
targeted market regulation and subsidies. Rather than accommodating and facilitating
regulated markets, governments were keen to eradicate regulations that were prone to
rent-seeking and inefficiencies. State failure, rather than market failure, moved into
the centre of attention and the state itself became a key target for policy reform.
In that context, trade unions were forced to assume a different role. Instead of being
the key institutional pillars for underwriting stability, protection and egalitarian
wages, trade unions were increasingly perceived by policy-makers and business as
rent seekers. They presented obstacles for supply-side reforms, flexible adjustment
and competitiveness. Restrictive monetary policy punished high settlements with
higher unemployment and, therefore, attacked trade unions directly and intentionally.
Trade unions met increasing political opposition, not just from centre-right
governments, initially the Thatcher and Reagan administrations, but subsequently also
from the centre-left. Policies of the ‘Third Way’, as initiated and developed by the
government of Tony Blair in the UK after 1997, embraced supply- side policies as
well as public service reforms, and had a similarly sceptical view of trade unions as
the centre-right. Trade unions, therefore, not only met increasing opposition from
business but also in the political arena. Fritz Scharpf concluded that, in a neo-liberal
setting, the cooperation of trade unions was not required any more (Scharpf 1991).
However, the move towards supply-side policies and restrictive monetary and fiscal
policies did not initially diminish the importance of trade unions. Austerity and
deregulation policies were politically costly for governments. In many countries,
where proportional representation dominated and governments were in coalition, there
was still a tendency to cooperate with trade unions over wages and social policy
reforms. The 1990s in particular saw a new wave of tripartite agreements between
government and unions over wage restraint in the context of economic restraints by
European Monetary Union (Hassel 2006, Hancké and Rhodes 2005). Governments
realized that the economic costs of negotiated adjustment were lower than forcing
trade unions to accept new realities of high interest rates and higher unemployment.
These tripartite negotiations largely vanished once EMU set in and governments could
temporarily relax over public deficits and inflation differentials. This also showed that
social pacts were not intended as a permanent policy tool but rather a temporary and
instable phenomenon (Avdagic et al. 2011).
Over time, a new economic and political reality set in. Flexible labour markets,
activating social policies and supply-side economic policies have largely succeeded as
policy blueprints – even after the financial crisis of 2008. They were reinforced by
policy-recommendations from international organizations, such as the OECD, the
World Bank and IMF, and became part of the policy agenda of the EU Commission.
Today, they are part of the parcel of Troika recommendations in the conditionality
section of bail-out programmes (Armingeon and Baccaro 2011).
Globalization and the rise of the service economy added to the policy change. The
opportunity of off-shoring altered the conditions under which manufacturing firms
were willing to invest in advanced industrialized countries. Concession bargaining
and vigorous cost-cutting became standard management practices in big
manufacturing firms. Permanent core workers remained largely protected, but an
increasing share of manufacturing workers moved into fringe employment, which was
temporary and insecure. In the service sectors, where unions remained weak and
underrepresented, working conditions and employment protection were below
manufacturing standards in many areas and remained as such.
Therefore, the wave of tripartite concertation during the 1980s and 1990s, which gave
European trade unions a new temporary lease of life, did not solve the fundamental
dilemma trade unions found themselves in with the end of the Keynesian Welfare
State. The new economic policy paradigm focused on liberalization, deregulation and
supply-side reforms. Trade unions benefitted from regulation and Keynesian demand
policies and were, therefore, a natural target of policy-makers who were seeking
change. The financial crisis did not change this. While governments continue to hold
on to a neoclassic macro-economic paradigm that recommends constant supply-side
reforms, trade unions did not gain from the rise of critical perspectives on financial
capitalism. Unions were neither generally consulted over austerity policies, nor did
social pacts or policy concertation revive during the financial crisis.
Insert figure 9.3. about here
Power resource theory can neither explain the rise nor the decline of policy
concertation over the last three decades. Rather, neo-corporatist theory assumes a
return to policy concertation to lure trade unions into cooperation during an economic
boom. New attempts to utilize the beneficial effects of neo-corporatist policy-making
drove governments to engage in social pacts. This is the case even under conditions of
increasing union weakness. The decline of social pacts after the crisis, however,
shows the limits of neo-corporatism as a policy tool.
9.2.2. Effects of industrial relations on economic performance
In the literature, the effect of industrial relations institutions on economic performance
is widely established (Traxler et al. 2000). Different types of bargaining institutions
and unionization have affected nominal wage changes and unemployment levels.
Based on basic assumptions about union behaviour in different institutional settings,
this literature embeds the assumptions of neo-corporatism and assumes that trade
unions face a trade-off of choosing between pay and employment. Union bargaining
strategies can favour one over the other. Industrial relations institutions enable trade
unions to exercise nominal wage restraint, while at the same time making wages less
flexible and generally more compressed. In the VoC literature, comprehensive wage
bargaining institutions ensure that companies do not compete for skilled workers by
leap-frogging. Either way, centralized wage bargaining provides a dampening effect
on wages, which in turn contributes positively to economic performance.
Economy-wide coordination mechanisms have been identified as the most important
factor influencing wage bargaining behaviour. Several authors have pointed out that
the coordination of wage bargaining can take place even in organizationally
decentralized wage bargaining institutions (Soskice 1990; Traxler et al. 2000). The
lack of formal centralization can be compensated by a wage bargaining structure that
is organized around a pattern-setter mechanism or replaced by other mechanisms such
as government intervention.
Without coordination of wage bargaining behaviour, local wage bargaining will
reflect the local conditions on the labour market and not the wider economic
constraints. Local bargaining can encourage leap-frogging, with highly profitable
companies influencing the expectations of workers in other companies. Local trade
unions that are not embedded in a national bargaining system tend to exploit their
bargaining power, since they do not have any reason not to do so (Soskice 1990;
Flanagan 1999).
However, centralization of wage bargaining might contribute to the power of trade
unions. As union bargaining power increases, wage settlements can, therefore, be less
responsive to economic constraints. In decentralized bargaining structures, unionized
firms might be out-competed by non-unionized firms (Flanagan 2003). The result is a
hump-shaped relationship, where highly centralized and highly decentralized wage
bargaining institutions outperform intermediate levels of centralization (Calmfors and
Driffil 1988).
With regard to empirical evidence, research has shown mixed results. Many studies
covering the OECD countries between the 1960s and today find that labour market
rigidities are related to institutional variables. For instance, in a comprehensive
empirical study, labour market institutions were seen as a major explanation for
differences in economic performance, accounting for 55% of the variation in
unemployment, the generosity of the unemployment benefit system being the most
important factor, followed by taxes and union density (Nickell et al, 2005).
The OECD Employment Outlook concluded in 2006:
“Overall, recent empirical research suggests that high corporatism bargaining
systems tend to achieve lower unemployment than do other institutional set-
ups. Nevertheless, the evidence concerning the impact of collective bargaining
structures on aggregate employment and unemployment continues to be
somewhat inconclusive. The overall non-robustness of results across studies
probably reflects, at least in part, the difficulty of measuring bargaining
structures and practices, as well the fact that the same institutional set-up may
perform differently in different economic and political contexts. One exception
to this pattern is the robust association between higher centralisation/co-
ordination of bargaining and lower wage dispersion. Evidence is mixed,
however, about whether the compressed wage structures associated with
corporatist bargaining reduce employment by pricing low-skilled workers – or
those residing in economically disadvantage regions – out of work” (OECD,
2006 p.86).
Which institutions are responsible for rigidities and to what extent do these
institutions matter? Baker presented a comparison of findings from 11 econometric
studies between 1997 and 2005 and focused on a number of institutional variables,
such as employment protection, unemployment benefit replacement rates, union
density, a bargaining coordination index and the magnitude of the tax wedge,
unemployment benefit duration, collective bargaining coverage and expenditures in
active labour market policies. The review shows that so far no single institutional
variable is consistently found to be significantly different from zero across all studies
(Baker et al, 2007).
Another recent study by Baccaro and Rei focused on the same set of variables and
data came to the conclusion that there was no robust evidence of labour market
institutions’ effects on the unemployment rate. The authors concluded that the within-
country variation of bargaining coordination is not associated with lower
unemployment and that bargaining coordination does not moderate the impact of
other institutions (Baccaro and Rei, 2007). Similarly, a report by the EU Commission
shows that encompassing labour relations have some moderating effects on nominal
wage developments. Stronger labour relations contribute to positive economic
outcomes on the labour market and have a robust dampening effect on wage
inequality, poverty and gender pay inequality. It also argues that the effect of labour
relations on economic performance seems to have become weaker in recent years (EU
Commission 2008).
On the other hand, when assessing the periods before and after the financial crisis, the
data is more supportive of a return to the positive effects of coordinating institutions.
While economic performance during the years of the financial bubble, in the early
2000s, favoured LMEs, the post-crisis years again show a pattern of slightly better
economic performance in countries with higher levels of wage bargaining
coordination. CMEs as a group outperform LMEs after 2008, even when Ireland is
taken out of the groups of LMEs. In particular the continental CMEs (Austria,
Germany, Belgium, Luxembourg and Netherlands) all had lower unemployment rates
in the post-crisis years (2008-2013) compared to the pre-crisis years (2001-2007).
MMEs have been hit hard by the financial crisis and the subsequent sovereign debt
crisis. This implies that higher levels of coordination, combined with articulate trade
unions, still carry some weight for crisis adjustment. As performance has diverged
between the different groups of countries after 2008, we might expect a return to a
bifurcated development of coordinated (corporatist) institutions versus liberal ones.
Insert figure 9.4. about here.
Wage inequality
During the golden years of Democratic Capitalism, centralized wage bargaining
institutions and trade union strength have been key factors for explaining different
patterns of wage and income distributions (Baccaro 2011, Bradley et al. 2003, EU
Commission 2008, Pontusson 1996, Pontusson et al. 2003, Rowthorn 1992,
Wallerstein 1999). Centralized trade union organizations pushed up wages for the low
paid and centralized wage bargaining institutions ensured that standard pay scales
were applied across all industries. As a result, countries with centralized bargaining
institutions and strong trade unions tended to have more compressed wage structures
as well as more egalitarian income distribution. Power resource theories would expect
that a decline in union strength would be associated with an increase in wage
inequality. Neo-corporatism and VoC, on the other hand, would assume that as long
as bargaining centralization and coordination holds, there would be sufficient
incentive for employers to maintain a compressed wage structure.
In recent years, the effects of labour market institutions on wage compression have
been far weaker than in earlier decades (Baccaro 2011). Baccaro suggests that unions
began to abandon egalitarian wage policies during the 1980s, due to increasing
resistance by high skilled workers (Baccaro 2011). Wage compression made it harder
for employers to recruit high-skilled workers, but also created competition between
blue and white collar unions in Sweden, which contributed to the demise of
centralized bargaining. In other cases, centralized bargaining lost its distributive
function. ‘While income inequality increased in almost all countries in the sample,
this increase does not seem to have been caused by the deterioration in industrial
relations institutions (trade union decline and collective bargaining decentralization)’
(Baccaro 2011).
Baccaro does not find any statistical correlation between union decline or other labour
market institutions and growing inequality (except in the Central and Eastern
European countries). Instead, economic factors such as technology-induced shifts for
the demand of skilled labour and increasing globalization seem to be better predictors.
Similarly, Golden and Wallerstein report that the determinants of wage inequality are
different in the 1980s and in the 1990s. While in the 1980s, growing wage dispersion
was due to changes in the institutions of the labour market, including declining
unionization and a decline in the level at which wages are bargained collectively. In
the 1990s, increases in pay inequality were due to increasing trade with less
developed nations and a weakening of social insurance programmes (Golden and
Wallerstein 2011).
Moreover, as the literature assumes, there is evidence that more insider-oriented
unions are correlated to higher levels of wage inequality compared to more universal
trade unions. As the scatterplot in Figure 9.5 shows, countries where unions are more
universal are also countries where wage inequality is comparatively lower. While the
causality can, in principle, go both ways, with more egalitarian wages propping up
union membership among outsiders, this might also hint at a process of social closure
of some trade unions against labour market outsiders.
Insert figure 9.5. about here
9.3. Conclusion
In this chapter, I looked at trends of union and business organizations and their
implications for the future of democratic capitalism. As in earlier assessments, the
results concentrated on a steady union decline within much more stable wage
bargaining institutions (Golden et al. 1999; Avdagic and Baccaro 2012). Given the
rapid economic changes of deindustrialization and globalization, business
coordination and wage bargaining centralization showed remarkably high levels of
institutional resilience.
We can draw several conclusions from the observation that unions weaken while
institutions remain relatively stable:
Stability of wage bargaining institutions does not guarantee
unionization rates. High levels of union density are almost exclusively
due to the ‘Ghent’ system of linking union membership with
unemployment insurance administration. Wage bargaining
centralization or wage bargaining coverage does not prevent unions
from declining. While union density rates are still positively related to
centralized wage bargaining institutions, they cannot prevent union
density rates from falling.
Wage bargaining coordination can persist without union strength.
Existing institutions have important benefits for employers as well as
for unions. Coordination capacities can be exercised through
employers’ organizations, bargaining coverage and bargaining
centralization, even though trade unions are very weak. Coordination
and liberalization of labour markets can, therefore, go hand in hand.
The decline of trade unions is, therefore, not in itself an indication that
coordination also declines. It is not trade unions who push employers
into coordinated wage bargaining institutions.
While the unionization rates of women are catching up with those of
men in a number of countries, unionization rates of young workers are
worryingly low. In 2008, in no country in our sample, unionization
rates of young workers were more than a quarter of those of older
workers. Seen in this light, the future of unions appears pretty bleak.
Union organizations that operate under Ghent systems have high
coverage rates for labour market outsiders. They are generally
universal. Countries with universal trade unionism are Denmark,
Finland, Belgium and Sweden. LMEs have dualist union structure
while CMEs become more segmented.
Policy concertation re-emerged in Western Europe during the 1980s
but is in secular decline since the early 1990s, as supply-side policies
continue to dominate the policy agenda even after the financial crisis.
Post-crisis economic performance indicates a return to positive effects
of coordination and wage bargaining centralization. CMEs have
outperformed both LMEs and MMEs in the post-crisis era.
Moreover, wage inequality remains greater in countries with
decentralized bargaining systems and segmented trade union
structures. The corporatist/coordinated economies have still lower
levels of wage inequality.
The trends that are described in this chapter imply that with the decline of
unionization labour market institutions have become somewhat less important for
economic management and the performance of modern economies. Governments
pursue less policy concertation and the impact of institutions on performance has
weakened.
Labour market institutions in all economic models are in a process of transformation.
LMEs continue to liberalize and increase flexibility. MMEs have been hit hard by the
sovereign debt crisis and labour market institutions are undergoing fundamental
policy reforms. CMEs utilize their own comparative institutional advantages when
responding to economic shocks and the rise of the service economy. In particular,
dualization of labour markets and the increase of labour market outsiders has been a
common trend.
However, labour market institutions are still relevant for the patterns of coordination
of economies as VoC/neo-corporatist theory suggests. Rather than converging on a
model of liberal market economies, CMEs (both continental and Nordic countries)
continue to develop along their own trajectories based on business coordination and a
more negotiated political economy. Continental and Nordic coordinated market
economies pursue distinct paths and might over time diverge from each other into
different models of coordination when coping with economic shocks (Thelen 2014).
But the main finding is that their economies are still governed by different rules
compared to both LMEs and MMEs.
Moreover, the observed trends of union decline do not have to persist. Change is
possible at any time and social movements and political unrest can reverse the current
decline. Nobody expected the outburst of social activism in the late 1960s before it
occurred. Similarly, a new wave of activism might still follow the austerity policies of
the financial crisis. However, there has been no sign that trade unions have benefitted
from the financial crisis or that the current wave of austerity policy has increased
trade union influence over governments.
References
Armingeon, Klaus, and Lucio Baccaro. 2011. “The Sorrows of Young Euro: Policy
Responses to the Sovereign Debt Crisis”, paper presented at the CES conference in
Barcelona.
Avdagic, Sabina, Martin Rhodes, and Jelle Visser, eds. 2011. Social Pacts in Europe:
Emergence, Evolution, and Institutionalization. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Avdagic, Sabina, and Lucio Baccaro. 2012. “The Future of Employment Relations in
Advanced Capitalism: Inexorable Decline?” unpublished manuscript, April 2012.
Baccaro, Lucio, and Chris Howell. 2011. “A Common Neoliberal Trajectory: The
Transformation of Industrial Relations in Advanced Capitalism”. Politics & Society
39 (4): 521–563.
Baccaro, Lucio. 2011. “Labor, Globalization and Inequality: Are Trade Unions Still
Redistributive?” In Comparing European Workers Part B: Policies and Institutions
(Research in the Sociology of Work, Volume 22), ed. David Brady. Bingley: Emerald
Group Publishing Limited: 213-285.
Baccaro Lucio, and Rei, Diego. 2007. ‘Institutional Determinants of Unemployment
in OECD Countries: Does the Deregulatory View Hold Water?’. International
Organization 61 (2): 527–569.
Baker, Dean, David R. Howell, Andrew Glyn, and John Schmitt. 2007. ‘Are
Protective Labor Market Institutions at the Root of Unemployment? A Critical
Review of the Evidence’. Capitalism and Society 2 (1): 1-71.
Barbieri Paolo, and Stefani Scherer (2009) “Labour Market Flexibilization and its
Consequences in Italy”. European Sociological Review 25 (6): 677–692.
Becher, Michael, and Jonas Pontusson. 2011. “Whose Interests Do Unions Represent?
Unionization by Income in Western Europe”. Research in the Sociology of Work 22:
181-211.
Boeri, Tito, Agar Brugiavini, and Lars Calmfors. 2001. The Role of Trade Unions in
the Twenty-First Century. A Study for the Fondazione Rodolfo Debenedetti. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Bradley, David, Evelyne Huber, Stephanie Moller, François Nielsen, and John D.
Stephens. 2003. “Distribution and Redistribution in Postindustrial Democracies”.
World Politics 55: 193-228.
Braun, Anne Romanis. 1975. “The Role of Incomes Policy in Industrial Countries
since World War II”. IMF Staff Papers 23 (1): 1–36.
Calmfors, Lars, and John Driffill. 1988. ‘Bargaining Structure, Corporatism and
Macroeconomic Performance.’ Economic Policy 3 (6): 14-47.
Emmenegger, Patrick, Silja Hausermann, Bruno Palier, and Martin Seeleib-Kaiser.
2012. The Age of Dualization: The Changing Face of Inequality in Deindustrializing
Societies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Emmenegger, Patrick, and Romana Careja. 2012. ‘From Dilemma to Dualization:
Social and Migration Policies in the “Reluctant Countries of Immigration”’. In: The
Age of Dualization: The Changing Face of Inequality in Deindustrializing Societies,
eds. Patrick Emmenegger, Silja Häusermann, Bruno Palier, and Martin Seeleib-
Kaiser. Oxford: Oxford University Press: 124-148.
Esping-Andersen, Gosta. 1985. Politics against Markets: The Social Democratic
Road to Power. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
EU Commission. 2008. Industrial Relations in Europe 2008. Brussels.
Flanagan, Robert J. 1999. “Macroeconomic Performance and Collective Bargaining:
An International Perspective.” Journal of Economic Literature 37 (3): 1150–1175.
—— 2003. “Collective Bargaining and Macroeconomic Performance”. In:
International Handbook of Trade Unions, eds. John T. Addison, and Claus Schnabel.
London: Edward Elgar: 172-196.
Golden, Miriam A., Michael Wallerstein, and Peter Lange. 1999. ‘Postwar Trade-
Union Organization and Industrial Relations in Twelve Countries’. In: Continuity and
Change in Contemporary Capitalism, eds. Herbert Kitschelt, Peter Lange, Gary
Marks, John D. Stephens. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 194–230.
Golden, Miriam A., and Michael Wallerstein. 2011. “Domestic and International
Causes for the Rise of Pay Inequality in OECD Nations Between 1980 and 2000”. In:
Comparing European Workerss Part A (Research in the Sociology of Work, Volume
22), ed. David Brady. Bingley: Emerald Group Publishing Limited: 209-249.
Hall, Peter A,. and Daniel W. Gingerich. 2009. “Varieties of Capitalism and
Institutional Complementarities in the Political Economy: An Empirical Analysis”.
British Journal of Political Science, Volume 39 (3): 449–482.
Hall, Peter A., and David Soskice.2001. An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism.
In: Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage,
eds. Peter A. Hall and David Soskice. Oxford: Oxford University Press: 1-68.
Hancké, Bob, and Martin Rhodes. 2005. “EMU and Labor Market Institutions in
Europe: The Rise and Fall of National Social Pacts”. Work and Occupations 32 (2):
196-228.
Hassel, Anke. 2006. Wage Setting, Social Pacts and the Euro. A New Role for the
State. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.
—— 2012. “The Paradox of Liberalization – Understanding dualism and the
recovery of the German political economy”. British Journal of Industrial Relations.
Häusermann, Silja, and Hanna Schwander. 2009. “Who are the outsiders and what do
they want? Welfare state preferences in dualized societies”, paper prepared for the
Panel ‘Security, Freedom and the Varieties of Welfare Capitalism’, 5th General
Conference of the European Consortium for Political Research, 10 – 12 September,
Potsdam, Germany.
Korpi, Walter. 1989. “Power, Politics, and State Autonomy in the Development of
Social Citizenship: Social Rights during Sickness in Eighteen OECD Countries since
1930”. American Sociological Review 54 (3): 309–328.
Lange, Peter, and Geoffrey Garrett. 1985. “The Politics of Growth – Strategic
Interaction and Economic Performance, 1974–1980”. Journal of Politics 47: 792–827.
Lind, Jens. 2009. “The end of the Ghent system as trade union recruitment
machinery?”. Industrial Relations Journal 40 (6): 510–523.
Molina, Oscar, and Martin Rhodes. 2007. “The Political Economy of Adjustment in
Mixed Market Economies: A Study of Spain and Italy” In: Beyond Varieties of
Capitalism: Conflict, Contradictions, and Complementarities in the European
Economy, eds. Bob Hancké, Martin Rhodes, and Mark Thatcher. Oxford: Oxford
University Press: 223-252.
Nickell, S., L. Nunziata, and W. Ochel. 2005. “Unemployment in the OECD since the
1960s. What Do We Know?Economic Journal. 115 (500):1–27.
OECD. 2006. Employment Outlook 2006, Paris.
Palme, Joakim. 1990. Pension Rights in Welfare Capitalism: The Development of
Old-Age Pensions in Eighteen OECD Countries, 1930 to 1985. Stockholm: Swedish
Institute for Social Research.
Pizzorno, Alessandro. 1978. “Political Exchange and Collective Identity in Industrial
Conflict”. In: The Resurgence of Class Conflict in Western Societies since 1968, eds.
C. Crouch, and A. Pizzorno. London: Macmillan: 277–298.
Pontusson, Jonas. 1996. Wage distribution and Labor Market Institutions in Sweden,
Austria and other OECD countries. Institute for European Studies.
Pontusson, Jonas, David Rueda, and C. R. Way. 2003. “Comparative Political
Economy of Wage Distribution: The Role of Partisanship and Labour Market
Institutions”. British Journal of Political Science 32: 281-308.
Rothstein, B. 1992. “Labor market institutions and working-class strength”. In:
Structuring Politics: Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis, eds. Sven
Steinmo, Kathleen Thelen, F. Longstreth. New York: Cambridge University Press:
33-56.
Rowthorn, B. 1992. “Corporatism and Labour Market Performance”. In: Social
Corporatism: A Superior Economic System?, eds. J. Pekkarinen, M. Pohjola, and B.
Rowthorn, Oxford: Clarendon Press:. 82-131.
Rueda, David. 2007. Social Democracy Inside Out. Partisanship and Labor Market
Policy in Industrialized Democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Scharpf, Fritz W. 1991. Crisis and choice in European Social Democracy. Ithaca:
Cornell University Press.
Schmitter, Philippe C. 1974. “Still the Century of Corporatism?” Review of Politics
36: 85–131.
Schwander, Hanna, and Silja Häusermann. 2013. “Who is in and who is out? A risk-
based conceptualization of insiders and outsiders”. Journal of European Social Policy
23 (3): 248-269.
Scruggs, L. 2002. “The Ghent system and union membership in Europe, 1970-1996”.
Political Research Quarterly 55 (2): 275-297.
Shonfield, Andrew. 1965. Modern Capitalism. The Changing Balance of Public and
Private Power. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Soskice, D. 1990. “Wage Determination - The Changing Role of Institutions in
Advanced Industrialized Countries”. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 6 (4): 36-61.
—— 1999. “Civergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated
Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s”. In: Continuity and Change in
Contemporary Capitalism, eds. Herbert Kitschelt, Peter Lange, Gary Marks, John D.
Stephens. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 101-135.
Thelen, K. (2014) Varieties of Liberalization and the New Politics of Social
Solidarity, New York, Cambridge University Press.
Traxler, Franz, Sabine Blaschke and Bernhard Kittel. 2000. National Labor Relations
in Internationalized Markets. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Wallerstein, Michael. 1999. “Wage-Setting Institutions and Pay Inequality in
Advanced Industrial Societies”. American Journal of Political Science 43 (3): 649-
680.
Figures and tables
Source: Data based on ICTWSS
Figure 9.1: Trade Union Density in selected OECD countries (LMEs, CMEs, Nordic
CMEs and MMEs)
30
35
40
45
50
55
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
average trade union density
Source: EES, own calculations
Figure 9.2: Union Density Rates of Insiders and Outsiders, 2010.
0,00
10,00
20,00
30,00
40,00
50,00
60,00
70,00
80,00
90,00
100,00
Outsiders
Insiders
Source: ICTWSS
Note: pre-crisis: 2000-2007; post-crisis: 2008-2012
Figure 9.3. Number of Social Pacts signed per year
0,00
0,05
0,10
0,15
0,20
0,25
LME
CME
MME
1990s
pre-crisis
post
-
crisis
Source: OECD Statistics
Figure 9.4. Unemployment Rates 1990-2012
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012
Unemployment %
LME
CME
Nordic CME
MME
Source: ESS
Figure 9.5. Insider/outsider ratio of unionization and wage inequality, selected
countries 2008
union density employers' organization density collective bargaining coverage collective bargaining
centralization
collective bargaining
coordination
1980s 1990s 2000s chang
e
1980s 1990s 2000s chang
e
1980s 1990s 2000s chang
e
1980s 1990s 2000s chan
ge
1980s 199
0s
200
0s
chang
e
Nordic 73.14 76.58 72.21 -1% 65 68.83 68.92 +6% 79 85.16 85.24 +8% 3.8 3.48 2.79 -
27%
3.98 3.6 3.1 -22%
CME 36.37 31.98 27.03 -25% 100 87 79 -21% 88.25 88.14 86.72 -2% 3.25 2.9 2.78 -
14%
4.28 3.64 3.64 -15%
MME 34.20 27.87 25.10 -27% 59.85 - 76.7 78.85 72.25 -6% 3.1 3.13 3.05 -2% 3.4 3.33 3.18 -6%
LME 43.89 33.20 25.22 -43% 48.75 - 54.28 43.18 32.30 -41% 2.17 1.80 1.58 -
27%
2.13 1.87 1.83 -14%
Source: ICTWSS
Table 9.1: Union density, employers‘ density, wage bargaining coordination, centralization and coverage by type of market economy and decade
Employers
Density
Coverage Centralization Coordination
Union Density
Correlation
Coefficient
.434* .589** .493** 0.331
N 23 33 32 30
Employers
Density
Correlation
Coefficient
.806** .521* .593**
N 22 22 22
Coverage
Correlation
Coefficient
.817** .614**
N 32 30
Centralization
Correlation
Coefficient
.823**
N 30
Source: ICTWSS
Table 9.2: Correlations of union density, employers‘ density, wage bargaining
coverage, centralization and coordination (2000s)
COUNTRY group
LME
MME
CME
Nordic
CME
Gender Female/Male 1.09 .77 .60 1.10
Age <25/25-65 .20 .14 .19 .23
Contract
Limited
term/Unlimited term .55 .39 .61 .73
Income
Lower than median/
higher than median .49 .48 .80 .83
Unemployment
(last 5 years) Yes/No .25 .54 .72 .84
Unemployment
(long-term more
than 12 months) Yes/No .36 .66 .93 .84
Working hours <17/>17hours .47 .45 .51 .52
Sector
Service/
Manufacturing .65 .63 .96 .77
Sector private/public .26 .25 .63 .67
Source: ESS
Note: LME: UK, IRE; MME: ESP, FR, GR, PT; CME: BE, GE, NL, SWI; Nordic
CME: DK, FI, NO, SW.
Table 9.3: Union density ratios of selected employment segments 2008
51
Appendix
union density
employers' organization
density
collective bargaining
coverage
collective bargaining
centralization
collective bargaining
coordination
1980s 1990s
2000s
1980s 1990s
2000s
1980s 1990s
2000s
1980s 1990s
2000s
1980s 1990s
2000s
Australia 45.00 33.34 21.33 85.0 66.7 45.0 3.70 2.40 1.80 3.50 2.40 1.80
Austria 52.12 41.72 32.80 100 100 100 95.0 98.0 98.8 3.30 2.90 2.50 4.30 4.00 4.00
Belgium 52.29 54.45 51.88 74 96.5 96.0 96.0 3.40 3.40 3.40 4.50 4.20 4.20
Canada 34.71 33.96 29.97 37.5 36.4 31.9 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00
Denmark 77.87 76.21 71.62 58 62.50 82.5 84.0 82.3 3.00 2.90 2.50 3.80 3.20 3.30
Finland 69.89 78.19 72.03 65 62.50 68.57 78.0 89.8 90.0 3.90 4.20 3.75 3.60 3.70 3.60
France 14.38 8.96 7.84 74.00 74.50 92.0 90.0 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00
Germany 34.24 29.85 21.72 61.50 76.5 70.2 64.4 3.00 3.00 2.70 4.00 4.00 4.00
Greece 37.62 32.20 25.03 43.73 70.0 67.5 65.0 4.00 3.50 3.50 4.00 4.00 4.00
Ireland 60.26 51.80 37.50 60.00 61.8 60.0 49.5 2.50 4.40 3.70 2.20 4.60 4.70
Italy 43.72 37.70 38.68 60.67 84.5 81.8 80.0 2.40 3.00 2.90 3.50 2.90 2.40
Netherlands 28.84 24.91 20.91 85.00 85.0 84.5 84.4 3.30 3.20 3.30 4.30 4.00 4.00
New Zealand 58.56 30.99 21.42 39.9 18.8 3.40 1.00 1.00 4.10 1.20 1.50
Norway 57.51 56.99 54.40 61.00 70.0 71.5 73.5 4.30 3.50 2.20 4.50 4.00 2.50
Portugal 44.48 25.62 21.08 61.50 72.5 79.0 56.2 2.20 3.00 2.80 2.50 3.40 2.60
Spain 10.99 15.97 15.60 73.50 79.8 87.1 87.8 3.80 3.00 3.00 3.60 3.00 3.70
52
Sweden 81.23 84.14 75.63 86.00 83.60 85.3 90.7 92.8 4.00 3.30 2.70 4.00 3.50 3.00
United
Kingdom 46.34 34.60 28.94 37.50 65.5 39.2 34.6 1.40 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00
United States 18.46 14.48 12.14 21.6 16.9 14.0 1 1 1 1 1 1
Average 45.4 39.0 30.6 63.6 73.4 57.4 70.2 69.1 56.2 2.6 2.3 2.1 3.2 2.9 2.7
Source: ICTWSS
Table 1.1: Industrial relations indicators 1980s, 1990s, 2000s, OECD
53
COUNTRY BE DE DK ES FI FR GB GR IE NL NO PT SE SW
Age 15-25 16.00 3.41 26.26 2.08 25.76 1.74 5.86 2.40 4.71 5.73 12.74 1.18 17.51 2.53
26-65 45.08 13.91 79.06 9.76 63.32 9.70 20.35 11.03 19.03 19.76 52.45 8.82 66.00 12.89
Gender Male 0.43 0.15 0.71 0.09 0.56 0.10 0.18 0.13 0.17 0.21 0.44 0.08 0.56 0.15
Female 0.36 0.10 0.75 0.08 0.63 0.08 0.19 0.08 0.19 0.14 0.49 0.08 0.60 0.07
Contract Unlimited 0.44 0.15 0.70 0.12 0.61 0.09 0.22 0.13 0.25 0.21 0.52 0.09 0.58 0.12
Limited 0.36 0.07 0.59 0.06 0.45 0.03 0.09 0.07 0.17 0.07 0.38 0.04 0.36 0.10
No contract 0.17 0.05 0.33 0.02 0.35 0.02 0.06 0.04 0.08 0.06 0.22 0.03 0.06 0.03
Income Upper median 0.42 0.16 0.80 0.10 0.67 0.11 0.25 0.15 0.25 0.20 0.51 0.13 0.63 0.15
Lower median 0.44 0.12 0.72 0.09 0.55 0.07 0.13 0.07 0.15 0.15 0.39 0.05 0.50 0.10
Unemployment (last 5
years) Yes 0.57 0.08 0.71 0.06 0.57 0.03 0.05 0.05 0.04 0.12 0.30 0.04 0.48 0.11
No 0.50 0.13 0.69 0.14 0.65 0.10 0.25 0.10 0.21 0.26 0.41 0.08 0.64 0.18
Unemployment (long-
term more than 12
monhts) Yes 0.54 0.09 0.59 0.07 0.57 0.05 0.07 0.08 0.07 0.20 0.30 0.05 0.55 0.14
No 0.52 0.13 0.76 0.11 0.66 0.07 0.23 0.07 0.15 0.19 0.40 0.05 0.58 0.14
Working hours <17 hours 29.58 5.65 33.98 4.55 31.25 7.58 10.96 7.14 9.03 8.45 19.66 2.44 29.23 8.55
>17 hours 40.08 13.39 76.32 8.70 60.75 9.12 19.73 10.55 18.94 18.73 48.76 8.29 59.27 12.01
Sector Manufacturing
0.48 0.17 0.65 0.11 0.57 0.07 0.13 0.08 0.12 0.16 0.45 0.05 0.61 0.08
Services 0.34 0.07 0.56 0.04 0.49 0.05 0.12 0.06 0.07 0.14 0.30 0.02 0.43 0.04
Public etc 0.34 0.14 0.71 0.18 0.67 0.13 0.29 0.20 0.31 0.25 0.68 0.15 0.63 0.16
Source: ESS, own calculations
Table 2.1: Unionization rates, selected countries, 2008
54
... While this decline has occurred in nearly every industrialized country, its magnitude differs greatly across countries (Hassel 2015). In the Scandinavian countries membership levels continue to be between 50 and 70% (Visser 2019), while in liberal countries density is now at 10%, in the case of the US, and at approximately 23% in the UK (Visser 2019) (see Figure 1.1 for a display of the density trajectory in several countries). ...
... In the Continental European countries it is for the most part around 17% (ibid.). Institutions seem to be of major importance in explaining this variation; one noticeable feature, for example, is the continuously high union density in countries with a (quasi-)Ghent system, namely Belgium, Denmark, Finland, Iceland, and Sweden (Hassel 2015). The developments of union density also differ across sectors: generally, the public sector has been able to sustain much higher membership rates. ...
... Oesch (2006), however, finds that the difference between part-time workers and full-time workers is not large in all contexts: in Sweden and Switzerland, part-time workers are only slightly less likely to join a union. The divergence holds similarly for other types of atypically employed people: Hassel (2015) compares individuals in insecure labor market positions (outsiders) to those in more secure position (insiders) in different countries. 3 She finds that one can differentiate between two types of countries: universalist countries, where a substantial amount of the complete workforce is unionized, and segmented countries, where unionization is largely restricted to particular segments of the workforce (cf. ...
... to 30% in the 2000s (Hassel 2014). The associational power of this bloc seems, therefore, to be declining. ...
Thesis
Full-text available
This PhD Thesis discusses the actual and potential impacts of Radical Right Parties (RRPs) on the economy and assesses these impacts – quantitatively and qualitatively – by considering the economic policy and performances of 27 European countries.We start discussing the different definitions of RRPs (Chapter 1) and their position on economic issues (Chapter 2 We derive an original taxonomy of RRPs’ positions on economic matters confirming the heterogeneity between RRPs. In Chapter 3, we critically review the literature on the political determinants of the economy and identify three conceptualisations of the ‘political’ in neo-classical economics: opportunistic, partisan, and institutional models. Chapter 4 tests our main hypotheses by using a dynamic panel data model. Results show no significant and robust evidence in support of an impact on authoritarian (e.g. security) and populist (e.g. deficits) indicators. We find evidence in support of a nativist impact, different in Eastern and Western European countries. In Eastern Europe, RRPs’ electoral scores, as well as their inclusion in a ruling coalition, are a significant predictor of increased imports and decreased exports. In Western Europe, RRPs’ strength and presence in a ruling coalition are a significant predictor of increasing gap in unemployment rates between native and foreign workforce.In order to understand the mechanisms behind our results, Chapter 5 proposes an original contribution to Amable and Palombarini (2005)’s neo-realist approach. We argue that economic policy is the result of the political regulation of social conflict and illustrate our framework with the case study of the Italian Lega Nord.
... Second, the involvement of unions has a dissimilar impact on the protection of outsiders in a diverse set of Eu ro pean coun tries: the higher the inclusiveness of union movements, the more they push for outsider oriented policy choices when invited to reform negotiations. This claim rests on the empirical observation that differences in inclusiveness increased over time (Hassel 2015), and that these differences impact on the repre sen ta tional out look of unions (Thelen 2014;Gordon 2015). It follows that I expect reform ne gotiations with unions characterized by low levels of inclusiveness-measured in terms of density and centralization rates-to be less effective in compensating out siders for liberalizing government reforms. ...
Book
Why do some European welfare states protect unemployed and inadequately employed workers ("outsiders") from economic uncertainty better than others? Philip Rathgeb’s study of labor market policy change in three somewhat-similar small states—Austria, Denmark, and Sweden—explores this fundamental question. He does so by examining the distribution of power between trade unions and political parties, attempting to bridge these two lines of research—trade unions and party politics—that, with few exceptions, have advanced without a mutual exchange. Inclusive trade unions have high political stakes in the protection of outsiders, because they incorporate workers at risk of unemployment into their representational outlook. Yet, the impact of union preferences has declined over time, with a shift in the balance of class power from labor to capital across the Western world. National governments have accordingly prioritized flexibility for employers over the social protection of outsiders. As a result, organized labor can only protect outsiders when governments are reliant on union consent for successful consensus mobilization. When governments have a united majority of seats, on the other hand, they are strong enough to exclude unions. Strong Governments, Precarious Workers calls into question the electoral responsiveness of national governments—and thus political parties—to the social needs of an increasingly numerous group of precarious workers. In the end, Rathgeb concludes that the weaker the government, the stronger the capacity of organized labor to enhance the social protection of precarious workers. Advance Praise by Lucio Baccaro, Marius Busemeyer, Jonas Pontusson, and Wolfgang Streeck.
... A unilateral reform strategy against the interests of unions has therefore become less risky for the electoral fortune of national governments. A growing amount of literature documents the declining capacity of unions to resist neoliberal reform ambitions of partisan policy entrepreneurs (Baccaro/Howell 2011; Culpepper/Regan 2014;Hassel 2015). But governments cannot impose any agreement on unions, when their own reform capacity is constrained by intra-coalitional divisions. ...
Article
Full-text available
Austrian political actors have improved the protection of outsiders by expanding the coverage of labour rights, social security , and active labour market policy spending in the past two decades. The article attributes these 'solidaristic' traits of Austrian labour market policy change to the persistent reliance of weak governments on trade union support in the mobilisation of a durable consensus. When governments are internally divided and prone to reform deadlocks, they face a powerful incentive to share policy-making authority with the social partners. Despite a significant decline in power resources, the Austrian trade union confederation has therefore remained influential enough to compensate outsiders for growing economic uncertainty on a volatile labour market. To substantiate this claim empirically, the article draws on primary and secondary sources as well as interview evidence with policy-making elites.
... In the wake of labour market reforms during the past few decades, Denmark has managed to maintain a high level of comprehensive co-ordination, while Germany is now seen as more disorganized (Thelen and Martin 2007). Moreover, trade unions in Denmark have been open and inclusive for so-called labour market outsiders and included them into their positioning and industrial relations institutions, whereas Germany does not (Hassel 2015). As migrant workers are generally defined as labour market outsiders, Denmark is expected to opt for strategies that include mobile workers into their labour market system. ...
Article
We examine the relationship between union power and redistribution in Canada’s ten provinces between 1986 and 2014. Subnational jurisdictions are thus the focus of research questions that have previously been addressed at the international level. Multilevel models with time-series cross-sectional data are used to estimate the long-term association between union density and redistribution through provincial transfer payments and income taxes. We found that higher union density correlates with considerably more redistribution over the long term but not over the short term. This finding is confirmed by three distinct measures of inequality and poverty reduction, an indication that it is quite robust. The association is significant for the entire study period and for its second half. This finding is consistent with power resource theory in its original form, but not with more recent work in that area or with comparative political economy scholarship, which generally now neglects or downplays the impact of organized labour on social and economic policy outcomes. Our findings suggest a need to re-assess the diminished interest of recent researchers in the political influence of organized labour. It will also interest scholars in other countries where tax and transfer systems are decentralized, and where the impact of organized labour on such measures has been understudied at the subnational level. Additionally, we show that unionized voters in Canada are more favourably disposed than their non-unionized counterparts toward redistribution and toward pro-redistribution political parties. Unions may consequently affect redistribution in part by socializing their members to favour it. This possibility is advanced with preliminary data in this paper. We argue that further scholarly attention is both required and deserved on this subject in Canada and elsewhere.
Chapter
Against the background of the recent electoral success of the right-wing populist Alternative for Germany (Alternative für Deutschland, AfD), this contribution deals with the relevance of trade union membership for voters’ support of this party. As organizations with large parts of their identity shaped by their historic pride as pioneers of the fight for freedom and democracy in anti-fascist resistance, trade unions have taken a clear stance against the AfD. Has this organizational positioning caught on among trade union members? The analysis of voter behavior in the Bundestag elections of 2017 does not show any direct effects of the affiliation with trade unions on voter preferences for or against the AfD, and equally few effects on general opinions of this party. However, subtle indirect effects of trade union membership are discernable. Among union members, certain forms of social and political alienation only weakly translate into positive attitudes towards the AfD. In total, however, union membership does not constitute a massive barrier for the AfD on their path to electoral success. In agreement with previous studies, these results also suggest that trade union membership nowadays is of no relevance when it comes to general political issues that do not directly concern voters’ social and economic interests.
Article
Full-text available
Using data from the European Social Survey (2002–14), this article explores the effect of union membership on support for redistribution. The authors hypothesize that the wage-bargaining practices of unions promote egalitarian distributive norms, which lead union members to support redistribution, and that this effect is strongest among high-wage workers. Consistent with the authors’ expectations, the empirical analysis shows that the solidarity effect of union membership is strongest when unions encompass a very large share of the labor force or primarily organize low-wage workers. The authors also show that low-wage workers have become a significantly less important union constituency in many European countries over the time period covered by the analysis.
Article
Applying the new economics of organization and relational theories of the firm to the problem of understanding cross‐national variation in the political economy, this volume elaborates a new understanding of the institutional differences that characterize the ‘varieties of capitalism’ found among the developed economies. Building on a distinction between ‘liberal market economies’ and ‘coordinated market economies’, it explores the impact of these variations on economic performance and many spheres of policy‐making, including macroeconomic policy, social policy, vocational training, legal decision‐making, and international economic negotiations. The volume examines the institutional complementarities across spheres of the political economy, including labour markets, markets for corporate finance, the system of skill formation, and inter‐firm collaboration on research and development that reinforce national equilibria and give rise to comparative institutional advantages, notably in the sphere of innovation where LMEs are better placed to sponsor radical innovation and CMEs to sponsor incremental innovation. By linking managerial strategy to national institutions, the volume builds a firm‐centred comparative political economy that can be used to assess the response of firms and governments to the pressures associated with globalization. Its new perspectives on the welfare state emphasize the role of business interests and of economic systems built on general or specific skills in the development of social policy. It explores the relationship between national legal systems, as well as systems of standards setting, and the political economy. The analysis has many implications for economic policy‐making, at national and international levels, in the global age.
Chapter
The purpose of this article is to explore whether the various events which followed the sudden increase in wages of the years 1968–70 in the main industrial countries can be accounted for by one general theoretical framework. Do the very high wage claims, the intensity of conflicts, their new forms and the new types of claim put forward, the increase in the political involvement of the unions, the spread of unionisation and of social movements into new groups of the population belong to a common pattern? Are they to be explained as a consequence of some structural trend or as a temporary alteration of the systems of political and of labour representation?
Chapter
Ten years ago, when the volume Order and Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism (Goldthorpe 1984) was published, conventional academic wisdom regarding the future of trade unions and corporatism in western Europe was optimistic. As numerous contributors to that earlier volume emphasized, systems of industrial relations involving encompassing unions, in which authority was concentrated in either a small number of large industrial unions or in national confederations, had performed remarkably well in the decade after the first oil price shock of 1973. Most contributors to the Goldthorpe volume shared the view articulated by Peter Lange (1984) that unions could be thought of as playing an n-person prisoner's dilemma in which decentralized action among organizations resulted in collectively suboptimal outcomes. Unions would accept greater wage restraint collectively, the argument went, but not willingly concede acting individually. The prisoner's dilemma analogy suggested that the more encompassing the union movement, the greater the concentration among unions, and the more centralized the authority of the peak associations, the more likely it was that the collectively optimal cooperative solution could be obtained. David Cameron (1984), among others, provided support for this view with evidence showing that corporatism was associated with wage restraint and low strike rates, as well as with lower inflation and less unemployment than in noncorporatist OECD countries. The concern with how the organizational features of trade unionism affect economic performance and the optimism about the relative merits of corporatism were premised on an important if often inexplicit assumption: that unions themselves would remain effective agents for the promotion of the economic interests of workers.
Chapter
VoC theory seems to be caught in a trade-off between parsimony and explanatory capacity. It provides high heuristic value-added for analysing countries where performance-enhancing complementarities rely on clearly different patterns of actor interaction and forms of coordination. It appears more difficult to extend to 'deviant' cases where there is a mix of logics, a high degree of institutional incoherence and an apparent absence of complementarities. This chapter uses the tools of VoC to explain how mechanisms of market and non-market coordination work and change over time in two 'mixed market economies' (MMEs) - Italy and Spain. It focuses on the relationship between production regimes and welfare systems, and specifically the wage-labour nexus and employment protection. In contrast to arguments for a distinctive form of state capitalism alongside 'market' and 'managed' varieties, this chapter argues that the state's role is distinctive but not unique in the Mediterranean countries, and has also undergone considerable change in recent years. It also argues that two different trends can be perceived in these countries: the growth of 'autonomous coordination' in which actors seek to manage the economy via new kinds of non-market governance; and 'market colonization', a process whereby market modes of coordination emerge and prevail.