ArticlePDF Available

Abstract

This article reviews some recent developments in the study of crowdfunding – i.e., the practice of raising funds through an open call on the Internet. It also shows how microeconomic theory can help us understand some important aspects of crowdfunding that go beyond the finance sphere of the firm. A special attention is devoted to the role and behavior of crowdfunding platforms, which intermediate between entrepreneurs and funders. Throughout the paper, the Belgian market for crowdfunding serves as the main source of illustrations.
Paul Belleflamme
CORE & Louvain School of Management
Thomas Lambert
Louvain School of Management
WORKING
PAPER
2014/04
Crowdfunding: some empirical
findings and microeconomic
underpinnings
LOU V A I N S CH O O L O F M A N A GE M E N T R E S E AR C H IN S T I T U TE
Crowdfunding: some empirical findings and microeconomic
underpinnings
Paul Belleflamme, CORE & Louvain School of Management
Thomas Lambert, Louvain School of Management
Summary
This article reviews some recent developments in the study of crowdfunding i.e., the practice of
raising funds through an open call on the Internet. It also shows how microeconomic theory can help us
understand some important aspects of crowdfunding that go beyond the finance sphere of the firm. A
special attention is devoted to the role and behavior of crowdfunding platforms, which intermediate
between entrepreneurs and funders. Throughout the paper, the Belgian market for crowdfunding serves
as the main source of illustrations.
Keywords: crowdfunding, multisided platforms, information asymmetry, price discrimination
JEL Classification: G32, L11, L13, L15, L21, L26
Louvain School of Management
Working Paper Series
Editor : Prof. Jean Vanderdonckt
(president-ilsm@uclouvain.be)
Corresponding author:
Thomas Lambert
Center for Excellence CESAM
Louvain School of Management / Campus Louvain-la-Neuve
UCLouvain
Place des Doyens 1
B-1348 Louvain-la-Neuve, BELGIUM
Email : thomas.lambert@uclouvain.be
The papers in the WP series have undergone only limited review and may be updated, corrected or withdrawn without changing
numbering. Please contact the corresponding author directly for any comments or questions regarding the paper.
President-ilsm@uclouvain.be, ILSM, UCL, 1 Place des Doyens, B-1348 Louvain-la-Neuve, BELGIUM
www.uclouvain.be/ilsm and www.uclouvain.be/lsm_WP
Crowdfunding: some empirical findings and
microeconomic underpinnings
Paul Belleflamme Thomas Lambert
May 15, 2014
Abstract
This article reviews some recent developments in the study of crowdfunding – i.e., the
practice of raising funds through an open call on the Internet. It also shows how microeco-
nomic theory can help us understand some important aspects of crowdfunding that go beyond
the finance sphere of the firm. A special attention is devoted to the role and behavior of
crowdfunding platforms, which intermediate between entrepreneurs and funders. Through-
out the paper, the Belgian market for crowdfunding serves as the main source of illustrations.
JEL classification codes: G32, L11, L13, L15, L21, L26
Keywords: crowdfunding, multisided platforms, information asymmetry, price discrimi-
nation
Prepared for a special issue of the Revue Bancaire et Financi`ere.
Universit´e catholique de Louvain, CORE and Louvain School of Management, Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium,
Paul.Belleflamme@uclouvain.be. Other affiliation: CESifo.
Universit´e catholique de Louvain, Louvain School of Management, Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium,
Thomas.Lambert@uclouvain.be. Other affiliation: Universit´e Lille Nord de France – SKEMA.
1 Introduction
Crowdfunding has recently emerged as a novel way of financing new ventures. The basic idea
behind crowdfunding is simple: instead of raising funds from a small group of sophisticated
investors, entrepreneurs try to obtain them through the Internet from a large audience (the
so-called “crowd”), where each individual provides a small amount. For example, by early
2014, about 8,850 individuals pledged money online through the Belgium-based publishing house
Sandawe; together they raised e850,000 to finance several projects of comic books. Sharing a
similar business model, Akamusic allowed more than 80 artists to produce and distribute their
album. While crowdfunding developed primarily in the arts and creativity-based industries,
initiatives have been undertaken in other industries. For example, Angel.me, CroFun, Look&Fin,
and MyMicroInvest are crowdfunding platforms that have experienced encouraging successes in
raising funds for various entrepreneurial projects. Crowdfunding is naturally not confined within
Belgian borders. Massolution (2013) reports that the market for crowdfunding has continuously
grown worldwide since its infancy and should exceed $5 billion in 2013.
While crowdfunding is an umbrella term used to describe the request of funding from many
individuals through an online platform, four types of crowdfunding models can be identified.
First, crowdfunding can take the form of donations, where individuals give money to a given
project and are not promised anything in return. Second, the reward-based model offers the
contributors a non-financial benefit in return for their funding. In many cases, reward models
offer the possibility to pre-order the product that the entrepreneur is making. Third, the lending-
based model offers the possibility for entrepreneurs to act as borrowers, while contributors take
the position of lenders. Finally, the profit-sharing model is a particular form of crowdfunding
model in which contributors receive a share in the profits of the business or royalties of the
artist. The latter model may also take the label of “equity crowdfunding”, meaning that it
implies investments into securities: shares or bonds.
The startling rise of crowdfunding has raised awareness of and interest in its potential. From
a public policy point of view, it is now widely agreed that crowdfunding should be promoted
as it offers an alternative – and potentially powerful – means for channeling funds towards
small innovative firms; these firms are indeed recognized as a leading source of growth and
job creation, but are facing difficulties to raise funds from traditional sources, especially since
the financial crisis. Yet, it is also admitted that crowdfunding raises a number of important
concerns (risk of fraud, misleading advertisings and advices by entrepreneurs and platforms,
treatment of payments by platforms, etc). There is thus an urgent need for the adoption of
an appropriate regulatory framework concerning the sale of securities, as well as investor and
consumer protection.
Within the European Union (EU), crowdfunding is restricted by national regulatory provi-
2
sions. In Belgium, the Financial Services and Markets Authority (FSMA) published two commu-
nications about the regulatory framework applicable to Belgian crowdfunding platforms. These
communications specify to what extent crowdfunding initiatives fall under the Prospectuses Act
and/or the Payments Services Act. Although very limited political initiatives in Belgium so
far have attempted to legalize crowdfunding for equity, only an initiative at the EU level would
really open up the market for crowdfunding and level the playing field amongst EU countries. In
this respect, the European Commission has launched a public consultation to identify measures
that could help to facilitate crowdfunding practices.1
The United States are ahead of the game. On April 5, 2012, President Obama signed into
law the Jumpstart Our Business Startups (JOBS) Act, designed to help small firms start and
expand. A key provision of the JOBS Act allows various exemptions for crowdfunded securities
concerning, among other things, the number of shareholders that a private company may have,
reporting requirements by the Securities and Exchange Commission, and general solicitation.
In this article, we argue that the current regulatory efforts could be inappropriate if regu-
lators overlook two main features of crowdfunding. First, it is important to understand that
crowdfunding has implications that go beyond the financial and legal spheres of the firm as
crowdfunding also affects the flow of information between entrepreneurs and contributors. In
fact, raising money is not the only strong motivation for entrepreneurs. Other motivations for re-
sorting to crowdfunding are seen as equally important; in particular, getting attention (reduced
marketing costs) and obtaining feedback (market testing, market validation). Crowdfunding
can be used as a promotion device, as a means to support mass customization or user-based
innovation, or as a way for the producer to gain a better knowledge of the preferences of its
consumers.2We argue here that a deeper perspective on these other dimensions might help in
our understanding of the dynamics of crowdfunding and enlighten the ongoing debate in many
ways. From a research standpoint, we examine how traditional models in microeconomics can
be used and extended to account for these dimensions. In particular, we show some preliminary
efforts that have been done so far in that direction and articulate open questions.
The second feature of crowdfunding that regulators must take into account (and that has
received scant attention so far in the literature) is that crowdfunding is now essentially inter-
mediated by Internet platforms.3Crowdfunding platforms assist entrepreneurs in publishing
campaigns and collecting funds. Thereby, they facilitate the interaction between entrepreneurs
1See Hornuf and Schwienbacher (2014b), who examine how securities regulation, particularly the exemptions
to prospectus and registration requirements, affects the structure of equity crowdfunding platforms, fundrais-
ing campaigns of firms, and the type of contributors. See also Cumming and Johan (2013) on demand-driven
regulations for equity crowdfunding based on a nation-wide survey in Canada.
2A better knowledge of the consumers’ preferences may allow the producer to practice price discrimination.
We study this important characteristic of crowdfunding in Section 3.1.
3Entrepreneurs may manage to collect funds directly online from many people without the help of a third
party (see Belleflamme, Lambert, and Schwienbacher, 2013); yet, nowadays, such practice is the exception rather
than the rule.
3
and the crowd of contributors. As the participation of each group is beneficial to the other
group, we argue that crowdfunding platforms can be seen as multisided platforms. We then
use the recent research on the economics of multisided platforms to gain a better understanding
of a number of issues related to crowdfunding platforms (What are their price and non-price
strategies? How do they compete? Why do some succeed while others fail?). We also show how
these platforms manage to mitigate some of the concerns about uncertainty and information
asymmetries that are prevalent in the context of crowdfunding. Hence, crowdfunding platforms
have a natural tendency to self-regulation, which suggests that heavy and complex regulation
by governments may be useless, if not counterproductive.
We explore these two important microeconomic aspects of crowdfunding in Section 3. Before
that, in Section 2, we review recent empirical research so as to highlight a number of stylized
facts. We present a number of concluding remarks in Section 4. Throughout the paper, we try
to illustrate our findings by using examples from the Belgian crowdfunding scene.
2 Recent empirical findings about crowdfunding
This section presents some early research in the study of crowdfunding. To date, important pieces
of research shed light on community benefits, quality signals, herding behaviors, geographical
constraints, skewness in the distribution of funds raised, and concerns about delivery.
First, contributors to the crowdfunding mechanism are not regular investors or consumers.
They have other (intrinsic) motivations. In particular, contributors commit capital not just to
get monetary compensation, but also because they value non-monetary benefits. Their partic-
ipation to the crowdfunding mechanism is truly a social activity from which they derive “com-
munity benefits” (Belleflamme, Lambert, and Schwienbacher, 2014). Contributors feel that they
are part of a community of “special” or “privileged” investors and/or consumers. The nature
and the source of these community benefits vary, especially with the form of crowdfunding. For
example, community benefits can be tied to the consumption experience (usually the case un-
der reward-based models) or to the investment experience (mostly the case under profit-sharing
models). The sources of these community benefits are broad: preferential access to the artist
or the entrepreneur (direct communication, voting on specific issues related to project develop-
ment), token of appreciation (name credited on a CD sleeve or listed on a website), material
reward (T-shirt, original drawing, limited edition album, memorabilia).
Second, contributors respond to quality signals. In particular, equity crowdfunding is most
successful if entrepreneurs are able to reduce uncertainty for potential investors. The empiri-
cal study by Ahlers, Cumming, Gunther, and Schweizer (2013) suggests that retaining equity,
disclosure of detailed information about risk (e.g., financial forecasts), and internal governance
(e.g., qualified board member, proper board structure) are seen as effective signals by the crowd
4
and enhance the likelihood of funding success. Using the universe of projects on Kickstarter,
Mollick (2014) shows interesting correlations between funding propensity and quality signals, as
captured by preparedness of project pitches in terms of time and effort.
Third, contributors react to the actions of other contributors. Indeed, the amount of capital
raised and the length of time in fundraising are partly determined by accumulated capital. On
a lending platform, Zhan and Liu (2012) observe that well-funded borrowers tend to attract
more funding and find evidence of herding among lenders. On a profit-sharing platform in the
recording industry, Agrawal, Catalini, and Goldfarb (2011) show that individuals are more likely
to invest if the funding goal is almost reached. Although herding patterns are found in profit-
sharing and lending-based platforms, contributor support over time on reward-based platforms –
such as Kickstarter – is bathtub shaped. This means that projects typically get a lot of financial
support in the early and last weeks of their funding cycle, consistent with bystander effects
(Kuppuswamy and Bayus, 2013).
Fourth, crowdfunding relaxes geographical constraints. Agrawal, Catalini, and Goldfarb
(2011) uncover that artists and contributors on Sellaband, a music-only platform based in Am-
sterdam, are on average distant by approximately 3,000 miles, suggesting attenuation of the
links between spatial proximity and funding. Still, geography does matter at early financing
stage. The latter geography effect is driven by investors who have a personal tie with the artist
(the so-called “friends and family”). While the latter empirical evidence is robust, the effect
of geography on entrepreneurs is less clear cut. Mollick’s (2014) exploratory study contains a
very preliminary effort in that direction. It shows that geographic clusters are still apparent in
crowdfunding and determine the type of crowdfunded project and the success in raising funds.
Fifth, funding is highly skewed. On one hand, the rate of failure is relatively high. For
example, by early 2014, Kickstarter lists about 57% of failed projects – that is, not reaching
their initial funding goal. During their period of observation on Sellaband platform, Agrawal,
Catalini, and Goldfarb (2011) report a more impressive rate of failures: only 34 artists raised the
threshold required to access their capital to finance the making of their album – this represents
less than 1% of the artists having received at least $10 via this platform. On the other hand, a
small number of project accounts for a very large proportion of funds raised. The 34 successful
projects examined in Agrawal, Catalini, and Goldfarb’s (2011) study account for 73% of the total
amount invested on Sellaband over the period. Belleflamme, Lambert, and Schwienbacher (2013)
drawn similar conclusions from summary statistics of their sample of individually crowdfunded
projects. Interestingly, conditioning on sample on successfully (unsuccessfully) funded projects,
Mollick (2014) stresses skewed distributions in the dollar amounts by which projects exceeding
(not exceeding) their funding goal.
Finally, fraud is rare, delays not. While crowdfunding is commonly viewed as a means to
fundamentally change the investment and financing process, one of the main concern expounded
5
by many is the risk of fraud or at best risk of delay in delivering goods and services. The money
is usually raised up front and the likelihood that unscrupulous entrepreneurs take advantage of
contributors is in theory not negligible. From the technology and design projects on Kickstarter,
case of potential fraud is identified in only 14 out of 381 projects, accounting for less than 0.5%
of dollars in pledges (Mollick, 2014). However, there are more concerns about the ability of
entrepreneurs to deliver on their initial promises. According to Mollick (2014), the majority of
products are delivered late. Of the delayed projects, the mean delay is 2.4 months. Empirical
tests also suggest that larger projects tend to have longer delays than smaller projects. Two
reasons can be advanced to explain the evidence that many entrepreneurs struggle to meet dead-
lines in delivering their product: (1) entrepreneurs tend to be overoptimistic about outcomes,4
and (2) when unexpected success occurs, entrepreneurs may face a range of problems such as
shipping and manufacturing problems, changes in scale and scope, administrative/certification
issues.
These early findings give important insights into the dynamics of crowdfunding. However,
many questions remain open. In addition, establishing causality and identifying transmission
mechanisms are surely the main challenges of future empirical work. In what follows, we argue
that further theoretical developments may stimulate and also help empirical research related to
these issues.
3 A microeconomic perspective
This section offers some theoretical support for the empirical findings described above. First,
we present the microeconomic foundations of the entrepreneur’s choice between various forms
of crowdfunding. Second, we discuss the roles and strategies of crowdfunding platforms, which
intermediate between entrepreneurs and contributors.
3.1 Choosing the right crowdfunding form
Belleflamme, Lambert, and Schwienbacher (2014) build a stylized model to understand what
drives an entrepreneur to choose between the two main forms of crowdfunding, namely the
reward-based and the profit-sharing models.5To make the comparison as neat as possible, the
two crowdfunding models only differ in two key aspects; all the other features of the modeling
framework are common. In particular, it is assumed that the entrepreneur must raise a given
amount of capital to launch her project; the cost of raising this capital is set, without loss
of generality, to zero irrespective of the form of crowdfunding that is chosen. In other words,
4This tendency is well documented in psychology. Indeed, most people display systematic planning fallacy
(Buehler, Griffin, and Ross, 1994) and unrealistically rosy views of their abilities and prospects (Weinstein, 1980).
5See also Sahm et al. (2014), which slightly corrects (and, thereby, simplifies) the analysis.
6
launching a reward-based or a profit-sharing crowdfunding campaign is supposed to be equally
costly for the entrepreneur. It is also assumed that the entrepreneur faces the same crowd of
investors/consumers in the two forms of crowdfunding; the crowd has no a priori preference for
participating in one or the other type of campaign.
By “freezing” the cost and the participation dimensions, the authors clearly want to focus
on another dimension of crowdfunding that they see as crucial, namely the relationship that
crowdfunding allows the entrepreneur to establish with the crowd. As indicated in the previous
section, this relationship goes beyond the sheer financing objective of crowdfunding and has
been understudied so far in the literature. The key argument developed in the paper is that this
relationship differs across crowdfunding models. That is, when choosing one or the other form
of crowdfunding, the entrepreneur also chooses what she can learn about the crowd and what
she can extract from them through the pricing of her product.
Let us be more specific. The reward-based model of crowdfunding that the authors depict is
based on pre-ordering: the contributors are consumers who have a strong taste for the announced
product and who therefore decide to pre-order it, that is, to pay for it before it is actually
produced. The entrepreneur can reward the contributors in various ways, as described above;
what matters for the analysis is that these rewards (called “community benefits”) increase the
contributors’ willingness to pay for the product. It is assumed that this increase in willingness
to pay is proportional to the consumer’s taste for the product; that is, those consumers who
like the product the most are also those who value the rewards the most. As a result, this
form of crowdfunding allows the entrepreneur to segment her consumers into two groups: the
early contributors who signal themselves as high-paying consumers (and whose willingness to
pay is further enhanced by the value that they attach to the rewards), and the other, regular,
consumers who wait for the product to be put on the market to consider buying it. The
entrepreneur can thus price discriminate between these groups, which has the potential to raise
her profits as she is assumed to be in a monopoly position for her product.6However, the optimal
price discrimination scheme may not be feasible if the initial capital requirement is too high.
The obligation to finance the capital through pre-sales puts indeed a constraint on the price
that can be charged to those consumers who choose to pre-order the product. One understands
therefore that the profitability of this form of crowdfunding decreases with the size of the capital
requirement.
The profit-sharing model differs with the reward-based model on two accounts. First, the
nature of contributions and compensations is different: instead of pre-ordering the product, the
crowd is invited to directly provide a fixed sum of money to the entrepreneur and is promised
a share of the future profits in exchange. Second, contributors also enjoy community benefits
6We have here a form of behavior-based price discrimination (BBPD) as consumers self-select into one group
and are then charged a specific price corresponding to their choice; see, for example, Fudenberg and Villas-Boas
(2007) for a general analysis of BBPD and Belleflamme and Peitz (2010, chapter 10) for a textbook treatment.
7
but it is assumed here that these benefits are independent of the contributor’s taste for the
product; this assumption makes sense as contributors are seen here as investors, who may well
decide to finance the venture without purchasing the product eventually. The implications of
these differences are the following. On the minus side, the entrepreneur is no longer able to
segment the crowd and, especially, to single out the high-paying consumers. On the plus side, all
individuals value community benefits in the same way, which makes it easier for the entrepreneur
to capture this extra value; moreover, this ability to capture the value that contributors attach
to community benefits is not impaired by the size of the capital requirement.
The comparison of the profits that the entrepreneur can achieve under the two forms of
crowdfunding yields the main result of the analysis: the entrepreneur prefers the reward-based
model when the capital requirement is relatively small and the profit-based model otherwise. The
intuition behind this result has been outlined above: pre-ordering in the reward-based model
allows the entrepreneur to practice price discrimination, which should give her a higher profit
than in the profit-sharing model (in which she is bound to set a uniform price for her product).
However, price discrimination is constrained, and thus less profitable, when the initial capital
requirement grows larger than some threshold. Above this threshold, the profit-sharing model,
which allows the entrepreneur to turn all individuals into investors, becomes the best option.
3.2 Crowdfunding platforms
We focus here on the roles and strategies of crowdfunding platforms, which facilitate the interac-
tion between entrepreneurs trying to raise funds and consumers/investors willing to participate
in the financing of new projects. We first identify crowdfunding platforms as “multisided plat-
forms”. Then, we describe the price and non-price strategies that these platforms implement.
Finally, we briefly analyze competition among crowdfunding platforms.
3.2.1 Multisidedness of crowdfunding platforms
Crowdfunding platforms can be seen as multisided platforms. As Evans (2011) explains it, a
business opportunity emerges for a multisided platform when three conditions are met. First,
there are distinct groups of customers. Second, a member of one group benefits from having his
demand coordinated with one or more members of another group; in the jargon of the economics
literature, it is said that each group exerts indirect, or cross-side, network effects on the other
groups. Finally, an intermediary can facilitate that coordination more efficiently than bilateral
relationships between the members of the groups.
Crowdfunding platforms seem to meet these three conditions. First, they link at least two
distinct groups: entrepreneurs (fundraisers) on one side and contributors (funders) on the other
8
side.7Second, each group’s valuation of the platform depends on the participation of the other
group(s). As far as contributors are concerned, there are two reasons for which they are likely
to prefer platforms with a larger number of entrepreneurs: such platforms provide them with a
wider set of campaigns that they can choose to support and, in the reward-based model, such
platforms also increase the probability that contributors will obtain rewards that fit their tastes.
Yet, another force may play in the opposite direction: the chances that any given campaign
will be successful (i.e., will reach the required threshold) are inversely related to the number of
campaigns that the platform hosts; for that reason, contributors may prefer platforms with a
smaller number of entrepreneurs. We may conjecture that the former effects outweigh the latter
(in particular if contributors can find some way to coordinate on projects that are more likely
to be successful). It is thus reasonable to say that entrepreneurs exert positive indirect network
effects on contributors. The same obviously applies in the opposite direction: contributors exert
positive indirect network effects on entrepreneurs: entrepreneurs value platforms that are able to
attract larger crowds of contributors as they increase their chances to raise the targeted funds;
platforms that attract a larger number of contributors are also more interesting because they
allow entrepreneurs to showcase their products and to “test the waters” on a larger scale. As for
the third condition, even though entrepreneurs may be able to connect with the crowd by their
own means,8platforms undoubtedly offer them both higher prospects of success and lower costs.
In particular, as we discuss it below, crowdfunding platforms are able to mitigate the problems
raised by information asymmetries much more efficiently than any individual fundraiser could
do on his/her own.
It is important to note that agents on both sides also care about what the members of their
own group do; that is, within-side external effects are also present. Such effects are likely to be
negative among entrepreneurs as they compete for the funds that the crowdfunders are willing
to contribute: the more campaigns the platform hosts, the tougher the competition. In contrast,
positive within-group effects exist among contributors: the project that a particular contributor
has chosen to support is more likely to reach the required threshold the larger is the number of
contributors who may choose to back this project too.
3.2.2 Strategies of crowdfunding platforms
Facing these various cross-side and within-side external effects, crowdfunding platforms use price
and non-price instruments to manage participation and usage on both sides of the market. As
7We discuss below the pros and cons of bringing other groups on board. For a deeper analysis of the contributors
and entrepreneurs’ respective incentives and desincentives to participate in crowdfunding campaigns, see Agrawal,
Catalini, and Goldfarb (2013).
8For instance, Verity Price, a South-African singer, managed to crowdfund her first album by appealing to
her fans through her own website. See more specifically Belleflamme, Lambert, and Schwienbacher (2013) who
analyze a broad set of individual crowdfunding campaigns.
9
far as prices are concerned, what matters for a platform’s profits is not the sum of the prices
paid on the two sides but the structure of these prices (see Rochet and Tirole, 2006). In general,
a multisided platform that decides to charge a little bit less on one side and to compensate by
charging a little bit more on another side, thereby keeping the sum of prices unchanged, is likely
to affect its profits in a dramatic way. This certainly applies to crowdfunding platforms. As for
now, the vast majority of them only charge the entrepreneur side and let contributors use the
platform services for free. One can easily understand that platforms would not achieve the same
levels of profits if they lowered the entrepreneurs’ fees and charged, in compensation, a small fee
to contributors. It is indeed very likely that any positive fee would discourage many contributors
to participate; this would in turn make the crowdfunding platform much less attractive for
entrepreneurs, whose willingness to pay would therefore decrease. Subsidizing the participation
on one side is often the only way for multisided platforms to solve the so-called “chicken-and-
egg” problem: as each group’s participation is conditioned on the other group’s participation,
the intermediary has no choice but to let one group use the platform for free so as to initiate a
positive feedback loop.
Regarding non-price instruments, Hagiu (2014) explains the importance for multisided plat-
forms to make the right decisions about the design of the platform (functionalities and features of
the platform, which sides to take on board) and about its governance rules (regulation of access
and participation). In the case of crowdfunding platforms, design and governance decisions are
generally geared to address issues related to information asymmetries. As clearly explained by
Agrawal, Catalini, and Goldfarb (2013), crowdfunding faces the two typical asymmetric informa-
tion problems of hidden information and hidden action, which plague the relationship between
entrepeneurs and contributors respectively before (“ex ante”) and after (“ex post”) financing
takes place. Ex ante, contributors often lack the necessary information to evaluate correctly
how successful the proposed projects are likely to be. This can lead to adverse selection and
the well-known “lemon effect” (see Akerlof, 1970): platforms only manage to attract low-quality
projects because high-quality entrepreneurs anticipate that they will not be identified as such by
the contributors and will therefore fail to raise the capital that they need.9Ex post, a problem
of moral hazard arises as contributors face difficulties to control whether entrepreneurs exert the
needed effort to keep up with their promises; for instance, as indicated in Section 2, delays in
product delivery are commonplace.10
9Free-riding among contributors may worsen the hidden information problem: because contributors only have
a small stake, their incentive to investigate entrepreneurs may be low. As a result, the natural tendency is to wait
for the due diligence efforts of other crowdfunders. Such a wait may lead to a mere failure of projects (everyone
waiting for someone else to make the first move) or to “information cascades”: as described in Section 2, herd
behavior is observed on crowdfunding platforms because crowdfunders take accumulated contributions as a signal
of quality (note that a precondition for such signal to be efficient is that early funders carefully screened the
proposed projects).
10Outright fraud, however, remains rare. It is only recently (in May 2014) that a first consumer protection
lawsuit involving crowdfunding was filed in the United States (by the Washington State Office of the Attorney
10
What strategies can crowdfunding platforms implement to address these problems? A first
strategy consist in bringing an additional side on board, namely sophisticated investors (such
as venture capitalists, business angels, and institutional investors). Two Belgian platforms
have chosen this route: MyMicroInvest allows projects to be funded by the crowd together
with a professional venture capitalist; Angel.me has established a partnership with the bank
Belfius. The objective is clear: the participation of sophisticated investors is meant to reassure
individual contributors; because these investors have much larger capacities and experience
to investigate the reliability and success probability of proposed projects, crowdfunders can
infer useful information from the choices that these investors make.11 A potential drawback of
this strategy is that it may create conflicts of interest between the two groups of investors. An
important empirical question is then to measure the extent to which the two groups complement
or substitute each other; Hornuf and Schwienbacher (2014a) make a first step in that direction
by focusing on equity crowdfunding and angel finance.
Crowdfunding platforms also design specific rules to reduce information asymmetry. First,
most platforms have implemented the “provision point mechanism”, whereby entrepreneurs only
receive funds if the total contributions reach (or surpass) a chosen threshold within a certain
period of time; as pointed by Agrawal, Catalini, and Goldfarb (2013), with this mechanism,
contributors know that they will only provide funds for projects that will eventually raise the
capital that they need to be viable. Some platforms also force entrepreneurs, whose projects are
deemed more risky, to disclose more information. Others devote themselves more resources to
detect potential fraud.12
Finally, crowdfunding platforms can tackle information asymmetry by acting as trusted
intermediaries. Their objective is to become bearers of reputation and, thereby, effectively certify
the quality and reliability of the projects that they take on board. To do so, platforms must
carefully screen projects so as to accept only the high-quality ones.13 The reason is simple: a
project accepted on the platform is believed to be of high quality by a contributor unless he/she
previously experienced low quality of some other project proposed on the platform; hence, to
avoid any stain on its reputation, the platform must keep away from low quality projects.
Understanding that, entrepreneurs do not find it profitable to try to have low quality projects
funded, implying that only high quality projects are eventually proposed on the platform. In
General). The suit alleged that the company Altius Management failed to make good on a successful Kickstarter
campaign for a card game. In particular, after having collected the money, the company neglected to deliver
either the cards or the various backer rewards.
11The opposite may be true as well: sophisticated investors may use the “wisdom of the crowd” as an indicator
of the potential success of a new product (something that they may have a hard time to evaluate otherwise).
12Hardware and product design pro jects on Kickstarter require further detailed information about the products
development and progress. With those projects, entrepreneurs are also constrained in the number of rewards
per pledge they can offer (to avoid delay or fraud). In the same vein, the publishing house Sandawe designs its
contracts with authors so as to have the exclusivity in the edition of the author’s comic book pro ject.
13They should also try, from an ex post point of view, to make sure that funded entrepreneurs deliver on their
commitments.
11
a nutshell, the platform can be trusted simply because it suffices to have one rotten apple in
the bag to spoil the rest of them in no time, something that crowdfunding platforms simply
cannot afford. In practice, crowdfunding platforms are aware of the importance of acting as
trusted intermediaries. For instance, MyMicroInvest publishes on its website a Code of ethics,
which stresses the values that the platform itself and the entrepreneurs it selects commit to
abide by. Similarly, Fed´eric L´evy Morelle, founder and manager at Look&Fin, mentioned in a
recent interview about the first year of existence of his platform: “We have received more than
120 files and if we only kept 5 of them, it was because we wanted to keep our independence and
to take the time to select the right projects on which our investors would take a limited risk.” 14
3.2.3 Competition among crowdfunding platforms
We have explained above that crowdfunding platforms facilitate the interaction between con-
tributors and entrepreneurs, with the participation of each group reinforcing the other’s. The
presence of such positive cross-side effects on both sides of a platform is a powerful force to-
wards the concentration of the crowdfunding market: big platforms tend to become even bigger,
whereas small platforms face a downward spiral, which will eventually lead them to leave the
market. Economies of scale in the operation of crowdfunding services (e.g., due diligence efforts
and project screening) further contribute to this “winner-takes-all” market configuration.
However, some forces may play in the opposite direction and favor the coexistence of several
crowdfunding platforms. First, we have mentioned above that contributors may have reasons
to prefer smaller platforms (i.e., platforms attracting fewer entrepreneurs, thereby raising the
prospect for each contributor to be pivotal for the existence of any particular project). We
also evoked the negative within-side effects among entrepreneurs: they may also prefer smaller
platforms where competition for funds may be relaxed. Second, like in any market, differenti-
ation allows firms to coexist. In the crowdfunding market, differentiation is mostly horizontal:
platforms differentiate in terms of business model (e.g., reward-based versus equity), sector of
activity (e.g., artistic creations, innovating companies) or geographical basis (e.g., platforms are
most of the time region- or country-specific). For instance, on the Belgium crowdfunding mar-
ket, MyMicroInvest proposes an equity-based model and focuses on new ventures with a clear
innovative content, whereas Look&Fin offers a lending-based model.
In view of these conflicting forces and of the fact that the crowdfunding market is still in
its infancy, it is hard to predict how it will evolve. It is, however, quite clear that among the
500 or so crowdfunding platforms that were listed in 2013 (see Massolution, 2013), many will
quickly disappear because they will have failed to reach a critical mass of either contributors or
14Original quote: “Nous avons re¸cu plus de 120 dossiers, et si nous n’en avons retenu que 5, c’est pour
garder notre ind´ependance, et pour prendre le temps de s´electionner de bons dossiers sur lesquels les in-
vestisseurs prendront un risque limit´e.”http://www.lecho.be/dossier/techno/Les_defis_du_crowdfunding_
en_Belgique.9389750-7342.art (published online on August 19, 2013).
12
entrepreneurs, or failed to find the right business model to monetize the interaction between the
two sides. An illustration of such failure on the Belgian crowdfunding market is Akamusic, which
created Akastarter to further develop its business model by enlarging its field of activity, but
failed to reach sufficient projects to be profitable and allow the continuation of its business. In
contrast, it is also likely that platforms that are currently successful will extend their activities.
The obvious example is the US-based Kickstarter that now intends to set up in Continental
Europe (starting with the Netherlands) so as to enlarge its base of proposed projects (and
thereby further fuel the positive reinforcing effects between the two sides of the platform).15
4 Conclusion
In this article we have first reviewed the early academic literature on crowdfunding. To date,
research – mostly empirical – has brought important insights into the role and behavior of en-
trepreneurs and contributors. No less important though, platforms have received less attention.
While early findings on crowdfunding provided significant advances, we think that important
theoretical efforts have still to be made to better understand the underlying logic of the dynamics
of crowdfunding. After having presented the very first study that goes in that direction, we have
then shown how microeconomic theory can help in this perspective. We did so by focusing our
discussion on the role and behavior of platforms. In particular, we have depicted how advances
in the theory of multisided platforms can be applied to the study of crowdfunding platforms.
As food for thought for future research, we would like to stress the following points. After
a few years of existence, crowdfunding is surely becoming an important alternative method of
financing for SMEs. We think that two features are instrumental in this development. First,
crowdfunding has implications that go beyond the financial sphere: on the one hand, it is a
vector by which information can flow between entrepreneurs and contributors (e.g., marketing
and signaling dimensions); on the other hand, crowdfunding cleverly leverages the contribu-
tors’ extrinsic and intrinsic motivations by complementing monetary compensations with com-
munity benefits. Second, crowdfunding platforms provide new and inventive ways to match
entrepreneurs and contributors, and to reduce information-related market failures.
Clearly, the latter two features have been made possible by the development of the Internet.
Therefore, the current success of crowdfunding blatantly shows that the traditional financial
sector, concentrated in bodies such as stock exchanges and banks, can no longer ignore the
potential of Internet for its future evolutions. Internet is a general-purpose technology that has
already triggered a number of important (r)evolutions. Think, for example, of the effects of dig-
ital piracy on cultural industries or of the so-called “sharing economy” (with platforms like Uber
15While Kickstarter has been accepting contributors from all over the globe for some time now, only en-
trepreneurs in the United States, the United Kingdom, Canada, Australia and New Zealand were allowed to
actually create campaigns.
13
or Airbnb) on the transportation and traveling industries. What crowdfunding demonstrates is
that similar forces threaten the traditional financial sector as it is now possible to “desinterme-
diate” or “debank” the financial system by letting individuals and firms interact more directly
and (at least partially) bypass traditional intermediaries.
References
[1] Agrawal, A., C. Catalini, and A. Goldfarb, 2011. The geography of crowdfunding. NBER
Working Paper, No. 16820.
[2] Agrawal, A., C. Catalini, and A. Goldfarb, 2013. Some simple economics of crowdfunding.
NBER Working Paper, No. 19133.
[3] Ahlers, G., D. Cumming, C. Gunther, and D. Schweizer, 2013. Equity crowdfunding. Work-
ing Paper.
[4] Akerlof, G., 1970. The market for “lemons”: Quality uncertainty and the market mecha-
nism. Quarterly Journal of Economics 84, 488-500.
[5] Belleflamme, P., T. Lambert, and A. Schwienbacher, 2013. Individual crowdfunding prac-
tices. Venture Capital 15, 313–333.
[6] Belleflamme, P., T. Lambert, and A. Schwienbacher, 2014. Crowdfunding: Tapping the
right crowd. Journal of Business Venturing, forthcoming.
[7] Belleflamme, P., and M. Peitz, 2010. Industrial organization: Markets and strategies. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
[8] Buehler, R., D. Griffin, and M. Ross, 1994. Exploring the planning fallacy: Why people
underestimate their task completion times. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology
67, 366–381.
[9] Cumming, D., and S. Johan, 2013. Demand-driven securities regulation: Evidence from
crowdfunding. Venture Capital 15, 361–379.
[10] Evans, D.S., 2011. Platform economics: Essays on multi-sided businesses. Competition
Policy International.
[11] Fudenberg, D., and J. M. Villas-Boas, 2007. Behavior-based price discrimination and cus-
tomer recognition. In Hendershott, T. J. (ed.), Economics and information systems. Ams-
terdam: Elsevier.
14
[12] Hagiu, A., 2014. Strategic decisions for multisided platforms. MIT Sloan Management Re-
view 55, 71–80.
[13] Hornuf, L., and A. Schwienbacher, 2014a. Crowdinvesting – Angel investing for the masses?
Working Paper.
[14] Hornuf, L., and A. Schwienbacher, 2014b. Which securities regulations promotes crowdin-
vesting? Working Paper.
[15] Kuppuswamy, V., and B. Bayus, 2013. Crowdfunding creative ideas: The dynamics of
project backers in Kickstarter. Working Paper.
[16] Massolution, 2013. 2013 Crowdfunding Report.
[17] Mollick, E., 2014. The dynamics of crowdfunding: An exploratory study. Journal of Busi-
ness Venturing 29, 1–16.
[18] Rochet, J.C. and J. Tirole 2006. Two-sided markets: A progress report. Rand Journal of
Economics 37, 1–36.
[19] Sahm, M., P. Belleflamme, T. Lambert, and A. Schwienbacher, 2014. Corrigendum to
“Crowdfunding: Tapping the right crowd”. Journal of Business Venturing, forthcoming.
[20] Weinstein, N, 1980. Unrealistic optimism about future life events, Journal of Personality
and Social Psychology 39, 806-820.
[21] Zhang, J., and P. Liu, 2012. Rational herding in microloan markets. Management Science
58, 892-912.
15
... Platforms can either specialize in specific niches, such as innovative and creative projects, start-ups, sustainability, or charity projects or be generalists (Presenza et al., 2019). Platforms have experienced significant growth and continue to develop worldwide, representing an opportunity to fund entrepreneurs (Belleflamme and Lambert, 2014). In recent years, research has highlighted the importance of crowdfunding as a funding option and source of knowledge to support innovative initiatives and harness the wisdom of crowds (Herv e and Schwienbacher, 2018;Troise and Tani, 2020). ...
Article
Abstract Purpose Innovative initiatives focusing on social and environmental impact often need help to secure traditional financial resources for their launch. Equity crowdfunding platforms (ECF) provide a potential funding source for these initiatives, particularly for technological inventors. This research paper aims to theorize how ECF campaigns attract investors to invest in technological initiatives with social and environmental value proposition impacts. Design/methodology/approach Using an inductive qualitative approach, the authors have gained insights, from 35 sustainable technological projects sponsored by a Chilean equity-crowdfunding platform, regarding the business model's transformation to achieve sustainable social and environmental impacts. Findings Findings show that disruptive technologies and sustainable aims are pivotal factors in successfully attracting investors to support sustainable technological initiatives through ECF platforms or campaigns. These factors led investors to actively engage with these projects and contribute to the value-creation process by transforming business models with social and environmental impacts and utilizing sustainable technology to enhance efficiency and optimize available resources. Research limitations/implications Due to the nature of this research, researchers must test the proposed conceptual framework using longitudinal quantitative data from multiple ECF platforms, technological solutions and investors worldwide in future research to enhance the comprehension of this phenomenon. Practical implications The findings highlight the significant contribution of ECF platforms and technological portfolios toward creating sustainable impacts. It is a good signal for investors interested in investing in technological initiatives and addressing social and environmental challenges. Social implications The contribution of disruptive technological projects from ECF platforms and ECF investors to tackle social and environmental challenges. Originality/value This research theorizes how ECF platforms tackle social challenges by encouraging investors to invest and participate with entrepreneurs in the co-creation process of sustainable technological solutions.
... Yazar İçeriği Belleflamme & Lambert (2014) Çalışmada, girişimciler ve yatırımcılara dair yapılan diğer çalışmalara yer verilmiş, ancak literatürdeki bir eksiklik olarak nitelenen kitle fonlama platformları üzerine yapılan çalışmaların azlığına dikkat çekilmiştir. Çok taraflı platformlar teorisindeki gelişmelerin, kitle fonlama platformlarının çalışmasına nasıl entegre edileceğine ilişkin değerlendirmeler yapılmıştır. ...
Article
Full-text available
Alternatif finansman sistemlerinden biri olan kitle fonlama sistemi, yaşanan finansal krizlerin de etkisiyle, hızla gelişmekte ve geleneksel finansman yöntemleri ile rekabet edebilir bir seviyeye gelmektedir. Ancak, kitle fonlama sistemlerinin gelişim hızı ülkeler bazında değişmektedir. Çalışmanın amacı ülkeler arası farklılıkların söz konusu ülkelerin makroekonomik değişkenlerinden nasıl etkilendiğinin belirlenmesidir. Bu amaç doğrultusunda, kitle fonlama sistemlerinin (borç bazlı, pay bazlı ve toplam) işlem hacimleri AB ülkelerinde çoklu doğrusal regresyon modeli ile incelenmiştir. Çalışmada, borç bazlı kitle fonlama sisteminde etkili olan değişkenlerin yurtiçi tasarruflar, cari açık, belirsizlikten kaçınma endeksi ve banka-ATM sayısı olduğu bulgusuna ulaşılmıştır. Pay bazlı kitle fonlama ve toplam kitle fonlama sisteminde ise etkili olan değişkenlerin yurtiçi tasarruflar, ödenmemiş borçlar olduğu belirlenmiştir. Bu noktada, yurtiçi tasarrufların her üç modelde de en önemli değişken olduğu görülmektedir. Yurtiçi tasarrufların arttırılması ile ülkelerin sermaye birikiminin ve kitle fonlama sistemlerine olan talebin artması beklenmektedir. Ayrıca, ülkelerin kitle fonlama sistemlerini geliştirme amacını, makroekonomik verilerine göre kendilerine en uygun türdeki sistemle gerçekleştirebilecekleri düşünülmektedir. Abstract The crowdfunding system, which is one of the alternative financing systems, is developing rapidly with the effect of the financial crises and is reaching a level that can compete with traditional financing methods. However, the pace of development of crowdfunding systems varies between countries. The aim of the study is to determine how the differences between countries are affected by macroeconomic variables. For this purpose, the transaction volumes of crowdfunding systems (debt-based, equity-based, and total) were examined with the multiple linear regression model in EU countries. In the study, it was found that the effective variables in the debt-based crowdfunding system are domestic savings, current account deficit, uncertainty avoidance, and number of banks-ATMs. It was determined that the effective variables in the equity-based and the total crowdfunding systems are domestic savings and outstanding loans. It was seen that domestic savings are the most important variable in all three models. It is expected that with the increase in domestic savings, the capital accumulation of the countries and the demand for crowdfunding systems will increase. In addition, it is thought that countries can achieve their goal of developing their crowdfunding systems with the most appropriate type of system according to macroeconomic data.
... Planning tailored education for the immigrant entrepreneurs to teach them how to access bank loans and other formal means of finance would be beneficial in utilizing their innovation potential similar to native entrepreneurs. Training immigrant entrepreneurs on new alternative financing methods such as crowdfunding (Belleflamme et al., 2014) and peer-to-peer lending can also be fruitful to obtain financial sources (Bruton et al., 2015). When their project is assessed as highly innovative, they can be supported through a team of experts specializing in finance and market sectors to avoid denial and attract financial investors to exploit the opportunity for innovation. ...
Article
Full-text available
Objective: The article investigates the relative benefit of formality/informality of finance sources for innovation and compares this benefit amongst immigrant and native entrepreneurs. The authors investigate whether formal finance (here, bank loan) benefit innovation more than informal sources (personal savings and friend/family loan). Then, they explore whether an entrepreneur‘s status strengthens or weakens the benefit finance sources for innovation. Research Design & Methods: This study applies a quantitative approach to conduct the research. The data of 15,850 entrepreneurs surveyed by Global Entrepreneurship Monitor in 2015 were analysed using the hierarchical linear modelling (HLM) technique. Findings: Results indicated that formal finance benefits innovation more than informal sources, and this advantage is the same for both immigrant and native entrepreneurs. Implications & Recommendations: Despite the prevalence of some stereotypes regarding the simplistic and repetitive nature of immigrants ‘ businesses, the study recommends that financial institutions and policymakers plan to enhance entrepreneurs ‘ access to formal financial resources irrespective of their migrant status. Policymakers also can plan to increase the immigrant entrepreneurs ‘ access to the formal sources of finance by tailored educations to boost innovation. Contribution & Value Added: The results highlight that immigrant entrepreneurs benefit from formal finance towards innovation similarly to their native counterparts. Such a clarification informs the studies on the liability of foreignness and innovation finance that immigration status cannot be a barrier to innovation as portrayed and conceptualized by some studies.
... These numbers show that crowdfunding has attracted more and more attention. Recently, people have been more interested in research issues and practices of crowdfunding [1,7,79]. The total amount of funds raised through Kickstarter, the world's largest crowdfunding platform, exceeded US$ 4.88 billion and the number of participants exceeded 18.06 million until June 2020. ...
Article
Full-text available
Low success rates have been one of the critical issues in crowdfunding. Previous studies already indicated that the project description will affects the success of the crowdfunding project. However, there is no research to explore which factors should be included in the project description for directly affecting the success of the project. The participants’ text comments have been confirmed that they might change supporters’ decisions. In most of crowdfunding related studies, they often used questionnaires survey which may have sampling bias and require a lot of manpower and time. In addition, they merely focus on music and sports fields but have not yet discussed the movie projects. Consequently, this study attempts to present a scheme to identify the key success factors, especially for project description and user comments, using text mining and data mining approaches. In our presented scheme, feature selection methods, including Decision Trees (DT), Least Absolute Shrinkage and Selection Operator (LASSO), and Back Propagation Network (BPN) pruning method are employed to select important factors from real projects in Kickstarter and Indiegogo. Then, a support vector machine (SVM) is performed to evaluate the performances of selected candidate factor subsets. Finally, we can determine the key success factors for movie crowdfunding projects. Experimental results can give the fundraisers useful suggestions for increasing the success rate of movie crowdfunding projects.
... The assessment of the roles and responsibilities of city administrations in the cases revealed that fraud and corruption were legitimate concerns, which is exacerbated by the nature of crowdfunding. Freitas and Amado (2013) and Belleflamme and Lambert (2014) confirm that fraud and corruption are prevalent wherever money is involved. However, in crowdfunding these threats become more prominent due to the fact that there is usually no personal contact between the contributors or investors and the entrepreneur who initiated the project. ...
Article
Full-text available
The emergence of civic crowdfunding is a relative new phenomenon in the city governance arena. Scholarly literature on the application thereof as urban renewal alternative is therefore rather muted. Based on perceived successes in cases where crowdfunding were applied, it is evident that it holds significant potential as alternative instrument for city renewal. Crowdfunding is being increasingly touted worldwide as an alternative revenue collection mechanism available to cities. However, the intricacies associated with the utilisation of civic crowdfunding as an alternative urban renewal instrument necessitates an exploration of the documented experiences of its applicability. The purpose of this article is to explore the emergence of crowdfunding in cities and to uncover best practices in its utilisation by interrogating selected cases in both developed and developing contexts. Using a qualitative methodology, a case study design and content analysis as the research design, seven cases were analysed to uncover success factors and key lessons to be learnt. Based on the analyses of seven cases, namely the Statue of Liberty, the Glyncoch Community Centre, the Liverpool Flyover, the BD Bacata Tower, Live Lebanon, Zambia's Sunny Money, and Kenya's Skynotch Energy, key lessons are drawn for city administrations as well as citizens as potential participants in crowdfunding initiatives. Critical success factors emerging from these cases are thematically analysed and include factors such as the role of social media, the utilisation of crowdfunding platforms, the importance of city regulations, and the significance of rewards and acknowledgements. Finally, some major operational concerns about civic crowdfunding as an alternative for urban renewal are identified. 2 | P a g e
Thesis
Full-text available
Abstract Crowdfunding and explaining its role in enhancing the financial inclusion of small, medium and micro enterprises (MSMES) is one of the important issues in the world, the Arab region and Iraq, and delving into it is a great challenge, since crowdfunding is one of the modern methods of financing, in addition to the critical importance of the financial inclusion of MSMES In supporting economic and social development, therefore, the study aimed to demonstrate the role of crowdfunding in enhancing the financial inclusion of small, medium and micro enterprises (MSMES). In order to test the role of crowdfunding in promoting financial inclusion, a sample of sixteen crowdfunding platforms operating in Indonesia (four platforms for each form of crowdfunding) was selected using the purposive sampling method. The analytical approach was relied on to test a set of indicators that reflect the dimensions of financial inclusion for MSMEs, represented by access to financial services, their availability, use, cost, and quality. Then, the data collected were analyzed using descriptive, correlation and regression analysis using the SPSS statistical program. The results of the study showed that crowdfunding can play an important role in the process of financial inclusion, especially in the case of an enabling and safe environment. Crowdfunding can also contribute to improving MSMEs' access to finance, and crowdfunding can enhance financial inclusion by providing financial services at a lower cost and high quality. The study recommended taking advantage of Indonesia's pioneering experience in dealing with crowdfunding and taking advantage of the great potential it provides and the possibility of its application in Iraq and the enactment of the legislative, regulatory and supervisory framework that governs this new type of financing.
Thesis
المستخلص. يعدّ التمويل الجماعي وبيان دوره في تعزيز الشمول المالي للمشاريع الصغيرة والمتوسطة والمتناهية الصغر MSMES من القضايا المهمة على مستوى العالم والمنطقة العربية والعراق، كما ان الخوض فيه يعد تحديا كبيرا، كون التمويل الجماعي من الأساليب الحديثة في التمويل، فضلا عن الأهمية البالغة للشمول المالي للـ MSMES في دعم التنمية الاقتصادية والاجتماعية، لذلك هدفت الدراسة الى بيان دور التمويل الجماعي في تعزيز الشمول المالي للمشاريع الصغيرة والمتوسطة والمتناهية الصغر ((MSMEs ولتحقيق هذا الهدف انطلقت من اشكالية رئيسة تمثلت بالتساؤل الآتي: هل يستطيع التمويل الجماعي من سد فجوة التمويل التي خلقتها شروط التمويل التقليدي، وبالتالي تعزيز الشمول المالي؟ وبغية اختبار دور التمويل الجماعي في تعزيز الشمول المالي تم اختيار عينة مكونة من ست عشرة منصة تمويل جماعي من منصات التمويل الجماعي العاملة في اندونيسيا، (أربع منصات لكل شكل من أشكال التمويل الجماعي)، باستعمال اسلوب العينات القصدية، كما تم الاعتماد على المنهج التحليلي لاختبار مجموعة من المؤشرات التي تعبر عن أبعاد الشمول المالي للـ ((MSMEs المتمثلة بالوصول الى الخدمات المالية وتوافرها واستخدامها وكلفتها وجودتها. ومن ثم تحليل البيانات التي تم جمعها باستعمال التحليل الوصفي والارتباط والانحدار باستعمال البرنامج الاحصائي SPSS. ولقد أظهرت نتائج الدراسة ان التمويل الجماعي يمكن أن يلعب دورًا مهمًا في عملية الشمول المالي ولاسيما في حالة وجود بيئة مواتية وآمنة. كما يمكن أن يساهم التمويل الجماعي من تحسين وصول المشاريع الصغيرة والمتوسطة والمتناهية الصغر MSMEs إلى التمويل كما يمكن للتمويل الجماعي أن يعزز الشمول المالي عن طريق توفير خدمات مالية بكلفة أقل وجودة عالية. وأوصت الدراسة بالاستفادة من تجربة اندونيسيا الرائدة في التعامل مع التمويل الجماعي والاستفادة من الامكانيات الكبيرة التي يوفرها وامكانية تطبيقها في العراق وسن الاطار التشريعي والتنظيمي والرقابي الذي يحكم هذا النمط الجديد من التمويل.
Article
Full-text available
Donation crowdfunding is a type of crowdfunding wherein the funders donate funds in order to support a particular project through the internet (crowdfunding website/platform) acting as the medium. It is based on pure philanthropic motives with no expectations of any reward or return. In this study, we intend to explore the antecedents that drive a funder’s intention to contribute in donation crowdfunding campaigns in India by investigating the impact of identified factors on a funder’s intention to donate. For the study, a survey was conducted on funders using a 5-point Likert Scale through a structured questionnaire. The identified constructs determining the funder’s intention to donate were perceived project integrity, fundraiser’s credibility, funder’s social influence, crowdfunding readiness, funder’s self-efficacy, crowdfunding platform reputation, and funder’s empathy. The findings of the study reveal that all the identified constructs significantly affect the funder’s intention to donate in donation crowdfunding campaigns. Moreover, crowdfunding readiness partially mediates the relationship between the identified factors (except for the funder’s social influence) and intention to donate.
Article
Full-text available
This paper explores differences between equity crowdfunding and peer-to-peer (p2p) lending determinants of cross-border activity, from a user’s perspective. We use a unique database of survey respondents, registered in equity crowdfunding and p2p lending platforms across Europe. We find clear differentiations between equity crowdfunding and p2p lending. Equity crowdfunders are driven mainly by excitement while p2p lenders are driven by higher returns. As regards cross-border activity, equity crowdfunders are almost 7 times more likely to invest in foreign projects. Both equity crowdfunders and p2p lenders try to achieve diversification via cross-border activity, following however different strategies. We conclude that these differences should be taken under consideration, while implementing the pan-European regulatory framework for crowdfunding with financial returns (ECSP).
Article
Full-text available
It is not surprising that the financing of early-stage creative projects and ventures is typically geographically localized since these types of funding decisions are usually predicated on personal relationships and due diligence requiring face-to-face interactions in response to high levels of risk, uncertainty, and information asymmetry. So, to economists, the recent rise of crowdfunding—raising capital from many people through an online platform—which offers little opportunity for careful due diligence and involves not only friends and family but also many strangers from near and far, is initially startling. On the eve of launching equity-based crowdfunding, a new market for early-stage finance in the United States, we provide a preliminary exploration of its underlying economics. We highlight the extent to which economic theory, in particular transaction costs, reputation, and market design, can explain the rise of nonequity crowdfunding and offer a framework for speculating on how equity-based crowdfunding may unfold. We conclude by articulating open questions related to how crowdfunding may affect social welfare and the rate and direction of innovation.
Chapter
Full-text available
This book chapter reviews crowdinvesting, which is sometimes referred to as equity crowdfunding. It specifically aims at answering the following question: Is crowdinvesting transforming the crowd into small business angels? In order to answer this question, we review the securities regulation in different jurisdictions and compare crowdinvesting practices in these countries with angel finance. Finally, we offer insights into different avenues for future research. One pertains to the question whether crowdinvesting will complement or substitute angel finance. While this issue cannot be answered unambiguously, we expect that in many cases, crowdinvesting may become a complementary source of funding to angel finance rather than a substitute. This is because crowdinvestors fill funding gaps at the lower end of the market or may at times co-invest with professional investors. In other cases, crowdinvestors may compete with business angels for the same investments since average funding volumes can be similar.
Article
Full-text available
Crowdfunding allows founders of for-profit, artistic, and cultural ventures to fund their efforts by drawing on relatively small contributions from a relatively large number of individuals using the internet, without standard financial intermediaries. Drawing on a dataset of over 48,500 projects with combined funding over $237 M, this paper offers a description of the underlying dynamics of success and failure among crowdfunded ventures. It suggests that personal networks and underlying project quality are associated with the success of crowdfunding efforts, and that geography is related to both the type of projects proposed and successful fundraising. Finally, I find that the vast majority of founders seem to fulfill their obligations to funders, but that over 75% deliver products later than expected, with the degree of delay predicted by the level and amount of funding a project receives. These results offer insight into the emerging phenomenon of crowdfunding, and also shed light more generally on the ways that the actions of founders may affect their ability to receive entrepreneurial financing.
Article
In this paper, we show that too strong investor protection may harm small firms and entrepreneurial initiatives, which contrasts with the traditional ‘law & finance’ view that stronger investor protection is better. This situation is particularly relevant in crowdinvesting, which refers to a recent financial innovation originating on the Internet and targets small, innovative firms. In many jurisdictions, securities regulation offers exemptions to prospectus and registration requirements. We provide an into-depth discussion of recent regulatory reforms in different countries and discuss how they may impact crowdinvesting. Building on a theoretical framework, we show that optimal regulation depends on the availability of alternative early-stage financing such as venture capital and angel finance. Finally, we offer exploratory portal-level evidence from Germany on the impact of securities regulation on small business finance.
Article
We study the law production race-to-the-bottom/race-to-the-top debate in a unique context of crowdfunding in which potential agency problems are extreme. Our empirical setting is based on survey data from Canada in 2013 Q1 when equity crowdfunding was not permitted but was openly contemplated by regulators. The data show some tension towards a race to the bottom insofar as start-ups prefer fewer restrictions on their ability to crowdfund, and portals prefer fewer disclosure requirements and fewer restrictions on free trading of crowdfunded shares. However, this evidence is tempered by the fact that investors demand more disclosure, limits on amounts entrepreneurs can raise, and lower thresholds for audited financial statements, among other things. Based on the ease with which the Internet facilitates cross-jurisdictional investment, we infer from the data that investor demands will give rise to a race to the top in the crowdfunding space.
Article
Microloan markets allow individual borrowers to raise funding from multiple individual lenders. We use a unique panel data set that tracks the funding dynamics of borrower listings on Prosper.com, the largest microloan market in the United States. We find evidence of rational herding among lenders. Well-funded borrower listings tend to attract more funding after we control for unobserved listing heterogeneity and payoff externalities. Moreover, instead of passively mimicking their peers (irrational herding), lenders engage in active observational learning (rational herding); they infer the creditworthiness of borrowers by observing peer lending decisions and use publicly observable borrower characteristics to moderate their inferences. Counterintuitively, obvious defects (e.g., poor credit grades) amplify a listing's herding momentum, as lenders infer superior creditworthiness to justify the herd. Similarly, favorable borrower characteristics (e.g., friend endorsements) weaken the herding effect, as lenders attribute herding to these observable merits. Follow-up analysis shows that rational herding beats irrational herding in predicting loan performance. This paper was accepted by Pradeep Chintagunta, marketing.