Content uploaded by Pece J. Mitrevski
Author content
All content in this area was uploaded by Pece J. Mitrevski on Dec 17, 2016
Content may be subject to copyright.
REDETE – ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND ENTEREPRENEURSHIP IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES
76
MEASURING THE QUALITATIVE COMPETITIVENESS
OF THE MACEDONIAN ECONOMY
Olivera KOSTOSKA28
Pece MITREVSKI29
Marjan ANGELESKI30
Gjorgji MANCESKI31
Abstract
The empirical evidence on trade patterns clearly indicates the fact that globalization has
rapidly altered the international economic space, introducing some new forms of competiti-
veness. International marketplace has been increasingly transformed from price to one domina-
ted by non-price factors, quality in particular. Products having the price as a major determina-
nt of competitiveness have recorded a decreasing market share, which implicitly points towards
the possible loss of this kind competitive performance. Innovations and new lines to create value
might, therefore, designate higher average prices, as an indicator for a better quality, but at the
same time, they lead towards the higher productivity and trade growth. Indeed, creating
competitiveness in the targeted sectors is a serious task for national economies distinguished
mainly by their rigid production structure and limited funds. These features certainly bound the
possibilities for an economy and the supporting sectors (technological infrastructure, R&D
capacity, educational policy) to promptly adjust so as to capture the benefits of knowledge and
innovation-driven global economy. Hence, this paper, primarily, aims at estimating the qualita-
tive competitiveness of the Macedonian economy. At first, “unit value”, the signal of the Mace-
donia’s quality position, is to be calculated. This indicator may possibly be defined for exports
and imports, and it is available at all levels of disaggregation. Within the analysis made for the
Macedonian economy, we will refer to data for the total exports and imports according to 3-
digit SITC (0-9). Additionally, we develop a country specific segmentation of markets in line
with the concept of revealed price elasticity (REVELAST 1). The findings obtained suggest a
low unit value for the Macedonian exports due to the country specialization in those industries
to be found at lower levels of “quality ladder”. The analysis made for the product groups subdi-
vided into different segments indicates certain deterioration in the competitiveness of the Mace-
donian economy, i.e. there is an inadequate position either in levels or the type of competitive
performance. Finally, the estimates about the changes of product groups’ number according to
SITC sectors point to rather divergent results. It is of particular importance the growth of pro-
duct groups’ number in the segment with structural problems, especially in those sectors as
considered the most important for achieving a competitive performance with dynamic poten-
tials.
Keywords: qualitative competitiveness, Macedonian economy, unit value, revealed price ela-
sticity, Standard International Trade Classification
28 Faculty of Economics-Prilep, Republic of Macedonia, okostoska@t-home.mk
29 Faculty of Technical Sciences-Bitola, Republic of Macedonia, pece.mitrevski@uklo.edu.mk
30 Faculty of Economics-Prilep, Republic of Macedonia, angeleskimarjan@gmail.com
31 Faculty of Economics-Prilep, Republic of Macedonia, gmanceski@t-home.mk
REDETE – ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND ENTEREPRENEURSHIP IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES
77
Introduction – the Importance of Quality
The quality is considered a relatively intricate concept with no generally accepted definition. In
a certain context, the high quality product could possibly be regarded like a “good which
possesses one or more additional characteristics, which are valued by buyers” (Aiginger, 2000,
p.4). These features, usually reflected in higher prices, might be physically measurable (size,
speed, etc.) or intangible (reliability, goodwill, etc.). Yet, despite the possible movements of
prices up, note that higher quality permits the one not to lose the markets. The possibility to
improve the quality depends upon the components such as: the noble materials, skilled labor,
R&D etc.
The differentiation of goods in terms of crucial elements or minimal details is to be an impor-
tant strategy for businesses to defend their own prices. At the market level, differentiation
associates with the possibility to improve the quality of products owing to innovations. The
radical shifts which refer to new products with completely new performance make for the changes
in the market share and industry structure. The possibility to arrange the products from the highest
to the lowest level in line with their quality is commonly referred to as “vertical product differ-
rentiation”. It may perhaps be obtained: “along one decisive feature; along a few features, each of
which has a wide possible range of (continuous or discrete) values; across a large number of
features, each of which has only a presence/absence “flag” (Piana, 2003). In the last two scenarios
a certain product may perhaps be better in line with one parameter, but not as good as the other
according to another criterion. This imposes strains and trade-offs, with competing firms making
efforts to accentuate the relevance of the feature their products are better off. The vertical
differentiation is a kind of freehold of the goods offered, yet the observed difference in quality by
the customers will have a major influence in decisions they make to buy a certain product. Gene-
rally, there is an upward-slopping relationship between the price and quality owing to higher cost
of production, as well as benefits the customers expect to obtain. That is to say, consumers having
no personal opinion or ability to directly asses the quality may perhaps make an appropriate
decision by the price of a product.32 Note that quality is at variance with productivity, since the
second is commonly expressed in quantitative terms. The quality refers typically to heterogeneity
of outputs concerning the heterogeneous inputs, while productivity relates to the quantity of
output with regard to the quantity of inputs for indicators to be as much as homogenous in nature.
“If, however, value added is used as a numerator, then the prices and quality of output are taken
into account. And if we distinguish between several qualifications for labour, the quality of inputs
can be incorporated into the denominator of productivity” (Aiginger, 2000, p.5). Higher quality is,
by and large, considered a prerequisite to maintain the competitiveness of producers making
higher costs in the production process, since the supply of product with the same quality and
higher prices is not to be sustainable in long term. Despite the fact that higher productivity may
countervail the higher wages in certain countries nevertheless, such a strategy is not always likely
to succeed due to technology and managerial skills diffusion. Hence, the higher quality is
considered as an alternative, but also a supplement to higher productivity. Yet, such approach is
mostly acceptable in quality-sensitive industries in which certain quality improvements, instead of
low prices, define the competitive advantage. Hence, the “quality competition” may be described
as “a competitive environment, in which upgrading quality, and increasing the willingness to pay
is important relative to competing at low prices” (Aiginger, 2000, p.6).
Considering the aforementioned, this paper is to assess the quality position of the Macedonian
economy. At first, we will highlight the concept of quality as regards the theoretical models. The
32 In contrast, horizontal differentiation occurs when products differ along with features that may not be sort through an
objective way. It is related to variations in tastes, colors, etc. Note that difference can be made to elements of the supply
structure and those appertain to consumers’ bias. This contributes certain consumers to have a steady preference for one or
another kind. If they are not likely to have a steady preference, the consumers behave in a way to often change the
selected product, loving variety as such.
REDETE – ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND ENTEREPRENEURSHIP IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES
78
next section defines the methodology implemented to estimate the qualitative competitiveness.
Finally, we exhibit the empirical results and the foremost conclusions we obtained thereafter.
The concept of quality in theoretical models
The literature on trade theory is being extremely affluent and diversified, primarily due to freq-
uent changes and improvements set off by the necessity to study and adequately explain the socio-
economic reality. Its reflection has been expressed in classical authors and several neo-classical
variants, for certain evolution to be experienced in the mid-20 century owing to changes in
technological development.
The mainstream trade theories are generally founded on the principle of comparative advan-
tage. In other words, international trade in goods owns to differences among countries in relative
or comparative costs, and, hence, in relative prices. Each country is to export the product in which
it has a comparative advantage and import the one with comparative disadvantage.
The principle of comparative advantage stems from the Ricardian model of international trade
based on the classical labor theory of value. Under this model, comparative costs are determined
by the relative productivity of labor. In his model, Ricardo presumes different production
functions with constant returns to scale (Ricardo, 1817). Almost a century after Ricardo had set up
the principle of comparative advantage, Eli Heckscher blends international trade with the prices of
agents of production, pursuing the tradition of neo-classical school (Heckscher, 1919). Heckscher
has actually broadened the Ricardian model including other factors of production into his analysis.
Thereat, the assumption of identical technologies across the countries is to be of particular impor-
tance for the main propositions of the neoclassical model of international trade (Heckscher-
Ohlin model). Principally, Heckscher was mostly interested in the relation between internatio-
nal trade and income distribution. He has thereof argued the hypothesis of equalizing the
relative prices of the production factors (Heckscher, 1919), which was further elaborated by
Samuelson (Samuelson, 1948). Additionally, the Heckscher's model was restructured by
Ohlin (Ohlin, 1933), which therefore the neo-classical analysis of international trade became
known as Heckscher-Ohlin or Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson (H-O-S) theory. The neo-classical
model argues that comparative advantage rises out of differences among countries in factor
endowments. That is to say, differences in relative scarcity of production factors have an effect on
the relative costs, and hence the trade flows. Consequently, the neo-classical trade theory predicts
that country will export the products that make relatively intensive use of the most abundant
production factors.
During the sixties, the theorists were particularly focused on examining the importance of
specific variables, such as technology. In this context, the model on “technology gap” has expli-
citly proved the changes set off by the technological developments and their influence on patterns
of international trade. The model suggests that process of technological innovations creates com-
parative advantage and significantly contributes to international trade. On the other hand, it
stimulates the foreign producers (potential competitors) to respond all through the imitation of the
country's innovations. The idea that comparative advantage may alter over time was further
elaborated in the “product life cycle” model (Goncavles, 1996). At the origins of this theory were
the articles of Raymond Vernon, Seev Hirsch and Harry Johnson, while significant contribution to
its development was given by the research of Simon Kuznets, with the final elaboration and
formalization made by Krugman. The product life cycle theory has played a significant role in
further development of international trade doctrine, especially after the replacement of H-O-S
theorem achievements, when a new generation of trade models, drawing heavily on the insights of
the New Endogenous Growth Theory, comes to develop. Grossman and Helpman developed a
model of the product cycle with endogenous innovation and endogenous technology transfer and
quality competition (Grossman, Helpman, 1991a, 1991b, 1991c). The theoretical approach is
founded on models of endogenous technical change formulated by Romer (1990) and Aghion-
REDETE – ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND ENTEREPRENEURSHIP IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES
79
Howitt (1990) and takes product and process innovation owing to R&D by firms. Furthermore,
Grossman and Helpman decide between horizontal and vertical product innovation. The authors
set up the concept of “quality ladder” by identifying innovations with the new products having a
higher quality as compared to the similar ones. Each product is considered to occupy a certain
position on the “quality ladder”. The model defines two countries (“North” and the “South”).
The position of North, as innovative country, is jeopardized by the imitations of low cost
South. Innovation is the only way for the North to recover its advantage (Wolfmayr-Schnitzer,
1998). “In this process of ongoing product upgrading and imitation the North and South are
consecutively climbing up the quality ladder. Or in the words of Krugman (1995, p. 353): “In a
North-South set-up, the quality ladder would actually predict a product seesaw rather than a one-
way product cycle. When an improved variant is introduced, it would first be exported by high-
wage North; when the technology diffuses, the industry would move south; but North would
reclaim the industry when a still better variant was introduced" (Wolfmayr-Schnitzer, 1998).
Data and Methodology
One of the indicators we implement to assess the qualitative competitiveness of the Mace-
donian economy is the unit value (UV). Additionally, we make use of the revealed price elasticity
(REVELAST 1) concept for a country specific segmentation of markets (Aiginger, 1998). The
unit value is expressed as ratio of nominal value and some measure of physical volume. For the
data applied in this paper it is the value of exports and imports in USD divided by kilogram. The
unit value may indicate the qualitative features of competitiveness, i.e. moving toward the
dimensions that increase the value (e.g. advertising, service components, etc.). It is available at
almost any level of disaggregation and for a huge number of countries. The analysis we make for
the Republic of Macedonia is based upon data for the total exports and imports of the three-digit
Standard International Trade Classification (SITC 0-9) provided by UN Comtrade database.
Generally, the countries with high shares in industries mostly using the physical capital reveal the
lower unit values despite those specializing in technology-driven and skill-intensive industries.
Yet, reprocessing may cause a problem. Namely, “goods are shipped into low wage countries and
return at a somewhat higher unit value, indicating that the high wage country exports the lower
quality product (as compared to the re-imported good)” (Aiginger, 2000, p.13). Likewise, there
are some restraints about the application of unit values as to the precious metals due to the limited
supply in respect to demand. Nevertheless, the high-skill and high-tech industries are generally
among those having the highest export unit values (Aiginger, 2000). Hence, a positive correlation
may perhaps be expected between GNP per capita and export unit values if those reflect quality in
particular and countries constantly improve their production from low to high quality products.
Yet, if there is an export driven growth and exports rise due to the lower costs than the quality-
growth relationship may possibly fail. On the contrary, if exports are dependent upon the higher
quality, the relationship is expected to be stronger. Finally, there is not so straightforward linkage
between import unit values and GNP per capita (Aiginger, 1998).
The main problem to use the unit value is that it either be considered a cost indicator (e.g.
small unit value reflects low costs) or it may signal the quality and product differentiation (e.g.
high unit value as an indicator of greater performance). In order to make a difference between the
markets where unit value reflects the quality and those with the costs being notified, we apply the
following notion: “If unit values reflect costs and the product is homogenous, than countries with
lower costs should be net exporters in quantities and countries with higher costs should be net
import countries. If a country is net exporter in quantities despite the fact that is has higher unit
values, then this must be due to quality differences. This assertion makes use of the fact that
economic theory tells us that under quite broad circumstances demand is price elastic” (Aiginger,
1998, p.98).
REDETE – ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND ENTEREPRENEURSHIP IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES
80
The price elasticity may perhaps be a good sign for the market structure, i.e. it can certainly
indicate the predominance of price or non-price factors. The price competition prevails if higher
prices impose exports of smaller quantities and vice versa. If however the opposite is true, then
the quality competition is said to dominate. Hence, one may split the markets for a certain country
along with the prevalence of price or quality competition in accordance with the following criteria
(Aiginger, 1998):
- The first segment comprises those industries where export quantities outstrip the imports
even with the higher unit values (Qexp>Qimp, UVexp>UVimp). This situation is essentially the
result of better quality or it is about the effective specialization in the market segment as
considered the most sophisticated one. This is to be a segment one should focus on
(successful quality competition);
- The second segment covers the price elastic goods distinguished by the low unit values in
the home country. There is a trade surplus attained hereby with the relatively lower unit
value (Qexp>Qimp, UVexp<UVimp). It is therefore denoted a segment of successful price
competition;
- The third segment includes those products having the high unit values in the home country
and therefore they incite a trade deficit. The particular industries have actually lost the
price competitiveness in those markets where the prices are of the great importance
(Qexp<Qimp, UVexp>UVimp). The vast production costs are considered those causing this part
of the deficit, i.e. the segment is designated as deficit in price competitiveness;
- The fourth segment is the one where a trade deficit is being obtained even though the
prices are low (Qexp<Qimp, UVexp<UVimp). There are must be some structural problems
hereby.
Empirical results
The evidence suggests that unit value of the Macedonian exports has increased from 0.78
USD/kg in 2006 to 1.02 USD/kg in 2010 (Figure 1). Generally, the transitions and less developed
countries feature a low unit value of exports, unlike the developed ones where it reaches up to 7.5
USD/kg (Jefferson Institute, 2003). The reasons behind follow on specialization of the
Macedonian exports in those groups of manufactures to be found on lower levels of “quality
ladder”. Namely, labor- and resource intensive product groups prevail with the structure of the
Macedonian exports. The slight increasing tendency in the share of medium-technology exports is
not to reflect significantly the technological modernization of the Macedonian manufacturing
exports. This is primarily the result of the slow progress in structural reforms during the second
half of the nineties.
At the same time, low figures have been also recorded for the Macedonian imports (Figure 1).
Generally, the Macedonian imports feature a relatively higher share of human capital intensive
industries. Yet, an in depth analysis of this category indicates that the Macedonian economy,
throughout imports, incorporates the modern technological content mostly in the segment of
medium technology, primarily in the sphere of private consumption. In other words, it is not only
that the Macedonian economy cannot produce technology intensive products, but the country is
not able to adequately absorb these components. The benefits of modern technologies intended for
investment of the businesses are not embedded within the Macedonian imports.
REDETE – ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND ENTEREPRENEURSHIP IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES
81
Figure 1 Unit value of exports and imports
Source: Republic of Macedonia, State Statistical Office and own estimates
The comparative analysis for the product groups subdivided into corresponding segments
points to certain deterioration of the Macedonian competitiveness (Table 1).
The number of competitive groups from the first and second sector is much lower than that of
non-competitive segments (Figure 2). It is of particular concern hereby the decreasing number of
the product groups from the first segment indicating the successful qualitative competitiveness,
i.e. it has been halved in 2011 compared to 1998 along with the declining share of these groups in
total exports (45.13% and 58.75%, respectively). The second segment, that where the Macedonian
products are relatively cheap and the market is price elastic, has a positive contribution in the
trade balance. Note the increasing number of product groups in this segment. There is a certain
decline in 2007 compared to 2005 mostly coming from the increased costs of production (e.g. the
growth in the import price of electricity) (National Bank of the Republic of Macedonia, 2008).
Yet, the number of product groups in this segment is still higher in 2007 than that in 1998 and
2002, followed by the higher percentage share in total exports. Hence, the trade surplus obtained
in this segment is moving up, except for the unexpected situation in 2002 and 2011 when the trade
surplus decrease despite the higher number of groups in 2002 with respect to 1998 (31 and 25,
respectively) and 2011 compared to 2007 (37 and 36, respectively).
REDETE – ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND ENTEREPRENEURSHIP IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES
82
Table 1 Segmentation of the product groups*
Year Segment
Number of
3-digit SITC
groups
Share in
exports (%)
Trade balance
(million USD)
1998 First segment UVexp>UVimp, Qexp>Qimp 33 58.75 676.29
Second segment UVexp<UVimp, Qexp>Qimp 25 23.82 251.58
Third segment UVexp>UVimp, Qexp<Qimp 98 10.65 -555.16
Fourth segment UVexp<UVimp, Qexp<Qimp 92 5.91 -551.38
2002 First segment UVexp>UVimp, Qexp>Qimp 25 49.78 492.03
Second segment UVexp<UVimp, Qexp>Qimp 31 26.31 195.39
Third segment UVexp>UVimp, Qexp<Qimp 89 16.49 -547.99
Fourth segment UVexp<UVimp, Qexp<Qimp 109 7.06 -622.93
2005 First segment UVexp>UVimp, Qexp>Qimp 20 42.31 758.08
Second segment UVexp<UVimp, Qexp>Qimp 39 38.29 392.40
Third segment UVexp>UVimp, Qexp<Qimp 81 11.68 -657.78
Fourth segment UVexp<UVimp, Qexp<Qimp 114 7.50 -1680.71
2007 First segment UVexp>UVimp, Qexp>Qimp 19 43.85 1360.22
Second segment UVexp<UVimp, Qexp>Qimp 36 36.19 666.30
Third segment UVexp>UVimp, Qexp<Qimp 83 13.04 -1191.44
Fourth segment UVexp<UVimp, Qexp<Qimp 117 6.87 -2699.56
2011 First segment UVexp>UVimp, Qexp>Qimp 16 45.13 1824.16
Second segment UVexp<UVimp, Qexp>Qimp 37 24.48 325.99
Third segment UVexp>UVimp, Qexp<Qimp 87 17.25 -1243.53
Fourth segment UVexp<UVimp, Qexp<Qimp 112 13.14 -3177.70
*according to three-digit SITC
Source: UN Comtrade and own estimates
After the decreasing tendency in the number of product groups, a certain growth has been
recorded in 2007 and 2011 within the segment where the Macedonian exports are relatively
expensive and therefore impose a trade deficit. Generally, the number of product groups increases
in the fourth segment, followed by the growing trade deficit that amounts to 3.18 billion USD in
2011 (Figure 3). Taking the non-competitive position of the Macedonian exports in this segment
despite the low export prices, one may note that the quality of products is the main reason for the
negative results obtained.
REDETE – ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND ENTEREPRENEURSHIP IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES
83
Figure 2 Number of product groups according to different segments*
*according to three-digit SITC
Source: UN Comtrade and own estimates
Figure 3 Trade balance of product groups according to different segments*
*according to three-digit SITC
Source: UN Comtrade and own estimates
The analysis about the changes of product groups’ number according to SITC sectors in
different segments points to somewhat divergent results (Table 2). Generally, the number of
product groups in the segment of successful qualitative competitiveness has recorded either a
decreasing or equal movement in 2011 with regard to other periods taken into analysis. It is of
particular concern hereby the decline of the product groups’ number within the seventh and eighth
SITC sector (2011 compared to 1998), since it implies a loss in the qualitative competitiveness of
products with higher processing levels. There is either increasing or equal movements of the
product groups’ number in the second segment (2011 compared to 1998). The particular change
has been noticed within the “Food and live animals” SITC sector for even the six product groups.
In other words, there is a general tendency of growth for the product groups’ number achieving a
successful export at low unit value. The number of product groups that lost the competitiveness in
markets where the prices prevail has been reduced within the 0 SITC sector (2011 compared to all
other periods). By contrast, there is an increasing tendency in the number of product groups in
REDETE – ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND ENTEREPRENEURSHIP IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES
84
sectors with higher processing levels (seventh sector in 2011 with regard to 2007; sixth sector in
2007 compared to 2005). Noteworthy is the growth of the product groups’ number in the segment
with structural problems, particularly in the fifth sector (3 product groups), the sixth sector (12
product groups) and the eighth sector (7 product groups) in 2011 compared to 1998. That is to
say, there is a huge loss of competitiveness, especially in manufacturing as considered the most
important in achieving the competitive performance with dynamic potentials, predominantly
followed by the impact of non-price factors.
According to variable structure of the product groups at different sectors, one may note that
product groups within the first segment exhibit a kind of “fictional” qualitative competitiveness.
Namely, those are the products that are exported, but more difficult to sell in domestic market owing
to low purchasing power of domestic demand which is mainly satisfied by lower quality imports (e.g.
textile). Furthermore, export of clothing and textile has been largely dependent upon the imports of
products for further processing (National Bank of the Republic of Macedonia, 2004) and it still
dominates the Macedonian textile industry (University American College, 2011). This segment also
comprises several product groups with smaller imports, as well as those in which the qualitative lead
of exports is mostly due to natural advantages (e.g. ores and tobacco). Moreover, some of the product
groups revealing the price competitiveness are those predominantly sold on the markets of
neighboring countries. They may possibly be sold as cheaper products in near locations owing to the
high unit costs of transport (e.g. fruit, vegetable, cement, etc.).
The segment with deficit in price competitiveness contains several product groups with poten-
tials to improve their performance. In other words, some of them can reach certain levels of price
competitiveness and possibly shift to other segment by succeeding to complete a more efficient
production and optimize the transportation costs. As mentioned above, the number of product
groups within the extremely uncompetitive segment increases along with the growth of trade
deficit. Yet, the structure of fourth segment exhibits large variations. That is to say, there are pro-
duct groups not to be found in the Macedonian exports, but also those which might have a great
importance in exports (e.g. heating and cooling equipment, mechanical handling equipment and
telecommunications equipment). Hence, despite these product groups being uncompetitive and
generate the highest percentage of trade deficit, the larger inflows of foreign direct investment
(FDI) in this segment are supposed to create conditions for restructuring and changing the nature
of competitiveness.
Table 2 Number of product groups at different segments according to SITC sectors
1998 2002 2005 2007 2011
Sector I II III IV I II III IV I II III IV I II III IV I II III IV
Food and live animals 2 6 18 10 3 4 14 15 3 8 16 9 3 5 14 14 1 12 12 11
Beverages and tobacco 3 1 0 0 3 1 0 0 3 1 0 1 3 3 0 0 1 2 1 0
Crude materials, inedible, except fuels 8 3 9 14 5 4 8 16 5 8 6 11 4 6 10 12 5 5 8 13
Mineral fuels, lubricants and related materials 0 0 2 7 0 0 5 5 0 2 2 6 0 1 4 5 0 0 4 6
Animal and vegetable oils and fats 0 0 3 1 0 0 1 3 0 0 3 1 0 0 3 1 0 0 3 1
Chemicals 1 1 17 13 1 6 12 14 0 3 13 17 1 3 12 17 1 3 13 16
Manufactured goods classified chiefly by material 10 9 17 14 6 11 18 17 2 12 14 24 2 11 17 22 2 9 15 26
Machinery and transport equipment 2 4 18 26 1 3 20 26 1 3 15 31 1 3 13 33 0 4 20 26
Miscellaneous manufactured articles 7 1 14 6 6 2 11 12 5 2 10 14 5 3 10 13 5 2 10 13
Commodities and transactions not classified in SITC 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 1 0 1 0
Source: UN Comtrade and own estimates
The above analysis points toward a number of disadvantages which negatively affect the
Macedonian exports, such as: the high level of rivalry in international markets mostly by the less
developed countries; the inferior negotiating position either with suppliers or the buyers; the
substitutes continually created by the new technology, etc. Hence, the only way to achieve a better
REDETE – ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND ENTEREPRENEURSHIP IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES
85
structure of the Macedonian foreign trade and higher levels of competitiveness is the possibility to
create an adequate environment so as to shift a part of product groups from the fourth segment
(especially those generating higher value added) into the first and second segment for them to
significantly contribute to dynamics of total exports.
Conclusions
The empirical research indicates that the Macedonian economy features low export unit values
owing to the country specialization in those industries to be found at lower levels of “quality
ladder”. The imports have also recorded relatively low unit values, which specify the inability of
the Macedonian economy to effectively absorb the technology intensive products.
The analysis made for the product groups subdivided into different segments point towards the
poor competitive performance. Namely, the number of product groups from the first and second
segment is much lower than that of the non-competitive segments. It of particular concern hereby
that the number of product groups indicating successful qualitative competitiveness has been
halved in 2011 with regard to 1998 together with the decreasing share in total exports. The rising
trade deficit along with the general increase in the number of product groups in the segment where
the Macedonian exports are not competitive, despite the low export prices, point towards the
quality of products as the main reason for the negative results obtained.
The estimates about the changes of the product groups’ number according to SITC sectors in
different segments points toward somewhat divergent results. Particularly disturbing is the rise of
product groups’ number within the segment with structural problems, especially in the fifth, sixth
and the eighth sector in 2011 compared to 1998. In other words, a huge loss in competitiveness
has been noted in sectors which are the most important in achieving the competitive performance
with dynamic potentials, mostly followed by the impact of non-price factors.
According to variable structure of the product groups at different sectors, one may note that
product groups within the first segment exhibit a kind of “fictional” qualitative competitiveness.
Those are the products difficult to sell in domestic market owing to low purchasing power of
domestic demand or largely dependent upon the imports of products for further processing. Some
of the product groups revealing the price competitiveness may possibly be sold as cheaper
products in locations nearby owing to the high unit costs of transport. The segment with deficit in
price competitiveness contains several product groups with potentials to improve their
performance and possibly shift to other segment. Finally, the fourth segment exhibits large
variations. There are product groups either not to be found in the Macedonian exports or those
should have greater importance in exports. Despite these product groups being uncompetitive and
generate the highest percentage of trade deficit, the larger FDI inflows are supposed to create
good conditions for restructuring and changing the nature of competitiveness.
REDETE – ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND ENTEREPRENEURSHIP IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES
86
Reference list
1. Aiginger, K. (2000). Europe’s position in quality competition: Background Report for The
European Competitiveness Report 2000. DG Enterprise, Commissioned by DG Enterprise,
Brussels
2. Aiginger, K. (1998). Unit values to signal the quality position of CEES. The Competitiveness
of transition economies. OECD Proceedings
3. Goncalves, R. (1996). The theory of international trade: back to basics. Encontro Nacional de
Economica Classica e Politica, 5, pp. 31-37
4. Grossman, G. M., Helpman, E. (1991a). Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. MIT
Press, Cambridge, Mass
5. Grossman, G. M., Helpman, E. (1991b). Endogenous Product Cycles. The Economic Journal.
101 (408), pp. 1214-1229
6. Grossman, G. M., Helpman, E. (1991c). Quality Ladders and Product Cycles. Quarterly
Journal of Economics. 106 (2), pp. 557-586
7. Heckscher, E. (1919). The Effect of Foreign Trade on the Distribution of Income. Ekonomisk
Tidskrift. 21, pp. 497-512. An bbreviated English translation by Svend and Nita Laursen in
available in Howard S. Ellis and Lloyd A. Metzler, eds., Readings in the Theory of Interna-
tional Trade, Philadelphia: The Blakiston Co., 1949, pp. 272-300. A complete translation is
available in Harry Flam and M. June Flanders, eds., Heckscher-Ohlin Trade Theory, Cambri-
dge, MA: MIT Press, 1991, pp. 39-69
8. Jefferson Institute. (2003). Konkurentnost privrede Srbije [Competitiveness of the Serbian
Economy]. Belgrade. Serbia
9. Krugman, P. R. (1995). Technological Change in International Trade. in Stoneman, P. (ed.),
Handbook of the Economics of Innovation and Technological Change. Blackwell, Oxford,
pp. 342-365
10. National Bank of the Republic of Macedonia. (2008). Annual Report 2007. Skopje.
http://www.nbrm.mk/WBStorage/Files/web_ANNUAL_REPORT_2007.pdf (accessed
25.08.2012.)
11. National Bank of the Republic of Macedonia. (2004). Annual Report 2003. Skopje.
http://www.nbrm.mk/WBStorage/Files/AI_Annual_Report_200 3_ang.pdf (accessed
30.08.2012.)
12. Ohlin, B. (1933). Interregional and International Trade. Cambridge: Harvard University
Press
13. Piana, V. (2003). Product differentiation. Economics Web Institute.
http://www.economicswebinstitute.org/glossary/product.htm (accessed 01.08.2012.)
14. Ricardo, D. (1817). On the principles of political economy and taxation. London: John Murray
15. Samuelson, A. P. (1948). International trade and Equalization of Factor Prices. Economic
Journal. 58(230), pp. 163-184
16. University American College. (2011). Преглед на надворешната трговија на
Македонија [Review of the Foreign Trade of Macedonia]. Skopje. Macedonia
17. Wolfmayr-Schnitzer, Y. (1998). Trade performance of CEECs according to technology
classes. In The Competitiveness of Ttransition economies. OECD proceedings