ArticlePDF Available

Abstract

This article discusses recent empirical and theoretical research on the electoral rule, which is one feature of modern democracies. It determines that the electoral rule systematically shapes economic policy. An outline of some key objectives of electoral rules is presented in the first section; it further notes the stability and systematic selection that characterize real-world constitutions. It then introduces the main concepts that categorize different electoral rules, and explains how these elements help shape the accountability of government and the size of political rents and corruption. Finally, the article deals with representation in government and a variety of fiscal policy choices.
1
Electoral systems and economic policy
Torsten Persson and Guido Tabellini
Torsten Persson is Professor of Economics and Director of the Institute for International Economic
Studies, Stockholm University, Stockholm, Sweden, and Centennial Professor at the London School
of Economics, London, U.K. Guido Tabellini is Professor of Economics and President of the
Innocenzo Gasparini Institute for Economic Research, Bocconi University, Milan, Italy.
We are grateful to the editors of this Handbook, Barry Weingast and Don Wittman, for helpful
comments and to the Canadian Institute of Advanced Research for financial support.
2
What is the effect of the constitution on economic policy choices? This issue is often at the
heart of debates on constitutional reform. Recently, Italy replaced its system of
proportional representation, where legislators were elected according to the proportions of
the popular national vote received by their parties, with one that includes ingredients of
plurality rule, where legislators are elected in each district according to who receives the
highest number of votes. Italian political leaders are now considering proposals to replace
the current parliamentary regime with elements of presidentialism, where the head of
government is elected by direct popular vote. An important motivation for these reforms
was the idea that they would reduce political corruption and the propensity of Italian
governments to run budget deficits.
In recent years, a number of other countries have implemented related reforms.
For instance, New Zealand altered its system of plurality rule in single-member districts to
a system mixing elements of proportional representation. Japan moved to a system that
mixes elements of proportional and plurality representation from its special form of plurality
rule (the so-called single non-transferable vote. The UK has debated similar proposals.
What are the effects of these reforms on economic policy outcomes and economic
performance?
It is only recently that this question has been addressed by social scientists.
Political scientists specializing in comparative politics have described the fundamental
features of constitutions and their political effects. Yet they have mainly focused on
political phenomena, failing to study how constitutional rules shape economic policies.
Although economists in the field of political economics have studied the determinants of
policy choices, they rarely study constitutional details and their implications for policy
choice and economic performance.
This chapter discusses recent theoretical and empirical research on one feature of
modern democracies: the electoral rule. Our central conclusion is that the electoral rule
systematically shapes economic policy. We show that to understand the extent of political
corruption, the devil is in the details of electoral systems, such as the ballot structure or
district magnitude. In the case of the size of government and fiscal policy outcomes, the
effects are associated with the broad distinction between proportional vs majoritarian
systems. The effects are often large enough to be of genuine economic interest.
A closely related question concerns the effects on economic policy of the
constitutional rules that define the form of government, especially the crucial distinction
3
between parliamentary and presidential systems. We do not address this topic here and
refer the interested reader to Persson and Tabellini (2003, 2004a).
We develop our arguments as follows. Section 1 outlines some key objectives of
electoral rules and notes the stability and systematic selection that characterize real world
constitutions. Section 2 introduces the main concepts that categorize different electoral
rules. Section 3 explains how these elements shape the accountability of government and
the size of political rents and corruption. Section 4 deals with representation in
government and a variety of fiscal policy choices. Section 5 offers our conclusions and
brief comments on emerging research.
1. Electoral systems: Motives, stability and selection
In a representative democracy, elected officials determine policy. Electoral systems
decide how well voters can hold politicians accountable and which groups in society are
more likely to see their interests represented.
Economists in the field of corporate finance show that alternative rules of corporate
governance entail a trade off between agency problems and representation of minority
interests. Rules that concentrate powers in the hands of a dominant shareholder reduce
managerial discretion and limit the scope of the agency problem, but this control is likely to
come at the expense of minority shareholders (cf. for instance Becht, Bolton, and Röell,
2003).
A similar tradeoff between accountability and representation arises in the design of
electoral rules. Indeed, this idea is familiar to political scientists in the field of comparative
politics (see e.g., Bingham Powell; 2000, Prezworski et al., 1999). Compared to
proportional representation, plurality rule in single member districts translates swings in
voter sentiment into larger changes in legislative majorities. This leverage effect of plurality
rule strengthens the incentives of politicians to please the voters, leading to smaller
political rents and less corruption. But since it makes political candidates more responsive
to the wishes of pivotal groups of voters, stronger accountability also raises the propensity
to target benefits to narrow constituencies. This targeting comes at the expense of broad
spending programs that benefit many citizens. Hence the design of electoral rules entails a
tradeoff between accountability and representation.
Overall features of electoral systems change very seldom. In the sample of 60
democracies studied by Persson and Tabellini (2003), only two enacted important reforms
of the electoral system between 1960 and 1990 (Cyprus and France) – though more
4
reforms are observed if one considers marginal changes and transitions from autocracy to
democracy. At the same time, the electoral system is strongly correlated with stable
country characteristics: former British colonies tend to have U.K.-style plurality rule in
single-member districts, while continental Europe predominantly has proportional
representation.
These patterns make it difficult to draw causal inferences from the data. Electoral
stability means that reforms are very seldom observed; but cross-country comparisons risk
confounding the effects of the constitution with other country characteristics, since the
electoral rule itself could be selected on the basis of unobserved variables that also
influence policy outcomes.
In our own work, we have exploited econometric techniques developed by labor
economists to estimate the causal effects of non-random treatments from cross-sectional
comparisons. For us, treatment is the electoral reform. We have relied on three estimation
methods. First, we isolate exogenous variation in electoral rules through instrumental
variables. If change is very rare, it may be largely determined by historical circumstances
(whatever was “fashionable” at the time). The broad period in which the current
constitution was adopted can thus be used as an instrument for the electoral system. The
identifying assumption is that, controlling for other determinants of policy (including the age
of democracy), the birth period of the constitution is not directly related to current policy
outcomes. Second, we adjust the estimates for possible correlation between the random
components of policy outcomes and the selection of electoral systems, as suggested by
Heckman and others. Third, we exploit so-called “matching methods” where countries are
ranked by the probability of adopting a specific electoral system, called a propensity score.
Comparisons of countries with similar propensity scores, but with different actual systems,
receive more weight. This third method avoids biased estimates due to heterogeneous
treatment effects. Persson and Tabellini (2003) discuss these three estimation methods in
context, while Acemoglu (2005) provides a critical review.
2. Categorizing electoral systems
Political scientists commonly emphasize three aspects of electoral rules for legislatures.
Electoral formulas translate votes into seats. Under plurality rule, only the winner(s)
of the highest vote share(s) are elected in a given district. In contrast, proportional
representation awards legislative seats in proportion to votes in each district. To ensure
5
closeness between overall vote shares and seat shares, a district system of plurality rule is
often amended by a system of “adjustment seats” at the national level.
District magnitudes reflect the number of legislators (given the size of the
legislature) acquiring a seat in a typical voting district. One polar case is where all districts
have a single seat, as in the U.S. House of Representatives; the other polar case is where
all legislators are all elected in a single, all-encompassing district, such as the Israeli
Knesset. See Grofman (this volume) for a more extended discussion.
Ballot structures determine how citizens cast their ballot. One possibility is that they
choose among individual candidates. Another common possibility is that each voter
chooses from a set of closed lists of candidates drawn up by the parties participating in the
election. In the latter, if an electoral district has ten seats and Party A wins, say, four of
these seats, the first four candidates on the list of Party A get elected.
1
Although these three aspects are theoretically distinct, their use is correlated across
countries. Anglo-Saxon countries often implement plurality rule with voting for individual
candidates in single-member districts. Others implement proportional representation
though a system of closed party lists in large districts, sometimes a single national district.
In the wake of this pattern, many observers have classified countries into two archetypical
electoral systems, labelled “majoritarian” and “proportional” (or “consensual”). These
correlations are nonetheless not perfect, and several countries employ “mixed” electoral
system. German voters, e.g., cast two ballots, electing half the Bundestag by plurality in
single-member districts, and the other half by proportional representation at a national
level, to achieve proportionality between national vote and seat shares. Furthermore,
some proportional representation systems, such as the Irish, do not rely on party lists.
2
Blais and Massicotte (1996) and Cox (1997) present overviews of world electoral systems.
3. Accountability
How do electoral rules affect accountability? In this section, we consider only policies
evaluated in roughly the same way by all voters (so-called valence issues), leaving the
problem of how elected officials react to disagreement among voters for the next section
that focuses on representation. Accountability in this context refers to two things. It gives
1
The distinction between open and closed party lists is discussed further below.
2
To achieve proportionality, the Irish “single transferable vote” system (also used in Malta) relies on votes over
individuals in multi-member districts where each voter can only vote for a single candidate, and a complicated
procedure where seats are awarded sequentially and votes for losing candidates are transferred from one seat to the next.
6
voters some control over politicians who abuse their power: voters can punish or reward
politicians through re-election or other career concerns, and this creates incentives for
good behavior. Accountability also refers to the ability of voters to select the most “able”
candidate, where ability can be interpreted as integrity, technical expertise, or other
intrinsic features valued by voters at large. As the emphasis of this chapter is on
economic policymaking, we focus on how the electoral rule affects corruption, rent
seeking, and electoral budget cycles.
The details of electoral rules have direct effects on the incentives of politicians.
They also have indirect effects through party structure and, more generally, who holds
office. We consider the direct and indirect effects of the three aspects of electoral rules
mentioned above: ballot structure, district magnitude and the electoral formula.
3.1 Direct effects
Politicians have stronger direct incentives to please the voters if they are held accountable
individually, rather than collectively. Because they disconnect individual efforts and re-
election prospects, party lists discourage effort by office-holders. Persson and Tabellini
(2000) formalize this idea and predict that political rents will be higher under electoral
systems that rely on list voting, than in systems where voters directly select individual
candidates. The same argument also implies that open lists (voters can modify the order
of candidates) should be more conducive to good behavior than closed lists (non-
amendable by voters), as should preferential voting (voters are asked to rank candidates
of the same party).
What does the evidence say? If higher political rents are associated with illegal
benefits, then we can study whether corruption by public officials in different countries is
systematically correlated to the electoral rule. Of course, corruption is only an imperfect
proxy for political rents. Furthermore, corruption is measured with error and is determined
by many other country features.
Cross-sectional and panel data suggest some connections. Persson and Tabellini
(2003) and Persson, Tabellini and Trebbi (2003) study about 80 democracies in the 1990s.
They measure corruption as perceived through surveys assembled by the World Bank,
Transparency International and private risk services. They also control for country
characteristics that earlier studies have found to correlate with corruption, notably per
capita income, openness to international trade, the citizens’ education and religious
beliefs, a country’s history as captured by colonial heritage, and geographic location as
7
measured by a set of dummy variables. The ballot structure is indeed strongly correlated
with corruption: a switch from a system with all legislators elected on party lists, to plurality
rule with all legislators individually elected, would reduce perceptions of corruption by as
much as 20 percent. This is about twice the estimated effect of being in Latin America. The
decline in corruption is stronger when individual voting is implemented by plurality rule,
rather than by using preferential voting or open lists in proportional electoral systems. Of
course, the result could also reflect effects of the electoral formula (as discussed below),
rather than just the ballot structure. Kunicova and Rose Ackerman (2001) obtain similar
empirical results, although they single out closed-list, proportional representation systems
as the most conducive to corruption.
Some of these conclusions run counter to those in Carey and Shugart (1995) and
Golden and Chang (2001), who instead emphasize the distinction between inter-party and
intra-party competition. These scholars argue that competition between parties is
desirable, as it leads to legislation that pleases voters at large. In contrast, competition
within parties is not desirable, as it leads candidates to provide favors to their
constituencies, through patronage and other illegal activities. The Italian and Japanese
electoral systems before the 1990s reforms are deemed to exemplify this problem.
Measuring corruption by judicial inquiries against Italian members of parliament, Golden
and Chang (2001) show that corruption is more frequent in districts with more intense
intra-party competition. They conclude that open-list systems are worse than closed-list
systems, and claim that the empirical results by Kunicova and Rose Ackerman (2001)
reflect a misspecified model (see also Golden and Chang, 2003).
Summarizing the argument so far, both theory and evidence suggest that individual
accountability under plurality rule strengthens the incentives of politicians to please the
voters and is conducive to good behavior. But the effects of individual accountability under
proportional representation, implemented with open rather than closed lists, are more
controversial.
The electoral formula, including district magnitude, seems to affect the incentives for
politicians also in other ways. Under plurality rule, the mapping from votes to seats
becomes steep when electoral races are close. This connection ought to create strong
incentives for good behavior: a small improvement in the chance of victory would create a
large return in terms of seats. The incentives under proportional representation are
weaker, as additional effort has a lower expected return on seats (or on the probability of
winning). If electoral races have likely winners, however, incentives may instead be
8
weaker under plurality than proportional representation: if seats are next to certain, little
effort goes into pleasing the voters of those districts.
3
Aggregating over all districts (and
thus over races of different closeness), the relative incentives to extract rents under
different electoral formulas become an empirical question. Strömberg ‘s (2003) results
bear on these arguments. Employing a theoretical and structurally estimated model of the
U.S. Electoral College, he studies the effects of a (hypothetical) reform to a national vote
for president. Given the empirical distribution of voter preferences, he finds that the
incentives for rent extraction are basically unaffected by such a reform.
3.2 Indirect effects
Electoral rules (and in particular district magnitude) also have indirect effects on
accountability, by altering the set of candidates that have a chance to be elected, or more
generally by changing the party system.
Myerson (1993) presents a model in which barriers to entry allow dishonest
candidates to survive. He assumes that parties (or equivalently, candidates) differ in two
dimensions: honesty and ideology. Voters always prefer honest candidates, but disagree
on ideology. With proportional representation and multi-member district, honest candidates
are always available for all ideological positions, so dishonest candidates have no chance
of being elected. But in single-member districts, only one candidate can win the election.
Voters may then cast their ballot, strategically, for dishonest but ideologically preferred
candidates, if they expect all other voters with the same ideology to do the same: switching
to an honest candidate risks giving the victory to a candidate of the opposite ideology.
Thus, plurality rule in single-member districts can be associated with dishonest
incumbents, whom it is difficult to oust from office.
But electoral systems that make it easy for political parties to be represented in
parliament (for example, multi-member districts and proportional representation) may
actually encourage rent seeking, through another channel. If many factions are
represented in parliament, the government is more likely to be supported by a coalition of
parties, rather than by a single party. Under single-party government, voters know
precisely whom to blame or reward for observed performance. Under coalition
government, voters may not know whom to blame, and the votes lost for bad performance
are shared amongst all coalition partners; this dilutes the incentives of individual parties to
3
Of course, districts can be redesigned at will at some intervals, which makes the closeness of elections an endogenous
choice. This possibility opens up the door for strategic manipulation (gerrymandering) where protection of incumbents
is one of several possible objectives.
9
please the voters. These ideas are discussed by Persson, Roland and Tabellini (2003) and
Bingham Powell (2000).
Do the data shed light on these alternative predictions? The hypothesis that
coalition governments are associated with more corruption remains untested, as far as we
know, though some of the blatant corruption scandals in Europe – Belgium and Italy –
have been intimately associated with such governments. Other evidence supports the idea
that barriers to entry raise corruption, however. Persson and Tabellini (2003) and Persson,
Tabellini and Trebbi (2003) find corruption to be higher in countries and years with small
district magnitude (that is, few legislators elected in each district), again with large
quantitative effects. Alt and Lassen (2002) show that restrictions on primaries in
gubernatorial elections, that raise barriers to entry for new candidates, are positively
associated with perceptions of corruption in U.S. states.
We have thus far emphasized the implications of the electoral rule for political rents
and corruption. A strong incentive of political representatives to please the voters can also
show up in electoral policy cycles, however. Persson and Tabellini (2003) consider panel
data from 1960 covering about 500 elections in over 50 democracies. They classify
countries in two groups according to the electoral formula and estimate the extent of
electoral cycles in different specifications, including fixed country and time effects and
other regressors. Governments elected under plurality rule tend to cut taxes and
government spending during election years, by about 0.5% of GDP. In proportional
representation democracies, tax cuts are less pronounced, and no spending cuts are
observed. This finding is consistent with better accountability under plurality rule, allowing
voters to punish governments for high taxes and spending either because they are fiscal
conservatives (as in Peltzman, 1992) or because they are subject to a political agency
problem (as in Persson and Tabellini, 2000 or Besley and Case, 1995).
3.3 Summing up
What does all of this imply about the consequences of electoral reforms for corruption?
Because it would entail changing several features of the electoral rule, a large-scale
reform from “proportional” to “majoritarian” elections would have ambiguous effects. A
switch from proportional representation to plurality rule, accompanied by a change in the
ballot structure from party lists to voting over individuals, would strengthen political
incentives for good behavior, both directly and indirectly through the type of government.
But these welfare-improving effects might be offset if the reform diminishes district
10
magnitude, thus erecting barriers to entry to the detriment of honest or talented
incumbents. The net effects of electoral reform thus depend on which channel is stronger,
and on the precise architecture of reform. The empirical evidence in Persson and Tabellini
(2003) and Persson, Tabellini and Trebbi (2003) support this nuanced conclusion. After
controlling for other variables and taking into account the self-selection of countries into
constitutions, they find no robust difference in corruption across a broad classification of
majoritarian vs. proportional electoral systems.
4. Representation
Economic policy generates conflicts of interest. Individuals and groups in society differ in
many dimensions: they have different levels and sources of income, work in different
sectors and occupations, live in different geographic areas, and possess different
ideologies. As a result, people differ in their views about public policies: the appropriate
level and structure of taxation, the preferred structure of tariffs, subsidies, and regulations,
the support for programs aimed at different regions, and so on. Electoral rules help
aggregate such conflicting interests into public policy decisions, but the weight given to
specific groups varies with the system. In this section we discuss how this influences
fiscal policy choices.
4.1 Direct effects on the composition of government spending
Single-member districts and plurality vote both tend to pull in the direction of narrowly
targeted programs benefiting small geographic constituencies. Conversely, multi-member
districts and proportional representation induce politicians to provide benefits for broad
groups of voters. Building on this insight, some recent papers have studied the influence of
district magnitude and the electoral formula on the composition of government spending.
Persson and Tabellini (1999, 2000, Ch. 8) study electoral competition between two
opportunistic and office-seeking parties. Multimember districts and proportional
representation diffuse electoral competition, giving the parties strong incentives to seek
electoral support from broad coalitions in the population through general public goods or
universalistic redistributive programs (e.g., public pensions or other welfare programs). In
contrast, single-member districts and plurality rule typically make each party a sure winner
in some of the districts, concentrating electoral competition in the other pivotal districts.
Both parties thus have a strong incentive to target voters in these swing districts.
Strömberg (2003) considers the effect of the Electoral College on the allocation of
11
campaign resources or policy benefits in his afore-mentioned structural model of the
election for U.S. president. He shows empirically that this election method implies a much
more lopsided distribution across states, where spending is focused on states where a
relatively small number of votes might tip the entire state, compared to a (counterfactual)
system of a national vote.
Moreover, the winner-takes-all property of plurality rule reduces the minimal
coalition of voters needed to win the election. Under plurality rule, a party can control the
legislature with only 25% of the national vote: half the vote in half the districts. Under full
proportional representation, 50% percent of the national vote is needed, which gives
politicians a stronger incentive to provide benefits for many voters. This point has been
made in different frameworks. Lizzeri and Persico (2001) study a model with binding
electoral promises, where candidates can use tax revenue to provide either (general)
public goods or targeted redistribution. Persson and Tabellini (2000, Ch. 9) consider a
broad or narrow policy choice by an incumbent policymaker trying to win re-election.
Milesi-Ferretti et al. (2002) obtain similar results in a model where policy is set in post-
election bargaining among the elected politicians. They also predict that proportional
elections lead to a bigger overall size of spending.
Is the evidence consistent with the prediction that proportional electoral systems
lead to more spending in broad redistributive programs, such as public pensions and
welfare spending? Without controlling for other determinants of welfare spending,
legislatures elected under proportional electoral systems spend much more in social
security and welfare compared to majoritarian elections: on average, the difference is
about 8% of GDP. Controlling for other determinants of social security and welfare
spending, such as demographics, per capita income, the age and quality of democracy,
this magnitude shrinks to 2-3% of GDP and remains statistically significant. This estimate
is robust to the sample of countries and to taking into account the non-random nature of
electoral systems (cf. Milesi-Ferretti et al, 2002 and Persson and Tabellini, 2003, 2004b).
If politicians have stronger incentives to vie for electoral support through broad
spending programs under proportional representation than under plurality rule, we might
expect to observe systematic differences around election time in the two systems. Persson
and Tabellini (2003) indeed find a significant electoral cycle in welfare-state spending –
expansions of such budget items in election and post-election years – in proportional
representation systems, but not in plurality systems.
12
4.2 Indirect effects on the overall size of government spending
The papers discussed so far in this section focus on the incentives of individual
candidates, in a two party system. Many studies of comparative politics, however, observe
that electoral rules also shape party structure and types of government. Plurality rule and
small district magnitude produce fewer parties and a more skewed distribution of seats
than proportional representation and large district magnitude (for example, Duverger, 1954
and Lijphart, 1990). Moreover, in parliamentary democracies few parties mean more
frequent single-party majority governments, and less frequent coalition governments
(Taagepera and Shugart, 1989; Strom, 1990). Evidence presented in Persson, Roland
and Tabellini (2003) suggests that these political effects of the electoral rule may be large.
In about 50 parliamentary democracies, proportional electoral rule is associated with a
more fragmented party system, more frequent coalition governments and less frequent
governments ruled by a single-party majority.
It would be surprising if such large political effects did not also show up in the
economic policies implemented by these different party systems and types of government.
Indeed, a few recent papers have argued that the more fractionalized party systems
induced by proportional elections lead to a greater overall size of government spending.
For example, Austen-Smith (2000) studies a model where redistributive tax policy is set in
post-election bargaining. He assumes that there are fewer parties under plurality rule (two
parties) than under proportional representation (three parties). The coalition of two parties
spends and taxes more compared to the single-party. But here the number and size of
parties is not allowed to depend on policy choices, imposing an artificial constraint on
political competition.
Persson, Roland and Tabellini (2003) and Bawn and Rosenbluth (2003) also predict
that proportional representation leads to more government spending than plurality rule; but
they treat the number of parties as endogenous and stress how the type of government
determines the nature of electoral competition. When the government relies on a single-
party majority, the main competition for votes is between the incumbent and the
opposition; this pushes the incumbent towards efficient policies, or at least towards
policies that benefit the voters represented in office. If instead the government is supported
by a coalition of parties, voters can discriminate between the parties in government and
this creates electoral conflict inside the coalition. Under plausible assumptions,
inefficiencies in bargaining induce excessive government spending.
13
These theoretical predictions are supported by the data: without conditioning on
other determinants of fiscal policy, legislatures elected under proportional representation
spend about 10% of GDP more than legislatures elected under plurality rule. Careful
estimates obtained from cross-country data confirm this result. Persson and Tabellini
(2003, 2004b) consider a sample of 80 democracies in the 1990s, controlling for a variety
of other policy determinants (including the distinction between presidential and
parliamentary democracy) and allow for self-selection of countries into electoral systems.
Their estimates are very robust, and imply that proportional representation rather than
plurality rule raises total expenditures by central government by a whopping 5% of GDP.
4
Persson, Roland and Tabellini (2003) focus on 50 parliamentary democracies,
identifying the effect of electoral rules on spending either from the cross-sectional
variation, or from the time-series variation around electoral reforms. They find spending to
be higher under proportional elections by an amount similar to that found by Persson and
Tabellini (2003, 2004b). But here the effect seems to be entirely due to a higher incidence
of coalition governments in proportional electoral systems. This conclusion is reached by
testing an over-identifying restriction that follows from the underlying theoretical model.
Several features of the electoral rule -- such as the electoral formula, district magnitude
and minimum thresholds for being represented in parliament -- are jointly used as
instruments for the type of government. The data cannot reject the restriction that all these
measures of electoral systems are valid instruments for the type of government; that is, the
electoral rule only influences government spending through the type of government, with
no direct effects of the electoral rule on spending. Earlier empirical papers that treated the
type of government as exogenous also find evidence that larger parliamentary coalitions
spend more (e.g. Kontopoulos and Perotti, 1999; Baqir, 2002).
As noted above, the selection of countries into electoral systems is certainly not
random, and some of the empirical research takes account of this (in particular, Persson
and Tabellini, 2003, 2004b). But Ticchi and Vindigni (2003) and Iversen and Soskice
(2003) note a particularly subtle problem: at least in the OECD countries, proportional
electoral rule is frequently associated with center-left governments, while right-wing
governments are more frequent under majoritarian elections. This correlation, rather than
the prevalence of coalition governments, could explain why proportional representation
systems spend more.
4
Variables held constant in the underlying regressions include per capita income, the quality and age of democracy,
openness of the economy, the size and age composition of the population, plus indicators for federalism, OECD
membership, colonial history, and continental location. Various estimation techniques produced similar results.
14
But why should the electoral rule be correlated with government ideology? These
papers argue that majoritarian elections concentrate power, which tends to favor the
wealthy. In such systems, the argument goes, minorities (groups unlikely to benefit from
spending, irrespective of who holds office) would rather see fiscal conservatives than fiscal
liberals in office, since this reduces their tax burden. Hence, in winner-takes-all systems,
conservative parties have an electoral advantage. If electoral rules are chosen on the
basis of the policies they will deliver, this might explain the observed correlation: where the
center-left voters dominate proportional systems have been selected, whereas majoritarian
systems have been selected where conservatives dominate. The empirical results by
Persson, Roland and Tabellini (2003) cast some doubt on this line of thought, however. If
indeed the electoral rule influences policy through the ideology of governments, rather
than through the number of parties in government, the electoral rule cannot be a valid
instrument for the incidence of coalition governments in a regression on government
spending – contrary to the findings discussed above.
4.3 Indirect effects on budget deficits
Finally, if bargaining inefficiencies inside coalition governments lead to high spending, they
may also produce other distortions. Several papers have studied inter-temporal fiscal
policy, treating the type of government as exogenous, but arguing that coalition
governments face more severe “common-pool problems.” The latter concept refers to the
tendency for over-exploitation when multiple users make independent decisions on how
much to exploit a common resource such as fish; the analogy to this common resource is
current and future tax revenue. In reviewing the extensive work on government budget
deficits, Alesina and Perotti (1995) draw on the work by Velasco (1999) to argue that
coalition governments are more prone to run deficits. Hallerberg and von Hagen (1998,
1999) and von Hagen (this volume) explicitly link the severity of the common-pool problem
to electoral systems and argue that this has implications for the appropriate form of
budgetary process.
The experiences of European and Latin American countries suggest a second
reason why coalition governments might be prone to run budget deficits. As coalition
governments have more players who could potentially veto a change, they may be less
able to alter policy in the wake of adverse shocks (Roubini and Sachs, 1989; Alesina and
Drazen, 1991). These ideas are related to those in Tsebelis (1995, 1999, 2002), where a
large number of veto players tends to “lock in”' economic policy and reduce its ability to
15
respond to shocks. In Tsebelis's conception, proportional elections often lead to multiple
partisan veto players in government and thus to more policy myopia, even though the
electoral rule is not the primitive in his analysis.
Finally, changes of government or the threat of government crisis are more frequent
under proportional elections (due to the greater incidence of minority and coalition
governments). And governments facing a vote on their own survival are more likely to
behave myopically and run large budget deficits (Grilli, Masciandaro and Tabellini, 1991).
A priori, this argument could also go the other way, however. In a coalition government,
some parties will remain in government for a long time, despite changes in the coalition.
With plurality rule, the party in power this time may be completely out of power next time.
So the party in power today will take the money and run. In other words, political instability
(i.e. large swings in political majorities), rather than government instability, undermines
fiscal prudence (Alesina and Tabellini, 1990).
The empirical evidence confirms that proportional electoral systems behave more
myopically. In the raw data, budget deficits are larger by about 1% of GDP in legislatures
elected under proportional representation, compared to those elected under plurality rule.
Persson and Tabellini (2003) show that, when controlling for other determinants of policy,
this difference grows to about 2 percent of GDP and is statistically significant in a large
sample of democracies. There is also evidence that the electoral rule is correlated with
government reaction to economic shocks: in proportional democracies, spending as a
share of GDP rises in recessions but does not decline in booms, while cyclical fluctuations
tend to have symmetric impacts on fiscal policy under other electoral systems.
5. Discussion
One of the principal conclusions of this chapter is that electoral reforms entail a trade off
between accountability and representation, as political scientists have suggested, and this
has sharp implications for economic policy outcomes. This tradeoff shows up in the direct
effects of the electoral rule on incentives of political candidates, as well as the indirect
effects on party structure and type of government.
Plurality rule strengthens accountability. It does so directly, by reinforcing the
incentives of politicians to please the voters, which results in smaller political rents and
less corruption. But plurality rule also makes political candidates more responsive to the
wishes of pivotal groups of voters, which increases the propensity to target benefits to
narrow constituencies, at the expense of broad and universalistic programs such as
16
welfare-state spending and general public goods. We surveyed a range of evidence
suggesting that both effects are quantitatively important.
Electoral rules also have indirect effects on policy outcomes, through the party
structure. Small district magnitude combined with plurality rule results in fewer political
parties. This makes it more difficult to oust dishonest or incompetent incumbents, because
voters often support such incumbents over honest but ideologically opposed challengers.
Fewer parties also reduce the incidence of coalition governments (in parliamentary
democracies), and this is likely to lead to more efficient policies. As these indirect effects
work in opposite directions, the overall impact on accountability is ambiguous. The
approach also reveals that the overall size of government and budget deficits are much
larger under coalition governments, and the latter are promoted by proportional
representation and large district magnitude.
Whether economists or political scientists, at the end of the day we are interested
not only in economic policies, but also in their overall effects on economic performance.
The interaction between electoral systems, other political institutions, and economic
development is one of the most exciting new areas of research at the boundary between
economics and political science. As discussed by Helpman (2004), progress in this area
will have to combine insights not only from these two disciplines, but also from sociology,
and from many branches of economics, such as macroeconomics, economic
development, political economics and economic history. This line of research will also
have to focus on the distinction between democratic and autocratic forms of government,
trying to understand which features of democratic institutions make democracy more
stable, and how the quality of democracy interacts with specific institutional features.
Although it is still premature to review this rapidly evolving line of research, one thing is
sure. When such a review is written a few years down the line, the state of our knowledge
in economics and political science will be very different from what it is today.
17
References
Acemoglu, D. (2005), “Constitutions, Politics and Economics; A Review Essay on Persson
and Tabellini's "The Economic Effects of Constitutions" ”, forthcoming, Journal of
Economic Literature.
Alesina, A. and A. Drazen (1991), “Why are Stabilizations Delayed?”, American Economic
Review, 81:1170-1188.
Alesina, A. and R. Perotti (1995), “The Political Economy of Budget Deficits”, IMF Staff
Papers, 42:1-31.
Alesina A. and G. Tabellini, (1990), “A Positive Theory of Fiscal Deficits and Government
Debt”, Review of Economic Studies, 57:403-414.
Alt,J. and D. Lassen (2002), “The Political Economy of Institutions and Corruption in
American States”, EPRU Working Paper Series 02-16, University of Copenhagen.
Austen-Smith, D. (2000), “Redistributing Income under Proportional Representation”,
Journal of Political Economy, 108:1235-1269.
Baqir, R. (2002), “Districting and Government Overspending”, Journal of Political
Economy, 110:1318-1354.
Bawn, K. and N. Rosenbluth (2003), “Coalition Parties vs. Coalition of Parties. How
Electoral Agency Shapes the Political Logic of Costs and Benefits”, mimeo, Yale
University.
Becht, M., P. Bolton, A. Röell (2003), “Corporate Governance and Control”, European
Corporate Governance Institute, WP n. 02/2002.
Besley, T. and A. Case (1995), “Does Political Accountability Affect Economic Policy
Choices? Evidence from Gubernatorial Term Limits”,
Quarterly Journal of Economics,
110:769-798.
18
Besley T. and A. Case (2003), “Political Institutions and Policy Choices: Evidence from the
United States”,
Journal of Economic Literature,
41:7-73.
Bingham Powell, G. (2000), Elections as Instruments of Democracy – Majoritarian and
Proportional Visions, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Blais, A. and L. Massicotte (1996), "Electoral Systems" in LeDuc, L., R. Niemei and P.
Norris (eds.) Comparing Democracies: Elections and Voting in Global Perspective, Sage.
Carey, J. and M. Shugart (1995), “Incentives to Cultivate a Personal Vote: A Rank
Ordering of Electoral Formulas”, Electoral Studies, 14:417-439.
Cox, G. (1997), Making Votes Count, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Duverger, M. (1954), Political Parties: Their Organization and Activity in the Modern State,
B. North and R. North, trans. New York: John Wiley.
Golden, M. and E. Chang (2001), “Competitive Corruption: Factional Conflict and Political
Malfeasance in Postwar Italian Christian Democracy”, World Politics, 53:558-622.
Golden, M. and E. Chang (2003), “Electoral Systems, District Magnitude and Corruption”,
mimeo, UCLA.
Grilli, V., D. Masciandaro and G. Tabellini (1991), “Political and Monetary Institutions and
Public Financial Policies in the Industrialized Countries”, Economic Policy,13:342-392.
Grofman, B. this volume
Hallerberg, M. and J. Von Hagen (1998), “Electoral Institutions and the Budget Process.”
In Fukasaka, K. and R. Hausmann (eds.), Democracy, Decentralization and Deficits in
Latin America. Paris: OECD Development Center, 65-94 .
19
Hallerberg, M. and J. Von Hagen (1999), “Electoral Institutions, Cabinet Negotiations, and
Budget Deficits in the European Union.” In J. Poterba and J. Von Hagen (eds.),
Fiscal
Institutions and Fiscal Performance, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
von Hagen, J. This volume
Heplman, E. (2004), The Mystery of Economic Growth, Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
Iversen, T. and D. Soskice (2003), “Electoral Systems and the Politics of Coalitions: Why
some Democracies Redistribute more than Others?”, mimeo, Harvard University.
Kontopoulos, Y. and R. Perotti (1999), “Government Fragmentation and Fiscal Policy
Outcomes: Evidence from the OECD Countries.” In: Poterba, J. and J. von Hagen, (eds.),
Fiscal Institutions and Fiscal Preference. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
Kunicova, J. and S. Rose Ackerman (2001), “Electoral Rules as Constraints on Corruption:
the Risks of Closed-List Proportional Representation”, mimeo, Yale University.
Lijphart, A. (1990), “The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws 1945-85”, American
Political Science Review, 84:481-496.
Lizzeri, A. and N. Persico (2001), “The Provision of Public Goods under Alternative
Electoral Incentives”, American Economic Review, 91:225-245.
Milesi-Ferretti G-M., Perotti, R. and M. Rostagno (2002), “Electoral Systems and the
Composition of Public Spending”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117:609-657.
Myerson, R. (1993), “Effectiveness of Electoral Systems for Reducing Government
Corruption: A Game Theoretic Analysis”, Games and Economic Behavior, 5:118-132.
Peltzman, S. (1992), “Voters as Fiscal Conservatives”, Quarterly Journal of Economics,
107:329-361.
20
Persson, T., G. Roland., and G. Tabellini, (2003), “How do Electoral Rules Shape Party
Structures, Government Coalitions and Economic Policies?, mimeo, Bocconi University.
Persson, T. and G. Tabellini (1999), “The Size and Scope of Government: Comparative
Politics with Rational Politicians, 1998 Alfred Marshall Lecture”, European Economic
Review, 43:699-735.
Persson, T. and G. Tabellini (2000), Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy,
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Persson, T. and G. Tabellini (2003), Economic Effects of Constitutions, Cambridge, MA:
MIT Press.
Persson, T. and G. Tabellini (2004a), “Constitutions and Economic Policy”,
Journal of
Economic Perspectives,18:75-98.
Persson, T. and G. Tabellini (2004b), “Constitutional Rules and Economic Policy
Outcomes”, American Economic Review, 94:25-46.
Persson, T., G. Tabellini and F. Trebbi (2003), “Electoral Rules and Corruption”, Journal of
the European Economic Association, 1:958-989.
Przeworski, A, S. Stokes and B. Manin (1999), Democracy, Accountability and
Representation, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Poterba and Von Hagen (1999) (eds.), Fiscal Rules and Fiscal Performance. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Roubini, N. and J. Sachs (1989), “Political and Economic Determinants of Budget Deficits
in the Industrial Democracies”, European Economic Review, 33:903-933.
Strom, K. (1990), Minority Government and Majority Rule, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
University Press.
21
Strömberg, D. (2003), “Optimal Campaigning in Presidential Elections: The Probability of
Being Florida,” mimeo, IIES.
Taagepera, R. and M. Shugart (1989), Seats and Votes: The Effects and Determinants of
Electoral Systems, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Ticchi, D. and A. Vindigni (2003), “Endogenous Constitutions”, mimeo, IIES, University of
Stockholm.
Tsebelis, G. (1995), “Decision-making in Political Systems: Veto Players in
Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, Multicameralism and Multipartyism.” British Journal of
Political Science, 25:289-236.
Tsebelis, G. (1999), “Veto Players and Law Production in Parliamentary Democracies”,
American Political Science Review, 93:591-608.
Tsebelis, G. (2002), Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work, Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
Velasco, A. (1999), “A Model of Endogenous Fiscal Deficit and Delayed Fiscal Reforms” In
J. Poterba and J. von Hagen (eds.), Fiscal Rules and Fiscal Performance, Chicago, IL:
University of Chicago Press for the NBER.
... A country does not present only one relevant dimension, but multiple political and constitutional features that may influence political instability. The political economy literature (Persson and Tabellini, 2004;Persson and Tabellini, 2006) has classified these political features, distinguishing those that are structural to the political system (e.g. related to a country's electoral system), and the features of the incumbent legislature (e.g. ...
Article
This paper investigates the relationship between political instability and labour market institutions. We develop a theoretical model in which political instability creates incentives for a government to introduce labour market regulation in the economy. The distortionary effect of regulation on unemployment effectively puts a constraint on the design of fiscal and public policies. We empirically investigate these predictions using panel data for 21 OECD countries for the period 1985–2006. Our results are consistent with the view that political instability is associated with more regulated labour markets, lower labour taxation, and lower unemployment benefit replacement rates.
... Marcelo Leiras3 El efecto de la desnacionalización postulado en estos estudios es semejante al que algunos modelos más generales atribuyen a los sistemas electorales mayoritarios(Persson & Tabellini 2006). ...
Book
Full-text available
Durante los últimos años, Argentina ha experimentado una profunda transformación de sus instituciones públicas, producto de la redefinición del rol del Estado en la economía, de la redemocratización del sistema político y del cambio en el modelo de inserción internacional, entre otros. Ciertamente una de las dimensiones centrales de esta transformación, además del alcance de la intervención estatal, ha sido su naturaleza, particularmente en el plano de la división de tareas entre distintos niveles de Gobierno. En efecto, uno de los ejes principales del proceso de reformas acontecido en los años noventa en Argentina ha sido la descentralización. El punto a destacar en este libro es que la descentralización consiste en una transformación de la estructura político-institucional y de la dinámica de incentivos de las relaciones intergubernamentales que, al modificar los modos de operar de los diferentes niveles de gobierno en una estructura federal como la Argentina, impactan en las políticas públicas, tanto en su naturaleza como en su calidad. En este contexto, la dimensión intergubernamental deviene una dimensión clave, aunque frecuentemente soslayada, para comprender la problemática de la formulación e implementación de políticas estatales en la Argentina actual. Esto implica poner el acento en los problemas de coordinación interjursidiccional, de construcción de coaliciones políticas interregionales, de la interrelación entre acuerdos políticos y transferencias de recursos, para explicar la configuración de las políticas públicas. En síntesis, el presente trabajo analiza el impacto de los cambios en las tres dimensiones de la descentralización (política, administrativa y fiscal) sobre los gobiernos subnacionales (provinciales y municipales) y sobre la dinámica de relaciones entre niveles de gobierno en Argentina. Para ello, se coordinan los esfuerzos de investigadores de diversos centros académicos en la Argentina y el exterior que están actualmente desarrollando trabajos de investigación en las aéreas que abarca este proyecto.
... It suggests that the structural factors are capable of predicting 0/317 of the variance of our dependent variable. Among the structural factors, therefore, capital and employment were found to be more powerful in predicting the success rate of the self-sufficiency plans, and this finding is consistent with the work of Persson and Guido (2006). These authors have explored the contributions that the economic factors (capital, employment, and space, to name a few) make to and their direct relationships with entrepreneurship and the entrepreneurs. ...
Article
This study is intended to examine the relationship between the structural, environmental, and behavioral factors with the success rate of Imam Khomeini Relief Committee's self-sufficiency and self-employment plans through taking a social entrepreneurship approach. Our sample comprised of 152 clients and 12 social workers who were affiliated to the abovementioned committee. As the methodology of our study, mixed method was adopted, in that we studied the clients quantitatively through correlation regression and path analysis. On the other hand, the social workers were treated qualitatively and though underlying theory. After analyzing the quantitative data, the structural, environmental, and behavioral factors were found to be the predicators of success rate of these occupational plans. In the examined structural, environmental, and behavioral factor, therefore, capital and employment, regulations and incentives, innovation and identifying the opportunities were meaningful, respectively. There also happened to be a correlation between our structural and behavioral factors. In analyzing the research's qualitative data, then, these three factors were of considerable significance. In sum, the highest rates of significance in these factors were as following: capital, employment, and communication system in the structural factors; regulations and incentives in the environmental factors; and training, innovation, and risk-taking in the behavioral factors.
... Public policy myopia is defined, as in the theoretical model, as H = 1 − φ(p, γ), which we measure using features that have been identified in the political economy literature as the main determinants of policy turnover and polarisation of political preferences (see, e.g. Persson and Tabellini [42], Persson and Tabellini [43]). In the empirical analysis, we specify H as a linear combination of p and γ and estimate separate coefficients in Equations (23)– (25). ...
Article
Full-text available
In the public debate, poor employment performance has often been associated with the existence of extensive labour market regulations and a lack of commitment to far-sighted public policies. This paper investigates the relation between policy myopia and labour market institutions. We develop a theoretical model in which policy myopia leads an incumbent government to choose institutions that allow the creation of rents in the labour market and reduce resources available to public goods provision and social expenditure. We test these predictions empirically using panel data for 21 OECD countries for the period 1985--2006. We show that policy myopia is associated with more regulated labour markets, lower unemployment benefit replacement rates, and smaller tax wedges on labour.
Article
We study the effect of a change in electoral rules on political competition, measured by the number of candidates and their political experience. We explore the effects of a change in legislation, introduced a year before the gubernatorial elections in Peru on the number of parties that participated in these elections. We also investigate how the legislative change affected the political experience of the candidates. Given that the legislative change did not apply to elections for provincial mayors, we use those elections as a control group, in a difference-in-differences design. Our estimates show the number of parties registered increased by a margin of around 2.2 after the legislative change. The change also increased the candidates' years of accumulated political experience, particularly in the subsequent gubernatorial elections.
Article
Full-text available
Recent work on conflict suggests that electoral systems impact foreign policy-making in important ways; however, the discipline has reached different conclusions regarding how different types of electoral systems affect conflict initiation. In this study we contend that legislators are more accountable individually in candidate-centred electoral systems which impacts a state’s decision to initiate interstate conflict. We test our argument using a time-series cross-sectional analysis of 54 democracies from 1975 to 2001. The results provide strong support for the hypothesis that candidate-centred electoral systems result in less conflict initiation than party-centric systems due to higher levels of individual accountability for legislative members.
Article
Full-text available
Multiparty government has often been associated with poor economic policy-making, with distortions like lower growth rates and high budget deficits. One proposed reason for such distortions is that coalition governments face more severe ‘common pool problems’ since parties use their control over specific ministries to advance their specific spending priorities rather than practice budgetary discipline. We suggest that this view of multiparty government is incomplete and that we need to take into account that coalitions may have established certain control mechanisms to deal with such problems. One such mechanism is the drafting of a coalition agreement. Our results, when focusing on the spending behavior of cabinets formed in 17 Western European countries (1970–1998), support our claim that coalition agreements matter for the performance of multiparty cabinets in economic policy-making. More specifically, we find clear support for an original conditional hypothesis suggesting that coalition agreements significantly reduce the negative effect of government fragmentation on government spending in those institutional contexts where prime ministerial power is low.
Article
Recent work on conflict suggests that electoral systems impact foreign policy-making in important ways; however, the discipline has reached different conclusions regarding how different types of electoral systems affect conflict initiation. In this study we contend that legislators are more accountable individually in candidate-centred electoral systems which impacts a state’s decision to initiate interstate conflict. We test our argument using a time-series cross-sectional analysis of 54 democracies from 1975 to 2001. The results provide strong support for the hypothesis that candidate-centred electoral systems result in less conflict initiation than party-centric systems due to higher levels of individual accountability for legislative members.
Article
Social trust is frequently claimed to be conducive for economic reforms. Likewise, the scope of policy liberalization is influenced by the political power structure as manifested in institutional and political constraints on the executive (IPCE). However, social trust and IPCE are possibly intertwined in their effects on economic liberalization. This paper empirically explores the relationship between social trust, IPCE and the scope of economic deregulation as measured by the first difference in the regulation subindex of the Economic Freedom of the World index. The results provide evidence in favor of a positive association of social trust with deregulation and of a negative association between institutional or partisan veto-points and deregulation. Yet, according to our analysis IPCE are an obstacle for economic deregulation only in relatively low trusting environments and social trust unfolds a particular strength as driver of deregulation with increasing levels of IPCE.
Article
Presidential candidates choose advertising strategically across markets based on each state's potential to tip the election. The winner-take-all rules in the Electoral College concentrate advertising in battleground states, ignoring most voters. We estimate an equilibrium model of competition between candidates to evaluate advertising and voting outcomes. In a direct vote counterfactual, all states receive positive advertising and both expenditures and turnout increase. Although states' political preferences drive competition in the Electoral College, candidates focus on cheap advertising targets in a direct vote. Simulations removing advertising price variation suggest a direct vote. Simulations removing advertising price variation suggest a direct vote spreads political attention uniformly across markets with diverse preferences.
Article
Full-text available
This paper investigates how different electoral rules influence political corruption. We argue that closed-list proportional representation systems are most susceptible to corruption relative to open-list proportional representation and plurality systems. This effect is due to the use of closed party lists and geographically large districts. We also examine interaction effects between electoral rules and other institutional forms, namely presidentialism, federalism, and bi-cameralism. We test our main predictions, the proposed causal mechanism, and interaction effects empirically on a cross-section of 105 countries, controlling for economic, political, and social background factors. The empirical findings strongly support our theoretical hypothesis that closed-list PR systems, especially together with presidentialism, are associated with higher levels of corruption. This result is robust to different model specifications and deleting influential observations. To the best of our knowledge, only one other study so far has explored the relationship between electoral rules and corruption empirically (Persson, Tabellini, and Trebbi 2001). While we confirm their finding that proportional elections are associated with higher levels of corruption, we single out closed-list PR systems as the most conducive to corruption. In addition, we show that our causal mechanism performs better than the causal mechanism tested by Persson, Tabellini, and Trebbi, especially after adding more institutional structure.
Article
Full-text available
Institutions and policies Vittorio Grilli, Donato Masciandaro and Guido Tabellini Why do countries as similar as the industrialized OECD countries go through such different experience in terms of public deficits and debts or in terms of inflation? The answer cannot come from macroeconomic policy responses to different disturbances, nor from the principles of optimal taxation, but rather from politics. This article focuses on the role that particular institutions exert in providing constraints and incentives which shape the actions of policymakers. The electoral process and political traditions affect the ability of governments to deal with deficits and mounting debts. What seems to matter most, it is found, is the effect of the durability of governments. Governments with short horizons act myopically and never quite tackle the hard choices. Such governments typically exist in countries with an electoral system favouring many small political parties. Central bank independence promotes low inflation with no apparent costs in terms of real economic performance, irrespective of the political institutions. In fact there is no link between monetary and fiscal discipline. These findings carry powerful implications for countries facing high indebtedness or stubborn inflation, but also for the construction of the European Economic and Monetary Union.
Article
We analyze the relationship between electoral systems and corruption in a large sample of contemporary democratic nations. Whereas previous studies have shown that closed-list proportional representation is associated with greater (perceived) corruption than open-list PR, we demonstrate that this relationship fails to hold once district magnitude is considered. The theory underlying our study draws on work on "the personal vote" that suggests that the incentives to amass resources - and perhaps even to do so illegally - increase with district magnitude in open-list settings but decrease in closed-list contexts. Extending this insight, we show that political corruption gets more (less) severe as district magnitude increases under open-list PR (closed-list PR) systems. In addition, once district magnitude exceeds a certain threshold - our estimates are that this is as low as 15 - corruption is greater in open list than in closed list settings. Only at unusually small district magnitudes (those below 15) is closed-list PR associated with more corruption, as conventionally held. Our results hold for alternate measures of corruption, for different specifications of the country cases to be included, for different measures of district magnitude, and regardless of whether the political system is presidential or parliamentary and the number of effective parties. Using an alternative, objective measure of political corruption, we also present corroborating evidence across Italian electoral districts. Within the open-list environment characterizing Italy for the eleven legislative periods that spanned the second half of the twentieth century, larger districts are more susceptible to suspected political corruption than smaller ones. This finding is consistent with the underlying model that predicts that larger electoral districts are associated with higher levels of corruption in open-list settings. It is robust to the inclusion of various important control variables, including per capita wealth and the efficiency of the judiciary.
Article
Theoretically, this article draws on political agency theory to formulate hypotheses. Empirically, it shows that political institutions have a role in explaining the prevalence of political corruption in American states. In the states, a set of democracies where the rule of law is relatively well established and the confounding effects of differing electoral systems and regimes are absent, institutional variables relating to the openness of the political system inhibit corruption. That is, other things equal, the extent to which aspiring politicians can enter and gain financial backing, and to which voters can focus their votes on policies and thereby hold incumbent politicians accountable for policy outcomes and find substitutes for them if dissatisfied with those outcomes, reduce corruption as a general problem of agency. These institutional effects are estimated in the presence of controls for variables representing other approaches.
Article
A systematic analysis of the relationships between the main electoral system variables (electoral formula, district magnitude, and ballot structure) and electoral outcomes (the degrees of disproportionality and multipartism) in the 20 Western democracies from 1945 to 1985--representing 32 distinct electoral systems (an electoral system being defined as a set of elections held under basically the same rules)--shows that the effects of both formula and magnitude on proportionality are very strong, much stronger than Douglas W. Rae and subsequent researchers have suggested; that on the other hand, their effects on the number of parties participating in elections is surprisingly weak; and that ballot structure affects the degree of multipartism only in single-member district systems. These findings suggest that strategic behavior by politicians and voters plays a less important role in reducing multipartism than is usually assumed.