ArticlePDF Available

Child Care and Economic Development: The Role for Planners

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

Child care in the US is now being recognized as part of the social infrastructure for economic development. Planners are now recognizing the complexity of child care as a market sector and is now engaging experts in early care and education policy to craft solutions to previous problems associated with families. A new report was released by Cornell University which aims to place childcare to a more comprehensive perspective. The report, called Economic development strategies to Promote Quality Child Care, places child care in the context of families and communities. It recognizes the importance of child care in the context of the long-term human development impact on children, the critical support role that child care plays in enabling parents to work and the importance of the child care sector itself in the regional economy. The framework that the report hs laid has been used by more than 50 states and localities which are composed of child care leaders, government policymakers and business leaders to assess the regional economic impact of the child care sector.
Content may be subject to copyright.
January/February 2006
Child Care and Economic Development:
The Role for Planners
By Mildred Warner
Traditionally, child care has been considered the private problem of families. Unlike other advanced industrialized
countries, the U.S. has not made a major public commitment to support early education and child care for our
youngest children (birth to age five) (Kammerman 2001). As a result, working parents here face more financial
and emotional stress than their Canadian and European counterparts (Gornick and Meyers 2003). Employers,
economic development professionals, and planners are now realizing the costs to productivity of this failure.
Child care is now being recognized as part of the social infrastructure for economic development (Warner, Ribeiro,
and Smith 2003). Just as roads and public transit help people get to work, so does child care. But public subsidies
for highways and transit allow the user to pay only a small portion of the total costs. In contrast, parents shoulder
the primary financial burden for child care. Public support is largely limited to children of low-income families (for
example, the Head Start program or child care subsidies developed as part of the 1996 welfare reform effort). For
the vast majority of working parents, there is no public support beyond the dependent care tax credit, which for
most families averages only a few hundred dollars a year.
The challenge of child care extends beyond the concerns of working families. It affects land-use planning,
economic development strategies, and both public and private finance. The child care sector, as an emerging
market, needs the attention of both professional planners and economic development professionals to help
address its market challenges and ensure it is included as part of the community planning process.
It is critically important that planners understand the complexity of child care as a market sector and engage
experts in early care and education policy before attempting to craft solutions. Differences in professional
language and expertise between the child care and economic fields have made this difficult. Lack of dialogue and
collaboration may also reflect gender bias, because child care has traditionally been considered the private
problem of women and not the public problem of economic developers. Planners are uniquely trained to cross
boundaries and facilitate communication and collaboration across sectors. That role is needed now as the child
care community reaches out to business and economic development leaders. Planners can and should play a key
facilitation role to ensure these new collaborations represent a sharing of power and expertise.
Integrating Child care and Economic Development
Cornell University's
Linking Economic Development and Child Care Project has been a leader in providing research,
analysis, and planning support for this work. This PAS Memo provides a summary of these issues, giving special
attention to a new report,
Economic Development Strategies to Promote Quality Child Care, published in 2004. It also
provides some background on the current state of underinvestment in the early care and education sector, and
explores the growing economic interest in the long-term impacts of the sector on human capital development.
This interest has created a momentum that planners can capture to effect real policy and programmatic change.
However, to be effective, this interest must be expanded from a narrow focus on preschool (Heckman and
Masterov 2004, Lynch 2004, Committee for Economic Development 2002) to a more comprehensive perspective
that places child care in the context of families and communities. Planners can play a critical role in ensuring
policies reflect the reality of the current structure of the child care sector and the context faced by working
families.
This PAS Memo also reviews current debates in economic development theory and practice and shows how they
can be related to child care. It outlines the key principles of economic development and demonstrates how they
can be applied to the child care sector. Specific examples are drawn from the 2004 Cornell University report.
From Private Problem to High Public Return
Mona Harrington, in her book Care and Equality: Inventing a New Family Politics (1999), describes how
Americans have defined child care as the private problem of families. The privacy of family, and belief in the
supremacy of market solutions, has led policy makers to avoid addressing the challenges of the inadequate social
infrastructure of child care in America. Rather than recognize the structural problem of an economy that requires
both parents to work outside the home and fails to provide an adequate system of child care, we instead tend to
define these problems as moral failures of parents. For example:
Recall the mother in Brooklyn, New York, who worked the night shift at McDonalds and, when her
child care provider failed to show up, had to choose between leaving her children home alone or
missing work and losing her job. She went to work; the provider never showed up; the apartment
caught fire; and the children were killed. The mother is now in jail for her moral failure to care
adequately for her children. (Bernstein 2003).
Michael Moore, in his film Bowling for Columbine, describes a similar case in Flint, Michigan, where
poor working mothers ride a bus for more than an hour to work in shopping malls in higher-income
suburbs, leaving their children to get to school on their own. In the case he describes, a six-year-old
boy took a gun to school and killed a classmate.
These are not private problems of individual parents; they represent three fundamental issues:
z
The structural challenges of an economy that fails to produce jobs that pay a family wage.
z
The lack of workplace policies that support the dual role of parents as workers.
z
The failure of planners and policymakers to build an adequate infrastructure for child care in America.
In recent years, recognition of the long-term economic returns of investment in early care and education has
caught the attention of economists. Building on the human capital arguments first advanced by Nobel laureate
Theodore Schultz (1961), James Heckman, another Noble laureate, has argued that investment in early education
promises even greater return than investments later in life, because "learning begets learning" (Heckman and
Masterov 2004). Art Rolnick of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis has argued that early education is an
economic development investment with "high public returns," higher than most other economic development
investments. He insists it is time for economic developers to look beyond "beggar thy neighbor" tax abatement
strategies, or short-term retail-focused investments such as sports stadiums, and instead invest in long-term
human capital investment, starting with preschool (Rolnick and Grunewald 2003). This research has helped to
fuel a
Pew Charitable Trusts
-funded campaign focused on expanding preschool programs for three- and four-year-
olds, but frequently this work results only in proposals for part-day programs limited to poor children.
The Cornell University team believes a broader approach is needed, one that includes communities, families, and
children of all ages and income levels. We use the trillium flower to illustrate the threefold importance of child
care (see Figure 1):
z
The long-term human development impact on children (as illustrated by Rolnick and Grunewald 2003,
Lynch 2004 and Heckman and Masterov 2004);
z
The critical support role that child care plays in enabling parents to work (as noted by Gornick and Meyers
2003 and Shellenback 2004); and
z
The importance of the child care sector itself in the regional economy, as small businesses, employers, and
sources of regional economic integration (Ribeiro and Warner 2004; Liu, Ribeiro, and Warner 2004).
Figure 1: The Threefold Economic Importance of Childcare
Source: Ribeiro, R. and M. Warner 2004.
The Need for a More Comprehensive Perspective
Child development experts have long known that investments in early education have high returns, and they have
crafted interventions to recognize the child in the context of family (Schweinhart et al. 2005, Shore 1997). Full-
day, full-year programs have been designed that support the child and her parents. Benefits in terms of health,
reduced violence, and improved parental career and wage trajectories have been found (Masse and Barnett
2002). While Heckman and Masterov (2004) recognize poor parenting as part of the problem, they do not
recommend financial support or more family-friendly employment options for parents as part of the solution. In
contrast, the American Psychological Association has challenged policymakers to give greater attention to the
stresses faced by parent workers (Halpern 2004). While preschool is certainly needed and welcome, this
intervention on its own will not solve the structural problems faced by working parents in America. For that, we
need planners with a broader, more comprehensive view.
Feminists have long pointed out that most care is provided by the unpaid work of relatives. MacArthur Fellow
Nancy Folbre, in her book The Invisible Heart: Economics and Family Values (2001), argues that care, reciprocity,
and altruism are the foundation for human and community well being. Such nonmarket care also provides the
foundation that enables the market to function. Blindness to the role of the unpaid, nonmarket care of parents
and families (a role filled predominately by women) undermines the altruism on which such care is based. Gornick
and Meyers, in their book Families that Work (2003), show how seriously the U.S. lags behind in workplace
policies that support the dual roles of parents as workers and parents.
Understanding the Child Care Market
Before planners can begin to address the structural problems in the child care sector, they must first understand
the full complexity of the child care market. The early care and education sector in America is composed of a
mixture of center and family-based care, preschool programs, and after-school care. Some programs, such as
Head Start or pre-kindergarten, are publicly supported and sometimes provided in public school settings. Other
programs are based in nonprofit community-based centers or in family homes. There is a growing for-profit sector
of center-based care. Additionally, parents rely on informal providers outside the regulated child care market for
evening and weekend care, when formal options are either unavailable or too expensive. These providers play a
critical role in supporting parent workers in the retail and service economy, but their wages are some of the
lowest in the sector.
I liken the child care sector to an iceberg. At the top are the workers in the formal part of the sector — those
workers captured in standard economic reports. Below them is an equally large number of workers who are
formal, regulated providers but are too small to be captured in standard economic census data. Below them are
the large number of informal providers also not counted in economic data. The foundation of it all is unpaid
relative and parental care. This unpaid care represents the majority of care — part of the unpaid household
economy.
Figure 2: Counting Child Care Workers
Note: Based in part on Burton, A., Whitebrook, M., Young, M., Bellm, D., Wayne, C., Brandon, R., et al. (2002). Estimating the Size and
Components of the U.S. Child Care Workforce and Caregiving Population: Key Findings from the Child Care Workforce Estimate.
Washington, DC and Seattle: Center for the Child Care Workforce and Human Services Policy Center. Extrapolating from data on 6,936
households' use of out-of-home care for children aged 0-5, Burton et al. (2002) estimated the child care work force for this age group at
2.5 million paid workers. This estimate is considerably larger than the 800,000 estimate of the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) (based
on establishment reports), or the 1.7 million estimated by the Current Population Survey (CPS). They also calculated unpaid nonparental
care to be an additional 2.5 million persons, 93 percent of whom are unpaid relatives. Although this unpaid care is not counted in
standard economic accounts, it makes a substantial economic contribution. Unpaid parental care was not included in their estimates.
Because of this complexity — the mixture of formal, informal, and non-market care, and public, for-profit, and
nonprofit providers — it has been difficult for economic developers to recognize the potential for economic
development strategies to strengthen the sector. Attention to the public benefits in terms of long-term human
capital development has caused most economists to focus solely on the preschool portion of the sector. But many
business leaders see the lack of child care support for their workers as an immediate problem that begs for
solution.
Most Fortune 500 companies have moved forward in exploring workplace policies that promote flexibility for
parents and enhance access to care (Shellenback 2004). Sometimes this means subsidizing employees' child care
expenses, buying spaces in child care centers, or providing onsite child care. Increasingly, business leaders are
concluding that adequate child care supply should be a part of the social infrastructure for economic development
— not the private problem of families or individual employers. As Tompkins County, New York, Chamber of
Commerce President Jeanne McPheeters noted in a 2004 interview, "The business community does not believe
that one parent should have to stay home to care for children. Child care supports both working parents —
fathers and mothers."
Broadening Economic Development Policy Debates
The interest shown in child care by chambers of commerce reflects the concerns of business leaders. Since 2000,
more than 50 states and localities have organized teams of child care leaders, government policymakers, and
business leaders to assess the regional economic impact of the child care sector. (For a complete list of these
state and local teams, visit
economicdevelopment.cce.cornell.edu). These teams have relied on the advice of the Cornell
University team (available in Ribeiro and Warner 2004), the National Economic Development and Law Center in California,
or local universities to conduct their studies. All teams have been frustrated by the inadequate picture of the
sector that standard economic data provide. A complete discussion of these data problems is provided in Ribeiro
and Warner (2004) and Warner (forthcoming).
Typically these studies describe the size of the sector — number and type of providers, children and parents
served, prices and costs faced by parents, and relevant government supports, for example. Many studies describe
the industries where parents work and use this to launch collaborations with those sectors. Special emphasis is
often given to the role of government policy — especially with regard to subsidies to lower-income working
parents — and how these subsidies could be enhanced or linked with business supports to enhance access and
quality (Warner et al. 2003).
Most of the studies also go one step further and calculate the linkage or multiplier effect of child care on the state
or regional economy. They find child care compares well in direct employment and in its linkage effects to other
industries that are more typical targets of economic development policy. An analysis of all 50 states, using
regional input-output models (IMPLAN), finds these relationships to be stable across states (Liu, Ribeiro, and
Warner 2004; Warner and Liu 2005).
These results are not without their detractors. Some economists argue child care work should not be counted as a
sector in the formal economy because it represents commodified household production. Some study teams have
gone to great lengths to discount the education portion of the sector, arguing that only the portion of the sector
that enables parents to work makes a contribution to the regional economy (BBC Research and Consulting 2003).
However, most teams recognize that child care's economic contribution is broader and includes education for
children, work supports for parents, and direct employment and regional linkage of the sector itself.
Planners are increasingly recognizing the important role that local service sectors play in direct employment,
provision of needed services, and regional economic integration (Markusen 2004, Warner and Liu 2005). Housing,
basic retail, and services designed for local consumption form a critical part of local quality of life (Clavel, Pitt, and
Yin 1997). Many urban areas lack sufficient retail services to meet local demand (BCG and ICIC 1998). The same
can be said of child care supply.
Recent economic development debates, stimulated in large measure by Richard Florida's 2002 book The Rise of
the Creative Class, have given more attention to local quality of life. However, Florida's focus has been primarily
on younger, generally childless, highly educated workers who enjoy entertainment, culture, and recreational
amenities. Florida has not given attention to the workers who staff such venues. Many of these cultural and
entertainment services are primary employers of working parents (Okuyama and Weber 2001). Planners
recognize the need to invest in services that support the economy as a whole — both the creative sector and the
sectors that support it.
Michael Porter (1995) has challenged planners to move beyond a focus on social supports and instead focus on
the competitive industries in the regional economy. He argues that if planners focus on helping these industries
become more competitive, then the additional resources necessary to enhance local services and quality of life
will result from the enhanced profitability of the private sector. Planners have responded that social supports
provide the foundation for economic development (Harrison and Glasmeier 1997). I argue that a balanced
approach is needed, one that recognizes the power of export-focused sectors and the need for investment in
quality of life and social supports for the broader population. Business leaders share a similar view in the concept
of the "triple bottom line," a business theory that argues investment in social and environmental improvements
will help long-term business profitability. As a society and an economy we have moved beyond simple solutions to
recognize the complexity of economic and community development and the need for balanced strategies.
Economic Development Strategies to Promote Quality Child Care
So how can economic development strategies be employed to improve quality and access in the child care sector?
First, we need to distinguish the challenges of an underdeveloped market, which can be addressed with economic
development solutions, from the problems of market failure, which require government regulation and
investment. Child care is both a public and private good. As a public good, society benefits from the long-term
investment in human capital for the future workforce. We also benefit from the expanded earnings and career
ladders that child care enables for working parents. Parents and the private market are likely to underinvest in
quality child care because the benefits are distributed society-wide and appear over the long term. These market
failures can be addressed with government regulations, to ensure quality subsidies that support access for
parents, and direct subsidies to providers to promote professionalizing the sector and to underwrite the cost of
high quality care. As a sector, child care does not benefit from the substitution of capital for labor, and thus
productivity (measured by the number of children served per teacher) is low. Low ratios ensure high-quality
interaction and education. Competition has been shown to erode quality in care work because cost pressures
encourage providers to increase the ratio of children to teachers (Folbre 2001). Thus, government regulatory and
subsidy policy is critical to ensure quality.
However, there are many areas in the child care market where economic development policies could be applied
with good effect. Recognizing that, as a private good, child care is purchased directly by parents, we can design
policies to increase demand for quality by providing better market information to parents on the quality of
different providers. Such information also would help reduce the search costs for parents as they seek
convenient, high-quality care that meets their social and cultural preferences. The emergence of intermediaries to
provide such information to parents also could help build better networks of communication among providers
themselves. Most child care providers are small businesses that lack economies of scale. While the direct
relationship between teacher and child should remain small to ensure the highest quality interaction, it is certainly
possible to achieve economies of scale in the administrative functions: billing, purchasing, and human resource
management (Stoney 2004a). It is also possible to use workforce development policy to support professionalizing
the sector and creating wage and career ladders within the child care sector itself, and addressing the needs of
working parents by providing child care when and where it is needed most. Examples are provided in Table 1.
Source: Warner et al 2004. Economic Development Strategies to Support Quality Child Care
Economic development policy at the local level focuses primarily on export attraction strategies, such as tax
abatements (Warner 2001). Such strategies can be applied to child care by providing tax credits to investors in
child care. Texas, Colorado, and Oregon have experimented with such approaches, and these are described in
more detail in Economic Development Strategies to Promote Quality Child Care.
However, economic development professionals recognize that export strategies have limited effectiveness, and
investments in productivity are likely to yield greater economic development returns (Bartik 2003). Planners
recognize that, in the long term, economic development is about sustainability and enhanced quality of life. The
purpose of economic development is community and human development as well as jobs and income. Figure 3
represents the three principles of economic development — exports, productivity, and sustainability — as the
three pillars that hold up the roof of economic development. The roof is presented as if the three pillars are equal
in height, but in reality, economic development policy at the local level is out of balance. The diagonal line shows
the path the roof truly follows: it slants downward from exports, the primary strategy; to productivity investment,
the secondary strategy; to sustainability, the least common approach to economic development. Incorporating
child care in economic development has the greatest impact on productivity and sustainability, and as such it can
help economic developers bring economic development policy back into balance.
Figure 3: Economic Development Principles and Strategies
Source: Warner et al 2004.
Planning Approaches Underway
Achieving this balance requires opening the economic development planning process to the child care community
and bringing in child care experts to help with economic development planning. For example, Vermont now
requires every town plan to include child care as one of 13 required elements. Local planning and development
boards in that state are now working with child care experts to identify key data needs, problems, and policy
interventions for the child care sector (Stoney 2004b). In California, similar planning efforts are being undertaken
at the county and city level. Land-use rules that restrict the placement of child care centers are being challenged,
and some communities are levying impact fees on new developers to ensure they build child care along with
housing in new developments (Anderson 2005). More information on all these examples can be found in
Economic
Development Strategies to Promote Quality Child Care.
Transportation
Planners are beginning to link transportation and child care by recognizing the journey to work is actually a
j
ourney to child care, then work. In Tennessee, bus routes have been reorganized and retimed to enable parents
to drop off children and proceed to work. In Florida and California, child care has been incorporated into the
transportation planning process, and in some cases child care centers have been located within transit hubs,
using Intermodal Surface Transportation Efficiency Act (ISTEA) dollars along with community development block
grant (CDBG) funds to defray construction costs.
Housing and Business Development
Child care is an eligible investment under both the federal
New Markets Tax Credit program and the CDBG program.
In Wisconsin, many communities are now building child care centers as part of industrial parks.
Financing
Perhaps the most work in connecting the child care sector to economic development has been done on facilities
finance. Efforts have been made by organizations such as the
National Children's Facilities Network; the Community
Investment Collaborative for Kids
, a program of the Local Initiatives Support Corporation (LISC) supported by the Annie E. Casey
Foundation; and two community development financial institutions (CDFIs): Coastal Enterprises, Inc., in Maine, and Self
Help
in North Carolina. Attracting private sector investment from banks seeking to meet their Community
Reinvestment Act
requirements has helped open up financing for some child care businesses.
Productivity Strategies: Realizing Economies of Scale
Productivity strategies (see Figure 4) can be applied to the child care sector to help achieve economies of scale
(Stoney 2004a). By recognizing child care as an economic sector in its own right, it is possible to apply business
retention and expansion strategies. In Ohio, intermediaries have built pools of substitute teachers that are shared
sector wide. In Virginia, a network provides managerial support to a wide range of home-based providers. In
North Carolina, Wisconsin, and Pennsylvania, child care and workforce development experts are exploring the
feasibility of using a private employer organization (PEO) as a model for providing health insurance and human
resource management. All of these strategies are described in more detail in
Economic Development Strategies to
Promote Quality Child Care.
Figure 4: Economic Development Principles — Productivity
Source: Warner et al 2004.
In collaboration with the Alliance for Early Childhood Finance (experts on financing in the child care sector) and the
Smart Start's National Technical Assistance Center (a networking and technical assistance provider to the child care sector
nation-wide), Cornell University is supporting a learning community of child care providers and economic
development professionals to address the importance of child care as an economic sector. The
W.K. Kellogg
Foundation
has taken a lead in providing funds for venture grants at the community level, national conferences to
share strategies, learning clusters networked via teleconferences, and publication of the resource guides produced
by Cornell University.
Conclusion
As Jeanne McPheeters, President of the Tompkins County, New York, Chamber of Commerce, says, "(Child care)
is more a community issue and not just a women's issue." Planners have a unique facilitating role to play in
bringing together planning, economic development, business and early childhood expertise to strengthen the child
care sector. The business and economic development communities are ready to engage, but it is critical they do
so as partners with child care experts. Proposals must broaden the focus beyond targeted preschool programs to
more adequately address the needs of children, parents, and their employers. Planners are in the perfect position
to facilitate a broader dialogue and ensure the voices of parents and providers are not ignored. The interest is
there, the time is ripe, and the background research has been done in many cities and states. The moment for
leadership by planners has arrived.
Mildred Warner is an associate professor in Cornell University's Department of City and Regional Planning. Her
research focuses on local economic development policy, local government and the role of social services in
economic development.
The Cornell University team can be contacted at
child care_econ@cornell.edu. Louise Stoney of the Alliance for Early
Childhood Finance
, Gerry Cobb of Smart Start
,
and Mildred Warner invite you to share your expertise and become part
of the learning community.
This research was supported by the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Administration for Children
and Families, Child Care Bureau research funds grant #90XC003 , and by the U.S. Department of Agriculture
Hatch Research Program administered by Cornell Agricultural Experiment Station Grant #NYC 121449 . The W.K.
Kellogg Foundation, in collaboration with Smart Start's National Technical Assistance Center, provides funding for
outreach. The analysis and interpretations do not reflect policy or position of the funders.
For More Information
All of the materials referenced in this PAS Memo may be found on Cornell University's
Linking Economic Development
and Child Care Project
website, but if you would like hard copies of the guides, please contact Smart Start at
gcobb@smartstart-nc.org.
References
Anderson, Kristen. 2005. Planning for Child Care in California. Point Arena, Calif.: Solano Press Books.
Bartik, Timothy J. 2003. Local Economic Development Policies. Kalamazoo, Mich.: Upjohn Institute for
Employment Research.
www.upjohninstitute.org/publications/wp/03-91.pdf
BBC Research and Consulting. 2003. Economic Impact of the Early Care and Education Industry in Larimer
County. Denver, Colo.: Larimer County Early Childhood Council.
www.larimer.org/compass/early_care_impact.pdf
BCG (Boston Consulting Group, Inc.) and ICIC (Initiative for a Competitive Inner City). 1998. The Business Case
for Pursuing Retail Opportunities in the Inner City.
www.icic.org/vsm/bin/smRenderFS.php?
PHPSESSID=61cd5543266ea038957922d1ef92cf31&cerror=
click on Publications, and search by title.
Bernstein, Nina. October 19, 2003. "Daily Choice Turned Deadly: Children Left on Their Own." The New York
Times.
Clavel, P., J. Pitt, and J. Yin. 1997. "The Community Option in Urban Policy." Urban Affairs Review. 32 (4): 435-
458.
Committee for Economic Development. 2002. Preschool for All: Investing in a Productive and Just Society.
www.ced.org/docs/report/report_preschool.pdf
Florida, Richard. 2002. The Rise of the Creative Class: And How It's Transforming Work, Leisure, Community and
Everyday Life. New York: Basic Books.
Folbre, Nancy. 2001. The Invisible Heart: Economics and Family Values. New York: New Press.
Gornick, Janet C., and Marcia K. Meyers. 2003. Families that Work: Policies for Reconciling Parenthood and
Employment. New York: Russell Sage Foundation Publications.
Halpern, Diane F. 2004. Public Policy, Work, and Families: The Report of the APA Presidential Initiative on Work
and Families. Washington, D.C.: American Psychological Association.
www.apa.org/work-family/fullreport.pdf
Harrington, Mona. 1999. Care and Equality: Inventing a New Family Politics. New York: Knopf.
Harrison, B., and A.K. Glasmeier. 1997. "Why business alone won't redevelop the inner city: A friendly critique of
Michael Porter's approach to urban revitalization — Response." Economic Development Quarterly. 11 (1): 28-38.
Heckman, James J., and Dimitriy V. Masterov. 2004. "The Productivity Argument for Investing in Young Children."
In Working Paper 5. Chicago: Invest in Kids Working Group, Committee for Economic Development.
Helburn, Suzanne W., and Barbara R. Bergmann. 2002. America's Child Care Problem: The Way Out. New York:
Palgrave Macmillan.
Kamerman, Sheila B. 2001. "An Overview of ECEC Developments in OECD Countries," in S. Kamerman ed. Early
Childhood Education and Care: International Perspectives International Aspects of Social Policy. New York:
Columbia University Institute for Child and Family Policy. pp 11-54.
Liu, Z., R. Ribeiro, and M. Warner. 2004. Comparing Child Care Multipliers in the Regional Economy: Analysis
from 50 States. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Department of City and Regional Planning.
government.cce.cornell.edu/doc/pdf/50States.pdf
Lynch, Robert G. 2004. Exceptional Returns: Economic, Fiscal and Social Benefits of Investment in Early
Childhood Development. Washington, D.C.: Economic Policy Institute.
Markusen, Ann. 2004. "Targeting Occupations in Regional and Community Economic Development." Journal of the
merican Planning Association. 70(3): 253-268.
Masse, Leonard N., and W. Steven Barnett. 2002. A Benefit-Cost Analysis of the Abecedarian Early Childhood
Intervention. New Brunswick, N.J.: National Institute for Early Education Research.
nieer.org/resources/research/AbecedarianStudy.pdf
Okuyama, Kumiko, and Roberta B. Weber. 2001. Parents Receiving Child Care Subsidies: Where Do They Work?
Albany, Ore.: Linn-Benton Community College, Oregon Child Care Research Partnership.
www.hhs.oregonstate.edu/familypolicy/occrp/publications/2001-Parents-Receiving-Child care-Subsidies.pdf
Porter, M.E. 1995. "The Competitive Advantage of the Inner City." Harvard Business Review, 73(3): 55-71.
Ribeiro, R., and M. Warner. 2004. Measuring the Regional Economic Importance of Early Child Care and
Education: The Cornell Methodology Guide. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Department of City and Regional
Planning.
government.cce.cornell.edu/doc/pdf/MethodologyGuide.pdf
Rolnick, A., and R. Grunewald. 2003. "Early Childhood Development: Economic Development with a High Public
Return." In Fedgazette: Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. March.
www.minneapolisfed.org/pubs/fedgaz/03-
03/earlychild.cfm
Schultz, Theodore W. 1961. "Investment in Human Capital." The American Economic Review 51:1 (March): 1-17.
Schweinhart, L.J., J. Montie, Z. Xiang, W.S. Barnett, C.R. Belfield, and M. Nores. 2005. Lifetime Effects: The
High/Scope Perry Preschool Study Through Age 40. Ypsilanti, Mich.: High/Scope Press.
Shellenback, Karen. 2004. Child Care and Parent Productivity: Making the Business Case. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell
Department of City and Regional Planning.
government.cce.cornell.edu/doc/pdf/Child careParentProductivity.pdf
Shore, Rima. 1997. Rethinking the Brain: New Insights into Early Development. New York: Families and Work
Institute.
Stoney, L. 2004a. Collective Management of Early Childhood Programs: Approaches that Aim to Maximize
Efficiency, Help Improve Quality and Stabilize the Industry. Raleigh, N.C.: Smart Start's National Technical
Assistance Center and Cornell University Department of City and Regional Planning.
Stoney, L. 2004b. Framing Child Care as Economic Development: Lessons from Early Studies. Ithaca NY: Cornell
University Department of City and Regional Planning.
government.cce.cornell.edu/doc/pdf/FramingChild care.pdf
Warner, M.E. 2001. "Local Government Support for Community-Based Economic Development," In The Municipal
Year Book 2001. Washington, D.C.: International City/County Management Association. pp. 21-27.
Warner, M.E., R. Ribeiro, and A.E. Smith. 2003. "Addressing the Affordability Gap: Framing Child Care as
Economic Development." Journal of Affordable Housing and Community Development Law, 12(3): 294-313.
Warner, M.E., S. Adriance, N. Barai, J. Hallas, B. Markeson, and W. Soref. 2004. Economic Development
Strategies to Promote Quality Child Care. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Department of City and Regional
Planning.
government.cce.cornell.edu/doc/pdf/EconDevStrat.pdf
Warner, M.E., and Z. Liu. 2005. "The Importance of Child Care in Economic Development: A Comparative Analysis
of Regional Economic Linkage." Economic Development Quarterly (forthcoming).
Warner, M.E. 2006. "Putting Child Care in the Regional Economy: Empirical and Conceptual Challenges Raised by
Regional Economic Impact Studies." Journal of the Community Development Society (Forthcoming special issue
on the economic importance of child care in the regional economy care).
©Copyright 2006 American Planning Association All Rights Reserved
... Planners have a unique facilitating role to play in bringing together planning, economic development, and business. Planners are in the perfect position to facilitate a broader dialogue and ensure the voices of communities that are ignored" (Warner, M. 2006). ...
Article
Full-text available
Town planning is defined as the art and science of ordering the use of land and the character and siting of buildings and communication routes so as to secure the maximum practicable degree of economy,convenience, health and beauty. So is the role of urban planners to manage and maintain this for the sustainability of the cities. They look for the present conditions of their surroundings and work to improve them and add new additions if required. But Unfortunately, lately, Pakistan lack planners in their said roles and responsibilities. The planners are not consulted before most of the urban development projects, thereby ignoring and not coordinating with various planning departments, the decisions of the government will become nothing but a blot on the future of already blighted cities. Hence there is a dire need to empower the planning profession in order to improve the urban contexts of our country. Sharing the field knowledge via hands-on workshops is a solution to better engage planners and help policymakers to internalize the findings. The Department of City and Regional Planning at the University of Management and Technology have gathered planners from all over Pakistan and asked for major planning issues and their subsequent suggestions to resolve these issues. Highlighted in the workshop, most of the core problems are related to housing, transportation, and sustainable development. The paper is basically to channel the findings of a workshop aiming at fostering discussions on urban issues among the professionals who're the ultimate stakeholders. Focusing on a multidimensional urban phenomenon, the paper aims to deepen the understanding of contemporary urban issues in Pakistan, leading toward the solutions to be adopted by government officials to advance progress and sustainability ultimately
... As child care organizations reach out to traditional economic development and planning organizations, challenges in collaboration arise. Differences in language and expertise, if not respected, can lead to dominance by planning and economic development leaders over the child care leaders (Warner 2006). Collaborations must strive to create "power with" child care leaders so it is a collaboration of equals. ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper challenges planners to incorporate child care into local economic development, land use, and transportation planning. For too long, child care has been ignored, but that is changing. The paper highlights innovative roles planners can play in facilitating new community approaches that promote inclusion of families with children. Children are expensive. Housing, recreation, schooling, and child care are all expensive services that families need and local communities must provide. In some communities, zoning ordinances restrict affordable family housing so the tax benefits of new development can be enjoyed without the burden of new demand for services. This is why inclusive zoning is so critical. If planners are to be socially responsible and promote inclusion, we must challenge regulatory barriers to serving children and family needs. Increasingly we are recognizing that children are an investment in our collective future and that communities should share with parents the burden of care. Planning for communities that support children and families is a critical inclusion challenge for planners. It is easy to use the planning process to restrict services and access. It is harder, and more expensive in the short term, to use the planning process to build a better child care infrastructure for families. There are political risks to doing so, but planners across the country are taking that risk. Planners are beginning to recognize child care as part of the social infrastructure for community development. Around the country more than 75 state and local teams of business, economic development, local government, and planners have formed in the last five years to study the economic impact of child care on the regional economy (Warner 2006a). This creates new opportunities to include attention to women, children, and family issues in local planning.
Chapter
Since the nineteenth century, when institutions for the education and care of young children outside the home first emerged in the West, rationales for supporting preschool and kindergarten, on the one hand, and child care, on the other, have varied over time and place and differed from one another. While some focus on the benefits of services to the children themselves, others point to the ways in which such services may, in fact, benefit society as a whole.
Article
For the past decade or so, the “social investment” paradigm has been sweeping policy debates across Western Europe and the United States, especially in the domain of Early Childhood Education and Care, where the ideas of economist James Heckman have been widely influential. This shift has led to a greater support for policies in this realm, but at what cost? This essay looks at earlier rationalizations for such policies in the United States and then examines the origins and spread of social investment thinking, concluding with an assessment of its consequences—practical, political, and philosophical.
Article
The purpose of this study was to examine similarities and differences in the perceptions of childcare among American, Chinese, Japanese and Swedish early childhood teachers. Participants consisted of 78 American teachers, 156 Chinese teachers, 158 Japanese teachers, and 157 Swedish teachers. The results of quantitative analysis revealed that these teachers had perceptions about childcare that were both similar and different. Both Chinese and Swedish teachers focused on the importance of gender equality in relation to childcare more than Japanese and American teachers did. Although American, Chinese and Swedish teachers viewed children developing attachments with their mothers in a positive light regardless of whether they are blood related, Japanese teachers considered that children's attachments should be only with their biological mothers because they value blood relations between the child and the mother. Both American and Japanese teachers shared similar notions about group care, indicating positive perceptions about such care, but their notions were not as strong as those of their Chinese and Swedish counterparts. The implications for early childhood education are presented.
Article
Full-text available
In the past four years, more than fifty states and localities have formed teams that have attempted to measure the economic importance of child care from a regional perspective, from a labor mobilization perspective, and from a human development perspective. Conceptual and empirical problems abound. Data to measure these economic effects are inadequate, in part because data systems were not designed to count care work. Conceptually, the fit with economic models is awkward. This suggests the need for new regional economic paradigms and new data systems. Recognizing the child care system as an underdeveloped market also offers the potential for new approaches to economic development policy, if the conceptual and methodological challenges can be overcome.
Article
This article analyzes why and how economic and community development planners might target occupations as well as industries in shaping an economic development strategy. Key occupations can be identified on the basis of captura-bility, high relative employment growth rates, connectivity across industries, fit with underemployed workforce groups, and potential for entrepreneurship. I demonstrate the potential for targeting occupations with quantitative and qualitative evidence on performing arts occupations for a set of medium-sized metropolitan areas and make the case for occupational location and development theories analogous to those for industry. I close by outlining steps planners can follow to incorporate occupational targeting into their work.
Article
Over the last few years, the future of Minnesota's economy has been called into question. The resulting debate illustrates how little is understood about the fundamentals that underlie economic development. While many recognize the success of the Minnesota economy in the past, they see a weakening in the foundations of that success. Some point to the decline in corporate headquarters located in Minnesota. Some point to the lack of funding for new startup companies, particularly in the areas of high-tech and biotech. Some point to the possible loss of professional sports teams. Some think the University of Minnesota is not visible enough in the business community. And still others raise the broader concern that Minnesota's citizens and policymakers have become too complacent and unwilling to make the public commitment to be competitive in a global economy. Those who raise these concerns conclude that Minnesota and local governments need to take a more active role in promoting our economy. Often that implies that the state or local governments subsidize private activities that the market is not funding. Proponents of this view argue that without such subsidies, either well-deserving businesses will not get funded or other states will lure our businesses to greener pastures. State and local subsidies to private businesses are not new. In the name of economic development and creating new jobs, Minnesota, and virtually every other state in the union, has a long history of subsidizing private businesses. We have argued in previous studies that the case for these subsidies is short-sighted and fundamentally flawed.1 From a national perspective, jobs are not created—they are only relocated. From a state and local perspective, the economic gains are suspect because many would have been realized without the subsidies. In summary, what often passes for economic development and sound public investment is neither. If subsidizing private businesses is the wrong way to promote Minnesota's economy, then what is the right way? To answer this question, we need to understand that unfettered markets generally allocate scarce resources to their most productive use. Consequently, governments should only intervene in markets when they fail. Market failures can occur for a variety of reasons; two well-documented failures are goods that have external effects or public attributes. Unfettered markets will generally produce the wrong amount of such goods. Education has long been recognized as a good that has external effects and public attributes. Without public support, the market will yield too few educated workers and too little basic research. This problem has long been understood in the United States and it is why our government, at all levels, has supported public funding for education. (According to the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development, for example, the United States in 1999 ranked high on public funding of higher education. 2 ) Nevertheless, recent studies suggest that one critical form of education, early childhood development, or ECD, is grossly underfunded. However, if properly funded and managed, investment in ECD yields an extraordinary return, far exceeding the return on most investments, private or public.