ArticlePDF Available

Land Policy and the Informal City in Nigeria

Authors:

Abstract

SUMMARY The arguments in Nigeria over whether the urban or the rural areas should be given greater priority in national development appear somewhat misplaced and unhelpful because the urban and rural areas are mutually interdependent, with many complex links and interactions between them, and the constant movements of people, goods, money, ideas and information from one to the other. For this reason, the Habitat Agenda of the Istanbul City Summit advocates "an integrated approach to promote balanced and mutually supportive urban-rural development (through) strong local and national institutions that place emphasis on rural- urban linkages, and treat villages and towns as two sides of the human settlement continuum" The paper considers ways to overcome the traditional divide between urban and rural planning and development, and by so doing achieve a balanced and more sustainable pattern of development and poverty reduction. It focuses on the promotion of small and intermediate urban centres as an appropriate middle course which combines the advantages of urban as well as rural approaches to development, but without the disadvantages of large population concentrations in a few metropolitan areas, or of the wide dispersal of investments and scarce resources in scattered villages too small to support basic services. Medium and small towns are uniquely placed in the urban-rural interface to foster mutually beneficial linkages between them, and also to promote the more sustainable use of natural resources in the surrounding region. Recent research suggests that more than half of the urban population in Africa lives in urban centres of this size group, and that the massive increase in urban population expected in the next 20 years will occur in these small towns, hence the urgent need to take their growth, planning and links with the rural areas fully into account in the development effort. The paper then discusses the policy, planning and investment implications of promoting medium and small towns as a way to enhance urban-rural linkages, drawing ideas from the Habitat Agenda, and other recent global initiatives that seek to support sustainable urbanization and the Millennium Development Goals. Particular emphasis is placed on the imperative of political and administrative decentralization to strengthen local government, especially with the recent creation of 36 States and 774 Local Governments Areas in Nigeria; the need to improve the infrastructure and services that connect producers and consumers in rural and urban areas; reforms in the macro-economic and regulatory framework to support rural agriculture and trade, and to remove needless constraints on the operation of the private sector, especially the informal sector and small-scale enterprises. Finally, the paper points out that the promotion of medium and small towns should not be seen as a substitute for direct programmes of urban and rural development, but rather as an essential and often overlooked component of a national policy for a balanced development of the whole range of human settlements in the country.
TS 35 – Informal Settlements: Policy, Land Use and Tenure
Geoffrey I. Nwaka
Land Policy and the Informal City in Nigeria
From Pharaohs to Geoinformatics
FIG Working Week 2005 and GSDI-8
Cairo, Egypt April 16-21, 2005
1/13
Land Policy and the Informal City in Nigeria
Geoffrey I. NWAKA, Nigeria
Key words: Decentralized urbanization, Urban-rural linkages
SUMMARY
The arguments in Nigeria over whether the urban or the rural areas should be given greater
priority in national development appear somewhat misplaced and unhelpful because the
urban and rural areas are mutually interdependent, with many complex links and interactions
between them, and the constant movements of people, goods, money, ideas and information
from one to the other. For this reason, the Habitat Agenda of the Istanbul City Summit
advocates "an integrated approach to promote balanced and mutually supportive urban-rural
development (through) strong local and national institutions that place emphasis on rural-
urban linkages, and treat villages and towns as two sides of the human settlement continuum"
The paper considers ways to overcome the traditional divide between urban and rural
planning and development, and by so doing achieve a balanced and more sustainable pattern
of development and poverty reduction. It focuses on the promotion of small and intermediate
urban centres as an appropriate middle course which combines the advantages of urban as
well as rural approaches to development, but without the disadvantages of large population
concentrations in a few metropolitan areas, or of the wide dispersal of investments and scarce
resources in scattered villages too small to support basic services. Medium and small towns
are uniquely placed in the urban-rural interface to foster mutually beneficial linkages between
them, and also to promote the more sustainable use of natural resources in the surrounding
region. Recent research suggests that more than half of the urban population in Africa lives in
urban centres of this size group, and that the massive increase in urban population expected in
the next 20 years will occur in these small towns, hence the urgent need to take their growth,
planning and links with the rural areas fully into account in the development effort.
The paper then discusses the policy, planning and investment implications of promoting
medium and small towns as a way to enhance urban-rural linkages, drawing ideas from the
Habitat Agenda, and other recent global initiatives that seek to support sustainable
urbanization and the Millennium Development Goals. Particular emphasis is placed on the
imperative of political and administrative decentralization to strengthen local government,
especially with the recent creation of 36 States and 774 Local Governments Areas in Nigeria;
the need to improve the infrastructure and services that connect producers and consumers in
rural and urban areas; reforms in the macro-economic and regulatory framework to support
rural agriculture and trade, and to remove needless constraints on the operation of the private
sector, especially the informal sector and small-scale enterprises. Finally, the paper points out
that the promotion of medium and small towns should not be seen as a substitute for direct
programmes of urban and rural development, but rather as an essential and often overlooked
component of a national policy for a balanced development of the whole range of human
settlements in the country.
TS 35 – Informal Settlements: Policy, Land Use and Tenure
Geoffrey I. Nwaka
Land Policy and the Informal City in Nigeria
From Pharaohs to Geoinformatics
FIG Working Week 2005 and GSDI-8
Cairo, Egypt April 16-21, 2005
2/13
Using Medium and Small Towns to Strengthen Urban-Rural
Linkages in Nigeria
Geoffrey I. NWAKA, Nigeria
1. INTRODUCTION
This paper examines the case for promoting medium and small towns as a way to achieve
balanced and equitable growth and development in Nigeria. After a brief review of the rapid
rate and uneven pattern of urbanisation in the country, the paper comments critically on past
development policies which overlooked the interdependence and complementary links
between the urban and rural areas, and concludes with some general reflections on how the
development of smaller urban centres could support the current programmes for
decentralization, rural transformation and poverty alleviation.
The development of small and intermediate urban centres has for the past several years been
canvassed by many scholars and influential aid agencies as an appropriate middle course,
which combines the advantages of urban as well as rural development, without the
shortcomings of excessive metropolitan growth or of the wide dispersal of limited resources
in scattered rural villages too small to support basic services. Following independence, many
African governments assumed that to concentrate productive activities and services in a few
large cities would bring about faster growth, the benefits of which would spontaneously
trickle down to the other sectors of the economy. Indeed many planners and policy makers
still maintain that rapid urban growth is inevitable and desirable, and that it would be
counterproductive to intervene prematurely to deconcentrate economic activities, or to unduly
disperse large population agglomerations (Egan, 1985; Egan and Bendrick, 1986). On the
other hand critics of large city bias complain that the top heavy pattern of urbanisation and
development is both unjust and inefficient; that economic development is not reaching the
poor because resources are disproportionately allocated in favour of the urban areas at the
expense of the countryside where the bulk of the people still live. To restore parity and health
in urban and rural development they urge developing countries to correct the policy
imbalances, and discourage urban privilege which attracts rural migration to compound the
problems and inefficiencies of the large cities (Todaro, 1981; Lipton, 1977).
Because of these pro-urban and anti-urban stereotypes, urban and rural development have
been misconceived as parallel or even antagonistic lines of development, ignoring the
mutually supportive elements between them. The advocacy of small town policies is based on
the belief that urbanisation is not necessarily detrimental to rural progress, and that it is the
unbalanced pattern of urbanisation rather than urban growth per se that may have created
disparities in the past. A more dispersed pattern of urban settlements, with a fair amount of
middle and lower order urban centres would not only relieve pressure on the large cities, but
would also stimulate and support regional, rural and agricultural development, increase the
proportion of people reached by basic services, and thus help to achieve the current
Millennium Development Goals (World Bank, 2003). The so called Urban Functions in Rural
TS 35 – Informal Settlements: Policy, Land Use and Tenure
Geoffrey I. Nwaka
Land Policy and the Informal City in Nigeria
From Pharaohs to Geoinformatics
FIG Working Week 2005 and GSDI-8
Cairo, Egypt April 16-21, 2005
3/13
Development (UFRD) approach is essentially a way of assessing the settlement system within
a given area in order to distribute investments and productive activities more efficiently and
equitably (Rondinelli, 1982; Kammeier and Swan, 1984; Bromley, 1983).
In spite of its wide appeal, critics of the small town approach, especially in political economy
literature, contend that the claims about its merits are purely hypothetical, and that the
prevailing political and economic structures in most developing countries are incompatible
with the equity ideals which the approach seeks to promote. In the circumstances, small
towns are more likely to promote exploitation than equitable growth, and to constitute a
blockage on rural progress (Southall, 1979; Southall, 1988).
1.1 Policy Debate on Medium and Small Towns
Several research groups and donor organizations have sponsored studies and conferences to
consider the benefits and shortcomings of promoting small towns; the role which this
category of urban centres can play in regional and national development, and the appropriate
policy instruments to foster these roles (World Bank, 2003; UNDP/UND-Habitat, 1995).
There are several unresolved questions about the exact size of settlements to promote, how to
identify those with the potential to support rural development and how to ensure that they do,
in fact, enhance the progress of the countryside. The proponents of the approach recognise
that the concept cannot be uniformly applied since towns of various sizes perform different
functions in different contexts; but settlements of between 5000 and 100,000 population
range are favoured because more than half of the urban population in Africa lives in uran
centres in this population range, and because they are better placed to foster the economic
interdependence between urban based enterprises and rural consumers, and between rural
producers and urban markets (Tacoli and Satterthwaite, in World Bank 2003).
Settlements in this size group have often been bypassed in the development effort when they
should in fact play a crucial role as the hubs of local economic, political, and social
development. They reflect a more dispersed pattern of urbanisation which should reinforce
the trend towards greater political decentralisation - to relieve the central government of
worsening administrative and financial burdens, and ensure a more broad based approach to
development. They should “provide the lower end of a decentralized administrative and
political hierarchy, channelling local concerns bottom up, and articulating government
objectives top down” (UNCHS-Habitat, 1981, p. 26).
Even more important, they are an effective tool for integrating the urban and rural economies,
and for achieving a balanced distribution of urban populations. If the appropriate linkages are
established, medium and small towns would greatly relieve the pressure on the overstrained
infrastructure, services and resources of the large cities, by deflecting the flood of migrants,
and helping to disperse the clustering of industrial and commercial activities there. They
would also provide the urban based support functions for the improvement and
commercialisation of the rural agricultural economy. As well, improved rural productivity,
increased opportunities for investments, and for non-farm employment in agro-processing
and small scale manufacturing enterprises would enhance rural incomes and purchasing
TS 35 – Informal Settlements: Policy, Land Use and Tenure
Geoffrey I. Nwaka
Land Policy and the Informal City in Nigeria
From Pharaohs to Geoinformatics
FIG Working Week 2005 and GSDI-8
Cairo, Egypt April 16-21, 2005
4/13
power, and thus improve the quality of rural life (Tacoli, 1998). A wide range of civic
services - for health care, education, transportation, religious and cultural activities - could be
provided in these towns at economically more attainable and accessible levels for the benefit
of the surrounding rural areas. Innovative ideas and methods are also easily diffused through
various channels to the rural households.
As indicated earlier, the concept and its application have been battered on both sides by those
who advocate direct rural investments, and those who endorse a more concerted and focused
approach to the development effort. With the prolonged recession and economic crisis of the
1980s and ‘90s, and the increasing tempo of globalization, many scholars caution developing
countries against socially and politically motivated policies of geographical balance and
small town creation, which run counter to the efficient and productive functioning of the
national economy, and are in any case difficult to enforce in free enterprise economies.
Besides, policies of spatial balance do not necessarily gaurantee social equality, as the
welfare of a place is not the same as the welfare of all the people who live there. Locating
social services and facilities in small towns, nearer the rural dwellers, does not necessarily
gaurantee access to these facilities, or provide the resources required by the peasants to avail
themselves of the services and opportunities (Egan, 1986; Dias, 1984). Above all it is argued
that since the rural people depend for most of their income on what they produce in the rural
area, direct rural investment is preferable to going through the intermediary of small and
medium towns, especially if direct links can be established between the rural areas and the
existing large cities. It is also common for brokers and middlemen to shortcircuit the small
towns and do business directly in the villages and periodic markets. A 1988 conferences on
small towns organised in Wisconsin Madison suggested from the experience of African
countries surveyed that small towns could worsen rather than remove social inequalities,
since most African governments tend to preach egalitarian ideologies but follow elitist and
centralist practices (Southall, 1988).
Granting these limitations, it would still seem that the weaknesses of the small town approach
arise more from defective implementation and political constraints than from any inhererent
defects in the logic of the concept itself, especially if small towns are seen not as a substitute
for but as complementary to national policies for urban and rural development. This is even
more true now that urban and rural livelihoods are becoming more and more interwined, with
increased flow of people, goods, ideas and other resources, and both urban and rural areas
acquiring more and more of the characteristics of each other (Hundzalz, 2001).
2. THE NIGERIAN EXPERIENCE
2.1 Trends and Patterns of Urban Growth
Unlike some African countries which have an explicit “District Focus” development
approach, Nigeria has no policies designed explicitly to promote medium and small towns;
but recent and current programmes for administrative decentralization and rural development
are consistent with the small town approach. The break up of Nigeria’s four former regions
TS 35 – Informal Settlements: Policy, Land Use and Tenure
Geoffrey I. Nwaka
Land Policy and the Informal City in Nigeria
From Pharaohs to Geoinformatics
FIG Working Week 2005 and GSDI-8
Cairo, Egypt April 16-21, 2005
5/13
into thirty six states, as well as the recent creation of as many as 774 local government areas
have fostered the growth of intermediate and small urban centres as the capitals of the new
states, and the headquarters of the new local governments. Also the development of roads and
economic oriented infrastructure through various central and state government directorates
and agencies could help to provide the necessary conditions and linkages needed for the
effective implementation of small town policies.
Nigeria is a vast country of some 923,768 square kilometers, with a disputed population of
about 125 million. Large cities had already developed in various parts of Nigeria long before
the establishment of British rule; but colonial change altered the pre-existing organization of
space and encouraged the emergence of many new centres of administration, trade and
transportation. The role of colonial cities was, however, narrowly conceived as enclaves for
external trade, with few productive links with the countryside, in spite of the obsession with
indirect rule.
Between 1952 and 1963 - the years for which reliable census figures are available, the
number of cities with population exceeding 20,000 rose from 56 to 183. By 1963 there were
24 cities with over 100,000 people, 55 with over 50,000, and 183 with over 20,000. Of the
183 cities with 20,000 and above, seventy were located in the northern parts of the country,
seventy-eight in the west, twenty nine in the east and six in the mid-western region. The vast
middle-belt region and parts of the deep north were grossly underserved by the urban system.
The import substituting industrialization policies of the 1960s worsened the uneven pattern of
urbanization, with the growth of certain distinct zones of urban concentration: the
Lagos/Ikeja-Ibadan cluster to the southwest, the Port Harcourt-Aba-Onitsha-Enugu group of
cities to the east, the Kano-Kaduna-Zaria axis to the north, and the chain of urban centres in
the Benin-Sapele-Warri area. (Mabogunje, 1977; Okafor, 1985). These large concentrations
attracted a disproportionately high percentage of national industrial investments, modern
infrastructure and productive resources, as well as commercial, administrative and
educational facilities. Estimates suggest that the total urban population in the country had
risen from 29.89 million or 31 percent of the national population in 1985 to 38.29 million or
34 percent of the population in 1990. Estimates at the turn of the century suggest that 43.5 per
cent of the population live in urban areas, up from 39 percent in 1986, and is projected to
reach 50 per cent by the year 2000, and 65 percent by 2020. The rate of urban growth is
thought to be 5.5 per cent, roughly double the national population growth rate of 2.9 percent.
By 1995, there were seven cities with populations that exceeded one million, 18 cities with
over 500,000; 36 with over 20,000; 78 with over 100,000, and over 5050 with more than
20,000. Lagos the former national capital has grown from 1.4 million in 1963 to 3.5 million
in 1975; is now thought to be six million, and projected to be 24 million by 2020 (Okunlola,
2001).
2.2 Urban-Rural Relations, and Small Town Policies
Nearly all Nigerian development plans have announced policies that pay lip service to rural
development and urban-rural balance. The Ten Year Plan of Development and Welfare,
1945-1956, emphasized the need to “simultaneously develop urban and rural areas... in order
TS 35 – Informal Settlements: Policy, Land Use and Tenure
Geoffrey I. Nwaka
Land Policy and the Informal City in Nigeria
From Pharaohs to Geoinformatics
FIG Working Week 2005 and GSDI-8
Cairo, Egypt April 16-21, 2005
6/13
to prevent any further flow of people from the country to the town with the attendant
consequences of squalor, unemployment and crime”. The Nigerian Town and Country
Planning Ordinance of 1946 established the legal basis for urban and regional planning; but
its provisions have been widely flouted and ignored. The first truly national plan after
independence, covering the period 1962 to 1968, pledged to “achieve a more equitable
distribution of income both among people and among regions”. The Second Plan 1970-1974
aimed at laying the basis not only for a self-reliant nation, but also of a dynamic economy,
and a just, egalitarian, free and democratic society, with full opportunities for all citizens. The
Third Plan, 1975-1980 contained a formal commitment to regional planning and rural
development, and advanced fresh proposals to ensure “integrated urban-rural development
based on the recognition of the vital function of each segment and the need to equip it for its
role in the overall development of the economy”; and the Fourth and last plan (1981-85)
promised “to revitalise and transform the Nigerian rural sector, and enhance the quality of
rural life”, through a more balanced allocation of investments and development effort.
In practice urban and rural development programmes have been merely juxtaposed, poorly
coordinated and undermined by resource and organisational constraints. Programmes for
rural development aimed at improving agricultural productivity and export earnings, and
ensuring self sufficiency in food, were marred by organizational bottlenecks and the
disadvantageous pricing policies of the marketing boards. After the disruptions of the civil
war, 1967-70, the military administration of General Gowon accorded agriculture “the
highest order of priority”, and launched the National Accelerated Food Production
Programme, NAFPP, which involved government in direct food production, to check the
escalating prices of local and imported food items. The results were as disappointing as the
equally extravagant Operation Feed The Nation (OFN) programme of the General Obasanjo
regime in the late 1970s. The ambitious programmes of Integrated Rural Development
through River Basin Development Authorities and Agricultural Development Projects, ADPs,
cost the nation more money than the results they produced. The planning defects and dismal
performance of rural agricultural development projects have been extensively discussed in
the literature, and need not detain us here (see Ukwu, 1983; Sokari George, 1987). Vast
amounts of resources were misallocated or otherwise misappropriated in projects of doubtful
priority, scattered thinly over widely dispersed rural villages (Onyemelukwe, 1980).
Direct rural development effort was further undermined by the phenomenal expansion of the
urban sector during the oil boom of the post civil war period of the 1970. The massive
increase in urban-based jobs - in administration, construction and commerce, as well as
generous wage increases accelerated the rate of urban migration, and widened urban-rural
disparities, even though there was also an increase in urban poverty. The large towns were
growing larger, and the smaller ones were not doing so well. Of the 2,215 industrial
establishments employing ten or more workers in Nigeria in 1975, the leading seven cities -
Lagos, Kano, Port Harcourt, Benin City, Jos, Ibadan and Enugu accounted for 68.2 percent.
Rapid urban growth appears to have speeded up rural agricultural decline. Government was
forced to meet food deficits through import, the bill for which rose from 126.3 million naira
in 1973 to 1.5 billion in 1980, just as agricultures contribution to export receipts had dropped
from as high as 83 percent in 1960 to as low as 06 per cent in 1977 (Fair, 1984).
TS 35 – Informal Settlements: Policy, Land Use and Tenure
Geoffrey I. Nwaka
Land Policy and the Informal City in Nigeria
From Pharaohs to Geoinformatics
FIG Working Week 2005 and GSDI-8
Cairo, Egypt April 16-21, 2005
7/13
Small towns received hardly any attention in the planning effort; and the large cities were
allowed to develop in a disorderly manner. A new Federal Ministry of Housing, Urban
Development and Environment was set up in 1975 to coordinate urban policy, but was soon
afterwards absorbed by the powerful Ministry of Works and Housing. Ambitious
programmes of urban housing and infrastructure development were initiated but were heavily
politicised and inequitably distributed. Over 200 towns in the country acquired new master-
plans to guide their development; but most of them achieved less than 30 per cent
implementation before the recession set in. Aggressive campaigns for environmental
sanitation turned out to be an instrument for the demolition of squatter settlements and the
harassment of the urban informal sector.
2.3 The Recession and Decentralisation
As oil prices dropped and export earnings declined, there was renewed interest in agricultural
development and other forms of adjustment, including deregulation and economic
liberalization, the abolition of marketing boards and restrictive pricing policies, and the
encouragement of greater private sector participation in the development process. In response
to the prolonged economic crisis and the weakening capacity of the state, the trend of
development thinking has shifted in favour of the principles of enablement, decentralization
and partnership as essential elements of good governance and sustainable urbanisation. To
relieve pressure on the central government, already overburdened by debt repayment,
decentralisation assumed a new importance. For political and military reasons the four former
regions of Nigeria had been broken up into twelve states at the onset of the civil war in 1967.
Seven additional states were created in 1976, and two more in 1986, bringing the total
number to twenty-one. By 1995 the number of states had risen to 36. The capitals of the new
states (see table 1) have developed into medium-sized centres at which decisions and
initiatives about development are taken for regional growth. The new state structure, more
than the regional arrangement that preceded it, provides a wider spread of centres for
administration, growth and development. Also to decongest Lagos, the government embarked
on the costly project to build and relocate the national capital in the frontier region of Abuja.
The decentralising impact of state creation on the distribution of urban populations and urban
opportunities was, however, fairly limited because of the vast size of the country. By 1989,
the states had populations ranging from 2,053,000 in Niger State to 9,926,000 in Kano State.
Niger, which was the smallest state was still two times the size of Botswana, and two and half
times the size of the Gambia. There was still the problem of urban primacy at the level of the
States. In Lagos, Kano and Rivers States, for instance, the capital cities of Lagos/Ikeja, Kano
City and Port Harcourt dominated the entire urban scene, and inhibited the growth of other
urban centres. Their impact on the remote rural areas of the states was bound to be limited
given the poorly developed transport connections between the state capitals and parts of their
rural hinterlands. As indicated above, the number of states has since been increased to 36,
with more far reaching decentralizing implications.
Happily, far reaching reforms have since 1976 also been introduced in the system of local
government “to further decentralise significant functions of the state governments to the local
TS 35 – Informal Settlements: Policy, Land Use and Tenure
Geoffrey I. Nwaka
Land Policy and the Informal City in Nigeria
From Pharaohs to Geoinformatics
FIG Working Week 2005 and GSDI-8
Cairo, Egypt April 16-21, 2005
8/13
level in order to enhance rapid development and stem rural to urban drift” (Federal Republic
of Nigeria: Guidelines, 1976). The reforms are guided by the idea of development from
below, to help redress the country’s inadequately developed system of lower and middle level
urban centres, and to enhance grassroots participation in the development effort. The reforms
are also specifically meant to strengthen the financial and managerial capacity of the local
governments, and to make them more development oriented. By May 1989 the number of
local governments was increased from 304 to 449. Several others illegally created during the
Second Republic were disbanded by the Buhari regime. But following further
decentralization, especially during the Babangida era, as many as 774 local governments
were created and some of the local governments cut across urban and rural areas. The
headquarters of these local government areas are being upgraded and developed as centres of
small scale manufacturing and commercial activities, in addition to their traditional
administrative and service functions. With the appropriate physical and economic linkage,
they provide an appropriate framework for creating third tier urban centres, nearer the life
and work of the rural people, and better placed for effective outreach to the surrounding
countryside.
Other initiatives to improve rural infrastructure and services have since been taken to further
enhance the development of medium and small towns. The 1986 Federal budget speech had
inaugurated an ambitious programme to “revitalise and transform the Nigerian rural sector
and enhance the quality of rural life” through the powerful and well funded Directorate for
Food, Roads and Rural Infrastructure (DFRRI), which had a broad mandate to liaise with
federal, state and local government authorities and agencies, as well as with local
communities and private organizations, to promote food production and rehabilitation of rural
feeder roads, and provide other forms of economic oriented infrastructure. Ancillary
Directorates for Mass Mobilization (MAMSER), for Employment, and for vocational training
and apprenticeship have also been established to promote rural development and informal
sector enterprises.
Thus, the decentralising impact of the creation of several states and local governments, and
the initiatives in rural infrastructure development provide a potentially favourable basis for
the development of secondary cities oriented to the development of the countryside. But as
with many other promising ideas in third world development, the gap between potential and
actual performance is still usually very wide.
2.4 Using Medium and Small Towns to Enhance Rural-Urban Linkages
It would be unhelpful to generalise or prescribe a single uniform approach for all the towns
and sectors of a country as large and diverse as Nigeria. But it is important to identify the
policy, planning and investment implications of the actual and potential linkages between
rural and urban development, and highlight how small towns can be used to promote regional
development and poverty alleviation. Some of the global action agendas of the 1990s,
especially Agenda 21 of the Rio Earth Summit and the Habitat Agenda of the Istanbul City
Summit provide useful guides that could profitably be adapted to local conditions in Nigeria
and other developing countries. The Habitat Agenda for instance advocates “an integrated
TS 35 – Informal Settlements: Policy, Land Use and Tenure
Geoffrey I. Nwaka
Land Policy and the Informal City in Nigeria
From Pharaohs to Geoinformatics
FIG Working Week 2005 and GSDI-8
Cairo, Egypt April 16-21, 2005
9/13
approach to promote balanced and mutually supportive urban-rural development” through
“strong local and national institutions... that place emphasis on rural-urban linkages and treat
villages and towns as two sides of the human settlement continuum”. (UN-Habitat 1998).
To accomplish this, current research on best practices suggests among other things the need
to create strong local government systems through genuine decentralization; the need to
support urban based informal/small enterprises sector which have strong links to and
influence on rural livelihoods; to emphasize linkages rather than boundaries in local
administrations and economies. These areas of emphasis have implications for the current
programmes of political restructuring and decentralization in Nigeria.
The 1976 local government reform is criticized for creating a uniform, single tier structure of
local government for the whole country, making no distinction between the urban and rural
areas. Current thinking on development suggests, however, that it is perhaps best to
emphasize linkages rather than boundaries in the structure of local governments, ‘as urban-
rural linkages can best be managed by new types of local authorities which transcend
traditional administrative boundaries between cities and rural areas, capable of managing
settlements and their economic, social and environmental linkages at the regional settlement
level” (Hundsalz, 2001).
Unfortunately, in spite of the decentralization of power implied in the creation of more states
and local governments in Nigeria, decision making and resource allocation have remained
highly centralized. Although the percentage of national revenue allocated to local
governments has increased from 3% in 1976 to 20% in 1991, local governments still remain
under the legal and political influence of the higher levels of government whose political
leaders appear to have different interests and priorities. Many of the local governments also
appear to be too large and distant from the grassroots to be able to play the catalytic role
expected of small and medium towns. It would be helpful in this regard to revisit the
recommendations of the Dasuki Committee on the Review of Local Government
Administration in Nigeria, (1985) and the Report of the Political Bureau (1987) both of
which urge further structural decentralization to ensure that local governments are close
enough to the people to be able to appreciate their needs and provide meaningful scope for
local participation.
Other measures are needed to strengthen explicit linkages between programmes for small
towns and agricultural/rural development. In respect of planning, there is a growing
consensus that planning practice needs to be made more realistic, more flexible and advisory,
and more compatible with local conditions. Although the discredited colonial Town and
Planning Act of 1946 has since been replaced by the 1992 Urban and Regional Planning Law,
the National Planning Commission, the State Planning Boards and the Local Government
Planning Authorities envisaged in the implementation of the provision of the law have yet to
become operational. There is also the long standing need to review the centralized approach
to land use control introduced by the 1978 Land Use Decree/Act, and to move towards a
more decentralized land delivery system that would be better able to ensure enhanced land
and housing tenure for townspeople, especially the uban poor (Nwaka, 2004b).
TS 35 – Informal Settlements: Policy, Land Use and Tenure
Geoffrey I. Nwaka
Land Policy and the Informal City in Nigeria
From Pharaohs to Geoinformatics
FIG Working Week 2005 and GSDI-8
Cairo, Egypt April 16-21, 2005
10/13
Proper links must also be forged among the small towns, and between them and the large
cities, to ensure that the growth impulses and benefits engendered in the secondary cities are
spread and not appropriated by the elite who live there. The towns themselves need to be
provided with basic services and economic oriented infrastructure - shelter, water supply,
electricity, markets, marketing and storage facilities and so on. Small businesses and informal
sector enterprises need to be promoted and protected through improved access to credit,
technical support and training opportunities, as well as less restrictive licensing procedure to
help legalise their status. Improved access to farm inputs, agro-processing equipment and
facilities for rural farmers, and opportunities for non-farm employment are essential for
improvement in rural conditions.
With the prevailing economic and political uncertainties and budgetary constraints in the
country central and state governments must sometimes be content to play a more enabling
role of promoting active partnership between the government and the people, and making
conditions for self help and private sector participation as favourable as possible.
Another way of incorporating rural development in urban development planning is to
recognise and promote the strong ties which exist between towns-people and country folk in
most African countries. In Nigeria most town dwellers straddle the urban and rural worlds,
and maintain close links with their hometowns. Individually, and collectively through ethnic
unions and clan associations, they channel resources and progressive ideas to their home
villages, and invest considerable proportions of their urban savings in social and productive
economic ventures in the villages. Official policy should seek ways to harness the enormous
amounts of urban to rural remittances, and fund-raising activities organised by townspeople
for development projects in their hometowns. Strengthening hometown ties may be one of the
ways of tying small town policies to rural development programmes; and it is in this sense
that “the road to rural development in Africa may well go through urban investments”
(Hyden, 1986, p. 211; Dike, 1982; Trager, 1988; Honey and Okafor, 1998).
Finally, the promotion of medium and small towns should not be seen as a substitute for
direct programmes of urban and rural development, but rather as an essential component of
national policy for balanced development of the whole range of human settlements in the
country.
REFERENCES
* An earlier version of this paper titled “The Role of Medium and Small Towns in
Countryside Development in Nigeria” was presented at the 40th World Congress of the
IFHP in Dublin in Sept. 1990.
Adepoju, Aderanti, (1985) Medium Sized Towns in Nigeria: Research and Policy Prospects,
UNESCO. Paris.
Baker, Jonathan, ed. (1990) Small Town Africa: Studies in Rural-Urban Interaction, NAI;
Uppsala.
Blitzer, Silvia et al, (1989). Outside the Large Cities: Annotated Bibliography and Guide to
Literature on Small and Intermediate Urban Centres in the Third World, IIED, London.
TS 35 – Informal Settlements: Policy, Land Use and Tenure
Geoffrey I. Nwaka
Land Policy and the Informal City in Nigeria
From Pharaohs to Geoinformatics
FIG Working Week 2005 and GSDI-8
Cairo, Egypt April 16-21, 2005
11/13
Bromley, Ray (1983) “The Urban Road to Rural Development: Reflections on USAID Urban
Functions Approach”, Environment and Planning, A Vol. 15, pp. 429-432.
Dike, Azuka (1982) “Urban Migration and Rural Development”, African Studies Review
Vol. 25, No. 4, pp. 85-94.
Egan, Mary Lou (1985) “Setting Priorities in African Urban Development: A Case for
Secondary Cities in Senegal”. Planning and Administration, Vol. 12, pp. 61-74.
Egan, Mary Lou and Benfrick Marck, (1986) “The Urban-Rural Dimension in National
Development”, Journal of Developing Areas, Vol. 20, pp. 203-22.
Fair, Dennis, (1984) “Nigeria’s Unbalanced Development: Urban Growth and Rural
Stagnation”, Africa Insight, Vol. 14, No. 2, pp. 237-257.
Fair, Dennis, (1986) “Medium-sized Towns and African Development”, African Insight, Vol.
16, No. 2, pp. 73-78 and 131.
Federal Republic of Nigeria, (1975) Third National Development Plan 1975-1980, Lagos.
Federal Republic of Nigeria, (1976) Guidelines for Local Government Reforms, Government
Press, Kaduna.
Federal Republic of Nigeria, (1981) Fourth National Development Plan 1981-1985, Lagos.
Hardoy, J.E. and Satterthwait, D. eds. (1986) Small and Intermediate Urban Centres: Their
Role in National and Regional Development, IIED, London.
Honey, Rex and S. Okafor eds. (1998) Hometown Associations: Indigenous Knowledge and
Development in Nigeria, London IT.
Hundsalz, Matthias, 2001, “Key Issues for an Integrated Policy on Integrated Development”
Agriculture and Rural Development by 8(2) pp. 51-55.
Hyden, Goran, “Urban Growth and Rural Development” in African Independence: The First
Twenty-Five Years, eds - Gwendolen M. carter and Patrick O’Merra, Indiana, pp. 188-
217.
IIED, 2003, Environment and Development Briefs No. 7, on Rural-Urban Transformation
and the Links between Urban and Rural Development, London.
ILO/JASP, (1981) First Things First: Meeting the Basic Needs fo the People of Nigeria,
Addis Ababa.
Kammeier, H.D. and Swan, P.J., eds. (1984) Equity with Growth? Planning Perspective for
Small Towns in Developing Countires, ALT, Bangkok, especially the contributions by
Rondinelli, Dias and Dhiratayakinant.
Lipton, Michael, (1977), Why Poor People Stay Poor: A Study of Urban Bias in World
Development, Cambridge, M.A.
Mabogunje, A.L. (1977) Cities and Social Order, Inaugural Lecture, Ibadan.
Nwaka, Geoffrey, I. (2004) “Using Indigenous Knowledge to Strengthen Local Governance
and Development in Nigeria”. Paper presented at the IKS Confernece, Penn State
University, USA, May 2004.
Nwaka, Geoffrey, I. (1996) “Planning Sustainable Cities in Africa” Canadian Journal of
Urban Research Vol. 5 (1) pp. 95-111.
Nwaka, Geoffrey, I. (2004b) “The Urban Informal Sector and Environmental Health Policy
in Nigeria: Strategies Towards Social Justice & Social Harmony” in Global Urban
Development, The Prague Institute.
TS 35 – Informal Settlements: Policy, Land Use and Tenure
Geoffrey I. Nwaka
Land Policy and the Informal City in Nigeria
From Pharaohs to Geoinformatics
FIG Working Week 2005 and GSDI-8
Cairo, Egypt April 16-21, 2005
12/13
Okafor, Francis, (1985) “The Functional Role of Medium-sized Towns in Regional
Development: The Case of Southeastern Nigeria” Third World Planning Review, Vol.
7, No. 2, -- 145-159.
Olatubosum, Dupe, (1975) Nigeria’s Neglected Rural Majority, OUP/Ibadan.
Olowu, Dele (1986) “A Decade of Local Government Reforms in Nigeria - 1976-1986”,
International Review of Administrative Sciences, Vol. 52, No. 1, pp. 287-299; cf
Olowo, African Decentralization Policies and Practices from the 1980s and Beyond,
ISS Working Paper Series, The Hague.
Omuta, E.D. Gideon, (1980) “Administrative Reforms and Rural-Urban Integration in
Nigeria” African Research Bulletin Vol. 10, Nos. 2&3, pp. 22-64.
Onyemelukwe, J.O.C. (1980) “Settlement Structure as Socio-economic constraint on
Nigerian rural Development, EKISTICS, Vol. 7 pp. 353-355.
Rondinelli, Dennis (1982) “The Potential Role of Secondary Cities in Facilitating
Deconcentrated Urbanisation in Africa”, African Urban Studies, No. 13, Spring.
Rondinelli, Dennis, (1986) “The Urban Transition and Agricultural Development:
Implications for International Assistance Policy”, Development and Change, Vol. 17,
No. 4, pp. 230-263.
Rondinelli, Dennis (1989) “Market Towns and Rural Growth: Building Urban-Rural
Linkages”, in Sub-Sahara Africa Conference on Market Towns and Rural Growth:
Econimic and Social Linkages, Yamoussoukro, Cote Ivoire.
Sokari, George E. (1987) “Planning in Nigeria: The Agricultural Base, 1962-1985”,
GeoJournal, Vol. 14, No. 1, pp. 97-108.
Southall, Aidan, (ed.) (1979) Small Urban Centres in Rural Development in Africa,
Wisconsin-Madison.
Southall, Aidan, (1988) “Small Urban Centres in Rural Development”, Introduction in
Special Issues of African Studies Review, Vol. 31, No. 3.
Southall, A. and Rondinelli, D. (1982) “Response and Counter-Reponse - A Debate”, in
Urbanism Past and Present, Vol. 7, No. 13, pp. 35-41.
Tacoli, Cecilia (1998) Bridging the Divide: Rural-Urban Interactions and Livelihood
Strategies IIED, Gatekeeper Series, No. 77.
Trager, Lillian, (1988) “Rural-Urban Linkages: The Role of Small Urban Centres in Nigeria”,
African Studies Review, Vol. 13, No. 3, pp. 29-38.
Todaro, M. and Skilland J. (1981) City-Bias and Rural Neglect: The Dilemma of Urban
Development, Population Council, Washington.
Ukwu, Ukwu I (1983) “Planning and Rural Development: The Nigerian Experience”,
Nigerian Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 3 (1&2) pp. 75-86.
UNCHS (Habitat) (1985) The Role of Small and Intermediate Settlements in National
Development, Nairobi, and the earlier publication, Development of Rural Settlements,
1981.
UN-Habitat (1998) The Istanbul Declaration and the Habitat Agenda, Nairobi, especially
pages. 163-169.
UN-Habitat (1999) Strengthening Rural-Urban Linkages, Special Issue of Habitat Debate,
Vol. 5(1), especially papers by Mutizwa-Mangiza, Jonas Rabinovideh, and B. Ayeni.
TS 35 – Informal Settlements: Policy, Land Use and Tenure
Geoffrey I. Nwaka
Land Policy and the Informal City in Nigeria
From Pharaohs to Geoinformatics
FIG Working Week 2005 and GSDI-8
Cairo, Egypt April 16-21, 2005
13/13
UNCRD (1984) Growth Profile of Small Cities, Nagaya; also the important work by Prakash
Mathur, The Role of Small Cities in Regional Development, issued by UNCRD in
1984.
World Bank, 2003, Integrating Rural Development and Small Urban Centers: An Evovling
Framework for Effective Regional and Local Economic Development, Seminar
Proceeding; www.worldbank.org/urban/urbanruralseminar, especially the contribution
by Tacoli and Satterthwaite.
CONTACTS
Geoffrey I. Nwaka
Abia State University
PMB 2000 UTURU
NIGERIA
Email: geoffreynwaka@yahoo.com
... According to this memorandum, areas such as Nassarawa, Sabon Gari and Fagge would be separated from the ancient city of Kano, especially by building free zones. 5 This effort ensured the duality of the landscaping of Kano along the 'traditional' African urbanism and the Western model. Despite the challenges raised by the colonial town-planning policies that promoted racial discrimination, loss of lands and the relegation of the 'traditional' Hausa architecture, historians and architects made little or no effort to document these changes and continuities. ...
Article
Full-text available
Hausaland to which Kano belongs had its unique age-long architectural designs rendered in a radial settlement pattern. However, with the British colonial conquest and the enactment of new town planning policies in 1903, a grid pattern of settlement was introduced, especially in the Government Reserved Areas (GRAs). This development further led to the promulgation of the British Township and Public Health Ordinances of 1917, the Housing and Town Planning Acts of 1909, as well as the Town and Country Planning Ordinance of 1946 to enforce not only western architectural housing planning but also to segregate the natives along land-uses, population density and status. Hinging on both primary and secondary sources, this article examines issues revolving around the transformation of architecture and town-planning development in Kano due to British colonial policies, which left lasting legacies in the peoples' choice of building materials, architectural designs and urbanisation. Emphasis is given to monumental buildings within the 'traditional' city and the emergence of British colonial buildings and settlements. Contrary to the notion that the British colonial government had not done anything positive in Africa, this article finds out that it had contributed immensely, especially in developing Kano's 'traditional' city and creating modern and rhythmic cities in the continent amidst its existing urbanisms. The article concludes that urban development and planning contributed immensely to the supremacy of the British colonial government over the Emirate, a struggle inherited by the Kano State government.
Book
Full-text available
Drawing on a collaborative research programme with teams from India, the Sudan, Nigeria and Argentina, this is one of the most detailed research initiatives on small and intermediate urban centres. Although it was published in 1986, it still has much of relevance to this topic
Article
A striking aspect of the spatial imbalance in the distribution of urban centres in Nigeria concerns the absence of medium-sized towns in most parts of the country. This pattern of city-sized distribution is not conducive to the spatial diffusion of development because it defeats the aim of trying to spread the benefits of development as widely as possible. Thus, an emerging pattern of medium-sized towns in south-eastern Nigeria merits attention in order to illustrate the roles the towns can play in the process of balanced regional development. Examines the central place functions of the medium-sized towns by discussing specifically their diffusion, social, commercial, and employment generating functions. Concludes by emphasizing the need for a spatial reorganization on a national or regional basis of the current pattern of polarized urban growth in order to achieve a spatially balanced and hierarchically organized urban system in Nigeria.-Author
Book
Why have growth and development in poor countries failed to improve the welfare of the poorest people? This question was raised by Michael Lipton in 1977. He then argued that poverty persists mainly because development was designed by and for people in urban areas. Most poor people lived in rural areas, but the towns and cities got a far larger share of national resources. This, he argued, was not only unjust but also inefficient. In this book, Lipton presents the theory of ‘urban bias’ arguing that the development of urban areas and industrialisation in poor countries has been at the expense of rural areas. During this time usual theory and practice saw development as a process of transformation from the rural and agricultural towards the urban and industrial, through fast and artificially stimulated resource transfers from village to city. Rural areas were not normally seen as a potential source of economic progress. The book shows that public spending in poor countries has been concentrated on the development of urban areas and on industrial growth. Governments tend to favour allocating resources to towns and cities as opposed to villages. This is mainly because people in urban areas have more political power to convince governments to make taxation and spending choices that favour their interests. Key findings include: The 60 to 80 percent of people in poor countries who depend on agriculture for their livelihoods are typically allocated less than 20 percent of development spending. Urban areas get a disproportionately and inefficiently high share of public spending, particularly in health and education. Poor people in rural areas are disadvantaged in terms of nutrition, education, health, technology and access to financial services. Government policies keep goods and services from rural areas (for example, food) under-priced and those from urban areas over-priced. Urban bias has resulted in a rural skills drain as educated younger workers leave to work in towns and cities. Urban bias has prevented the formation of valuable rural-urban links. Lipton argues that comparisons being made with the economic history of the industrialised countries were misleading: the gap between urban and rural wealth and power was much bigger in poor countries than it had been in rich countries during the early stages of their development. Successful pro-poor development would require a much larger share of resources for rural areas and farming. Key recommendations include: Development normally requires industrialisation but both are impeded when countries seek to industrialise too early, too quickly or by artificial resource extraction from rural areas. Resources should be initially directed towards developing the agricultural sector: growing farm productivity has almost invariably been a pre-condition of successful development in other sectors. Investment in small-scale agriculture would be the best way to raise incomes quickly in poor countries, with high ratios of labour to capital, because it is labour-intensive farming, especially on a small scale, and rural activity in general, uses less capital (directly and for infrastructure) per unit of labour than does urban industry. Rural and agricultural enterprises need better – but not normally subsidised – access to loans and investment. Incentives are needed to encourage public sector workers, particularly in education and healthcare, to work in rural areas. Governments should set and monitor targets for the share of public spending on farming and rural areas.