ArticlePDF Available

Towards a Pro-Poor Development Strategy for Middle-Income Countries: a Comment on Bresser-Pereira and Nakano

Authors:

Abstract

This paper draws upon Bresser-Pereira and Nakano (2003), in order to outline a pro-poor growth strategy for middle-income countries. This strategy avoids the pit- falls of the neoliberal model implemented in several countries in the aftermath of the 1982 international debt crisis, and is conducive to income distribution and sustain- able growth simultaneously. In a recent issue of the Brazilian Journal of Political Economy, Bresser-Pereira and Nakano (2003) published a remarkable paper that will surely become an im- portant reference in the contemporary Latin American economic debate. In their essay, Bresser-Pereira and Nakano cogently criticise the neoliberal ("dependent", p. 11) growth strategy of most Latin American countries in the closing years of the twentieth century, convincingly demonstrate that sustained growth must be based on domestic rather than foreign savings, and skillfully outline an alternative devel- opment strategy for middle-income countries. This paper builds upon the latter feature of Bresser-Pereira and Nakano's con- tribution. It is clearly important to devise alternative development strategies for middle-income countries. Neoliberal programmes based upon the so-called (post-) Washington Consensus have failed throughout Latin America. Voters in several countries, including Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Ecuador, Venezuela and elsewhere have expressed their dissatisfaction, and in several countries the majority is clearly unwilling to bear further costs of "adjustment". In nearly every country, these costs include increased external vulnerability, slower growth, rising unemployment and
130
Brazilian Journal of Political Economy, vol. 24, nº 1 (93), January-March/2004
Towards a Pro-Poor Development Strategy
for Middle-Income Countries: a Comment
on Bresser-Pereira and Nakano
ALFREDO SAAD FILHO*
This paper draws upon Bresser-Pereira and Nakano (2003), in order to outline a
pro-poor growth strategy for middle-income countries. This strategy avoids the pit-
falls of the neoliberal model implemented in several countries in the aftermath of the
1982 international debt crisis, and is conducive to income distribution and sustain-
able growth simultaneously.
In a recent issue of the Brazilian Journal of Political Economy, Bresser-Pereira
and Nakano (2003) published a remarkable paper that will surely become an im-
portant reference in the contemporary Latin American economic debate. In their
essay, Bresser-Pereira and Nakano cogently criticise the neoliberal (“dependent”,
p. 11) growth strategy of most Latin American countries in the closing years of the
twentieth century, convincingly demonstrate that sustained growth must be based
on domestic rather than foreign savings, and skillfully outline an alternative devel-
opment strategy for middle-income countries.
This paper builds upon the latter feature of Bresser-Pereira and Nakano’s con-
tribution. It is clearly important to devise alternative development strategies for
middle-income countries. Neoliberal programmes based upon the so-called (post-)
Washington Consensus have failed throughout Latin America. Voters in several
countries, including Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Ecuador, Venezuela and elsewhere
have expressed their dissatisfaction, and in several countries the majority is clearly
unwilling to bear further costs of “adjustment”. In nearly every country, these costs
include increased external vulnerability, slower growth, rising unemployment and
* Department of Development Studies, SOAS — School of Oriental and African Studies, University of
London, Thronhaugh Street, Russell Square, London WC1H 0XG, UK (e-mail: asfilho@aol.com).
[Submitted: July 2003; accepted: August 2003]
131
a deteriorating distribution of income and wealth. However, it remains to be shown
how alternative macroeconomic programmes can deliver rapid and sustained growth
with poverty alleviation and distribution. Latin American political economy can offer
an important contribution towards the achievement of these worthwhile objectives.
In this respect, the key insights of Bresser-Pereira and Nakano’s contribution
are the following:
• Middle-income countries should rely primarily on domestic rather than for-
eign savings to finance investment and growth. This requires a resolution of the
balance of payments, fiscal and financial constraints in these economies.
• Countries should adopt floating exchange rate regimes and avoid currency
overvaluation (exchange rate “neopopulism”, pp. 18, 20). This obviously presumes
that inflation can be tamed by other means.
• Foreign capital flows should be controlled in order to avoid destabilising ex-
change rate movements and excessive vulnerability to sudden capital outflows. These
controls should include, in different ways, foreign direct and portfolio investment,
and foreign loans. In this context, governments should attempt to reduce the for-
eign debt/exports ratio to manageable levels (e.g., below 2).
• Finally, it is essential to achieve long-term fiscal balance in order to prevent
runaway inflation and excessive (and costly) expansion of the domestic public debt.
In order to achieve this objective, Bresser-Pereira and Nakano suggest the imple-
mentation of contractionary fiscal policies, “beyond the levels usually required by
the IMF, together with a reduction of the domestic interest rates and currency de-
valuation” (p. 23). This combination of policies, and the ensuing macroeconomic
stability, may allow foreign savings to contribute to sustainable domestic growth,
rather than generating instability.
Most political economists will find these suggestions uncontroversial. Bresser-
Pereira and Nakano’s recommendation that countries should rely primarily on do-
mestic rather than foreign savings is supported not only by the pioneering work of
Feldstein and Horioka (1980), but also by recent research by Calvo (1996) and Calvo,
Leiderman and Heinhart (1996). A political economy interpretation of these find-
ings is provided by Palma (1998). Relative undervaluation of the exchange rate is
strongly supported by recent work on trade and industrial policy, including Agosín
and Tussie (1993), Chang (1994), Gereffi and Wyman (1990) and UNDP (2003).
Capital controls are advocated by Epstein, Grabel and Jomo (2003). In contrast,
however, fiscal restraint is likely to be the most hotly debated aspect of Bresser-Pereira
and Nakano’s suggestions. In what follows, this paper supports this particular as-
pect of Bresser-Pereira and Nakano’s agenda. It also outlines, in further detail, pos-
sible directions for an alternative (pro-poor) economic strategy that may be imple-
mented immediately (with suitable adaptations to local conditions) in a range of
middle-income countries. This strategy draws upon the rapidly growing literature
on “pro-poor growth policies” (see, for example, Cornia et al 1988, Dagdeviren et
al 2002, MacEwan 1999, Rao 2002, Saad Filho 2003 and Winters 2002).
132
TOWARDS AN ALTERNATIVE STRATEGY
Pro-poor policies should fulfil two primary objectives. First, growth must benefit
the poor more than the rich (in other words, it must reduce absolute as well as relative
poverty), and lead to sustained improvements in the living standards of the major-
ity. These outcomes must be independent from trickle-down effects, and they should
be unambiguous across a broad spectrum of measures of social welfare. Second, as
was mentioned above, these policies should be efficient, consistent, and sustainable.
Policies that are excessively costly to implement and monitor, that generate welfare
traps and disincentives, or that create macroeconomic instability are unsustainable
in the long-term, and should be avoided.
A pro-poor growth strategy for middle-income countries starts by recognising
the importance of growth. Economic growth contributes to poverty reduction in
several ways. Growth increases the availability of goods and services and expands
the country’s consumption possibilities. It creates employment, expands markets and
sales income, and raises wages through the creation of labour scarcities. Growth
also funds social programmes and finances the provision of public goods (see be-
low). Finally, economic growth generates the savings and the financial development
required to fund investment and consumer spending. In the absence of growth (and
foreign transfers, e.g., international aid), poverty-reducing outcomes must rely on
distribution alone, which tends to create severe political tensions. Having said this,
the success of a pro-poor strategy should not be judged by the economic growth
rates alone. Rather, it should be assessed through the quality of the growth process
and its outcomes. Specifically, a pro-poor strategy increases welfare and empowers
the majority of the population, whereas neoliberal strategies generally lead to the
opposite outcomes (this conclusion is cogently demonstrated by Bresser-Pereira and
Nakano; see also Milanovic 2002).
In this context, investment is essential. Investment is the driving force of growth
but, as is well known, growth is also the driving force of investment, because rapid
and sustained growth generates the demand that makes individual investment pro-
jects viable. In order to kick-start this virtuous circle of growth and investment, the
state should select priority sectors through targeted (vertical) industrial policies, and
offer incentives to the expansion of capacity and output, especially in areas likely
to relieve the balance of payments constraint. These policies and activities should
be financed by a progressive tax system, and by the additional tax revenues gener-
ated by economic growth.
In this context, fiscal policy becomes critically important. Critics of neoliberalism
often argue that alternative strategies should be based on loose fiscal, monetary and
exchange rate policies. This suggestion is misguided, for three reasons. First, it draws
upon a narrow reading of the experience of the United States (as well as key West-
ern European countries) between the mid-1930s and the mid-1970s. This is largely
inapplicable to middle-income countries, because of their much tighter balance of
payments constraint. Specifically, developed countries could either print the world
currency (especially Britain before World War II, and the US afterwards), or had
133
much easier access to foreign currency than is currently possible for middle-income
countries. Second, in semi-industrialised middle-income countries loose fiscal, mon-
etary and exchange rate policies tend to generate unsustainable booms, which are
destabilising both economically and politically. This is especially true in economies
starved of investment for long periods, and where high unemployment coexists with
low spare capacity in critically important industrial sectors. Third, the “fully” ex-
pansionary alternative is not politically feasible. The rapid reversal of the fiscal stance,
from a surplus (or balance) to a significant deficit, is likely to trigger strong resis-
tance from the IMF and the US Treasury Department, the local media, financial sector
interests, and conservative ideologues of every stripe. This is likely to destabilise the
government and demoralise the alternatives long before their expansionary impli-
cations can be felt.
It follows that the investment projects required by a pro-poor strategy must be
financed adequately. This will not only avoid the difficulties outlined above, but also
ensure that the liabilities of the central government (including the stock of circulat-
ing money and the domestic public debt) will not increase excessively rapidly, lead-
ing to inflation, high interest rates and high interest payments on the domestic debt.
Recent experience in Latin America and elsewhere shows that these consequences
of fiscal, monetary and exchange rate policy laxity eventually block economic growth,
generate political instability, and make distribution very difficult.
In order to achieve the desired outcomes, fiscal policy should generally have a
restrictive bias, with deficits under recessions but significant surpluses during the
boom, leading to a (possibly modest) surplus over the economic cycle. Bresser-Pereira
and Nakano are correct. Furthermore, this fiscal policy stance can play a more
constructive role than is generally acknowledged.
A pro-poor growth strategy should support worker representation through trade
unions and impose rising minimum wages, as well as providing incentives for the
payment of high and relatively equal wages within and between industries. These
will be at least partly funded by high (progressive) income taxes and social security
charges. These policies, together with a restrictive fiscal policy, can stimulate tech-
nical innovation and productivity growth.
Low inflation, a relatively undervalued exchange rate and low state demand
will stimulate exports rather than production for the domestic market, prevent in-
efficient firms from profiting systematically from price increases, and curtail their
reliance upon state procurement. Moreover, state regulation and inspection will make
it difficult for firms to increase profitability by cutting wages, arbitrarily extending
the working day or bypassing health and safety rules. By the same token, relatively
high wages across the board will guarantee extraordinary profits to those compa-
nies with the most productive techniques, while increasing the pressure on their
inefficient competitors. Workers unemployed because of the unavailability of low-
paid jobs or the bankruptcy of inefficient firms should be supported and retrained
with public funds. Finally, these workers may find it easier to move to other sectors
of the economy if the wages are relatively equal across different industries. This will
increase economic flexibility and help to reduce structural unemployment.
134
In this context, the choice of monetary and exchange rate policy is trivial. They
should be accommodating, as is suggested by Bresser-Pereira and Nakano, in order
to stimulate investment and keep the currency moderately undervalued. The poten-
tially inflationary implications of these policies will be cancelled out by the contrac-
tionary impact of fiscal policy.
Bresser-Pereira and Nakano are correct in arguing that the balance of payments
constraint must be considered carefully. The tax rates required to support pro-poor
policies will necessarily be higher than abroad. Therefore, capital controls are es-
sential not only to support domestic economic stability (as was argued above), but
also to minimise capital flight. Moreover, international trade must also be regulated
to the extent permissible under WTO rules (see UNDP 2003), since the international
experience shows that relatively autonomous late development is possible only if
domestic industry and agriculture are protected (see Amsden 1997, 2001, and Chang
2002). However, specific interventions must be justified, and progress must be che-
cked against clear performance standards.
Finally, a pro-poor strategy necessitates specific polices to protect the poor and
improve social welfare. These policies should prioritise the provision of public goods
(social wage) rather than monetary handouts (although the latter should not be
excluded). Programmes including the expansion of education, training and health
provision, water and sanitation, parks and public amenities, state-sponsored envi-
ronmental preservation programmes, staple foods, clothing, shoes and public trans-
port, have relatively low administrative costs and they can reach the poor directly.
In most middle-income countries, including Brazil, the required administrative in-
frastructure is already in place. In contrast, cash transfers (e.g., along the lines pro-
posed by Suplicy 2003) are less desirable. On the one hand, they assume that social
welfare is determined by the individual capacity to purchase private goods, rather
than the access to public goods. On the other hand, they foster the commodification
of social life and the development of competition. In contrast, a high social wage
ensures the provision of key goods and services to all, contributes to the de-commo-
dification of the social relations, and fosters human solidarity. The importance of
these objectives is widely acknowledged, for example by the UNDP Human Devel-
opment Index.
CONCLUSION
This paper has reviewed briefly the contribution of Bresser-Pereira and Nakano
(2003) towards an alternative development strategy for middle-income countries,
drawing upon the recent literature on pro-poor growth strategies.
Needless to say, implementation of alternative strategies depends less on their
internal consistency (which has nevertheless been demonstrated above) than on
political limitations. More specifically, the most important constraint preventing the
introduction of pro-poor economic strategies in middle-income countries, includ-
ing Argentina, Brazil, Indonesia, Thailand, Turkey and South Africa, among oth-
135
ers, is not resource scarcity. It is, rather, the lack of political will to confront neoli-
beralism and build alternatives based upon the interaction between progressive
governments and civil society organisations.
REFERENCES
AGOSÍN, M.R. and TUSSIE, D. (eds.) (1993) Trade and Growth: New Dilemmas in Trade Policy. Lon-
don: Macmillan.
AMSDEN, A. (1997) “Editorial: Bringing Production Back In — Understanding Government’s Economic
Role in Late Industrialization”, World Development 25 (4): 469-480.
AMSDEN, A. (2001) The Rise of the Rest: Challenges to the West from Late Industrializing Economies,
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
BRESSER-PEREIRA, L.C. and NAKANO, Y. (2003) “Crescimento Econômico com Poupança Externa?”,
Brazilian Journal of Political Economy 23 (2) (90): 3-27.
CALVO, G.A. (1996) “The Management of Capital Flows: Domestic Policy and International Coop-
eration”, in G.K. Helleiner (ed.) The International Monetary and Financial System. London: Mac-
millan.
CALVO, G.A., LEIDERMAN, L. and REINHART, C. (1996) “Inflows of Capital to Developing Coun-
tries in the 1990s”. Journal of Economic Perspectives 10 (2), Spring: 123-139.
CHANG, H.-J. (1994) The Political Economy of Industrial Policy, London: Macmillan.
CHANG, H.-J. (2002) Kicking Away the Ladder?: Policies and Institutions for Economic Development
in Historical Perspective. London: Anthem Press.
CORNIA, G., Jolly, R. and STEWART, F. (1988) Adjustment with a Human Face: Protecting the Vul-
nerable and Promoting Growth. Introduction and chapters 1, 6.
DAGDEVIREN, H., VAN DER HOEVEN, R. and WEEKS, J. (2002) “Poverty Reduction with Growth
and Redistribution”, Development and Change 33 (3): 383-413.
EPSTEIN, G., GRABEL, I. and JOMO K.S. (2003) “Capital Management Techniques in Developing
Countries: An Assessment of Experiences from the 1990’s and Lessons For the Future”, XVI Tech-
nical Group Meeting of the G-24, Port of Spain.
FELDSTEIN, M. and HORIOKA, C. (1980) “Domestic Savings and International Capital Flows”, Eco-
nomic Journal 90 (358): 314-29.
GEREFFI, G. and WYMAN, D.L. (1990) Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin
America and East Asia. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
MACEWAN, A. (1999) Neo-Liberalism or Democracy? Economic Strategy, Markets, and Alternatives
for the 21
st
Century. London: Zed Books.
MILANOVIC, B. (2002) “True World Income Distribution, 1988 and 1993: First Calculation Based on
Household Surveys Alone”, Economic Journal 112: 51-92.
PALMA, G. (1998) “Three and a Half Cycles of ‘Mania, Panic and [Asymmetric] Crash’: East Asia and
Latin America Compared”, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 22(6): 789-808.
RAO, J.M. (2002) The Possibility of Pro-Poor Development: Distribution, Growth and Policy Interac-
tions, manuscript.
SAAD FILHO, A. (2003) Democratic and Pro-Poor Economic Strategies for Developing Countries: an
Overview. VIII Encontro da Sociedade Brasileira de Economia Política, Florianópolis.
SUPLICY, E.M. (2003) “Renda Básica: A Resposta Está Sendo Soprada pelo Vento”, Brazilian Journal
of Political Economy 23 (2) (90): 47-62.
UNDP (2003) Making Global Trade Work for People. Geneva: UNDP.
WINTERS, L.A. (2002) “Trade Policies for Poverty Alleviation”, in B. Hoekman, A. Mattoo & P. En-
glish (eds.) Development, Trade, and the WTO. Washington D.C.: The World Bank.
... The neoliberal project represents the continuity of an exclusive way of policy making and implementation, run by an elite that is alienated and disconnected from reality (Harvey, 2005). This policy praxis results in a lack of commitment to people's experiences and needs and in a discriminatory and delusional perception of the reasons and the purpose of programmatic targeting and retrenchment (Boesten, 2007).! Neoliberalism uses discourse (as mere rhetoric) for the promotion of cuts, privatisation and widespread contempt for the poor (Saad, 2004). It means shifting the mainstream political discussion from the ethical dimensions of austerity measures to moralistic values of socially constructed roles (Ewig, 2010). ...
... By the second half of the 1990s, neoliberalism as promoted by the World Bank and the IMF was proving to be disappointing (Saad, 2004). Poverty reduction was unsatisfactory, uncontrolled international capital flow was once more on the brink of a crisis and growth was at a steady pace (Saad, 2007). ...
... It was only with the third generation reforms, i.e. post post-Washington consensus of propoor policies, that mixed markets and social democratic policies were introduced (Grugel, Roggirozzi and Thirkell- White, 2008). This was an extension (or perhaps a rejection) of the Pro-poor (or poverty alleviation) economic theory challenges the discourse on the origins and mechanisms of reproduction of poverty presented by the mainstream embodied by the first and second generation Washington consensus (Saad Filho, 2004;.! ! This wave of pro-poor theory directly aims for the achievement of distributive economic outcomes and defends the introduction of economic policies that not only take into account but purposefully focus on the needs of the poor by democratically distributing income, wealth and power (Saad Filho 2007). ...
Thesis
Full-text available
This thesis presents the results of an empirically-grounded exploration of the ascendance of maternal mortality as an issue and its neglect by Brazilian public policy. Its purpose is to contribute to the existing scholarly debate on social policy and participation in order to advance knowledge on the dynamics of agenda setting and activism. More specifically, it relies on a case study of political and policy strategies aimed at maternal mortality reduction, to determine whether or not decentralisation has led to processes and environments that are more adequate to the advancement of women’s rights. Policy and discourse analyses are used to discuss the continuous appropriation, transformation and re-appropriation of decentralisation by the different policy networks and its influence in the depoliticisation of the wider human rights movement. In-depth interviews with key-actors participating in the 1980s and 1990s health sector reforms in Brazil demonstrate that decentralisation does not live up to its social justice premise and that, as it is not inserted into a wider culture of political measures for positive change, it reinforces existing power hierarchies and elitism. This historical analysis serves as a statement of the voracious power neoliberalism has over all types of policy making as well as its opportunistic advancement of certain political strategies created by different individuals and networks involved in the institutionalisation of human rights-based approaches. This control exerted by neoliberalism over policy and policy discourse is particularly acute in the case of maternal mortality. In its most progressive format, maternal mortality touches upon politically contentious issues that are often resisted by conservative networks supporting neoliberal control over public health sector reforms, principles and practices. Furthermore, in the face of new and multiplying policy spaces created by decentralisation, women’s rights networks lose their political leverage as sophistication, capacity and resources become indispensable.
... 25 Neoliberalism uses discourse (as mere rhetoric) for the promotion of cuts, privatization and widespread contempt for the poor. 26 It means shifting the mainstream political discussion from the ethical dimensions of austerity measures to moralistic values of socially constructed roles. 27 It purposefully exposes individuals to criticism to protect the corporate determinism embodied in the shift of paradigm performed by policies under neoliberal governments. ...
Article
This article argues that the trend to zoom into mandatory human rights due diligence (mHRDD) as the sole solution to corporate abuse is misleading. In fact, it might risk missing entirely the main point which, as set out in this article, should be creating economic systems that enable rights-based and rights-driven business models. A small, but growing number of scholarly articles address the economic, fiscal and regulatory institutions needed to create an enabling environment for the fulfilment of human rights. These policy areas constitute what some of us understand as a ‘rights-based economy’ or ‘rights-enabling economies’. State-level efforts would be much more effective in promoting substantive equality if driven by a rights-based approach rather than a market logic. This article contends that while ensuring comprehensive mHRDD is in place as a preventative and mitigation tool, states must also push for transformative macroeconomic policies based on human rights principles as a way to fundamentally change business models.
... In this scenario, middle-income countries (MIC) (Saad Filho 2004;Gu et al 2016) and development banks may be considered increasingly important actors (Ferraz et al 2013;Ferraz and Countinho 2019;Orliange 2020 Soares and Inoue 2020). In addition, each source of financing brings impacts to the others, and international public finance encompasses much more than official development assistance (ODA) (FSDR 2019). ...
Article
Full-text available
How did the global framework for financing sustainable development evolve in the past ten years? We argue that its evolution is deeply connected to multilateral initiatives such as the Monterrey consensus,the Addis Ababa Action Agenda, the Sustainable Development Goals and the Paris Agreement on climate change. Therefore, the year 2015 may be considered as a landmark. In this vein, we identified five keychanges that affect the global framework for financing development worldwide, showing how traditional international cooperation mechanisms coexist with new ones. They are discussed in the followingorder: the evolution of global development agendas; systemic power relations and financial flows; the institutional entrepreneurship of emerging powers; the increased role of development banks; and from official development aid (ODA) to international public finance. Under the United Nations auspices or not, middle-income countries started to play a bigger role in financing mechanisms. Likewise, some national development banks became more important and started to act more closely under the International Development Finance Club (IDFC) auspices. Brazil, Colombia and South Africa are mentioned as cases for future research.
... Access to finance will reduce credit constraints, creating opportunities for investments in income-generating activities that now become available to the poor. Moreover, given their backward position, the poor may also profit disproportionally from the growth-enhancing effect of financial development in terms of creating employment, expanding markets and sales income and raising wages (Saad-Filho, 2004). Thus, the income equality enhancing impact of financial development stems from the idea of convergence of incomes following macroeconomic growth. ...
Article
Full-text available
This study addresses the question whether participation of the poor in microfinance contributes to reducing a country’s level of income inequality. Using data from 70 developing countries, we show that higher levels of microfinance participation are indeed associated with a reduction of the income gap between rich and poor people. We also show, however, that the effects of microfinance on reducing income inequality are relatively small. The results of this study add to the discussion on the impact of microfinance on poverty by showing that, although access to microfinance does seem to improve the relative income position of the poor, this improvement is modest, which is probably because the use of microfinance is generally small as compared to the size of the economy of the countries in our sample. Microfinance should, therefore, not be seen as a panacea for bringing down income inequality in a significant way.
Article
Localism is an ideology suggesting that small changes in economic organisation can foster widespread social change. However, it lacks an understanding of how capital centralization sets limits on the viability of decentralized production, local technologies and ethical small business. Localism shares the same bias towards individual exchange as the market economies it wants to reform.
Article
Full-text available
RESUMO Em palestra sobre o desenvolvimento da ideia de uma Renda Básica Incondicional proferida no dia 17 de agosto de 2002, na Universidade de São Paulo, o professor Phillipe Van Parijs afirmou que a introdução de um programa como esse, em países continentais como o Brasil, deve ser feita de forma gradual.
Chapter
Full-text available
This paper argues that, despite some significant differences, the 1982 debt crisis, the 1994 Mexican crisis, and the 1997 East Asian crisis share the common characteristic that ‘over-lending’ and ‘over-borrowing’ are basically endogenous market failures of over-liquid and under-regulated financial markets — along the lines described by Kindleberger’s Manias, Panics, and Crashes (although these crashes have tended to be ‘asymmetric’, as the largest international lenders have emerged relatively intact). The paper concludes with a discussion of Brazil’s increasing vulnerability to a sudden collapse of confidence and withdrawal of finance, which indicates the probability of another impending crisis. In the last 15 years, the world economy has witnessed three major financial crises: the 1982 (mainly Latin American) debt crisis; the 1994 Mexican crisis, and its repercussions throughout Latin America (commonly known as the ‘Tequila effect’); and the 1997 East Asian crisis. Furthermore, Brazil’s growing financial vulnerability signals the probability of another major crisis in the not too distant future (see Postscript, p. 273). This paper argues that the last three financial crises share many common characteristics.
Article
Full-text available
RESUMO Os países altamente endividados, particularmente os latino-americanos, apresentaram resultados econômicos negativos na década de 1990, que são a consequência da “estratégia de crescimento com poupança externa”, ou o Segundo Consenso de Washington. Juntamente com a liberalização dos fluxos financeiros internacionais, tal estratégia, que não fez parte do primeiro consenso, levou os países, na onda de um novo ciclo mundial de fluxos de capital, a déficits elevados em conta corrente e aumento da dívida externa, ignorando a restrição da solidez e o limiar da dívida. Em termos práticos, envolvia moedas supervalorizadas (baixas taxas de câmbio) e altas taxas de juros; em termos políticos, a tentativa de controlar o déficit orçamentário enquanto o déficit em conta corrente foi ignorado. A consequência paradoxal foi a adoção, pelos países altamente endividados, do “populismo cambial”, uma forma menos óbvia, mas mais perigosa, de populismo econômico.
Chapter
Capital flows into developing countries have exhibited a substantial increase since 1990. The change is especially dramatic in Latin America, where flows have more than doubled. However, capital flows have also been substantial in Asia where, as in Latin America, the change in those flows has represented about 3 per cent of GDP. This phenomenon has roots in both domestic and external factors. Statistical analysis for Latin America suggests that the weight of these factors is about the same. Therefore, in addition to good domestic policies, external factors are likely to play an important role in future developments. In this connection, the paper singles out two factors that may contribute to a gradual drying up of capital flows towards developing countries: (a) a worsening of the current account (of the balance of payments) in the industrialized countries (implying an improvement in the developing countries), and (b) a tendency on the part of developing countries to channel capital inflows more towards a current account deficit, and less towards the accumulation of international reserves. The combination of these two factors implies (recalling that, abstracting from errors and omissions, capital inflows = current account deficit + reserves accumulation) lower capital inflows into developing countries.
Article
However you define it, poverty is not directly the result of international trade. Rather poverty reflects low earning power, few assets, poor access to communal resources, poor health and education, powerlessness and vulnerability. It does not matter what causes these features so long as they exist, nor what relieves them if they can be relieved. Trade policy matters only to the extent (a) that it affects the direct determinants of poverty and (b) that, relative to the whole range of other possible policies, it offers an efficient policy lever for poverty alleviation (more poverty bang for your buck of foregone opportunities). Trade liberalisation may have adverse consequences for some – including some poor – that should be avoided or ameliorated to the greatest extent possible. However, my fundamental belief is that trade liberalisation aids growth which, in turn, aids poverty alleviation. I also believe that a widespread reform will contain enough positive elements that, in general, only a few people will end up as net losers. Trade policy should therefore generally not be closely manipulated with an eye on its direct poverty consequences, but set on a sound basis overall (with recognition that some modification may be inevitable for political and other reasons) with poverty being treated by general anti-poverty policies. Trade reform and poverty International trade scholars have long understood that although for small countries trade interventions are generally inefficient and wasteful, their inefficiency is usually dominated quantitatively by their redistributive effects. That is, the net loses from intervention will generally comprise large positive effects for some people/households and large negative effects for others. Correspondingly, although removing interventions will generally be income-enhancing overall, it is likely to generate both winners and losers 2 . For example, liberalising an import sector typically redistributes real income from producers to consumers as prices fall, and between different factors of production so that some gain while other lose more heavily than average.
Article
In the late 1990s the bilateral and multilateral development agencies placed increasing emphasis on poverty reduction in developing countries. This led to the establishment by the United Nations of the ‘International Development Targets’ for poverty reduction. The target of poverty reduction might be achieved through faster economic growth alone, through redistribution, or through a combination of the two. This article presents an analytical framework to assess the effectiveness of growth and redistribution for poverty reduction. It concludes that redistribution, either of current income or the growth increment of income, is more effective in reducing poverty for a majority of countries than growth alone.
Book
After World War II a select number of countries outside Japan and the West--those that Alice Amsden calls "the rest"--gained market share in modern industries and altered global competition. By 2000, a great divide had developed within "the rest", the lines drawn according to prewar manufacturing experience and equality in income distribution. China, India, Korea and Taiwan had built their own national manufacturing enterprises that were investing heavily in R&D. Their developmental states had transformed themselves into champions of science and technology. By contrast, Argentina, Brazil and Mexico had experienced a wave of acquisitions and mergers that left even more of their leading enterprises controlled by multinational firms. The developmental states of Mexico and Turkey had become hand-tied by membership in NAFTA and the European Union. Which model of late industrialization will prevail, the "independent" or the "integrationist," is a question that challenges the twenty-first century. Available in OSO: http://www.oxfordscholarship.com/oso/public/content/economicsfinance/0195139690/toc.html