ArticlePDF Available

Which democracies prosper? Electoral rules, form of government and economic growth

Authors:

Abstract

Electoral rules and form of government have important economic effects, for example on taxation and public spending. However, there are no robust results in the literature when it comes to their effect on economic growth. This paper investigates whether electoral rules and form of government affects economic growth by applying panel data techniques on a very extensive dataset. There is no robust effect of presidentialism or parliamentarism on growth. However, there is very robust evidence for a positive, and quite substantial, effect of Proportional Representation (PR) electoral rules on economic growth. This is partly due to PR systems’ propensity to generate broad-interest policies, like universal education spending, property rights protection and free-trade, rather than special interest economic policies. Also semi-proportional systems seem to enhance growth relative to plural-majoritarian systems.
1
Which democracies prosper? Electoral rules, form of government and economic growth
Carl Henrik Knutsen
Department of Political Science, University of Oslo
ABSTRACT
Electoral rules and form of government have important economic effects, for example on
taxation and public spending. However, there are no robust results in the literature when it
comes to their effect on economic growth. This paper investigates whether electoral rules and
form of government affects economic growth by applying panel data techniques on a very
extensive dataset. There is no robust effect of presidentialism or parliamentarism on growth.
However, there is very robust evidence for a positive, and quite substantial, effect of
Proportional Representation (PR) electoral rules on economic growth. This is partly due to PR
systems’ propensity to generate broad-interest policies, like universal education spending,
property rights protection and free-trade, rather than special interest economic policies. Also,
semi-proportional systems seem to enhance growth relative to plural-majoritarian systems.
RESEARCH HIGHLIGHTS
There is no effect of parliamentarism or presidentialism on economic growth
PR and semi-PR systems increase growth relative to plural-majoritarian systems
These results are based on panel data analysis, using a very extensive dataset
PR may enhance growth through inducing broad-interest- and credible policies.
2
1. INTRODUCTION
Do electoral rules or form of government (the parliamentarism-presidentialism distinction)
matter for economic growth? Political scientists have long been interested in the potential
political consequences of electoral rules and form of government, such as nature of the party
system and regime stability. However, there has lately been an increasing focus also on
constitutional rules’ economic effects, largely thanks to the great work by Torsten Persson
and Guido Tabellini (e.g. 2003; 2004). This has resulted in several theoretical insights and
empirical results. Among others, presidential systems and plural-majoritarian systems likely
have lower tax rates, less public spending, and allocate a smaller share of public spending to
universal programs (but, see Acemoglu, 2005; Gabel and Hix, 2005).
Constitutional rules may also affect economic growth through systematically affecting
governments’ economic policies (e.g. Persson and Tabellini, 2003; Rodrik, 1996) and
countries’ economic institutions (e.g. North, 1990; Acemoglu et al., 2001; Persson, 2005).
However, there is no consensus on what specific types of constitutional features that improve
growth. Although some studies indicate that PR and parliamentarism may improve growth,
there are no well-established, robust results in the literature. By utilizing a greatly expanded
dataset and panel data methodology, this study is able to more accurately test hypotheses
related to whether electoral rules and form of government affect growth.
Section 2 discusses why electoral rules and form of government may matter for growth.
Section 3 presents the data, and Section 4 the empirical analysis. The analysis finds no robust
effect of parliamentarism or presidentialism on economic growth. However, PR and semi-PR
electoral rules produce substantially higher growth rates than plural-majoritarian rules. This
result is very robust, particularly for PR, and contrasts with the mainly non-robust results in
previous studies based on less extensive data material.
3
2. LITERATURE REVIEW AND ARGUMENTS
2.1 ELECTORAL SYSTEMS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH
As Gabel and Hix (2005: 4-5) put it, “[i]n their purest form, in PR systems voters choose
between lists of candidates presented by parties in multi-member districts and seats are
allocated in proportion to the share of votes received. In majoritarian systems, in contrast,
voters choose between individual politicians in single-member districts and the winning
candidate in each district is the one who receive the most votes in a district”. The simple
dichotomy of PR and plural-majoritarian electoral rules hides substantial variation in electoral
rule design (e.g. Grofman and Lijphart, 2003; Lijphart, 1999; Cox, 1997). In the empirical
section, I add a third category of semi-PR systems, based on Schjølset’s (2008) classification.
As Schjølset notes, this is a somewhat heteregenous category, incorporating different systems
that tend to produce intermediate outcomes in terms of proportionality between votes received
and seats in parliament (p. 80). This category includes systems based on specific electoral
rules, like the Single Nontransferable Vote, which is often considered semi-proportional
(Lijphart, 1994), and systems, like Germany’s, that utilize both plurality- and PR rules when
electing legislators.
1
Political economic literature emphasizes political accountability’s importance for achieving
“good” policies and outcomes, for example economic growth (e.g. Ferejohn, 1986; Benhabib
and Przeworski, 2005). When accountability is high, voters can and do vote poorly
performing politicians out of office (e.g. Powell and Whitten, 1993). This in turn induces
politicians to exert extra effort and opt for better macroeconomic policies. Under plurality rule
“mapping from votes to seats becomes steep if electoral races are close. This connection
ought to create strong incentives for good behavior: a small improvement in the chance of
1
As for example Lijphart (1994) notes, also other aspects, such as election (or legal) treshold,
district magnitude and assembly size affect the proportionality between votes and seats.
4
victory would create a large return in terms of seats.” (Persson and Tabellini, 2004: 82).
However, if parties or candidates expect to win or lose by a landslide, the incentives to exert
effort or forego rents are weaker under plurality rule. Nevertheless, PR increases the
frequency of coalition governments (Persson et al., 2003; Powell, 2000). Under coalition
governments, voters are less able to discern which party to blame for bad performance or
reward for good. Thus, retrospective “economic voting” decreases under coalition
governments (Powell and Whitten, 1993). Also, plurality rule is associated with smaller
district magnitudes, which eases voters’ monitoring of candidates, thus improving
accountability at the district level.
Electoral rules may also affect economic growth through affecting public sector size. PR
increases taxation and public spending (Persson, 2003; Persson and Tabellini, 2003, 2004).
However, it is unclear whether balanced increases in tax revenues and public spending
increase or reduce economic growth. Microeconomic theory points to distortionary effects
from high tax-rates. However, more public revenue means better opportunities for investing in
infrastructure, education and public health care, which enhance growth (e.g. Easterly and
Rebello, 1993; Mankiw et al., 1992).
As seen above, plural-majoritarian rules were expected to increase district-level
accountability. However, voters in small districts are perhaps less concerned with policies that
enhance nationwide growth than with obtaining government resources at the rest of the
country’s expense, or protectionist measures for their cornerstone industries. Voters in PR
systems may also be concerned with redistributive policies, but larger districts and more
continuous mapping from voters to seats reduce the political incentives for proposing
narrowly targeted redistributive programs (e.g. Persson and Tabellini, 2004). Rather,
politicians under PR systems may want to propose universal redistributive programs that
5
appeal to large, geographically dispersed groups of voters. Such redistributive programs often
include increased spending on broad-based public education programs and healthcare
spending, both of which boost growth through increasing human capital (e.g. Mankiw et al.,
1992). Indeed, several studies indicate that PR increases the share of public spending going to
universal programs, and that plurality rule increases the share going to special interest groups,
particularly geographically concentrated groups in electoral distrcits with tough competition
(e.g. Persson and Tabellini, 2004; Milesi-Feretti et al., 2002). Such spending-allocation is a
rational political strategy for office-motivated politicians, but narrow programs that affect
only particular regions and groups are likely to generate less economic benefit than broader
programs related to national public goods.
Generally, PR produces “policies better serving the interests of broad majorities than do
majoritarian elections, either directly through incentives of politicians, or indirectly via party
formation and the incidence of coalition government” (Persson, 2005: 7-8). Politicians with
large winning coalitions have stronger incentives for pursuing general property rights
protection (Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2003). Thus, as PR increases the size of government’s
winning coalition, we would expect PR systems to perform better on property rights
protection. PR is also expected to induce open trade policies rather than selective
protectionism for narrow producer interests, as it insulates politicians from protectionist
demands by regional or sector-specific interests (Rogowski, 1987: 207-8). Empirically,
Persson (2005) indeed finds that PR improves property rights protection and induces trade
liberalization (see also Persson and Tabellini, 2006).
PR systems should also enhance growth rates relative to plural-majoritarian systems through
yielding less abrupt changes in parliamentary seat composition before and after elections;
policies by governments elected in PR systems are expected to last longer, and, if changed,
6
policies will be adjusted rather than reversed (e.g. Rogowski, 1987). Conversely, one of the
main problems with “majoritarian democracies” is the sudden and substantive policy-
alterations induced by shifting electoral fortunes (Lijphart, 1999). Policy- and reform
reversals have negative economic effects, as they create instability and render private
investments less productive (Rodrik, 1991). Policy reversals become even more problematic
when foresighted investors, in anticipation, withhold investments altogether. Policies’
economic success hinge upon private actors’ beliefs about their expected stability; success is
negatively related to the probability of reversal (Kydland and Prescott, 1977; North and
Weingast, 1989). In addition to having less dramatic temporal changes in parliamentary seat
composition, PR systems more often have broad coalition governments, implying that many
reforms are political compromises with broad support.
To sum up, the political economic literature has focused on the beneficial accountability
characteristics of plural-majoritarian systems, which may induce office-motivated politicians
to enact growth-promoting policies. However, other aspects with PR systems may counter
such an effect. First, there are stronger incentives for politicians under PR systems to enact
public policies that benefit broad rather than narrow interests, including growth enhancing
policies such as provision of education for the masses, property rights protection and free-
trade policies. Moreover, PR systems should increase investment, as the investment climate is
less risky because of less abrupt policy changes. Persson and Tabellini (2003) find some
evidence for the hypotheses that PR increases productivity growth, but the result is not robust.
Although Persson (2005) in some models finds a positive effect of PR on GDP per capita and
total factor productivity, the effects are not robust. Persson and Tabellini (2006) find no
significant effect of electoral rules on growth, when studying democratizing countries. Older
7
empirical studies using smaller samples generally find a small, positive or no effect of
“Consensus democracy” or PR more specifically on GDP growth (Lijphart, 1999: 263-270).
Carey and Hix (2009) show that ‘intermediate’ electoral systems to a large extent generate
one of the beneficial outcomes of PR systems, relatively accurate representation of various
voters’ preferences, without reducing the accountability-benfit of plural-majoritarian systems
too much. Above, plurality systems were hypothezised to enhance growth mainly through
enhancing accountability. Moreover, representational issues are at least indirectly related to
the argument on PR enhancing growth through inducing politicians to follow broad-interest
policies. If the representation-accountability trade-off is concave, as argued by Carey and Hix,
semi-PR systems may be expected to produce relatively high growth rates. The reason is
simply that semi-PR systems may to a large degree possess the different advantages of both
PR and plurality systems, without having the respective systems’ drawbacks.
2.2 FORM OF GOVERNMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH
There is considerable institutional variation within the classes of presidential and
parliamentary systems (e.g. Shugart and Carey, 1992; Strøm, 1990). However, in a
parliamentary system “the executive … is chosen by and responsible to an elective body (the
legislature), thus creating a single locus of sovereignty”, whereas in a presidential system
“policy-making power is divided between two separately elected bodies: the legislature and
the president” (Gerring et al., 2009: 337). It is common to operate with a third category, semi-
presidential systems; also denoted “mixed systems” (Cheibub, 2007). Cheibub classifies these
as systems where either the assembly or the directly elected president can remove the
government (2007: 34).
Presidential systems are more fragmented, institutionally, than parliamentary systems,
because of weaker ties between legislature and executive. Separation of executive and
8
legislative power is argued to facilitate credible political commitments (Keefer and Stasavage,
2003) and increase information revelation about political processes to the public (Persson et
al., 1997), thus improving political accountability, which may again enhance growth (e.g.
Benhabib and Przeworski, 2005). Moreover, in a presidential system, both executive and
legislature are “institutional veto players” (Tsebelis, 2002). Presidential systems are thus
assumed to have greater checks and balances on executive power, which mitigates
opportunities for power abuse. Power concentration may reduce growth, as the incentives of
those in power are often not aligned with growth-conducive policies (e.g. Olson, 1993).
However, separation of powers under presidentialism may also amplify rigidity in the political
system (Linz, 1990). The possibility of different parties controlling the legislature and the
executive under presidentialism could result in political gridlock, thereby complicating
passing of efficiency-enhancing economic reforms.
2
Presidential systems may also increase
special interest groups’ opportunity to affect political processes, which may reduce economic
dynamism (Olson, 1982). Industrial groups or other lobbies can tie their fortunes with
important groups in parliament or the president (e.g. Cox and McCubbins, 2001).
Presidential systems reduce public spending and taxation (see e.g. Persson et al., 2000;
Persson and Tabellini 2004). But as there is no clear link between public sector size and
economic growth, it is unclear whether presidentialism hurts or helps growth through this
channel. However, according to Gerring et al. (2009: 353), there are several other reasons
why parliamentarism improves governance, and thus economic outcomes. One underlying
factor is parliamentarism’s propensity to better solve political coordination problems, since it
2
Several contributions have either nuanced (e.g. Shugart & Carey, 1992) or disputed (e.g.
Cheibub, 2007) Linz’ argument (1990) that presidentialism increases the probability of
democratic breakdown.
9
institutionalizes debate and negotiations, and reduces the number of veto players (pp. 354-5).
Parliamentarism also strengthens party discipline (e.g. Gerring et al., 2009), among others
because of the vote of confidence procedure (e.g. Huber, 1996). High party discipline
channels public spending towards broad, national programs, instead of narrow, targeted
programs to region-specific interests. Indeed, parliamentary regimes allocate more of their
public spending to broad, universal programs (Persson and Tabellini, 2004).
Gerring et al. (2009) find that parliamentarism outperforms presidentialism on among others
economic growth, bureaucratic quality, investment environment and life expectancy. But,
Persson and Tabellini (2003) find no robust effect on corruption of form of government.
However, presidential systems inhibit economic institutional factors like bureaucratic quality
and property rights, and may reduce labor- and total factor productivity growth in low-quality
democracies (Persson and Tabellini, 2003). Persson (2005) finds that reform towards
parliamentary democracy may generate higher economic growth than reforms towards
presidential democracy, but the results are not robust. Reforms into parliamentarism
strengthen property rights and enhance trade openness (Persson, 2005). But, Persson and
Tabellini (2006: 321) find that a “new parliamentary democracy grows 1.5 percentage points
less than a new presidential democracy”, when studying democratizing countries.
3. DATA AND METHODOLOGICAL ISSUES
Several models below include more than 3500 country-year observations from over 100
countries. Some countries have time-series from 1820 to 2002, although most have shorter
time series. This is the most extensive dataset used for analyzing constitutional rules’
economic effects. The long time-series used here dramatically expands the number of data
points, and panel data analysis becomes an option. This allows utilizing within-nation-, as
well as cross-sectional, variation. Constitutional structures seldom change (Persson and
10
Tabellini, 2003: 88). However, there are democracies with different constitutional
experiences, particularly on electoral rules. To name some, Argentina, Belgium, Chile,
Colombia, Greece, Italy, Macedonia, New Zealand, Norway, The Philippines, Spain and Sri
Lanka have all experimented with different electoral rules over the time period covered here.
Thus, the dramatic expansion of time series and application of panel data models contribute to
a literature where empirical tests have found ambiguous and mainly non-robust results.
Data on PPP-adjusted GDP per capita and population are from Maddison (2006). Maddison
has estimated GDP and population using a variety of sources, and some estimates rely on less
valid proxies than others, especially before WWII (Maddison, 2006). Some of the population
and GDP time-series are interpolated, assuming constant GDP- and population growth rates
(REFERENCE REMOVED). Data on democracy level and regime duration are from Polity
IV (Marshall and Jagger, 2002). I use Schjølset’s (2008: 135-42) classification and data on
constitutional structures. Only country-years with a Polity-score 3 are classified as
democratic by Schjølset (the Polity-index goes from -10 to 10), and thus included in the
analysis. After 1820, 38 percent of classified country-years are presidential systems, 26
percent are semi-presidential, and 37 percent are parliamentarian. Also, 44 percent are PR
systems, 10 percent are semi-PR and 46 percent are plural-majoritarian.
I furthermore use Schjølset’s (2008) data on federal, unitary and mixed federal-unitary
systems. Colonizer-, region- and plurality religion dummies are from REFERENCE
REMOVED. Data on latitude, the Frankel-Romer instrument for trade openness (FRAROM),
and fraction of English (ENGFRAC) and other major European language speakers
(EURFRAC) are from Hall and Jones (1999). Ethnic fractionalization data are from Alesina et
al. (2003). This index covers more countries than the older ELF-index used by Persson and
Tabellini (2003).
11
On average, presidential systems had lower economic growth rates than semi-presidential-
and parliamentarian systems from 1820 to 2002. Whereas presidential systems’ GDP per
capita on average grew 1.5 percent annually, parliamentarian systems grew with 2.2 percent
and semi-presidential with 2.5 percent. Especially after the oil-crisis in 1972, presidential
systems grew slowly relative to other systems. On average, PR systems grew with 2.5 percent,
whereas semi-PR and plural-majoritarian systems grew with 1.9 and 1.6 percent respectively.
There are few observed semi-PR and PR country-years in the 19th century. Differences
between electoral systems are therefore primarily based on data from the 20th century. PR
systems outperformed plural-majoritarian systems throughout the 20th century, especially
before 1972. However, countries with PR rules and parliamentarism may grow faster because
they are systematically related to other relevant variables, like initial income level or
geographic factors. We therefore control for such factors below.
There is no single, overarching theoretical framework on this issue, which complicates
statistical modeling. However, the solid empirical work by Persson and Tabellini (2003), and
later methodical criticisms (e.g. Acemoglu, 2005), has helped identify plausible control
variables. I follow Persson and Tabellini (2003) closely, in terms of control variables used.
Since particular institutional structures have been relatively popular in different time periods,
and these periods are associated with different global economic growth rates, I enter decade
dummies as controls in all models (1990s extend to 2002), to control for time-specific effects.
In all models, the independent variables are lagged with two years, to reduce endogeneity
problems.
I first employ OLS with Panel Corrected Standard Errors (PCSE) (Beck and Katz, 1995).
OLS with PCSE utilizes both between- and within-nation variation. The interpretation of
coefficients is similar to OLS, but the models take into account the cross-sectional time-
12
series structure of the data (standard errors take into account heteroskedasticity and
contemporaneous correlation between panels, and AR1-autocorrelation within panels). GDP
per capita growth is the dependent variable. In Model 1A, I enter dummies for PR and semi-
PR systems and dummies for parliamentary and semi-presidential systems. Plural-
majoritarian and presidential systems are reference categories. In addition, following Persson
and Tabellini (2003), I add dummies for British (plus American) colonies, a dummy for
Spanish and Portuguese colonies, and a dummy for other former colonies. I also add region
dummies, dummies for federal and mixed federal-unitary systems, the ethnic fractionalization
index, log GDP per capita, log population, log regime duration and decade dummies.
4. EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS
4. 1 MAIN RESULTS
The results from Model 1A in Table 1, based on 3701 country-years from 107 countries,
indicate a strong, significant effect of electoral rules; both PR and semi-PR systems produce
higher growth than plural-majoritarian. The effect of PR is significant at the 0.1%-level and
the effect of semi-PR at the 1%-level. The estimates indicate that PR elections increase annual
GDP per capita growth with almost 1 percentage point relative to plural-majoritarian.
However, 1A shows no significant effects of form of government on growth.
Model 1B controls also for fraction of English speakers, fraction of other major European
language speakers, the Frankel Romer trade instrument and latitude. In 1B, several
observations drop out because of missing data. The results are however strikingly similar to
those from 1A; the positive effects of PR and semi-PR are quite large, and significant at the
1%- and 5%-levels respectively. There is still no significant effect of form of government.
Model 1C also controls for degree of democracy (Polity) and plurality religion. As seen in
Table 1, the results are relatively similar to those from 1A and 1B. The positive effects of PR
and semi-PR are quite robust. Form of government, however, does not matter for growth.
13
Table 1 Results from OLS with PCSE and Fixed Effects modelsa
OLS1A
OLS1B
OLS1C
FE2A
FE2B
FE2C
b/(t)
b/(t)
b/(t)
b/(t)
b/(t)
b/(t)
PR
0.93*** (3.31)
0.95** (3.20)
1.04*** (3.36)
1.22** (3.14)
0.95* (2.45)
0.81* (2.11)
Semi-PR
1.17** (2.86)
1.02* (2.53)
1.02* (2.39)
1.38* (2.30)
0.53 (0.91)
0.44 (0.75)
Parliam.
-0.15 (-0.45)
-0.19 (-0.57)
-0.21 (-0.62)
0.30 (0.54)
0.41 (0.74)
0.58 (1.05)
Semi-pres.
-0.04 (-0.12)
-0.25 (-0.68)
-0.43 (-1.07)
0.02 (0.03)
0.15 (0.28)
0.43 (0.82)
Ethnic fract.
-1.67*** (-3.86)
-1.55*** (-3.45)
-1.34* (-2.54)
British col.
0.26 (0.69)
-0.24 (-0.47)
-0.16 (-0.29)
Iberian col.
-1.61* (-2.16)
-2.62*** (-3.47)
-2.46** (-2.96)
Other col.
-2.03* (-2.52)
-2.651** (-3.10)
-2.23^ (-1.78)
Federalist
0.09 (0.32)
-0.02 (-0.07)
0.01 (0.04)
0.11 (0.11)
0.19 (0.20)
0.63 (0.65)
Hyb. fed-un.
0.33 (0.76)
0.40 (0.97)
0.40 (0.98)
-0.22 (-0.37)
-0.00 (-0.00)
0.27 (0.44)
E.Eur.-Sov.
-0.73 (-0.64)
-0.26 (-0.27)
-0.41 (-0.42)
Africa SS
-1.28* (-2.02)
-1.23 (-1.50)
-0.83 (-1.00)
Asia-Pacific
0.61 (0.99)
1.05 (1.34)
1.25 (1.27)
M.E. - N.A.
0.18 (0.32)
0.22 (0.35)
0.78 (0.64)
Latin Am.
0.27 (0.36)
0.14 (0.19)
-0.12 (-0.17)
Ln GDP pc
-0.41 (-1.55)
-0.35 (-1.36)
-0.35 (-1.30)
-4.99*** (-9.22)
-4.21*** (-8.28)
-4.30*** (-8.42)
Ln Pop.
-0.08 (-0.95)
-0.27* (-2.33)
-0.37** (-2.89)
-1.26*** (-3.36)
-1.04** (-2.84)
-1.06** (-2.90)
Ln Reg. dur.
0.02 (0.21)
-0.08 (-0.74)
-0.12 (-1.06)
0.13 (0.95)
-0.12 (-0.92)
-0.17 (-1.33)
ENGFRAC
-0.55 (-0.93)
-0.66 (-1.01)
EURFRAC
0.64 (1.43)
1.10* (2.12)
HJFRAROM
-0.50* (-2.08)
-0.58* (-2.21)
Latitude
-0.00 (-0.46)
0.00 (0.47)
Polity
-0.07 (-1.00)
-0.17** (-2.61)
Sunni
-1.44 (-1.46)
Shia
1.57 (1.29)
Catholic
-0.60 (-0.47)
Protestant
-0.45 (-0.33)
Orthodox
0.63 (0.39)
Hindu
0.22 (0.17)
Buddhist+
-0.54 (-0.43)
Indigeneous
-1.50 (-1.11)
N
3701
3521
3520
3701
3521
3520
The results above may be driven by omitted country-specific factors. There is relatively little
within-nation variation in electoral systems and form of government over time (Persson and
Tabellini, 2003: 88). However, I have more within-nation variation to draw on than Persson
and Tabellini, because of much longer time-series. I therefore estimate Fixed Effects (FE)
models, which control for country-specific factors by adding country-dummies. FE models
thus estimate effects based only on within-nation variation over time. The FE results are
strikingly similar to the OLS with PCSE results. There is no significant effect of form of
government. PR significantly improves growth in all models (at least 5%-level). Even if we
a *** indicates p<0.001, ** indicates p<0.01, * indicates p<0.05 and ^ indicates p<0.10.
Decade dummies and constant are omitted.
14
estimate the effect of PR without utilizing cross-country comparisons, we find that it
improves growth. Only the FE model with the fewest controls yields a significant effect (5%-
level) for semi-PR. However, there are relatively few observations to draw inferences from
for semi-PR, and the non-robust result is thus perhaps not very surprising, particularly given
that the FE models do not utilize cross-country vatiation.
4. 2 ROBUSTNESS CHECKS
The results above may however be sensitive to different specifications. I therefore conducted
additional robustness checks. OLS with PCSE results are reported, but results are quite similar
when using FE models. First, I conducted sensitivity checks, leaving out one independent
variable or set of dummies at a time from 1A. All models showed significant PR and semi-PR
coefficients at least at the 5%-level. The forms of government dummies were always
insignificant. Second, I tested models with annual dummies rather than decade dummies. PR
was still significant (1%-level) in all models, and form of government was still insignificant.
Third, I tested different lags on the independent variables. Models where independent
variables were lagged with one or three years had significant PR-coefficients at the 1%-level;
and models with four or five years had significant coefficients at the 5%-level. Also the semi-
PR dummy was robust. There were no significant forms of government dummies in any
model. Fourth, the criterion for being included in the samples above was a Polity-score ≥3.
Polity cut-offs of 4, 5, 6 and 7 were tested, and the results remain stable. The results above are
thus not driven by the inclusion of “semi-democracies”.
Fifth, I estimated models using only data from after 1899, 1945 and 1979 respectively. All
models still showed a positive, significant effect of PR (at least 1%-level) and semi-PR (at
least 5%-level). Parliamentarism and semi-presidentialism were still insignificant (10%-
level), but with an exception for the post-1979 sample: In 1A and 1B, parliamentarism had a
positive, significant (5%-level) effect. This will be discussed further below.
15
Sixh, I tested whether electoral rules had different effects in Western countries (Western
Europe, US, Canada, Australia and New Zealand) than in other countries. The effect of PR in
the Western sample was somewhat weaker, but still significant at the 5%-level in 1A, 10%-
level in 1B, and insignificant in 1C (p=0.16). This non-robust result is not very dramatic for
the conclusion above, given the relatively few observations in the sample. Interestingly, PR
systems had a significant positive effect at the 1%-level in all models in “the rest” of the
world. The effect of PR is thus relatively robust over time and space.
Seventh, there may be outliers driving the results. The five Nordic countries have been
economically successful, and have mostly used PR. However, the PR coefficient was still
significant (1%-level), when excluding these countries from the global sample. The lack of
positive effect of parliamentarism could have been due to the US’ high growth. But, the effect
of parliamentarism on growth was still insignificant when excluding the US. Table A2 in the
Internet Appendix presents some of the results described above.
I also applied 2SLS to check whether the results above are due to economic growth affecting
constitutional structures (see Persson and Tabellini, 2003; Acemoglu, 2005). These results
yield weaker results for the hypothesis that PR enhances growth, and, like above, find no
effect of form of government. These results, and a methodical discussion, are provided in the
Internet Appendix together with other robustness checks, for example random effects- and
non-parametric matching models. The latter models find quite similar results to those reported
above; a positive effect of PR and semi-PR and no effect of form of government.
4. 3 A BRIEF DISCUSSION
Section 2.2 presented arguments indicating that presidentialism had both positive and
negative effects on growth; the results above may be due to these effects cancelling each other
out. However, the arguments in 2.2 may have questionable relevance in the first place. The
16
number of veto players may affect growth. However, as Tsebelis (2002) points out, this
number depends on several other institutional structures and political factors. There is also
large institutional variation within the categories of parliamentary and presidential regimes.
These variations matter for different political processes and outcomes (e.g. Shugart and
Carey, 1992), and may also matter for growth.
Moreover, formal checks on executive powers are at best moderately correlated with de facto
checks. The negative effect of presidentialism in the post-1980 sample, Gerring et al.’s (2009)
results based on data from after 1960, and Persson and Tabellini’s result (2003) that
presidentialism is economically harmful in low-quality democracies, may all be explained by
personal power concentration in new, low-quality presidential democracies. Parliamentarism
may concentrate power to parties controlling the majority of seats in parliament. However,
personal power concentration is likely worse for an economy (e.g. Olson, 1993), and
presidents may abuse their positions for personal gains. Presidentialism has been linked to
power concentration, personification of politics and weak parties in Africa (van de Walle,
2003) and Eastern European and ex-Soviet countries (Fesnic, 2006). There might thus be a
selection effect in the post-1980 sample, as elites in young democracies have substituted low-
quality presidential democracy for autocracy. However, if elites in democratizing African or
ex-Soviet countries opt for presidentialism because of its (correctly) perceived advantages
in allowing for personal power concentration, it is unclear whether this selection generates
pure bias or is indirectly part of a negative effect of presidentialism on growth.
Section 2.1 presented an argument pointing out that plural-majoritarian systems enhanced
growth because of high political accountability. Empirically, this seems to be trumped by
other factors. The theoretical discussion pointed out PR systems’ ability to reduce economic
risk through generating more stable and credible policies. Risk reduction and stability could
17
affect a wide variety of economic activities and transactions (North, 1990). One plausible
candidate is physical capital investment. However, when I substitute real investment as share
of GDP for economic growth as dependent variable, there is no significant effect of PR. The
investment-data from the World Development Indicators (WDI) are not as extensive as the
GDP data from Maddison. However, these results may indicate that PR does not enhance
investment, which casts doubts on the “PR and credible policies” argument’s validity.
However, another likely factor behind PR systems’ higher growth is their tendency to produce
broad-interest policies. There is already strong empirical evidence that PR enhances trade
openness and property rights protection (Persson, 2005). Human capital is another vital source
of economic growth (e.g. Mankiw et al., 1992), and provision of universal education is a
typical broad-interest policy (Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2003). Indeed, models where primary
or secondary school enrollment ratios (from WDI) are substituted for economic growth,
typically find a positive, significant effect of PR. The 1A-model, for example, finds a
significant effect at the 1%-level for primary- and 0.1%-level for secondary schooling. This is
a likely important pathway through which PR increases growth.
5. CONCLUSION
This paper estimated the effects of electoral rules and form of government on economic
growth. The results were based on a much larger dataset than earlier studies draw on.
Pesidentialism does not seem to reduce economic growth. Cheibub (2007) contested Linz
(1990) perils-of-presidentialism thesis on democratic survival. This paper contests the
economic-perils-of-presidentialism results recently recorded by Gerring et al. (2009).
However, also this paper finds a negative effect of presidentialism on growth after 1979.
Persson and Tabellini (2003) find that presidentialism only hurts growth in low-quality
18
democracies, and Gerring et al.’s results may stem from many new, low-quality democracies
opting for presidentialism.
Electoral systems, however, seem to matter systematically for growth. Plural-majoritarian
systems may generate higher political accountability than PR systems, but not necessarily
much higher than semi-PR systems (Carey and Hix, 2009). However, plural-majoritarian
systems produce lower economic growth than both PR- and semi-PR systems. PR systems
likely produce higher growth because they promote broad interest-, rather than special
interest, policies, and perhaps because PR systems produce more stable and thus credible
economic policies. The effect is astonishingly robust, and point-estimates indicate that PR
increases growth rates with 1 percentage point relative to plural-majoritarian systems. PR and
semi-PR systems are thus not only beneficial for representation of diverse groups in politics
(Lijphart, 1999; Carey and Hix, 2009) and for decreasing the distance between median voter
and median government member (Huber and Powell, 1994; Carey and Hix, 2009). PR and
semi-PR systems also generate more prosperity than plural-majoritarian systems.
19
6. LITERATURE
Acemoglu, D., 2005. Constitutions, Politics and Economics: A Review Essay on Persson and
Tabellini’s "The Economic Effect of Constitutions". Cambridge, MA. NBER Working Paper
11235.
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J.A., 2001. The Colonial Origins of Comparative
Development: An Empirical Investigation. American Economic Review 91 (5), 1369-1401.
Alesina, A., Devleeschauwer, A., Easterly, W., Kurlat, S., Wacziarg, R., 2003.
Fractionalization. Journal of Economic Growth 8 (2), 155-194.
Beck, N., Katz, J.N., 1995. What to do (and not to do) with Time-Series Cross-Section Data.
The American Political Science Review 89 (3), 634-647.
Beck, N., Katz, J.N., 2001. Throwing Out the Baby with the Bath Water: A Comment on
Green, Kim, and Yoon. International Organization 55 (2), 487495.
Benhabib, J., Przeworski, A., 2005. Economic Growth under Political Accountability. New
York University. Working Paper.
Bueno de Mesquita, B., Smith, A., Siverson, R.M., and Morrow, J.D., 2003. The Logic of
Political Survival. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
Carey, J.M., Hix, S., 2009. The Electoral Sweet Spot: Low-Magnitude Proportional Electoral
Systems. Working Paper.
Cheibub, J.A., 2007. Presidentialism, Parliamentarism and Democracy. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Cox, G., 1997. Making votes count: Strategic coordination in the world’s electoral systems.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Cox, G., McCubbins, M., 2001. The Institutional Determinants of Economic Policy
Outcomes. In: Haggard, S., McCubbins, M., (Eds.), Presidents and Parliaments. Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, pp. 21-63.
Ferejohn, J., 1986. Incumbent performance and electoral control. Public Choice 50 (1-3), 5-
25.
Fesnic, F., 2006. Institutional Design and Democracy in Post-Communist Countries.
University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign. Paper.
Gabel, M., Hix, S., 2005. Reconsidering the Economic Effects of Constitutions. Paper.
Gerring, J., Thacker, S.C., Moreno, C., 2009. Are Parliamentary Systems Better?
Comparative Political Studies 42 (3), 327-359.
Hall, R.E., Jones, C.I., 1999. Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output Per
Worker Than Others? Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (1), 83-116.
20
Huber, J.D., 1996. The vote of confidence in parliamentary democracies. American Political
Science Review 90 (2), 269-282.
Huber, J.D., Powell, G.B., 1994. Congruence between citizens and policymakers in two
visions of liberal democracy. World Politics 46 (3), 291-326.
Kydland, F.E., Prescott, E.C., 1977. Rules rather than discretion: The inconsistency of optimal
plans. Journal of political economy 85 (3), 473-493.
Lijphart, A., 1994. Electoral Systems and Party Systems: A Study of Twenty-Seven
Democracies 1945-1990. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Lijphart, A., 1999. Patterns of Democracy. Yale University-Press, New Haven.
Lijphart, A., Grofman, B., 2003. Introduction. In: Lijphart, A., Grofman, B., (Eds.), Electoral
Rules and Their Political Consequences. Agathon Press, New York, pp.1-15.
Linz, J.J., 1990. The Perils of Presidentialism. Journal of Democracy 1 (1), 51-69.
Maddison, A., 2006. The World Economy. OECD Publishing, Paris.
Mankiw, G.N., Romer, D., Weil, D.N., 1992. A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic
Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107 (2), 407-437.
Marshall, M.G., Jaggers, K., 2002. Polity IV Project Dataset Users’ Manual. College Park:
Program Center for International Development and Conflict Management, University of
Maryland. Manual.
Milesi-Ferretti, G.M., Perotti, R., Rostagno, M., 2002. Electoral Systems and Public
Spending. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (2), 609-657.
North, D.C., 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge
University Press, New York.
North, D.C., Weingast, B.R., 1989. Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of
Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England. The Journal of
Economic History 49 (4), 803-832.
Olson, M., 1982. The Rise and Decline of Nations. Economic Growth, Stagflation and Social
Rigidities. Yale University Press, New Haven.
Olson, M., 1993. Dictatorship, Democracy and Development. The American Political Science
Review 87 (3), 567-576.
Persson, T., 2005. Forms of democracy, policy and economic development. Working Paper.
Persson, T., Tabellini, G., 2003. The Economic Effects of Constitutions. The MIT Press,
Cambridge, MA.
21
Persson, T., Tabellini, G., 2004. Constitutions and Economic Policy. The Journal of
Economic Perspectives 18 (1), 75-98.
Persson, T., Tabellini, G., 2006. Democracy and development: The devil in the details.
American Economic Review 96 (2), 319-324.
Persson, T., Roland, G., Tabellini, G., 1997. Separation of powers and political accountability.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (4), 1163-1202.
Persson, T., Roland, G., Tabellini, G., 2000. Comparative politics and public finance. Journal
of Political Economy 108 (6), 1121-1161.
Persson, T., Roland, G., Tabellini, G., 2003. How do electoral rules shape party structures,
government coalitions, and economic policies? Working Paper.
Powell, G.B., 2000. Elections as instruments of democracy. Yale University Press, New
Haven.
Powell, G.B., Whitten, G.D., 1993. A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking
Account of the Political Context. American Journal of Political Science 37 (2), 391-414.
Rodrik, D., 1991. Policy Uncertainty and Private Investment in Developing Countries. Journal
of Development Economics 36 (2), 229-242.
Rodrik, D., 1996. Understanding Economic Policy Reform. Journal of Economic Literature
34 (1), 9-41.
Rogowski, R., 1987. Trade and the Variety of Democratic Institutions. International
Organization 41 (2), 203-23.
Schjølset, A., 2008. Institutional Variance of the Democratic Peace, 1816-2002: Electoral,
Executive, and Federal Systems in Time and Space. University of Southern California. PhD
thesis.
Shugart, M.S., Carey, J.M., 1992. Presidents and Assemblies: Constitutional Design and
Electoral Dynamics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Strøm, K., 1990. Minority Government and Majority Rule. Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge.
Tsebelis, G., 2002. Veto Players How Political Institutions Work. Princeton University
Press, Princeton.
van de Walle, N., 1993. Presidentialism and clientelism in Africa’s emerging party systems.
Journal of Modern African Studies 41 (2), 297-321.
TWO REFERENCES ARE REMOVED FOR ANONYMITY
... The adoption of alternative electoral systems (Boix 1999;Benoit 2004;Colomer 2016;Yeung 2017) and their political consequences (Lijphart 1990;Norris 2004) have long been studied in political science. Along similar lines, the economic implications of electoral rules have also attracted scholarly attention (Rodrik 1996;Persson et al. 2003;Knutsen 2011). Yet there is no robust consensus on which type of electoral rule is more conducive to economic growth. 1 The mechanism linking the electoral rule a country adopted to the overall macroeconomic growth is complex, intertwined with many other factors. ...
... Electoral rules have long been the focus of research in constitutional political economy (Voigt 2011). Theories and evidence are found between electoral rules and growth (Knutsen 2011), public spending (Lizzeri and Persico 2001;Persson and Tabellini 2004), trade (Martin and Steiner 2016) and R&D (Krūminas 2019). ...
... Even if voters can differentiate politicians in terms of performance, they cannot directly vote them out due to the party-list voting system and thus "retrospective economic voting" is less feasible. PR have certain features that could countervail the potential negative effects (Knutsen 2011). An alternative channel suggests that PR might be more likely to have positive growth effect as it tends to implement universal redistributive programs and spending programs that appeal to broader electorate than MR. ...
Article
Full-text available
Electoral rules are found to induce different incentives to politicians and have various effects on the economic performance of countries. The literature is however silent on whether this effect is homogeneous across industries within a country. This paper argues with an analytical model that an incumbent government under majoritarian rules tends to favour larger industries so as to secure votes from the employees and relatives of those industries. By constructing and exploiting an original dataset that covers disaggregated data on output growth of 61 industries in 55 countries, we find that larger industries in terms of employment size grow slower than smaller ones under non-majoritarian electoral rules, but such a correlation is absent under majoritarian rule. This result is robust across different regression models and could well be explained by favouritism of governments towards larger industries.
... The aim of this paper is to develop and test an explanation on how electoral systems could affect the composition of public R&D spending. Although there is literature on the economic effects of electoral systems (Persson et al. 2007;Knutsen 2011) as well as literature on the economics of government R&D spending (David et al. 2000;Czarnitzki and Licht 2006;Zúñiga-Vicente et al. 2014), they have been considered together very rarely to the author's knowledge (Kim 2011;Krūminas 2017). Therefore, the main value added of the paper is connecting the two branches of research. ...
... Given this economic undercurrent, that pervades the role of electoral systems; one can assume that impacts would be felt across a wider spectrum of public policy. Indeed, scholars have found links between electoral systems and economic growth (Knutsen 2011), inequality (Verardi 2005), firm performance (Camyar and Ulupinar 2019), trade (Martin and Steiner 2016), and importantly public spending (Lizzeri and Persico 2001;Milesi-Ferretti et al. 2002;Persson and Tabellini 1999, 2005Breunig and Busemeyer 2012). Indeed, electoral rules are often considered 1 3 ...
... Milesi-Ferretti et al. 2002) • measuring vote shares (cf. Milesi-Ferretti et al. 2002) For this research, I use a dummy variable approach following Knutsen (2011). This ensures that conceptual difference between the two types of electoral systems is not lost. ...
Article
Full-text available
Despite research on R&D and innovation policies, the effect of constitutional rules in this area has not received adequate attention yet. The paper contributes to filling this research gap by proposing that electoral systems affect governments’ decisions regarding R&D spending. It is expected that investment in R&D is closer to a bounded public good than to transfer payment. Therefore, governments in countries with majoritarian electoral rules should be willing to use this instrument to influence election outcomes. Both the amount invested and structure of funding is expected to depend on whether a government is elected via proportional or majoritarian rules. The analysis covers 25 OECD countries between 1981 and 2014, and relies on panel data analysis. The findings suggest that governments elected under majoritarian rules project higher government budget appropriations or outlays for research and development (GBAORD) than governments elected under proportional rules. Furthermore, GBAORD is more fragmented thematically in countries with proportional electoral rules.
... Some analysts identify positive, yet inconsistent effects of proportional rules on economic growth (Lijphart 1999;Persson and Tabellini 2003) and on GDP per capita (Persson 2005). Others ascertain a somewhat stronger electoral effect on economic performance, but in opposite directions; Knutsen (2011) discerns a positive effect of higher electoral proportionality on economic growth and Alfano and Baraldi (2008) report stronger economic growth under greater disproportionality. Then, these weak and inconsistent findings lead to the question of whether the key institutional mechanism of preference aggregation and mediation in modern representative democracies matters economically at all. ...
... Studies indicate that public sector size varies under different electoral systems. In particular, taxation and public spending are shown to be higher under proportional rules than under plurality-majoritarian rules (Knutsen 2011;Milesi-Ferretti et al. 2002;Persson and Tabellini 2003). That is because electoral competition is supposedly stiffer under plurality-majoritarian rules, leading to more targeted redistribution and lower supply of public goods. ...
Article
Full-text available
Prior research presents mixed results for electoral impact on economic performance, thereby raising the question of whether electoral systems matter economically at all. We argue that electoral systems can conceivably generate a robust economic impact at the firm level. This argument is grounded in a recent scholarship on the political economy of corporate governance. Analysts discern electoral systems as a significant determinant of a country’s corporate governance regime and its two central components: investor and employment protection. Building on a wealth of research relating investor and employment protection to firms’ economic behavior, we develop the hypothesis that firm performance is stronger under plurality-majoritarian rules than under proportional rules. Our panel study of firms in 21 advanced democracies from 1989 to 2007 supports our hypothesis. Overall, this research helps to fill in an important gap in understanding of why it matters to choose one electoral system over another.
... Papaioannou and Siourounis [74], using annual data for a panel of 166 countries during the period 1960-2009, found that democratisation leads to at least a 1% increase in the growth rate of GDP per capita. Knutsen [75] confirmed this finding. Doucouliagos and Ulubasoglu [70] concluded that the net effect of democracy on the economy does not seem to be harmful. ...
Article
Full-text available
This study provides empirical evidence about the effects of various dimensions of gender inequalities (education, labour market and institutional representation) on economic growth. We use data from the World Bank Development Indicators database for the period 1990–2017. We initially use a large panel of 105 developing countries. Subsequently we study a panel with the sub-Saharan African (SSA) countries since this region is one of the poorest regions in the world. We estimate cross-country and panel regressions. The results suggest that gender equality in education contributes to economic growth and this is a common feature in developing countries. The contribution of equality in education to growth seems to be greater in the SSA countries than in the entire sample of developing countries. The female–male ratio of labour market participation is not statistically significant. We also find a significant link between the presence of women in parliaments and growth in the sample of all developing countries, while this relationship is negative for the SSA countries. It is likely that despite the increased participation of women in the political arena in these countries, women may still encounter major obstacles to altering political priorities and affecting economic growth.
... The debate on economic growth-democracy nexus both in theory and previous research has been caused by differences in methodology, data and patterns of development policies in each country (regions) also often caused by the government regime's policy in responding to political changes and political will to improve development, consequently, the empirical findings have mixed results and lack of consensus. For example, Rock (2009) and Knutsen (2011) found a strong and positive influence of democracy on economic growth. Conversely, the viewpoint of others confirmed that democracy negatively influenced growth (You, 2011;Rachdi and Saidi, 2015). ...
Article
Full-text available
Purpose of the study: Firstly, to construct a modified human development index by incorporating new dimensions (democracy and employment). Secondly, to measure and compare human development progress in Indonesian provinces. Thirdly, to examine the nexus between human development, economic growth, and democracy during the period 2010-2017. Methodology: Principle Component Analysis (PCA) method is employed to combining components into one index (composite index) which we call MHDI. The panel simultaneous equation model is applied to examine the nexus between human development, economic growth, and democracy. Main Findings: There were significant ranking differences between MHDI and HDI-UNDP in 24 provinces of 33 Indonesian provinces. The most significant ranking differences were found in several provinces, especially Maluku, West Java, Central Java, East Java, and Central Kalimantan. The study found a strong two-way relationship between human development and economic growth as well as between human development and democracy. Applications of this study: This study recommends that human development policies supported by rapid economic growth and democratic stability should be one of the development priorities through government spending and support from private investment (the private sector) which focuses on the development of education and health infrastructure throughout the Indonesian province. Novelty/Originality of this study: This study employs different methods for constructing a human development index by incorporating a new dimension (democracy and employment).
... Similarly, it must be taken into account that in Spain there are also many legislative chambers under a complex multilevel political system that in fact works as a federal system and generates many interdependencies between levels of government (Field, 2009;León, 2014;Rodden and Wibbels, 2011;Toboso and Scorsone, 2015). These interactions do in fact also influence electoral results and the final share of seats as well as emerging public policies (Pallarés and Keating, 2003;Leon, 2012;Sanguinetti and Tomassi, 2004;Rodden, 2002;Toboso 2005Toboso , 2006Knutsen, 2011). Finally, to clearly state that our research endeavour is not that of obtaining predictions but a more modest one, it is also relevant to stress that electoral results and seat sharing also depend on many other institutional and non-institutional factors besides those electoral ones mentioned above (Scartascini et al., 2013;Spiller et al., 2010;Holm-Hadullaa et al., 2012;Schofield and Caballero, 2011;Schofield et al., 2013). ...
Article
Full-text available
The current paper focuses on the Spanish electoral rules governing political competition for the central “Congreso de los Diputados”. It is well-documented that the system as a whole has traditionally favoured one or the other of the two main political parties (PP and PSOE) at the expense of proportionality and the remaining political parties. This paper focuses on some key Spanish electoral rules and investigates how much the observed biases could be altered by introducing some alternative rules taken from the Swedish electoral system, ceteris paribus. Measures of disproportionality are made through the Loosemore-Hanby index and the Gallagher index. The electoral raw data used for our estimations comes from the 2011, 2015 and 2016 last three Spanish general elections. The basic contribution of the paper is an empirical one as it provides a new example that institutions matter for results.
... This study found that, statically, there is weakly negative relationship between these variables. As seen above, Heshamti and Kim (2017) Knutsen (2011) found that there appears no effect democracy on the economic growth. ...
Article
There is growing body of literature over the last decade years examining the question “Does democracy induce economic performance or slow it down? If so, what way it does? This relationship studied by social scientists especially since 19th centuries have been become more of an issue with democracy movements occurring middle east. Previous studies have pointed out there may exist the existence of either positive or negative relationship between these two variables. The proponents of democratization put forward that the democracy fosters economic growth by increasing the accumulation of human capital, reducing income inequality, providing with political stability and preventing social disasters. In this context, this paper searches for this relationship based on Islamic Countries containing totally 49 countries. The study covers data for years between 2010 and 2016 and analysis this relationship through Generalized Moment Methods (GMM). The results of this study show that there is a positive relationship between them and one-point increase in democracy index causes averagely 0.45 basis point rise on the growth of GDP Per Capita for related countries.
... As such, plurality electoral rules should correspond with more trade protection owing to greater receptiveness to lobbying by firms or industries that are or would be vulnerable to competition with more competitive foreign firms. Other scholars reach analogous conclusions with different arguments: Knutsen (2011) contends that landslide wins under plurality rules lead to more rent seeking and particularistic policy-making by legislators; Saksena and Anderson (2008) attribute the link between PR systems and liberal trade policies to the insulation of politicians from special interest lobbying. Ito (2015), Grossman and Helpman (2005) and Hatfield and Hauk (2014) all find evidence of a relationship between PR systems and freer trade policies in panel analyses across a range of samples. ...
Article
Full-text available
Despite established benefits in free trade, protectionism persists to varying degrees across the world. Why is that? Political institutions govern the ways in which competing trade-policy preferences are aggregated, shaping policy outcomes. The ubiquitous binary PR/plurality indicator in the trade-politics literature is divorced from comparative institutional research. We build on the latter body of research to generate a new 13-point index that captures the extent to which electoral systems incentivize personal-vote cultivation, based on a combination of established theoretical and new empirical evidence on candidate incentives. We argue that institutional incentives to pursue a personal vote are positively linked to the provision of particularistic policies, including trade protectionism. We find strong empirical support for the hypothesized relationship, and our results highlight the importance of applying parsimonious approaches to studying domestic institutions when analyzing their impact on foreign economic policy.
Article
The study assessed the impact of democracy on economic development in Africa from 1996 to 2017 for a panel study of 50 African countries. The study employed panel methodologies such as panel stepwise regression, generalized linear model, and Arellano-Bond dynamic panel data GMM (two-step) and censored Tobit regression methods for its robustness inference. The study found a negative and strong statistically significant relationship between democracy and economic development in Africa. Whereas the rule of law negatively relates to economic growth and voice and accountability also relates at a statistical significance level of 1% across all the methods used for the data analysis. İn the wake to achieve higher economic development, one variable critically showed promising thus human development index. The human development index encompasses a composite measure of life expectancy at birth, per capita income indicators, and level of education in every country. KEYWORDS: Democracy; Economic development; Rule of law; Voice and Accountability; Corruption control
Article
Full-text available
This paper aims to identify the nature of the relationship between democracy and economic growth. We will answer the question: Does democracy improve economic growth? We study the case of Tunisia during the period from 1980 until 2014; this country has experienced a democratic transition after the revolution of 14 th January 2011. Our study is divided into two parts. The first part is a literature review of overview on the causality between democracy and economic growth. The second part as an application uses the Autoregressive Distributed Lag Model (ARDL). The choice of the technical SARL aimed the study of the existence of a long-run equilibrium relationship between two variables in level, a procedure co-integration has been proposed by Pesaran et al (2001). The results of different empirical studies were inconclusive. Some generated a negative impact of democracy on growth while others showed the opposite. The empirical results of our work have shown that in a nascent democracy such is the case of Tunisia; democracy has no effect on economic growth in the short term. It is to add an observation rate of GDP during the period post -revolution generated a sawtooth trend which demonstrates the unstable economic situation in the country.
Article
This book addresses the following question: why are presidential democracies more likely to break down than parliamentary ones? Conventional wisdom among political scientists pointS to the incentives generated by the form of government itself; the independence of the executive and legislature that defines presidentialism generates incentives that are not conducive to the consolidation of democracy. On the basis of a data set that covers all democracies between 1946 and 2002, this book demonstrates that this is not the case: the incentives generated by presidentialism are as conducive to the consolidation of democracy as the ones generated by parliamentarism. The book argues that what kills presidentialism is the fact that it exists in countries where democracies of any type are not likely to survive. This book will be of interest to academic researchers, graduates and advanced undergraduates enrolled in courses on comparative politics and political economy.
Article
The abstract for this document is available on CSA Illumina.To view the Abstract, click the Abstract button above the document title.
Article
A large literature has demonstrated that such economic factors as growth, inflation, and unemployment affect the popularity of incumbents within many democratic countries. However, cross-national aggregate analyses of ''economic voting'' show only weak and inconsistent economic effects. We argue for the systematic incorporation of political factors that shape the electoral consequences of economic performance. Multivariate analyses of 102 elections in 19 industrialized democracies are used to estimate the cross-national impact of economic and political factors. The analyses show that considerations of the ideological image of the government, its electoral base, and the clarity of its political responsibility are essential to understanding the effects of economic conditions on voting for or against incumbents.
Book
Political scientists have long classified systems of government as parliamentary or presidential, two-party or multiparty, and so on. But such distinctions often fail to provide useful insights. For example, how are we to compare the United States, a presidential bicameral regime with two weak parties, to Denmark, a parliamentary unicameral regime with many strong parties? Veto Players advances an important, new understanding of how governments are structured. The real distinctions between political systems, contends George Tsebelis, are to be found in the extent to which they afford political actors veto power over policy choices. Drawing richly on game theory, he develops a scheme by which governments can thus be classified. He shows why an increase in the number of "veto players," or an increase in their ideological distance from each other, increases policy stability, impeding significant departures from the status quo. Policy stability affects a series of other key characteristics of polities, argues the author. For example, it leads to high judicial and bureaucratic independence, as well as high government instability (in parliamentary systems). The propositions derived from the theoretical framework Tsebelis develops in the first part of the book are tested in the second part with various data sets from advanced industrialized countries, as well as analysis of legislation in the European Union. Representing the first consistent and consequential theory of comparative politics, Veto Players will be welcomed by students and scholars as a defining text of the discipline.
Article
This paper explores two quite different visions of the democratic processes that can create congruence between citizen preferences and public policies. In the Majority Control vision, electoral competition and citizen choices result in the direct election of governments committed to policies corresponding to the preferences of the median voter. In the Proportionate Influence vision, election outcomes result in legislatures that reflect the preferences of all citizens; legislative bargaining results in policies linked to the position of the median voter. The authors give more explicit theoretical form to those visions and link them empirically to specific types of modern democracies. They then attempt to test the success of each vision in bringing about congruence between citizen self-placements and the estimated positions of governments and policymaker coalitions on the left-right scale in twelve nations in the late 1970s and early 1980s. Although the analysis reveals weaknesses in each approach, it suggests a consistent advantage for the Proportionate Influence vision.