ArticlePDF Available

Abstract

There are standard economic reasons for promotion activities. Expenditure on advertising pays where economies of scale can be exploited. Economies of scale are characteristic of Fordist production. They are sizeable in the case of information goods since information products involve high overhead costs but negligible reproduction costs. In a communication network, both economic efficiency and attractiveness increase with the number of network participants. Accordingly, the role played by advertising in an industrial society expands in information society. Still, all those reasons do not sufficiently explain the penetrating force of publicity and its spillover beyond the limits of sales promotion. They may explain why the incitement, channelling and seduction of attention today regularly accompanies economic activity, but they fail to explain why the scramble for attention has turned into the overriding objective.
Published in: What People Want. Populism in Architecture and Design; ed. by Michael Shamiyeh
and DOM Research Laboratory; Basel, Boston & Berlin: Birkhäuser, 2005, pp. 98-115. First published
in German, in: Konrad Paul Liessmann (Hg.), Die Kanäle der Macht. Herrschaft und Freiheit im
Medienzeitalter. Philosophicum Lech Band 6, Wien: Zsolnay, 2003, pp. 36-60. Translated into
English by Silvia Plaza
Mental Capitalism
Georg Franck
Everything smacks of publicity. Wherever we look, there are logos, whatever the
event, we are reminded of sponsors. Advertising finances mass culture but,
increasingly, high culture, too. Consumption has shifted from products to brands.
Branded goods are commodity-shaped advertisements. We are witnessing an
invasion of brands. Before our eyes, cities and landscapes mutate into advertising
media. Publicity settles like mildew on everything open to public view. It
determines the shape of everything intent on making a public impression: also the
shape of politics. Political parties are advertised like registered trade marks. The
thirst of politics for promotion outlays has reached a point where it corrupts the
traditional party system and has become a major source of political scandal.
What is it that endows publicity with such power? Is it technological progress or
dominant economics? Are we confronted with a new phenomenon or with the
culmination of old trends? Is publicity a symptom of information society? Or is it a
novel manifestation of technology and social economy?
The publicity flood: symptom for what?
There are standard economic reasons for promotion activities. Expenditure on
advertising pays where economies of scale can be exploited. Economies of scale are
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 2/21
characteristic of Fordist production. They are sizeable in the case of information
goods since information products involve high overhead costs but negligible
reproduction costs. In a communication network, both economic efficiency and
attractiveness increase with the number of network participants. Accordingly, the
role played by advertising in an industrial society expands in information society.
Still, all those reasons do not sufficiently explain the penetrating force of publicity
and its spillover beyond the limits of sales promotion. They may explain why the
incitement, channelling and seduction of attention today regularly accompanies
economic activity, but they fail to explain why the scramble for attention has
turned into the overriding objective.
Publicity depends on media: media presenting a message while absorbing
attention. Electronic media are particularly well-equipped for presentation.
Electronic ways of reproducing, multiplying and spreading patterns of stimulation
have a clout in reinforcing presentation. At the same time, distribution via
technological channels facilitates the measurement of attention being skimmed off.
The effective sales of information delivered by the media are measured via
circulation figures, audience ratings, or number of visits to web sites. Together
with today’s technological media, an infrastructure has sprung up which provides
wholesale access to entire populations while at the same time continuously
surveying demand. And yet: not even state-of-the-art information and
communication technology fully explain the impertinence of publicity. We can
switch off TV but cannot forego facing advertisements. Wherever we look,
wherever we run, advertising is in place already.
The involuntary consumption of publicity amounts to a tax being levied on
perception. This tax is irrational from the point of view of the rational consumer
assumed in economic theory. It also contradicts the technological media’s role as
mind amplifiers. However, can a phenomenon of such overwhelming presence be
explained by sheer absence of reason? Shouldn’t we rather wonder whether our
conceptions of economics and technology are too narrow? Could the omnipresence
of advertising not be symptomatic for a dynamic of social change that so far has
gone unnoticed in economics and media theory?
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 3/21
The contention that we are dealing with some profound change takes shape if we
remember similar upheavals in the past, like the ones that accompanied
industrialisation. Industrial capitalism led to new ownership relations, to the
transformation of common land into private property, to the growth of vertically
integrated markets, to the enforcement of homogenous currency systems, and to
the evolution of finance as a specialised economic sector. In the following, I shall
elaborate on the conjecture that we are witnessing another revolution of this kind,
taking place beneath the surface on which advertising spreads. I suspect that we
have to do with a new kind of capitalism, a capitalism different from the one
usually addressed as New Economy. Let me sketch this – mental – kind of
capitalism
1
in the form of four propositions:
1. What we are witnessing is a new type of privatisation of public space:
privatisation of the space of experience.
2. The privatisation of this ‘experience-space‘ is connected with – and promoted
by – the emergence of new markets. New in the sense that it is not money
which is exchanged for information, but attention.
3. Attention as such is not a means of payment. It only becomes a currency when
it is measured in homogenous units and made to circulate via anonymous
exchange acts.
4. The currency system of attention relies on specialised financial services. This
banking and stock-exchange function is performed by the mass media.
(ad 1) Privatisation of public experience-space
Advertising would not be ubiquitous if presentation were only taking hold of the
technological media. Particularly striking, however, is the way in which public
space in cities, or areas along traffic routes, and increasingly also the open
landscape, are incorporated. Those kinds of space are epitomes of public goods.
1
The term mental capitalism is introduced in Franck 1998, ch. 6.
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 4/21
Even when buildings or land are privately owned, urban space or the open
landscape keep their public, communal nature. This public-good quality is the
object of building and landmark regulations. Precisely this public-good quality of
public space is now being privatised. Public space is studded with billboards and
installations serving as eye-catchers, it is transformed into an advertising medium.
A lot is paid for utilisation as advertising medium – both by those active in the
advertising business and those suffering from the disfigurement of public space.
However, while the benefit involved is appropriated privately, the respective costs
are borne by the general public.
The same development can be observed in public television and in publicly
financed culture. The existence of publicly-owned television companies goes back
to the same reasons that account for aesthetic commissioning in building codes and
landscape protection regulations. Their rationale lies in defending public
experience-space against the baseness of private profit-seeking. Quality standards
are established and fees are levied, so that people will have something decent to
look at. But what will public television companies do next? They will maximise
their audience ratings in order to use their medium as advertising vehicle. They
will engage in the same racket as private television companies, perhaps hampered
by a few inconvenient rules and standards. Their business, too, is the collection of
as much attention as possible. Audience ratings measure the attention a medium
attracts in return for the information it offers. This service of attraction is sold to
the advertising industry. Private television lives entirely on selling this service, but
public television profits from it, too. Both kinds of television companies thus feel
encouraged to investigate what the public wants to see or hear in order to
maximise the attraction of attention; this attraction can then be re-sold for money.
Nothing different is happening when sponsors take over the financing of culture.
Sponsors, too, buy the service of attraction. Whatever culture is on offer, it
performs this service of attraction; sponsors buy the service in order to plant
themselves in the limelight. Financing via advertising always means that
nominally public space is transformed into a market where, on the one hand, the
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 5/21
information offered is paid by attention and where, on the other hand, the service
of attraction is sold for money.
(ad 2) New markets
The emergence of those new markets is crowding out traditional forms and kinds
of public space. They are the new arenas for culture and sports, for political debate
and the struggle for power. One notices their operation by the pungent ferment of
publicity. The new markets are markets in the full sense of the term. They organise
supply by testing preparedness to pay. Only, in this case, payment is not effected
in money but in attention. The attention paid is measured through number of
visitors, audience ratings, or opinion-polls. By being measured, attention is
homogenised. Attention, when taken as such, is not a homogenous measure of
value. The value of attention we receive in inter-personal exchange is thoroughly
individual. It depends on our own esteem for the person paying attention to us,
and on the appreciation conveyed by way of the payment. But when we measure
the size of editions, number of viewers, or circulation figures, attention is reduced
to sheer quantity. Anything individual in it is neutralised by homogenisation.
Adaptation to sheer quantity lies behind the transition from elitist culture over to
event- and rating-culture; behind the invasion of brands; behind the change of
party democracy into media democracy. The consequences are even more
profound. Attention as a means of payment induces further technological change
and establishes a new slant between the rich and the poor.
Technological change induced through the new markets is not limited to
information and communication technology. Through competition for attention a
very special kind of technology has entered the scene. It is linked to
communication techniques, but differs from networks and technical equipment.
The technology applied to maximise editions, audience ratings, or circulation
figures consists in certain methods of filling the channels. This form of
maximisation relies on a technology of attraction differing from the technology of
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 6/21
engineers. Traditionally, the methods of mass attraction were not even recognised
as technology. They were developed in advertising agencies and film studios, by
the mass media and in the world of fashion. They are not based on any theory but
on experience and informed intuition. Meanwhile, they have developed into a
sophisticated technique. Mass attraction is staged with a high degree of
professionalism and is the technological basis of advanced industries.
2
A concept of technology not encompassing the technology of attraction would be
too narrow to account for the new economy. A narrow concept of technology
would suggest that in information society social classes are differentiated by being
“information-rich” or “information-poor”. Such a view would not just be
simplistic, it would overlook the crux of the matter. For, the wealth accumulated in
the new markets does not consist of knowledge, poverty in them does not just
mean unsatisfied thirst for knowledge. The wealthy ones, those who are successful
in the new markets, are wealthy in recognition. The poverty of those who are
passed over consists in lack of recognition. Wealthy people in the new economy
are those whose attention earnings are larger by orders of magnitude than their
spending. The poor are those who do not get enough attention to keep their
self-esteem intact.
3
This wealth of some and the poverty of all the others are inter-
related: the amount of recognition available for distribution is not unlimited. The
attention circulating in society is finite. Those who have can only be given if
something is taken away from those who have not.
(ad 3) From exchanged attention to psychic currency
Traditionally, it was the privilege of high birth, exceptional talent, or ravishing
beauty to grow rich in attention. Today, anyone can become prominent. In the new
economy, the office boy turned millionaire is the candidate in a casting show who
rises to being a media star. The production of media prominence, progress in
2
For an account of this type of industry in terms of conventional economic theory see De Vany
2004.
3
On the economy of self-esteem see Franck 1998, ch. 3, and de Botton 2004, chs. 2f.
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 7/21
attraction technology and the growth of new types of markets are all different
aspects of the same thing. They are possible because attention is minted into an
anonymous means of payment. The overall effect is that the currency in circulation
is expanding.
The volume of attention channelled off by the media and redistributed in the
competition over ratings or reach is not identical with the total amount of attention
circulating in society. What is circulating is both attention exchanged
person-to-person and attention spent on mediatised information. Only the latter
kind is homogenised by quantitative measurement, thus assuming the nature of an
anonymous means of payment. Only through unprecedented growth in the
volume of this currency could fortunes like media prominence arise. Only the rise
of mass business led to the emergence of a technology of mass attraction. The key
to understanding the development of mental capitalism thus lies in answering the
question how the spending and earning of attention became a technologically
advanced economy. Which growth factors were at work that turned the exchange
of information for attention into big business?
Provision of information in return for attention has been the job of culture since it
was industrialised. Looking for the driving forces at work therefore means tracing
the mutation of cultural life into a mass business. The prerequisites for this
mutation were the development of a technological infrastructure enabling mass
distribution of information as well as the evolution of certain types of popular
culture engaged in finding out what mass audiences want to see, hear, or read. A
further, decisive influence stimulating the unprecedented increase in the volume of
anonymously paid attention was the existence of an internal circuit for the
collection and reinvestment of attention. Only those genres of popular culture
succeeded in becoming mass media that invested a sufficiently large amount of
attraction power in breeding champions capable of mass attraction.
Stars drawing large audiences cannot be created simply with money. Something
else is needed. Talents have to be offered presentation space or broadcasting time.
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 8/21
Attention must be granted in advance. Only those suppliers of information that are
known for reliably attracting vast amounts of attention are capable of granting
such credit. Media of this kind can sell services of attraction to the advertising
business; but they can also reinvest their power of attraction to increase their
magnetism. Guaranteed attention can give talents a chance or can be used for
piling up so much attention on successful personalities that they become known by
everybody, and even become known for being known by everybody. The high
technology of attraction works with this kind of self-reinforcing publicity. It works
with known faces everybody wants to see because everybody knows that all the
others also see them. What would become of cinema, sports, talk shows or soap
operas without those stars?
But not only the stars are profiting from all the commotion around known faces. In
fact, through their stars, the media presenting them become major earners
themselves. A medium that invests in promoting a star will participate in the profit
created with the credit it offers. The analogy with banks goes even further.
Attention credit creates psychic currency in the same way that bank credit creates
money. The money supply grows if bank credit surpasses deposits, and the
amount of attention turned over by the media increases if it pays to expand
presentation space beyond realised attraction capacity.
(ad 4) The financial industries of mental capitalism
That the media are functioning as banks is exemplified by their interaction with
politics. Politics, like advertising, is pushing its way into the media. Politicians are
no longer happy with just being shown, they want to be presented in the best
possible way, by the most attractive channels, during prime time.
4
They demand
the advance payment of guaranteed attention also granted to people whom that
medium presents on its own initiative. Therefore, the conditions for receiving this
financial service will depend on the politicians’ personal performance in the
4
For illustrations see Derber (1979/2000), pp. xxii-xxiv.
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 9/21
medium. If a politician is likely to increase the attention paid to that medium, it
will grant him attention credit. If the politician’s presentation is not profitable, or
not profitable enough, then cash will have to be taken in hand.
The media are financing the making of politicians in the same way that banks are
financing business. Like business, politics is shaped by the respective financing
conditions. Politicians will make an effort to present themselves in a way
appreciated by the medium: they will not only watch out for their own image, but
also for the ratings. If they are willing to act as carthorses for the respective
medium, they can maximise their credit and minimise the money spent on media
presence. They will thus be interested in making use of professional attraction
technologies. They will entrust themselves to advisers well versed in those
technologies and also familiar with the credit sector of attention.
The transition from party- to media democracy is marked by politicians no longer
being satisfied with their role as objects of reporting. They become the medium’s
business partners. In this new role, politicians use the media not only for selling
their policies; they also serve the medium’s self-interest in order to get hold of as
much advertising space as possible. This change of role brings about a change in
the requirements for and the patterns of political careers. Being telegenic is
necessary today, but no longer sufficient. You have to have the makings for media
prominence. A politician’s typical career pattern will combine moving up in the
party hierarchy with increasing affluence in media attention. Prominence is that
level of attentive wealth where the affluence becomes conspicuous and itself turns
into a source of attention income.
What does this co-operation with politics reveal about the media? It shows that the
media, within the attention economy, are what the financial sector is in money
capitalism. The media are capitalising attention: they receive attention with such
regularly and certainty that they are able to offer it on credit as starting capital;
they make use of fortunes by reinvesting attention wealth into attraction; they list
the market value of fortunes by measuring their power of attraction. Just as banks
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 10/21
are providing growing economies with an expanding money supply, the media are
supplying expanding information markets with growing amounts of attention.
Lastly, in the same way that financial markets have transposed the internal
capitalisation strategy of companies to the macroeconomic level, the media are
transposing the capitalisation of attention from the level of personal dexterity to
that of an organised public sphere.
Is the conjecture of mental capitalism tenable?
If the economy of attention has in fact assumed the stature of a capitalist system,
the furnishing of experience-space with advertisements appears in a new light.
Capitalism is an exceedingly dynamic, thoroughly mobilising and aggressively
expanding economic system. A capitalist economy of attention means that the
struggle for attention becomes professional, technological and indispensable.
Anything that lives on being noticed will be drawn into this struggle. No selling
without mind-grabbing; no social impact without strategic placement in public
awareness.
Admittedly, speaking about a new stage of capitalism is no small matter.
Capitalism in terms of attention goes further than any apprehensions of cultural
criticism. It culminates in the idea that the cultural supra-structure not only reflects
the economic base, but that it has assimilated it. Such an assumption must
withstand testing in the counter-current. It must satisfy all the criteria implied in
the concept of capitalism. In order to reverse the burden of proof, the four initial
propositions discussed above will be tested against the following control
propositions:
1. The term capitalist production relations signifies more than production for
markets. Characteristic for those relations is the replacement of use value by
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 11/21
exchange value. Hence, the replacement of differences in quality by differences
in quantity ought to show up in cultural self-perception.
2. The successful establishment of capitalist production relations is heralded by
the unprecedented unleashing of productive forces and by a hitherto unknown
degree of creative destruction. This trait, too, would have to be discernible in
mental capitalism.
3. It is characteristic for capitalist production relations that they are ideologically
justified and beautified to camouflage unfettered commercialisation. Such
ideological removal of all inhibitions would have to be noticeable in mental
capitalism.
4. No capitalism without exploitation and social conflict. Capitalism in what is
mental would have to manifest itself in a tendency for growing psychic
destitution and in revolts against narcissistic injuries.
(ad 1) Qualitative difference dissolving into quantitative difference
The arrival of post-modernism marked a break in cultural self-perception. This not
only meant noting that current production constituted a completely new era but
also realising, in retrospect, that indications of change had been building up for a
long time. Post-modernist discourse distanced itself from modernism,
characterising it as an era in which rigid categorisation, binary dichotomies,
searching for essential differences were dissociated from the historical background
and cultural context. Accused of being typically modernistic, sharp distinctions
between nature and culture, male and female, high art and popular art, the arts
and science, economics and epistemology came under critical scrutiny. Essential
distinctions were replaced by systems of variation and differentiation, ontological
distinctions gave way to varying social constructs. The borderlines between
historical genesis and logical validity, between discovery context and justification
context, between the invention of hypotheses and the discovery of facts began to
be blurred. Everywhere one noted sliding scales, moving ratios, fuzzy interfaces,
hybrid mixtures, opportunistic adaptations.
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 12/21
Deconstruction goes all out, knows no ultimate limits, does not respect any central
core. If one takes it seriously as a way of perceiving cultural change, it is in fact a
reaction to the liquefaction and homogenisation processes actually taking place.
Deconstruction undermines a paradigm that partitions cultural life according to
bureaucratic departmentalisation; this old paradigm is replaced by chaotic
self-organisation. In the social context, systems of chaotic self-organisation able to
replace bureaucratic organisation take the shape of markets. Markets in this most
general sense are decentralised bargaining systems whose firm structures consist
in habitual exchange relations and established exchange values.
If cultural life has in fact arrived at a stage to be described as capitalist economy of
attention, this change of paradigm was indeed a highly sensitive reaction, even
more remarkable since it took place outside the trodden paths of economic
thought. In the economic sphere, the replacement of a use value-oriented regime
by an exchange value-oriented one would have been registered. Under capitalism,
factual validity assumes the format of capital – capital in the shape of confidence,
creditworthiness, reputation, whatever. The validity established and maintained
by this regime is relative from the outset and remains in force only as long as it
withstands erosion by constant competition and aggressive forces of dissolution.
Whatever survives will do so only as long as it satisfies effective demand, i.e. if
there is preparedness to pay – preparedness to pay attention, of course.
The spearheads of deconstruction are targeting the status of scientific theories and
facts. Proponents of the “strong programme” in the sociology of science view
scientific theories just as means of production used in the production of other
theories that are fabricated to replace the preceding ones.
5
Even scientific facts,
they assert, are social constructs, valid only as long as they prove their
productiveness through the construction of other facts. This extreme form of
relativism affects the issue of mental capitalism for two reasons. First, it means that
the scientific economy of attention must be taken into account. Second, it marks the
5
See, e.g., Latour & Woolgar 1979 and Latour 1999.
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 13/21
point where its provocation has had consequences. What happened was the
declaration of “science wars”.
(ad 2) Unleashing of productive forces
Science is a closed economy of attention.
6
Scientists invest their own attention to
obtain at the attention of other scientists. They are not only intent on satisfying
their own curiosity and their desire for exploration: what they also wish is to be
reviewed and cited. Review and citation measure the value of scientific
information. They measure the other scientists’ preparedness to pay attention to a
fellow-scientist’s production. Scientists spend their own attention on the
production of others in order to increase their own productivity. They are
interested in prefabricated knowledge acting as means of production in the
production of knowledge.
The scientific economy of attention is a capitalist one. The major inputs in
knowledge production are pre-fabricated knowledge and fresh attention. Scientific
information, being a produced means of production, is a capital good. The market
in which this kind of capital good is traded is called scientific communication.
Supply takes the shape of publication. Trough publication the respective
information becomes accessible for everyone, but it also establishes intellectual
property. Permission to use somebody else’s property as one’s own means of
production is obtained by acquiring a licence and by paying a fee. The licence for
productive re-use of published information is obtained through citation, the fee
takes the shape of attention which the citing author transfers to the cited one.
Science is a model economy in the dual sense of the term. It is a model both with
respect to its capitalist mode and because of its efficiency in production. It is
characteristic for the capitalist mode of production to employ pre-fabricated means
6
For a more comprehensive account of the scientific economy of attention than given here see
Franck 1999 and Franck 2002.
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 14/21
of production and to transform the heterogeneous assemblage of means of
production into a homogenous good called “capital”. Scientific information acting
as means of production consists of theses, hypotheses, theories, theorems, facts -
i.e. chunks of information that are factually incomparable and which, taken by
themselves, do not contain any common – e.g. information-theoretic – measure.
For this heterogeneous assemblage to be transformed into units of capital, it must
be evaluated, i.e. measured by homogenous units. In the case of assets of
production, this measurement is effected by their transformation into financial
capital, i.e. by translation into shares entitling the holder to obtain some of the
profit. In the case of scientific assets of production, no financial profit accrues
(unless the assets are cast in the mould of patents; but by being patented the
information completely disappears from the capital market of scientific
communication). The profits negotiated in this market accrue in terms of attention.
The respective measuring unit is the citation. The number of citations collected by
a particular piece of scientific information is a measure for both the amount of its
re-utilisation in production and for the attention income earned by the author. The
list of citations is the functional equivalent of financial capital; scientific real capital
must assume this form in order to operate as capital in the full sense of this
concept. Scientists’ personal accounts of citations represent the kind of wealth they
are out to maximise. Personal wealth of this kind is called scientific reputation.
Science is a capitalist sector of the attention economy, regardless whether or not
the rest of the economy is organised in a capitalist way. Science is also an example
for the unleashing of productive forces brought about by the introduction of
capitalist production relations. The scientific economy of attention has been
capitalist ever since the scientific division of labour became common practice and
since scientific communication began to function like a market for published
information. Scientific capitalism arose in parallel with industrial capitalism. Both
these capitalisms were characterised by an unprecedented degree of productive
destruction; they both revolutionised traditional production relations and were
both accompanied by a new, ruthless style of rationality. They both ran into
philosophical opposition – and have continued to do so until today. However, in
contrast to industrial capitalism, the capitalist mode of knowledge production did
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 15/21
not become the subject of radical economic criticism. From the very start, the
scientific economy of attention was a model economy. If mental capitalism has in
the meantime also become a category deserving criticism, then this must be due to
some fundamental change. The markets in which information and attention are
exchanged must have assumed a new character.
(ad 3) Economic base and ideological superstructure
Mental capitalism, manifesting itself in ebullience of advertising, actually serves a
kind of market that differs from the market of scientific communication. Scientific
communication is a capital market. Here, producers offer means of production to
other producers. The media, on the other hand, are markets for consumption
goods. The markets for mental assets are small and refined. The attention earned
there is limited in amount, but of superior quality. It comes from people sharing
the same interests, education and professional ethos. When this market opens up
to the general consumer, then small, noble attention incomes become ordinary and
large.
The way in which this opening-up is happening has a visible effect on science
itself. The potential customers of scientific information are now not only other
scientists, but also the mass media and the entertainment industry. Scientists can
earn hefty side-incomes of attention by running columns in newspapers, by
appearing in talk shows or by going into the popularisation business in some other
way. Scientists who succumb to such temptations, but also members of disciplines
with a longer tradition of serving large markets, will enjoy the message that,
anyway, what science is about is to cause a stir. They will be pleased to hear that
hard boundaries between scientific and non-scientific communication are nothing
but pretence, certainly nothing essential. The greatest hit for them would be if
someone managed to unmask all hard scientific facts as social constructs.
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 16/21
If one considers the deconstruction of scientific objectivity from this perspective,
the “science wars” are revealed to be classic cases of ideological debate
camouflaging fights over market shares. Fighting is done on an eminently
intellectual plane, but the battle heat is produced by solid economic interests. The
opening-up of firmly sealed capital markets requires a certain absence of
inhibitions, a loosening of restraints formerly imposed by strict professional codes
of conduct. It is very helpful indeed when intellectual libertinage and frivolity
become fashionable. In order to establish that a connection between this observed
loosening-up and some economic motive exists, it would be necessary for the
deconstruction message to land exclusively where opening-up promises profits.
And, indeed, actual battlefronts in the “science wars” run between disciplines that
owe their exceptional prestige to their rigorous sealing off of internal scientific
capital markets and other disciplines that are only able to enrich themselves
through outside sources, not having enjoyed their rival disciplines’ traditional
prestige.
Although the differentiation between capital goods markets and consumption
goods markets is particularly sharp within the scientific economy of attention,
science is by no means the only sphere where such a differentiation is made.
Wherever a clear slant between high culture and popular culture exists, this
distinction can be observed. High culture is autonomous, guided exclusively by its
own criteria and responding only to demands articulated from within. One’s own
personal criteria are the same as those of one’s fellow-producers, demands arising
within the sphere are formulated by members of one’s guild. High culture is
staged for co-producers and relies on judgement by colleagues. A brilliant example
for this is literature, as described by Pierre Bourdieu with respect to French
19
th
-century literary writing. The only people allowed to express any opinions
apart from the producers are, perhaps, critics who are themselves good at the
trade. But even in the literary field one can today observe restrictions melting
away. A prime example is the business of literature presentation on television.
However, even without TV involvement, quite generally, the borderlines between
cultural capital goods markets and cultural consumption goods markets are
eroding. A clear indicator for the crumbling of those borderlines is the presence of
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 17/21
advertising. One cannot fail to observe that the message of dissolution and
liquefaction dominates wherever the lure of larger audiences works. Ideological
justification and the removal of intellectual restraints on profiteering are features
not unfamiliar to mental capitalism.
(ad 4) Exploitation and social conflict
Conflicting economic interests hiding behind the facade of post-modern discourse
are nothing but internal struggles between different fractions of capital. Real
conflicts in capitalism are something else. True and existential conflicts in
capitalism are those between the class of capitalists on the one hand and the class
of those feeding the capitalists on the other hand. At first sight one might think
that mental capitalism, in this respect, is more harmless than financial capitalism.
What we are confronted with is a blatantly unequal distribution of attention
between those who appear in the media and those who do not. The masses behave
as if they could never get enough of prominent people.
However, taking a closer look, we notice signs of protest. Together with the
invasion of brand names and logos have we witnessed the infiltration of graffiti.
The sprayers have turned the tables. They react to the organised mass struggle for
attention by piercing the onlookers’ eyes. Early opposition expressed by graffiti
developed into a protest movement against the brands’ occupation policy. Today,
opponents of globalisation are protesting against this occupation not just in optical
ways and no longer surreptitiously. They view invasion by brands as one example
of negative globalisation. Another negative aspect of globalisation is economic
exploitation of low-wage workers and of low-wage countries – but this is not all.
There is also the global export of Western mass culture. The protest movement is
reacting with adequate sensitivity – but rather confused analyses - to the fact that
exploitation is taking place at two different levels: the level of labour markets and
the level of markets where information is exchanged for attention.
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 18/21
In the economy of attention, the units corresponding to national economies are
differing cultures. Exchange goes on between cultures just like between national
economies. Cultures export information goods and earn attention for them, or they
import information goods and export attention for them. For exchange to be fair
and profitable, trade balances need not be balanced for each individual exchange
act, but they ought to be balanced on a global scale. However, if we consider
today’s global cultural situation we observe an extreme imbalance between the
culture of advanced mental capitalism and the culture of the rest of the world. The
most advanced – Western – cultures export information massively and import
huge amounts of live attention for it, while the cultures of other regions export
very modest amounts of information and accordingly earn little attention for it.
Also, in the sphere of culture – perhaps particularly in culture – there are clear
winners and losers with respect to globalisation. The world is submerged by
Western mass culture, with the export culture barely camouflaging its
predominance by interspersed bits of multi-culture that are exported, too. The gap
between cultures poor or rich in attention is widening just like the economic gap
between economically poor or rich countries. The cultural gap is no less ominous.
One may not be able to make a living on attention income, but the attention one
earns nourishes self-esteem. People’s attention income determines how much
feeling of their own worth they can enjoy. The self-esteem of both individuals and
cultures depends on the appreciation they receive. If their self-esteem is shaken,
both individuals and countries may feel forced to resort to self-defence. They may
feel forced to convince themselves and others that those who refuse to pay
attention to them are unworthy of their own attention. Forced denigration of
others whose lack of esteem one cannot bear is an ancient source of aggression
between people. Under mental capitalism, it becomes a natural defence
mechanism, as it were, of those who find themselves on the exploited side.
The kind of exploitation characteristic for mental capitalism is the exploitation of
large numbers of people who always pay attention but are hardly ever respected.
The form of self-defence typical of this kind of capitalism consists in denigrating
what one desires, so one will suffer less from missing it. Misery because of lacking
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 19/21
self-esteem may hurt just like physical destitution; thirst for recognition may
render as aggressive as an empty stomach. The desire to humiliate those who
refuse to pay respect to others needing that respect to keep up their self-esteem lies
behind self-sacrificing terrorist attacks on symbols of Western export culture. It
also is the cause of resentments that new right-wing populist movements
manipulate and it explains the demonstrative violence and nazi symbols which the
attention economy’s lumpenproletariat use to grab some attention they will
otherwise never receive. The split between social classes follows the dividing line
between, on the one hand, the owners of cultural and social capital which is
providing them with more attention than they can spend, and, on the other hand,
the have-nots who can only pay attention to each other.
Narcissistic culture
Mental capitalism is hard and frivolous. It conquers the inner core of the self and
intervenes in identity-building. It is frivolous because of the unequal distribution
of chances and because of the extravagance it engenders. Here, on this side, there
are celebrities and sumptuously staged personalities bathing in attention; over
there, people are starving and committing acts of desperation to get into the
limelight just once. This inequality, as such, is not completely new. The innovation
lies in the systematic way in which it is created. What is new is the sheer volume of
attention being collected and redistributed; new is the self-organising economic
regularity expressing itself through anarchic fights over distribution; new is the
deterministic linkage between the wealth of some and the poverty of all the others.
Publicity, a surface phenomenon of this economic sphere, becomes symptomatic. It
is symptomatic for societies in which the desire for social status has overtaken the
desire for material wealth. No status without attention. The general fight for
attention leads to the mass production of means for inciting attention as well as to
the development of means for the public registration of attention income. Publicity
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 20/21
is the most direct, most mundane and least differentiated application of those
means. Advertising facilities and slogans are products exclusively manufactured to
attract attention. Their mass distribution is pungent to the point of giving offence
and is, at the same time, a means of documenting the successful accomplishment of
attraction. Something we stumble across constantly is not only pushing itself into
our consciousness; at the same time it tells us that everybody is familiar with it.
With primitive but effective methods it conquers the status of prominence.
Advertising, symptomatic for mental capitalism, means producing prominence of
things and symbols.
For things and symbols, the via regia into subjective experience is their promise that
consuming them will make the consumer irresistible. It is clear that in a society
where attention income becomes a major objective, consumption will follow the
pull of self-esteem. Consumption subjected to the pull of self-esteem means that
labour is being spent on one’s attractiveness. This individual labour opens up
unexpectedly ample fields of action for publicity. Advertising assumes the role of
personal counsellor on individual attractiveness. It can now unfold its subtle
qualities. The social psychologist Christopher Lasch has described the cult around
one’s own attractiveness as an aspect of narcissistic culture.
7
This is a social
expression of fragile self-esteem. When consumption style becomes a feature of
this culture, products have to carry the promise of conferring fitness in the fight for
attention. The nature of mental capitalism is such that advertising never tires of
drumming out this message.
References
de Botton, Alain (2004), Status Anxiety, London et al.: Hamish Hamilton
7
See Lasch 1979.
G. Franck, Mental Capitalism 21/21
Derber, Charles (1979/2000), The Pursuit of Attention. Power and Ego in Everyday
Life, Oxford et al.: Oxford University Press,
2
2000
de Vany, Arthur (2004), Hollywood Economics, London and New York: Routledge
Franck, Georg (1998), Ökonomie der Aufmerksamkeit (The Economy of Attention),
München: Carl Hanser. Translation in parts available at
http://www.iemar.tuwien.ac.at/publications
Franck, Georg (1999), Scientific communication – a vanity fair?, in: Science, vol.
286, pp. 53-55
Franck, Georg (2002), The scientific economy of attention: A novel approach to the
collective rationality of science, in: Scientometrics, vol. 55, pp. 3-26
Lasch, Christopher (1979), The Culture of Narcissm, London: Abacus
Latour, Bruno (1999), Pandora‘s Hope. Essays on the Reality of Science Studies,
Cambridge, Mass., and London: Harvard University Press
Latour, Bruno & Steve Woolgar (1979), Laboratory Life. The Construction of
Scientific Facts, Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press,
2
1986
... El criterio que la valida es la acumulación de seguidores, likes o visualizaciones. En una economía en la que la atención se ha vuelto una forma de capital (Franck, 2005), el valor del contenido digital se define por este bien externo. Se trata de una habilidad aislada, tal vez excepcional, pero a la que le cuesta trabajo forjar comunidad alrededor de ciertos bienes. ...
... La pregunta sobre quién merece nuestra atención no es una cuestión menor, en especial bajo el contexto de lo que se ha denominado "economía de la atención", en donde esta última se ha convertido en una forma de capital (Franck, 2005;Simon, 1971;Van Krieken, 2019). La lucha por la atención, un bien preciado dentro de la cultura contemporánea, ha generado una búsqueda incesante del estatus de celebridad por parte de los sujetos (Van Krieken, 2019) y nuevas formas de explotación y desigualdad en el capitalismo, entre los pocos individuos que reciben atención y los muchos que prestan atención a estos pocos, pero que no la reciben de regreso (Franck, 2005). ...
... La pregunta sobre quién merece nuestra atención no es una cuestión menor, en especial bajo el contexto de lo que se ha denominado "economía de la atención", en donde esta última se ha convertido en una forma de capital (Franck, 2005;Simon, 1971;Van Krieken, 2019). La lucha por la atención, un bien preciado dentro de la cultura contemporánea, ha generado una búsqueda incesante del estatus de celebridad por parte de los sujetos (Van Krieken, 2019) y nuevas formas de explotación y desigualdad en el capitalismo, entre los pocos individuos que reciben atención y los muchos que prestan atención a estos pocos, pero que no la reciben de regreso (Franck, 2005). Ante la competencia incesante por acumular atención, la pregunta por el valor es pertinente. ...
Article
Full-text available
Las plataformas de contenido digital muestran individuos realizando actividades que pueden ser calificadas como frívolas o peligrosas. Este artículo examina la problemática de la creación de contenidos digitales que abandonan la idea de excelencia. Esta se aborda desde la noción de la práctica y el desarrollo de bienes internos en la misma, propuesta por MacIntyre (2004), y desde la crítica al individualismo en la cultura contemporánea. Se afirma que el desinterés de los creadores de contenido digital por la excelencia, en el marco del neoliberalismo, representa una forma de éxito individualista que corrompe las prácticas y erosiona su sentido de comunidad.
Article
The author thematizes the operation of the political market of attention that is propelled by the willingness of citizens to credit populist leaders with their digital political labour. Mutual, nevertheless unequal, exchange of attention leads to the formation of a spiral of attention. Its expansive character is sustained by the strategically subsidized recognition of populist leaders. Accumulated attention, i. e. attention capital, is the resource that is used to maintain populist networked public spheres, while citizens are proletarianized: they are invited to apply their labour power to distributing political ideas but are pevented from evaluating the influence of competing public actors.
Article
Previous research on the effectiveness of event marketing was predominantly focused on single events and individual participants. This paper aims to expand the scope of inquiry into this topic by investigating how the frequency and magnitude of esports tournament events affect the numbers of Twitch live-stream viewers and channels. Data containing the monthly averages of Twitch viewers and channels in addition to the event dates and prize sizes of esports tournaments were collected from publicly available online sources. 829 monthly observations involving 17 popular esports games were analyzed and the results were further validated by robustness check. It was found that the frequency of esports tournament events significantly increased both the live-stream viewers and channels. However, event magnitude only positively affected viewership but had a negative impact on the number of active Twitch channels. This work applies underused metrics to appraise the effectiveness of event marketing in an attention economy. Empirical evidence based on event frequency and magnitude confirms the marketing efficacy of esports tournament events in captivating viewer attention. On the other hand, however, there might exist a substantial inequality in the distribution of attention (i.e., monetization opportunities) between big and small Twitch streamers.
Article
This article places Georg Franck’s ‘The Economy of Attention’ in the context of the broader discussions of ‘the attention economy’, and the increasing significance of attention in a knowledge society characterised by ever-increasing flows of information and data. I highlight the four core elements of Franck’s theory of the economy of attention: first, the importance of the fundamental human desire for attention; second, his emphasis on the parallels between attention and money, making it more literally a form of capital than is usually assumed; third, the self-reproducing character of attention capital, earning interest just as money does; fourth, the connections between the economy of attention and the expanding impetus towards everyone becoming a celebrity and a ‘brand’ within what he calls ‘mental capitalism’, with the field of academic labour a key example.
Article
This entry explores the development of gendered advertising and the feminist activism that surrounded anti‐advertising. It then looks at the emergence of “positive advertising,” comparing 1970s campaigns with contemporary marketing events such as Dove. Finally, it critiques positive advertising and questions its authenticity and effect.
Article
Full-text available
Science is the core sector of present-day knowledge production. Yet, the mechanisms of science as an industry are poorly understood. The economic theory of science is still in its infancy, and philosophy of science has only sparsely addressed the issue of economic rationality. Research, however, is costly. Inefficient use of resources consumed by the scientific industry is as detrimental to the collective advancement of knowledge as are deficiencies in method. Economic inefficiency encompasses methodological inadequacy. Methods are inadequate if they tend to misallocate time and effort. If one omits the question of how inputs are transformed into outputs in self-organised knowledge production, this means neglecting an essential aspect of the collective rationality of science. A self-organised tendency towards efficiency comes to the fore as soon as science is described as an economy in which researchers invest their own attention in order to obtain the attention of others. Viewed like this, scientific communication appears to be a market where information is exchanged for attention. Scientific information is measured in terms of the attention it earns. Since scientists demand scientific information as a means of production, the attention that a theory attracts is a measure of its value as a capital good. On the other hand, the attention a scientist earns is capitalised into the asset called reputation. Elaborating the ideas introduced in Franck (1998) and (1999), the paper describes science as a highly developed market economy. Science conceived as capital market covers the specific conditions under which scientists, while maximising their reputation, optimise output in the eyes of those competent to judge. Attention is not just any resource. It is the resource whose efficient use is called intelligence. Science, as an industry transforming attention into cognitive output, is bound to miss the hallmark of rationality if it does not pass a test of collective intelligence. The paper closes with considering the prospective outcome of such a test.
Book
Enough about me, goes the old joke, "what about you? What do you think about me?" Hence the pursuit of attention is alive and well. Even the Oxford English Dictionary reveals a modern coinage to reflect the chase in our technological age: 'ego-surfing' - searching the Internet for occurrences of your own name. What is the cause of this obsessive need for others' recognition? This useful and popular volume, now in a second edition that features major new introductory and concluding essays, entertainingly ponders this question. Derber argues that there is a general lack of social support in today's America, one which causes people to vie hungrily for attention, and he shows how individuals will often employ numerous techniques to turn the course of a conversation towards themselves. Illustrating this 'conversational narcissism' with sample dialogues that will seem disturbingly familiar to all readers, this book analyses the pursuit of attention in conversation - as well as in politics and celebrity culture - and demonstrates the ultimate importance of gender, class, and racial differences in competing for attention. Derber shows how changes in the economy and culture, such as the advent of the Internet, have intensified the rampant individualism and egotism of today. And finally, in a new afterword, he focuses on solutions: how to restructure the economy and culture to humanize ourselves and increase the capacity for community, empathy, and attention-giving.
Article
Success in science is rewarded with attention. Citation represents a fee paid through transfer of some of the attention earned by the citing author to the cited author. An economy of attention links the collectively most rewarding allocation of attention with the maximum value of the attention its holder can earn. In terms of the resulting collective efficiency it attains, the intelligence of science as a whole surpasses that which individual scientists can attain in isolation.
Article
Hollywood Economics Ökonomie der Aufmerksamkeit (The Economy of Attention)
  • Arthur De Vany
de Vany, Arthur (2004), Hollywood Economics, London and New York: Routledge Franck, Georg (1998), Ökonomie der Aufmerksamkeit (The Economy of Attention), München: Carl Hanser. Translation in parts available at http://www.iemar.tuwien.ac.at/publications
Pandora's Hope. Essays on the Reality of Science Studies
  • Christopher Lasch
Lasch, Christopher (1979), The Culture of Narcissm, London: Abacus Latour, Bruno (1999), Pandora's Hope. Essays on the Reality of Science Studies, Cambridge, Mass., and London: Harvard University Press