ArticlePDF Available

Owner-Occupied Housing and Household Asset Allocation: A Review of the Issues

Authors:

Abstract

This second of two related papers in this Journal, reviews empirical evidence available from the literature on the problem of household's optimal portfolio when owner-occupied housing is included in the list of available assets, namely the risk-return performance of residential investment, and its usefulness in efficient mixed-asset portfolios. The risk-return characteristics of the housing asset is highly dependent on the type of perspective under analysis (household or institutional investor's perspective) and therefore, the two housing investment approaches could lead to different conclusions about the role of housing investment in an portfolio context. The consumption demand for housing together with the markets imperfections place serious constraint on the household's portfolio problem.
Owner-occupied housing and
household asset allocation
A review of the issues
Joaquim Montezuma
Department of Urban Studies, University of Glasgow, Glasgow, UK
Keywords Assets management, Housing, Return on investment
Abstract This second of two related papers in this Journal, reviews empirical evidence available
from the literature on the problem of household’s optimal portfolio when owner-occupied housing
is included in the list of available assets, namely the risk-return performance of residential
investment, and its usefulness in efficient mixed-asset portfolios. The risk-return characteristics of
the housing asset is highly dependent on the type of perspective under analysis (household or
institutional investor’s perspective) and therefore, the two housing investment approaches could
lead to different conclusions about the role of housing investment in an portfolio context. The
consumption demand for housing together with the markets imperfections place serious constraint
on the household’s portfolio problem.
Introduction
This is the second of two related papers published in this journal. The first paper
(housing investment in an institutional portfolio content review of the issues) surveys
the role of residential property in an institutional portfolio context and finds evidence
that residential property is a more effective hedge against inflation than bonds and
shares. Additionally, that paper shows that unsecuritized housing investment not only
generates risk-adjusted returns comparable to those of bonds and shares, but also
exhibits low levels of correlation with classic institutional asset classes. This second
paper reviews empirical evidence available from the literature on the problem of a
household’s optimal portfolio when owner-occupied housing is included in the list of
available assets, namely the risk-return performance of residential investment, and its
usefulness in efficient mixed-asset portfolios (Englund et al., 2000; Flavin and
Yamashita, 1998; Goetzmann, 1993). There are a number of reasons why housing
investment in an institutional portfolio context is not entirely comparable to the
perspective of a household investor. For instance, portfolio constraint imposed by
housing consumption (“housing constraint”) has a critical influence on how households
allocate wealth amongst alternative assets. Additionally, the household is not able to
benefit from the risk and operational costs reduction created by holding large diversified
housing portfolios.
The paper is structured as follows. The next section reviews the literature on
owner-occupied housing in a household portfolio, identifies some weaknesses with the
housing diversification benefits argument and discusses future research directions.
The third section explores some theoretical explanations of property’s diversification
characteristics. Conclusions are drawn in the last section.
The Emerald Research Register for this journal is available at The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at
www.emeraldinsight.com/researchregister www.emeraldinsight.com/0263-7472.htm
Thanks go to Kenneth Gibb for his helpful comments and suggestions. All remaining errors and
omissions are the sole responsibility of the author.
Housing and
household asset
allocation
267
Received July 2003
Property Management
Vol. 22 No. 4, 2004
pp. 267-275
qEmerald Group Publishing Limited
0263-7472
DOI 10.1108/02637470410558134
Residential property in a household portfolio context
As mentioned earlier housing investment in a multi-asset portfolio context is
considered from two substantially different perspectives: institutional investor’s
perspective, in the earlier paper and the household’s perspective. The risk-return
characteristics of the housing asset is highly dependent on the type of perspective
under analysis and therefore, the two housing investment approaches could lead to
different conclusions about the role of housing investment in a portfolio context.
Housing is a dominant asset category in a household’s wealth portfolio and one of
the most important components of household consumption is the expenditure. For
instance, the average US homeowner holds 88 percent of his non-pension wealth in
home equity and the average household in Western Europe and US spends between 25
to 35 percent of its income on housing services (Englund et al., 2000).
Housing services consumption is essentially determined by the household’s
ownership of residential property. Thus, the household’s demand for housing, which
could be optimal from the point of view of the consumption of housing services, may
differ from the optimal level of housing allocation in a purely portfolio investment
context. In other words, the portfolio constraint imposed by the housing consumption
(“housing constraint”) has a critical influence on how households allocate wealth
among alternative assets.
Households would like to consume an optimal mix of consumption good and
housing services and maintain a balanced wealth portfolio and, at the same time, to
reduce the residential transaction costs. However, housing markets have several
imperfections such as tax distortions, transaction costs and moral hazard issues.
According to Flavin and Yamashita (1998), those market imperfections prevent
households from holding a diversified portfolio and renting to satisfy their housing
services consumption. In that sense, rental housing is not a perfect substitute for
owner-occupied housing. Other market frictions that influence homeowners’ wealth
portfolio include uninsurable labour income risk and borrowing constrains (Cocco,
2000). The latter author states that labour market incompleteness avoid human capital
to be capitalized and its risk insured. The author finds empirical evidence that both
labour income and interest rate risk crowed out housing investment. Grossman and
Laroque (1990) show that the transaction costs reduces the percentage of household’s
wealth allocated to risky assets (e.g. shares) after he purchases a new house. Following
Grossman and Laroque (1990), Cocco (2000) finds that transaction costs decrease the
frequency of housing adjustment and restricts investor’s ability to take advantage of
serial correlation in house prices.
By investing in large housing portfolios, the institutional investor has, relative to
the household investor, a lower risk exposure and higher net returns. Diversification
(e.g. geographical diversification) that results from holding a larger residential
portfolio, can improve investor welfare by reducing the exposure to any specific risk
borne by any single house. Additionally, the institutional investor benefits from
considerable economies of scale. In other words, size enables institutions to have lower
operating costs per amount of residential investment, and hence, higher net returns.
Papers by Devaney and Rayburn (1988), Goetzmann (1993), Flavin and Yamashita
(1998), Englund et al., (2000), Eichholtz et al., (2000) and Gatzlaff (2000), using different
procedures to measure housing returns, have all analysed the problem of households’
optimal portfolio when owner-occupied housing is included in the list of available
PM
22,4
268
assets. Their findings also confirm the institutional portfolio studies that correlations
between housing and other assets are low. However, when they look at housing
investment within a mean-variance framework, the precise amount of residential
assets to include in optimal portfolio is not the same for both types of investors.
Devaney and Rayburn (1988) examine the role of residential property in the
household investment portfolio, with capital appreciation returns based on a
transaction price index for Memphis (US) over the period 1970-1984. They find
empirical evidence of low correlation between residential property investment and
financial assets (shares, short and long term bonds). Additionally, they suggest that
there are low incremental benefits of diversification across housing submarkets[1] in
the same city. One note of caution in reading the empirical results is that the authors
use a housing appreciation return instead of a total housing return.
Goetzmann (1993) also examines the role of single family homes in the investors’
portfolio, with capital appreciation returns based on a value-weighted repeated-sales
index[2] in four urban US markets over the period 1971-1985. The author finds that
there are potential allocations for home investment in optimal portfolios comprising of
shares and bonds, although housing is not the predominant asset class and the
proportion of those allocations increases with the risk aversion of the investor. The
potential diversification benefits result is due primarily to the weak correlation
between housing returns and those of financial assets. Additionally, the paper confirms
the findings of Goetzmann and Ibbotson (1990) about the geographical diversification
benefits within residential property. The author presents evidence that even by
diversifying across four houses, one in each regional market, it is possible to reduce the
risk significantly. Furthermore, the study suggests that owning four homes in different
parts of the country generates risk-adjusted returns comparable to owning a fraction of
a portfolio composed of thousands of properties within a single region. In other words,
regional diversification dominates local diversification. Goetzmann further observes
that given the short time interval of analysis, one must be cautious in generalising the
results obtained regarding suggestions for future investment. Nevertheless, according
to the author, allocation studies based upon inputs derived from longer time intervals
suggest that housing may command an even larger percentage of the portfolio.
Flavin and Yamashita (1998) using data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics
(PSID)[3] on home values, compute real after-tax returns to owner-occupied housing
from 1968 to 1992. They report that owner-occupied housing returns and standard
deviation are slightly lower than those of shares. The authors also indicate that housing
returns are weakly correlated with those of financial assets (mortgages, short- and
long-term government bonds, and shares). Their empirical results show that households
hold different portfolios of financial assets because the constrain imposed by the
housing consumption varies considerably across households. In fact, the ratio of
housing investment to net worth declines over the household’s life-cycle, inducing a
life-cycle pattern in the household’s portfolio. Furthermore, they argue that
owner-occupied housing is an attractive asset for hedging fluctuations in financial
assets.
Recently, Englund et al., (2000), using a quarterly repeat sales house price index for
eight major Swedish regions between 1981 and 1993, examine the owner-occupied
housing investment in a multi-asset optimal portfolio (short- and long-term bonds,
market share index, and an index for real estate corporations traded on Stockholm
Housing and
household asset
allocation
269
share exchange) over different holding periods. The authors report that returns to
housing are positively correlated with real estate shares and negatively correlated with
bonds, and all correlations with housing are stronger at longer periods of time. The
correlation with market share index is nearly zero. Moreover, they point out that for
short-holding periods, housing allocation in an optimal portfolio is nearly zero. On the
other hand, for longer periods, low risk portfolios contain 15 to 50 percent on housing.
In disagreement with the Hoesli and Hamelink (1997) findings for Switzerland, the
authors indicate high correlations between housing returns across the different regions
of Sweden during the sample period. As a consequence, the diversification benefits
from holding a multi-regional housing portfolio within Sweden appear to be negligible.
Using a quarterly value-weighted repeated-sales index for Florida during the
1970-1999 period, Gatzlaff (2000) finds that housing returns are negatively correlated
with those on long-term government bonds, shares, and real estate investment trusts
and positively weakly correlated with equity REIT total returns. Moreover, the paper
shows evidence that housing assets allocation has potential benefits for mixed-asset
portfolios. They find that the efficient allocation of housing in these portfolios ranked
from 20 to 45 percent. Furthermore, the paper argues that housing assets reduce
the efficient institutional portfolios’ allocations to non-residential property. Thus, the
institutional investor should optimise not the plan’s investment portfolio, but rather
the wealth of individuals’ personal portfolio (members of the plan). This argument,
however, seems not valid for defined-benefit pension funds and life insurance
companies, because their liabilities tend to be defined in nominal terms.
Another recent study, Eichholtz et al., (2000), rely upon monthly value-weighted
repeat-sales index during the period 1980-1997 for five major US’ cities, to analyse the
performance of owner-occupied residential property in portfolios relative to shares and
bonds. The study reports that the housing property returns (measured by the
appreciation return component) and standard deviation have been lower than those of
shares and bonds. Additionally it shows that correlations between housing and
financial assets are small. In concordance with Hoesli and Hamelink’s (1997) results
(for Switzerland) and in disagreement with the findings of Englund et al., (2000)
(for Sweden), the paper shows evidence of diversification benefits from holding a
multi-regional housing portfolio within the US, since the relationship between the
different regional housing markets is not significant. In contrast to the Gatzlaff
argument, the study shows that the demand for shares and bonds is not strongly
affected by the issue of home ownership, as shares and bonds do not provide a good
housing property hedge.
In spite of the research evidence, there are several empirical weaknesses with the
housing diversification benefits argument.
First, the severe measurement problems of housing values. Thus, the results
obtained might actually be an artifact of the house price index used rather than a true
feature of the housing market. Second, the heterogeneity of the procedures to calculate
the housing returns. Some of the reviewed studies rely on appreciation returns as a
proxy for total returns and others use total returns. In addition, the income component
of the latter could be based either on a residential rent index or constant rent-to-value
ratio. Therefore, one must be careful to collate findings based on heterogeneous
housing returns.
PM
22,4
270
Third, the results are limited by the use of ex post returns instead of ex ante returns.
The previous studies assume that historic data are a good estimation of future values
on returns, variances and correlations. Sharpe (1990) however, suggests that financial
historical data appears to be useful for predicting future variances, reasonably useful
for forecasting correlations and virtually useless for estimation of expected returns.
Furthermore, MacGregor and Nanthakumaran (1992) report that the correlation of
property returns with those of financial assets is not stable over time. The authors
argue that the correlation is dependent on the economic fundamentals registered
during the time period analysed.
Fourth, the former empirical analysis was based on short-term transaction period
returns (that is, annual or quarterly holding periods). Recent research has indicated
that over long intervals there is a positive relationship between share returns and
commercial property price changes (Quan and Titman, 1999). Additionally, Geltner
and Miller (2001) suggest that when asset returns are correlated across time, the
optimal long-term portfolio could differ from the optimal short-term portfolio.
Fifth, the traditional minimum variance optimisers ignore the special features that
characterize some types of assets like property (illiquidity, marketability costs, and
measurement issues).
The statistical measure of risk, standard deviation, does not capture the illiquidity
of direct property, and thus standard optimisers tend to over weigh the portfolio
allocation into property. However, it is possible to account for these liquidity risk, by
subtracting illiquidity premiums from the average return on property. For instance,
MacGregor and Nanthakumaran (1992) use a quarterly illiquidity premium of 50 basis
points for UK property and Hoesli and Hamelink (1997) use illiquidity premiums of 50,
100 and 150 basis points for Swiss residential property. The illiquidity issue appears to
be more important in the commercial market than in the housing market, since the
latter, as mentioned before, exhibits a greater number of participants and transactions.
The traditional MPT ignores the marketability costs (Ibbotson and Siegel, 1984).
The marketability costs are related to the buying and selling process and comprise
information, transaction, and divisibility costs.
The information costs are, those related with the asset valuation process. The
unsecuritized property market, contrarily to the security markets, is characterized by
the absence of a transparent marketplace where it is easy to learn about expected asset
returns. Thus, the direct property should have higher before-cost expected returns than
assets that are easier to learn about (e.g. shares and bonds) (Ibbotson and Siegel, 1984).
The same authors also state that these type of costs tend to benefit the larger
investments, due to economies of scale.
The transaction costs (including the legal costs associated with the transaction,
costs of advertising, costs of brokers used to effect the transaction) in buying and
selling property are much greater than those in securities market. The transaction
costs could remove part of the potential residential investment profit from establishing
trading rules that consistently yield above-normal returns (Cho, 1996). Even so, the
transaction costs could be relieved by holding the property assets during longer
periods of time (Geltner and Miller, 2001). The transaction costs are extremely
important for investment strategies that require frequent trading, but less critical for
the long-term asset allocation decisions that are those usually faced by the institutional
investors.
Housing and
household asset
allocation
271
Divisibility costs emerge from the large size of some investments, such as property
(Ibbotson and Siegel, 1984). The indivisibility could cause some investors to hold a
non-optimal quantity of a particular investment. For instance, the smaller investors
may have difficulties in eliminating the systematic risk of property portfolios (Hoesli
and Macgregor, 2000) and, consequently, the portfolio theory methodology must be
applied to large portfolios only.
The mentioned special features that characterize the property assets comprise some
of the explanations like why the standard MPT optimisers tend to over weigh the
portfolio allocation into property. Despite the fact that these characteristics have an
effective influence on the “true” risk and return of property assets, they are not
incorporated in the traditional mean-variance approach.
Finally, Portfolio Theory assumes that investors derive utility from consumption,
which in turn is supported by financial wealth. The utility function takes a standard
form in which relative risk aversion is constant. In contrast, the behavioural finance
followers postulate that some investors have non-standard preferences. In a similar
vein, the prospect theory of Kehneman and Tversky (1979) models a utility function
that has a kink at the reference point and different patterns of curvature above and
below the point.
The prospect theory has been applied to housing price cycles with some interesting
results. For instance, Genesove and Mayer (2001) and Engelhardt (2001) suggest that
nominal loss aversion whereby house owners are particularly reluctant to realising
nominal price losses is an important explanation (along with housing equity
constraints) for some housing market puzzles, like the strong positive price-volume
correlation observed over the housing cycle and the negative correlation between house
prices and time on the market. Given the nominal loss aversion effect, one can
hypothesize that, during downward income cycles, the potential house purchasers may
prefer renting to buying houses at inflated prices. Such comportment would have a
positive effect over the demand in the rented housing sector during the downward
income cycles. These are times in which the investors in the private rented housing
would especially like their investments not to perform poorly. Additionally, Bernardes
and Montezuma (2002) consider the (indirect) effects that loss aversion in consumption
decisions might have on the housing market via demand behaviour. They argue that
house prices will be much more responsive to negative changes in income than to
positive changes, even at the start of the price cycle.
Others cite behaviour theory, include mental accounting, too much emphasis on
recent experience, overconfidence, amongst others. Behaviour finance appears to be a
promising research area with the potential to explain some types of investor behaviour
and possibly some patterns in asset pricing (Campbell and Viceira (2002)).
One can identify several possible directions for future research. The first involves a
consideration of the allocation factors that are not taken into account in the simplistic
modern portfolio theory framework, namely, the liability matching issue in the
institutional investment strategies and the special housing attributes (e.g. illiquidity,
indivisibility, political risk). One can speculate that the former factor may have a
positive impact on the proportion of institutional funds to residential property, since
the housing returns usually track household growth and incomes.
The inclusion of foreign-based equities as an institutional eligible asset could also
be a novel addition in relation to reviewed research. One can expect the inclusion of
PM
22,4
272
foreign equities to have a negative impact on the residential allocation, as a result of the
typically lower correlations between returns on foreign and those on national shares.
An additional direction involves the utilization of a multifactor asset pricing model
in order to produce forward-looking instead of historical-based risk and return
estimates (that is, ex post risk and returns). Given the cyclical behaviour of residential
property, the forward-based approach to estimate both risk and returns on housing
may well be advantageous for the analysis of residential property as an investment.
Developments in the study of the risk-return characteristics of housing property and
its role in a mixed-asset portfolio may also include the utilisation of residential data
pooled across countries, instead of data from a single country. Other research
extensions on this topic include the use of multi-asset time series over longer holding
periods (like five years) and the use of lags in time-series regressions.
Theoretical arguments for the property’s diversification characteristics
Different theoretical explanations are presented for the empirical results on the
correlations between property and financial assets. When the property returns are
affected essentially by the same economic factors (or systematic influences) that affect
the financial assets, property diversification benefits to multi-asset portfolios will be
minimal. In other words, when common economic factors strongly affect returns on
both property and financial asset classes, diversification across property may not be
cost justified. On the contrary, if the property returns also respond to property-specific
factors (non-systematic influences), diversification will be beneficial.
For instance, Quan and Titman (1999) hypothesize that positive correlations
between long-term share returns and those of commercial property are related to the
fact that commercial property and shares are both driven either, by changing
expectations (rational or irrational) of future economic growth or, by current economic
fundamentals.
Conversely, MacGregor and Nanthakumaran (1992) hypothesize that the low
correlations between property and financial assets are, to some extent, a result of the
property-specific factors rather than an artifact of the data. The authors’ argument is
that the property market supply responses to unexpected changes in the economic
fundamentals are slow. The production of new property is slow, not only because the
planning and building process is time-consuming, but also because the development
decision process itself is slow, i.e. the developers, in order to minimise their
investments risk, wait until the demand’ and prices’ increase is completely clear. The
short-term supply rigidity associated with a deficient demand forecast cause an
oversupply of property when demand is beginning to fall.
One can speculate that there are residential property-specific features able to reduce
the correlation between residential property returns and those of financial assets. For
example, foreign competition may lead to decreases in domestic wage rates, which in
turn leads to increased corporate profits and higher share prices. However, if
households’ income decreases, the housing demand will also decrease, and the
residential property values will fall. Changes in transport and communication network
features could also induce a negative relation between property and share values. For
instance, a more efficient transport and communication network may lead to increases
in corporate productivity and higher share prices, which in turn cause land rents to
decline and, consequently, decrease land values.
Housing and
household asset
allocation
273
From the empirical studies reviewed and the theoretical arguments offered, one
cannot reject, at least in the short-term, the hypothesized ability of housing to generate
improved risk-adjusted returns when added to share and bond portfolios.
Conclusions
The risk-return characteristics of the housing asset is highly dependent on the type of
perspective under analysis and therefore, the two housing investment approaches
could lead to different conclusions about the role of housing investment in a portfolio
context. The household’s demand for housing, which could be optimal from the point of
view of the consumption of housing services, may differ from the optimal level of
housing allocation in a purely portfolio investment context, the consumption demand
for housing together with the market imperfections places a constraint on the
household’s portfolio problem.
The empirical studies generally indicate that housing returns are weakly correlated
with those of financial assets (mortgages, short- and long-term government bonds, and
shares). They also suggest that housing is able to diversify a multi-asset portfolio and
that the proportion of housing allocations increases with the risk aversion of the
investor. However, the optimal amount of housing varies across the studies.
There is some theoretical and empirical evidences that the household’s optimal
portfolio is constrained by the ratio of housing investment to net worth, and this ratio
tends to be related to age. The households tend to hold different portfolios of financial
assets over their life-cycle. For example, a young household compared with a mature
household tends to hold an optimal portfolio with lower allocation on shares.
Because the housing returns tend to exhibit positive autocorrelation and the
transaction costs are high, the optimal household’s portfolio is dependent upon the
holding period (Englund et al., 2000). For instance, for short-holding periods, housing
allocation in an optimal portfolio is nearly zero. On the other hand, for longer periods,
low risk portfolios contain 15 to 50 percent on housing. Additionally, the transaction
costs decrease the frequency of housing adjustment and restrict investors’ ability to
take advantage of serial correlation in house prices. Finally, labour income and interest
rate risk seem to crowd out housing investment (Cocco, 2000).
Notes
1. The residential submarkets are based on Memphis City Planning Commission “planning
districts”. Planning districts were drawn to preserve the architectural integrity and to
incorporate natural and manmade boundaries.
2. The author uses estimated return series provided by Case and Shiller (1987).
3. On the PSID, the housing prices result from the owners’ own assessments of house values.
References
Bernardes, L. and Montezuma, J. (2002), “Loss aversion in consumption behavior and housing
price dynamics”, paper presented at the American Real Estate and Urban Economics
Association 2002 Annual Conference, Atlanta, GA.
Campbell, J. and Viceira, L. (2002), Strategic Asset Allocation Portfolio Choice for Long-Term
Investors, Oxford University Press, London.
Case, K.E. and Shiller, R. (1987), “Prices of single-family homes since 1970: new indices for four
cities”, New England Economic Review, pp. 45-56.
PM
22,4
274
Cho, M. (1996), “House price dynamics: a survey of theoretical and empirical issues”, Journal of
Housing Research, Vol. 7 No. 2, pp. 145-72.
Cocco, J.F. (2000), “Hedging house price risk with incomplete markets”, working paper, London
Business School, London.
Devaney, M. and Rayburn, W. (1988), “When a house is more than a home: performance of the
portfolio household portfolio”, The Journal of Real Estate Research, Vol. 3 No. 1, pp. 75-85.
Eichholtz, P., Koedijk, K. and De Roon, F. (2000), “The portfolio implications of home ownership”,
working paper, Maastricht University, Maastricht.
Engelhardt, G. (2001), “Nominal loss aversion, housing equity constraints, and household
mobility: evidence from the United States”, mimeo, Center for Policy Research, Syracuse
University, Syracuse, NY.
Englund, P., Min-Hwang and Quigley, J.M. (2000), “Hedging housing risk”, working paper
N. W00-07, University of California, Berkeley, CA.
Flavin, M. and Yamashita, T. (1998), “Owner-occupied housing and the composition of the
household portfolio owner the life cycle”, working paper No. 6389, National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Gatzlaff, D.H. (2000), “The effect of single-family housing on multi-asset portfolio allocations”,
working paper, Florida State University, Tallahassee, FL.
Geltner, D. and Miller, N. (2001), Commercial Real Estate Analysis and Investments,
South-Western Publishing, Cincinnati, OH.
Genesove, D. and Mayer, C. (2001), “Loss aversion and seller behavior: evidence from the housing
market”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 116 No. 4, pp. 1233-60.
Goetzmann, W.N. (1993), “The single family home in the investment portfolio”, Journal of Real
Estate Finance and Economics, Vol. 6 No. 3, pp. 201-22.
Goetzmann, W.N. and Ibbotson, R. (1990), “The performance of real estate as an asset class”,
Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 3 No. 1, pp. 65-76.
Grossman, S.J. and Laroque, G. (1990), “Asset pricing and optimal portfolio choice in the presence
of illiquid durable consumption goods”, Econometrica, Vol. 58, pp. 25-51.
Hoesli, M. and Hamelink, F. (1997), “An examination of the role of geneva and zurich housing in
swiss institutional portfolios”, Journal of Property Valuation & Investment, Vol. 15 No. 4,
pp. 354-71.
Hoesli, M. and MacGregor (2000), Property Investment Principles and Practices of Portfolio
Management, Longman Pearson Education Limited, Harlow.
Ibbotson, R. and Siegel, L. (1984), “Real estate returns: a comparison with other investments”,
Journal of American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, Vol. 12 No. 3, pp. 219-42.
Kahneman, D. and Tveraky, A. (1979), “Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk”,
Econometrica, pp. 263-91.
MacGregor, B. and Nanthakumaran, N. (1992), “The allocation to property in multi-asset
portfolio: the evidence and the theory reconsidered”, Journal of Property Research, Vol. 9,
pp. 5-32.
Quan, D. and Sheridan, T. (1999), “Do real estate prices and stocks prices move together? an
international analysis”, Real Estate Economics, Vol. 27 No. 2, pp. 183-207.
Sharpe, W. (1990) in Magin, J. and Tuttle, D. (Eds), Asset Allocation, in Management Investing
Portfolios A Dynamic Process.
Housing and
household asset
allocation
275
... Understandably, this is an attempt to reduce risk or to balance risk and return. Given this, if property prices in one area diverge too far from those in another location, an arbitrage opportunity will arise (William Nelson Goetzmann 1993; Joaquim J. Montezuma 2004). Table 3 reports the results of applying the PS convergence and clustering procedure. ...
Article
Full-text available
This study examines the convergence patterns of prices across 50 U.S. states over the period 1960-2007, by applying the convergence algorithm developed by Peter C. B. Phillips and Donggyu Sul (2007). The empirical findings suggest the rejection of full convergence across the 50 U.S. states? prices, and the presence of 11 subgroups, or convergence clubs. The main implications of this paper point to the low degree of market integration across the U.S. states, the limitations of using a unique national price deflator to calculate real U.S. state variables, and the different effects that national monetary policy decisions will have on U.S. state prices.
... Zapadnije, na drugoj strani kontinenta, stanovnici bogatijih europskih zemalja dijelove "globalizacijske berbe" također plasiraju u kuće i stanove. Izraženo u postocima ništa impresivno, ali dovoljno da se naglo poveća broj znanstvenih i stručnih tekstova koji se bave dilemom: ulagati u stanove ili u dionice (Montezuma, 2004.). ...
Article
Full-text available
Ovaj rad istražuje makroekonomske posljedice mikroekonomskih odluka u segmentu stanovanja. U radu se dokazuje teza da je posjedovanje stana ili kuće za pojedince i kućanstva cilj svih ciljeva, a za društvo je u cjelini put u nižu efi kasnost proizvodnih faktora. Postupnim analitičkim izvođenjem postaje poprilično jasno da (a) gospodarstvo postiže niže stope rasta u zemljama koje imaju veći postotak vlasnika stanova koji u njima žive, (b) što je iznajmljivanje stanova postotno veće, to je pokretljivost radnika veća, (c) što je viši postotak vlasnika stanova koji u tim stanovima žive, to su negativne eksternalije snažnije, (d) što je porez na promet viši, mobilnost radne snage je manja, (e) što je više vlasnika stanova, to je potražnja za stanovima više funkcija prometne nego njihove upotrebne vrijednosti. U završnom se komentaru ističe da se i na ovom segmentu hrvatskoga društvenoga života, politika, shvaćena u užem smislu, pokazala kao maćeha ekonomskoj politici. Ono što nam donekle može ublažiti nemoći i nesnalaženja jest činjenica da je u nekim aspektima stanovanja i drugdje slično, osobito u Europi. I tamo su cijene stanova i kuća neobično snažno sklone špekulacijama.
... In such conditions, the possibility of arbitrage always exists if house prices in one regional market diverge too far from another market (Goetzmann, 1993;Montezuma, 2004). Briefly, the implication of the LOOP is that, if regional housing markets are not segmented then their absolute prices should converge, meaning that they form a convergence club. ...
Article
This empirical study analyzes the long run behavior of provincial house prices in South Africa based on the club convergence and clustering procedure of Phillips and Sul. Using quarterly data covering the period of 1976Q2–2012Q4, 1974Q1–2012Q4 and 1977Q3–2012Q4 for the large, medium, and small middle segments of the housing market, respectively, we test the law of one price across nine provinces. The empirical findings suggest that the nine provinces do not form a homogeneous convergence club. Unlike the small middle segment, which consists of two convergence clubs of seven and two provinces, the large and medium middle segments have three convergence clubs corresponding to three segmented independent local markets. Possible intuitive explanations for the existence of such clubs are discussed and resulting policy implications provided.
... Understandably, this is an attempt to reduce risk or to create a balance between risk and return. Given this, if property prices in one area diverge too far from another area, an arbitrage opportunity always exists (Goetzmann, 1993;Montezuma, 2004). ...
Article
Full-text available
The paper examines the long-run behavior of house prices by addressing the issue of price convergence or divergence across fifteen metropolitan cities in India. Using available city-level quarterly data covering the period 2007-2011 and applying the Im, Pesaran and Shin (2003) panel unit root test, it is found that relative price levels among various metropolitan cities in India do not converge. This implies that the Law of One Price does not hold in the Indian housing market, hence the different metropolitan house markets operate independent to one another.
... Understandably, this is an attempt to reduce risk or balance between risk and return. Given this, if property prices in one area diverge too far off from another location, an arbitrage opportunity always exists (Goetzmann, 1993;Montezuma, 2004). ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper analyzes whether the Law of One Price (LOOP) holds in the housing market of five metropolitan areas of South Africa, namely Cape Town, Durban, Greater Johannesburg, Port Elizabeth/Uitenhage and Pretoria. We test the existence of LOOP using the efficient unit root tests proposed by Elliott et al. (1996) [DF-GLS] and Elliott (1999) [DF-GLSu] based on monthly data on residential property prices covering the period of 1967:01 to 2009:03 for the large-, medium and small-middle segments of the housing market. Based on the DF-GLSu test, we find overwhelming evidence of the existence of LOOP in twelve of the fifteen cases, especially as the sample periods include more recent data. More importantly, our results are in sharp contrast with those obtained by Burger and Van Rensburg (2008) using quarterly data to based on the Im, Pesharan and Shin (IPS, 2003) test, which are, in turn, shown to be highly sensitive to frequency of the data and temporal aggregation. With the rejection of the null hypothesis of unit roots, based on panel data tests, not providing sufficient evidence to conclude that all the series in the panels have a unit root or not, more reliability should be placed on our results obtained from the efficient unit root tests.
... Understandably, this is an attempt to reduce risk or balance between risk and return. Given this, if property prices in one area diverge too far off from another location, an arbitrage opportunity always exists (Goetzmann, 1993;Montezuma, 2004). ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper analyzes whether the Law of One Price (LOOP) holds in the housing market of five metropolitan areas of South Africa, namely Cape Town, Durban, Greater Johannesburg, Port Elizabeth/Uitenhage and Pretoria. We test the existence of LOOP using the efficient unit root tests proposed by Elliott et al. (1996) [DF-GLS] and Elliott (1999) [DF-GLSu] based on monthly data on residential property prices covering the period of 1967:01 to 2009:03 for the large-, medium and small-middle segments of the housing market. Based on the DF-GLSu test, we find overwhelming evidence of the existence of LOOP in twelve of the fifteen possible cases, especially as the sample period becomes more recent. More importantly, our results are in sharp contrast with those obtained by Burger and Van Rensburg (2008) using quarterly data based on the Im, Pesharan and Shin (IPS, 2003) test, which are, in turn, shown to be highly sensitive to frequency of the data and temporal aggregation. With the rejection or the non-rejection of the null hypothesis of unit roots, based on panel data tests, not providing sufficient evidence to conclude that all the series in the panels have a unit root or that they are all stationary, more reliability should be placed on our results obtained from the efficient unit root tests.
Article
Full-text available
Households participate in financial activities through asset allocation, which will not only maintain and increase the value of household assets, but also have a significant impact on China’s economic and financial development. China has a vast territory and obvious regional characteristics, and there are significant differences in economic structure and urbanization level among the eastern, central and western regions. Under this background, the development of family finance among regions is also unbalanced. After summarizing the macro characteristics of household asset allocation in China, this paper makes a micro empirical study of urban households in China with the help of China Household Financial survey database, and explores the regional differences between the eastern region and the central and western regions from different perspectives, by using the Tobit model. The empirical analysis results show that the proportion of stable holding in the eastern region is significantly lower than that in the central and western regions, and households in the eastern region have a greater preference for risky financial assets.
Article
The aim of this paper is the analysis of macroeconomic implications of microeconomic level decision making in the household sector. In the paper we show that while owning a flat or a house is perceived as the main goal for an individual, for the society this is a road to lower effi ciency of the production factors. Our further investigation finds that (a) the economies with high proportion of owner-occupied housing, experience lower growth rates; (b) the economies with high percentage of renting activity in the household sector have a more mobile labour force; (c) negative externalities increase with the higher percentage of owner-occupied housing; (d) labour force mobility decreases with the higher stamp duty; (e) the demand for flats/houses becomes more a function of the exchange value than use value with the higher proportion of owner-occupied housing in the economy. In the fi nal comments we argue that even in this segment of the Croatian social life the politics (narrowly implied) have been found to dominate over the economic policy. What may, to some extent, serve as a consolation in this situation is the finding that in other countries, especially in Europe, the situation in the housing sector is similar and that there too the prices of flats and houses are quite prone to speculation.
Article
The question this paper investigates is whether or not different metropolitan areas each constitute a separate housing market or whether or not there is a single South African housing market. Theory on the Law of One Price suggests that if products or geographic areas belong in the same market, their absolute prices must converge, so that their relative prices are stationary. By using cross-sectional time series data of five metropolitan areas, the paper tests for the Law of One Price by applying the Im, Pesaran and Shin panel unit root test. The paper finds strong evidence of convergence in large middle-segment house prices and weaker support for convergence in medium middle-segment house prices. In addition, the paper finds no evidence for convergence in small middle-segment house prices. This suggests the existence of a national market for large and possibly middle-segment houses in metropolitan areas, but separate metropolitan markets for small middle-segment houses. In addition, the paper estimates the speed of convergence and finds that large middle-segment house prices converge within two to seven quarters, while the speed of convergence for medium middle-segment house prices in three of the five areas is five to eight quarters. Copyright (c) 2008 The Authors. Journal compilation (c) 2008 Economic Society of South Africa.
Article
Full-text available
During the last decade, the number of studies dealing with dynamic movements of house prices has been rapidly increasing. Main contributive factors for this trend include better availability of extensive micro data sets, the progress in various dynamic modeling techniques, and heightened business applications. The current article aims to review the main theoretical, empirical, and methodological issues related to analyzing house price dynamics. The theoretical issue that received the most attention in the literature was the informational efficiency of the housing market. Despite the housing literature's short history on this topic, 29 papers, all focusing on residential real estate market, were identified and reviewed. The general conclusion from these studies supports our intuition that real estate markets are not efficient: that is, short-run intertemporal changes in house prices and excess returns are found to be positively serially correlated. There is also some evidence of mean reversion. However, the reviewed studies are generally short in developing a trading rule that can consistently yield above-normal returns, mainly due to substantial transaction costs in the housing market. There are also numerous recent studies that propose alternative models for estimating house price indices and measuring excess returns. These suggested models and related methodological issues are also surveyed to document the current state of research in this area. The paper concludes by discussing future research directions and some promising new modeling techniques.
Article
Swiss institutional investors hold approximately 19 per cent of their wealth in property, and the bulk of the allocation to property is housing. The financial reasons which are often given to motivate this investment strategy are twofold. First, property returns are hypothesized to be lowly correlated with the returns on stocks and bonds, and the inclusion of property in portfolios of financial assets should lead to diversification benefits. Second, property is viewed as acting as an effective hedge against inflation. Empirically investigates these two assumptions on the basis of hedonic price indices for Geneva and Zurich apartment buildings. Examines whether an investor who already holds Geneva (Zurich) housing should invest in the other canton. Investigates whether real estate mutual funds should be included in the portfolio in addition to direct real estate holdings. Results suggest that housing is an effective portfolio diversifier but does not provide any better short-term inflation-hedging effectiveness than financial assets.
Article
Studies which use modern portfolio theory (MPT) to calculate the optimal allocation to property in a multi‐asset portfolio are fundamentally flawed. These suggest optimal theoretical allocations for property which are much higher than actual allocations to property. Criticism can be made of: the exclusion of other eligible assets from the analysis; the use of a mean‐variance optimization technique on estimated data; the inadequacies of the historical data which understates risk and correlation and may overstate return; the changing characteristics of property as an investment; the indivisibility of property and the consequent difficulties in achieving a diversified property portfolio; the complexity of risk as a concept compared to the simple and simplistic definition used in MPT; and the omission of explicit consideration of differential liquidity. An alternative which offers a more practicable framework for decision‐making is a combination of econometric techniques to forecast income under differing economic scenarios and a discounted cash flow valuation model. This would produce a proper expectations‐based analysis of return and risk. However, it will always be important to understand the complexity of investors objectives as these extend far beyond the simple return‐risk trade‐off used in MPT.
Book
Academic finance has had a remarkable impact on many financial services, yet long-term investors have curiously received little guidance from academic financial economists. Using recent theoretical and empirical research, this book addresses the real world problem of how to develop a long term portfolio strategy. Written by a leading academic and bestselling author, this seminal work is a must read for practitioners, finance academics, and graduate students in finance. Available in OSO: http://www.oxfordscholarship.com/oso/public/content/economicsfinance//toc.html
Article
This paper exploits the recent variation in US house prices to examine the effect of equity constraints and nominal loss aversion on household mobility. Detailed data from the 1985–1996 National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY79) were matched with house price data from 149 metropolitan areas to estimate instrumental variables linear probability and semi-parametric proportional hazard models of intra-metropolitan mobility. Household mobility is significantly influenced by nominal loss aversion. There is little evidence that low equity because of fallen house prices constrains mobility.
The tradeoff between risk and return in equity markets is well established. This paper examines the existence of the same tradeoff in the single-family housing market. For home buyers, who constitute about two-thirds of U.S. households, the choice about how much housing and which house to buy is a joint consumption/investment decision. Does this consumption/investment link negate the risk/return tradeoff within the single-family hosuing market? Theory suggests the link still holds. This paper supplies empirical evidence in support of that theoretical result.
Article
We analyze a model of optimal consumption and portfolio selection in which consumption services are generated by holding a durable good. The durable good is illiquid in that a transaction cost must be paid when the good is sold. It is shown that optimal consumption is not a smooth function of wealth; it is optimal for the consumer to wait until a large change in wealth occurs before adjusting his consumption. As a consequence, the consumption based capital asset pricing model fails to hold. Nevertheless, it is shown that the standard, one factor, market portfolio based capital asset pricing model does hold in this environment. It is shown that the optimal durable level is characterized by three numbers (not random variables), say x, y, and z (where $x < y < z$ ). The consumer views the ratio of consumption to wealth (c/W) as his state variable. If this ratio is between x and z, then he does not sell the durable. If c/W is less than x or greater than z, then he sells his durable and buys a new durable of size S so that S/W = y. Thus y is his "target" level of c/W. If the stock market moves up enough so that c/W falls below x, then he sells his small durable to buy a larger durable. However, there will be many changes in the value of his wealth for which c/W stays between x and z, and thus consumption does not change. Numerical simulations show that small transactions costs can make consumption changes occur very infrequently. Further, the effect of consumption transactions costs on the demand for risky assets is substantial.