ArticlePDF Available

Abstract

In this paper, it is argued that, given its relatively short duration and high year-to-year variability, the MFP data set does not contain enough information to allow clear statistical discrimination between competing hypotheses. As a result of this lack of information, combined with the human predilection for observing patterns, a range of alternative stories, each of which may be supported by an appropriate interpretation of the data, has been produced. Three such stories are described here. The first is the ÔNew EconomyÕ story put forward by Parham and others. The second story agrees with the first regarding the 1990s, but interprets the subsequent decline in productivity growth as the result of a failure to pursue microeconomic reform with sufficient vigour. The third story rejects the idea of a productivity miracle in the 1990s and argues instead that productivity growth rates experienced a sharp decline at the end of the postwar ÔGolden AgeÕ around 1970, and that this decline has been sustained, although with fluctuations around the trend.
Research supported by an Australian Research Council Federation Fellowship and
Discovery Project
http://www.arc.gov.au/grant_programs/discovery_federation.htm
Stories about productivity
John Quiggin
Australian Research Council Federation Fellow, University of Queensland
Risk & Sustainable Management Group
Schools of Economics and Political Science
University of Queensland
Brisbane, 4072
rsmg@uq.edu.au
http://www.uq.edu.au/economics/rsmg
Australian Public Policy Program Working Paper: P06_4
This version: 4 April, 2006
Stories about productivity
John Quiggin
Australian Research Council Federation Fellow
School of Economics and School of Political Science and International
Studies
University of Queensland
EMAIL j.quiggin@uq.edu.au
PHONE + 61 7 3346 9646
FAX +61 7 3365 7299
http://www.uq.edu.au/economics/johnquiggin
I thank Nancy Wallace for helpful comments and criticism.
This research was supported by an Australian Research Council Federation Fellowship.
2
Stories about productivity
When asked about their methodological practices, most economists claim
to practise some form of instrumentalist positivism, as advocated by Friedman
(1953) or appeal to Popper’s (1963) notions of falsification, implemented by the
hypothesis-testing procedures of classical inference. More philosophically
sophisticated members of the profession might, following Blaug (1980), refer to
Lakatos’ (1970) methodology of scientific research programs.
In practice, however, particularly in debates over economic policy,
economists rely heavily on a ‘story-telling’ approach. What matters in this
approach is not the formulation of decisive tests of statistical significance, but
the application of economic reasoning to the relevant ‘stylised facts’ to produce a
convincing narrative account. Although most prescriptive methodologists regard
such story-telling as relying on inappropriate appeals to implicit presumptions
and collective authority, this approach has been strongly defended by McCloskey
(1983).
Beginning in the late 1990s, a narrative developed around the idea of a
‘new’ or ‘miracle’ economy in Australia. Although strong macroeconomic
performance, particularly during the Asian economic crisis, contributed to the
appeal of this narrative, the crucial element of the story was derived from
estimates of multifactor productivity (MFP) developed by the Australian Bureau
of Statistics (various years), first published by the in the late 1990s, and
presented by the Productivity Commission (Parham 1999, 2000) as evidence of
the success of microeconomic reform.
The ABS estimates showed a surge in productivity beginning around
1993-94, and were interpreted as showing the benefits of the micro-economic
reforms undertaken by the Hawke–Keating government. Although the
improvement in estimated MFP growth rate was not sustained beyond 1998-99,
the story of a productivity surge driven by reform continues to be told.
The statistical basis for the ‘new economy’ story has been disputed by
critics. Quiggin (2001) argued that the observed upsurge in estimated rates of
3
MFP growth could be explained, in large measure, by recovery from recession
and by an unsustainable increase in work intensity.1 Quiggin (2005) claimed
that the slowdown in MFP after 1998-99 supported this view. A more
fundamental criticism was offered by Hancock (2005), who fitted simple linear
and quadratic models to the data and found that the null hypothesis of a
constant rate of MFP growth could not be rejected. In response, Parham (2005a)
argued that an appropriate analysis of data, using smoothing, error-correction
and appropriate timing of cyclical breaks supported claims of a productivity
‘surge’ in the 1990s.
In this paper, it will be argued that, given its relatively short duration
and high year-to-year variability, the MFP data set does not contain enough
information to allow clear statistical discrimination between competing
hypotheses. As a result of this lack of information, combined with the human
predilection for observing patterns, a range of alternative stories, each of which
may be supported by an appropriate interpretation of the data, has been
produced.
Three such stories are described here. The first is the ‘New Economy’
story put forward by Parham and others. The second story agrees with the first
regarding the 1990s, but interprets the subsequent decline in productivity
growth as the result of a failure to pursue microeconomic reform with sufficient
vigour. The third story rejects the idea of a productivity miracle in the 1990s and
argues instead that productivity growth rates experienced a sharp decline at the
end of the postwar ‘Golden Age’ around 1970, and that this decline has been
sustained, although with fluctuations around the trend.
1 For reasons that are not clear, Parham (2005a) summarises this paper as follows: ‘A self-
professed sceptic, Quiggin (2001) has come to accept that there was a productivity surge, though
his is at the low end of estimates’. The conclusion of Quiggin (2001) was: ‘The claim that
economic performance in the 1990s was comparable with that of the golden age of the 1960s is
inconsistent with the empirical evidence. On the basis of the available data, it is not even
possible to conclude with confidence that the underlying rate of productivity growth was higher
in the 1990s than in the 1980s.’ This conclusion does not support Parham’s interpretation.
4
Background
Beginning in the late 1990s, the Australian Bureau of Statistics began
producing estimates of MFP for the market sector, going back to 1963-64. The
crucial requirement for the development of these estimates was the construction
of estimates of the capital stock, thereby permitting the derivation of estimates
of MFP in place of partial labour productivity measures.
The ABS statistics were organised using the concept of productivity
cycles, typically of about six years, which were inferred from the properties of the
annual MFP series. Although productivity cycles typically corresponded fairly
closely to expansion and contraction phases of macroeconomic cycles, no
exogenous information was used in dating cycles.
From a statistical viewpoint, the central question is whether the data set
contains enough information to make reliable claims about average levels and
trends in productivity growth and about the occurrence or absence of a structural
break in those trends in the early 1990s.
It is important to observe that the ability to derive robust inferences
from a data set typically declines each time the data is differenced. Thus, the
data contains more evidence on the level of MFP than on the rate of growth of
MFP, and more evidence on the rate of growth of MFP than on trends in the rate
of growth of MFP. Attempts to detect a structural break in the trend rate of
growth of MFP are therefore likely to be fraught with difficulty.
The data set allows a decisive rejection of the obvious null hypothesis
relating to the rate of growth of MFP, namely that the rate is zero. On the other
hand, as Hancock (2005) shows, using Ordinary Least Squares to estimate a
simple linear trend of the form
MFP(t) = a + bt,
the null hypothesis b!=!0 cannot be rejected at standard levels of significance.
Similar results are obtained using a quadratic functional form
MFP(t) = a + bt + ct2.
5
Parham (2005a) criticises Hancock’s analysis arguing that the failure to
find statistically significant results reflects short-term noise in the data, and
that it is better to focus on smoothed data. If the ABS analysis of productivity
cycles is accepted, it seems most natural to focus on a data set consisting of such
cycles, as is done in most of the informal discussion of the topic. This data set is
presented in Table 1.
Table 1: Multifactor productivity growth since 1964-65
a: Percentage points, annual average
b Percentage points
Notes
1. Source: Australian Bureau of Statistics
2. The long-term average rate from 1964-65 to 2004-05 is 1.2 per cent
3. Excluded observation for 2004-05, -1.7 per cent
The obvious problem for statistical analysis is that there are only eight
data points. This would be enough to detect a trend if the series declined or
increased steadily. There are seven differences in the series, so the probability
that they are all of the same sign (either positive or negative), under the null
hypothesis of stationarity, is 2-n+1 or 1.5 per cent for n=7, which is sufficiently
small to reject the null hypothesis. However, no such monotone trend is present
in the data set.
Any more complex pattern is impossible to confirm or reject with such a
limited data set, using standard classical inference testing. Parham (2005a)
claims that visual inspection of the smoothed data set supports the hypothesis of
Cycle
1964-65 to 68-69
1968-69 to 1973-74
1973-74 to 1981-82
1981-82 to 1984-85
1984-85 to 1988-89
1988-89 to 1993-94
1993-94 to 1998-99
1998-99 to 2003-04
Multifactor productivity
growth ratea
1.3
1.6
1.1
0.9
0.6
0.7
2.0
1.0
First difference
in MFP b
0.3
-0.5
-0.2
-0.3
0.1
1.3
-1.0
6
a productivity surge in the 1990s. However, the ability of the human eye to
detect apparent patterns in random data is notorious. It is not difficult to find
interpretations consistent with prior beliefs, but it seems clear from the course of
the debate so far that a wide range of prior beliefs can be supported by visual
inspection of the data.
Neither the raw annual data, nor the cyclical arrangement preferred by
the ABS justifies rejection of the null hypothesis of random variation about a
constant mean. There are a range of intermediate options, involving either the
use of smoothed versions of the data set or the application of error-correction
models to the raw data.
Parham (2005b) reports that statistical modelling using error correction
methods yielded support for the hypothesis of a structural break in 1990-91.
However, since there are a great many possible models incorporating structural
breaks at different points in the data series, it is hard to assess the power of
statistical tests. Given nearly 40 possible choices for a break point, it would be
not be surprising to find the null hypothesis of a constant trend rejected for at
least one of these points using standard statistical tests.
It seems unlikely that such results, mostly estimated over the period up
to 1998-99, would prove robust if the same model were fitted to the out-of-sample
data that has subsequently been observed. McKenzie (2005) using data for the
period up to 2002-03 finds no evidence that the ‘spike’ in productivity during the
mid-1990s was sustained.
Alternative stories
In the absence of any clear statistical resolution of disputes over the
correct interpretation of the productivity data, it may be useful to consider an
analysis of the debate based on a rhetorical or ‘storytelling’ approach to
descriptive methodology. In this approach, rather than considering a description
of research in terms of the formulation and testing of hypotheses, we consider
various alternative stories that can be told about the data, and the factors that
might lead to these stories being accepted or rejected in a given community.
7
The ‘New Economy’ story
According to the ‘New Economy’ the program of microeconomic reform
that began with the floating of the Australian dollar in 1983 has, after some
initial disruption, produced a new, more flexible and more productive Australian
economy. Thus, the pain of structural adjustment has been more than offset by
the gains from sustained high economic growth.
The ‘New Economy’ story was developed with a focus on estimates of MFP
for the 1990s, and particularly the cycle from 1993-94 to 1998-99. After declining
fairly steadily from the ‘Golden Age’ of the 1960s to the early 1990s, estimated
rates of MFP growth showed a sharp upturn for the cycle beginning in 1993–94,
matching or exceeding those of the ‘Golden Age’. The final estimates for the cycle
from 1993-94 to 1998-99 show a productivity growth rate of 2.0 per cent, the
highest of any period in the ABS data set.
Advocates of the New Economy story, most notably Parham (2005b), have
explained the relatively weak MFP growth estimated for the period since
1998-99 as the product of a variety of temporary factors, including a ‘short-term
blip’ in 2000-01, possibly associated with the introduction of the GST, drought in
2002-03 and 2003-04, the Olympic Games in 2004, and, more recently,
bottlenecks constraining growth in mineral exports.
Given underlying strong MFP growth, however, each of these temporary
shocks should have been followed by above-normal MFP growth, as productivity
returned to its long-term growth path. The idea of a ‘productivity cycle’
incorporates the notion that short-term effects like those discussed above should
wash out over the course of a cycle.
This point is developed further by Dolman et al. (2006) who conclude that
‘in an historical context, the productivity surge of the late
1990s, rather than the most recent productivity cycle,
appears to be the more unusual experience.’
Dolman et al. consider a variety of explanations of the surge in measured
productivity during the 1990s, including microeconomic reform, but find that
none of them are consistent with the slowdown observed after 1999.
8
The ‘New Economy’ story gains more support from macroeconomic than
from microeconomic outcomes. The current expansion, which has already lasted
fifteen years since the trough of the 1990-91 recession, is one of the longest on
record in Australia, and one of the longest for any OECD country in recent
decades. It was continued growth during the Asian economic crisis of 1997 and
1998 that led to Krugman (1998) describing Australia’s as a ‘miracle economy’.
There is, however, no clear reason to link microeconomic reform to
macroeconomic stability. Supporters of the ‘New Economy’ thesis argue that
market-oriented microeconomic reform has increased the flexibility of the
economy. However, observation of the global business cycle over the past two
centuries gives little support for this view. Even though economic intervention
was very limited in the 19th century, severe recessions and depressions occurred
regularly. Similarly, government intervention, regulation and unionisation were
very limited in the United States in the 1920s, but that did not prevent the
occurrence of the Great Depression.
Despite these objections, the rhetorical appeal of the New Economy story
is obvious. The narrative is one of virtue rewarded, always a popular theme. The
rapid growth in wealth observed over the past few years is attributed, not to
macroeconomic good fortune and a global decline in interest rates, but to the
hard work and sacrifice of the 1980s and early 1990s.
‘The light that failed’
An alternative story, also popular with some advocates of microeconomic
reform agrees with the New Economy story in presenting rapid growth during
the cycle from 1993-94 to 1998-99 as representing the benefits of microconomic
reform. However, the period from 1999-00 onwards is viewed more
pessimistically. The slowdown in productivity growth is regarded as real, and the
result of a slowdown in the pace of microeconomic reform.
The major difficulty for this story is one of timing. While the Howard
government has taken a less consistent approach to reform than its Labor
predecessors, it introduced a number of major reforms in its first few years in
9
office. Many of these were measures that had long been demanded by advocates
of radical reform but resisted by the Labor government because of political
sensitivities. These included the Workplace Relations Act 1996 (Cwlth), the
partial privatisation of Telstra in 1998 and 1999, waterfront reform in 1998, and,
most notably, the Goods and Services Tax, introduced in 2000.
Moreover, many reforms introduced by the Hawke–Keating government
did not begin to take effect until after 1998. The most notably of these is
National Competition Policy. Most states did not even complete their legislative
reviews or set up their general regulatory bodies until 1998, and the National
Competition Policy process, with associated payments to the states was still not
completed by 2003-04.
If such an array of reforms is not sufficient to maintain even an average
rate of productivity growth, the whole rationale of microeconomic reform is called
into question. Far from generating sustained growth, the ‘light that failed’ story
suggests that the decade or more of microeconomic reform that began with the
floating of the dollar in 1983, produced only five years of above average
productivity growth before requiring a renewed burst of reform merely to sustain
past gains.
In view of the substantial adjustment costs associated w i t h
microeconomic reform, the ‘light that failed’ story implies that, in many cases,
the net present value of microeconomic reform must be negative. It is generally
conceded, for example, that the short-term consequences of financial
deregulation included a relaxation of lending standards that contributed to the
severity of the 1990-91 recession. If the benefits of this reform were only
temporary, being exhausted by 1998-99, the present value, viewed from an ex
ante perspective, was almost certainly negative.
The most convincing argument for the ‘light that failed’ story is based on
the idea that international competition is becoming steadily more intense,
necessitating ever more radical reform. But this idea is obviously inconsistent
with the claim that microeconomic reform is associated with increasing welfare
and economic productivity. The whole point of economic progress is that the
10
choice set available to society should expand, not contract.
Again, however, the ‘light that failed’ story has a strong rhetorical appeal.
Surprisingly, perhaps, calls for sacrifice are always popular, and the view that it
is never time to rest on your oars can always count on a hearing. The ‘light that
failed’ story combines this rhetorical appeal with adherence to the claim that
Australia did indeed experience a productivity miracle.
The ‘blip’ story
The central point of the ‘blip’ story (Hancock 2005, McKenzie 2005,
Quiggin 2005) is that the productivity ‘surge’ of the 1990s was a statistical
illusion. The central theme of the story is that the notion of a ‘productivity cycle’
is misleading, since the correct basis for comparison is derived from the business
cycle rather than from internal properties of the series of productivity estimates.
Dividing business cycles into two or more productivity cycles is likely to produce
alternating periods of weak (contraction phases) and strong (expansion phases)
productivity growth. This point is observed by Dolman et al. (2006) who note (p.
42) ‘A period of strong multi-factor productivity growth is not typically followed
by another similar period.’
In addition to the general pattern of alternating expansion and
contraction phases, Quiggin (2001) points to a number of temporary factors that
led to an overestimation of MFP growth for the mid-1990s cycle. The most
important was an increase in work intensity, correlated with an increase in
reported and unreported working hours, and supported by widespread anecdotal
evidence. Reported working hours for full-time workers peaked around 2000, as
did popular discussion of increased work intensity. Thus, it seems likely that
gains in measured productivity from this source during the 1990s were, at least
partially, reversed after 2000.
Consideration of the MFP data supports this view. For the entire period
since 1993-94, including the most recent observation for 2004-05, the average
rate of MFP growth is 1.2 per cent, exactly the same as for the entire data
period. For the current incomplete macroeconomic cycle, beginning at the last
11
cyclical peak in 1988-89, the rate of MFP growth is below the long term average
Thus, the ‘blip’ story is parsimonious as an explanation, and fits the data
well. On the other hand, a negative finding lacks rhetorical appeal. The
publication bias against such findings is well-known (Scargle 2000).
To the extent that the ‘blip’ story has rhetorical appeal, it does so by
enhancing the contrast between the ‘Golden Age’ from World War II to the early
1970s and the long period of poor economic performance that began with the
breakdown of the Bretton Woods system in the early 1970s. Although the ABS
MFP data only goes back to the early 1960s, and begins with an anomalous
decline in MFP from 1964-65 to 1965-66, it seems likely that MFP growth was
strong throughout the Golden Age, which was also characterised by full
employment and steady reductions in the inequality of income distribution. By
contrast, the period since the early 1970s has been disappointing in all these
respects.
An analysis showing higher productivity growth for the period before
1970 compared to the subsequent period is appealing for those who prefer the
policies of the Golden Age, including Keynesian macroeconomic stabilisation, and
an expanding welfare state, to the less interventionist policies associated with
the program of microeconomic reform.
Concluding comments
Considered in Popperian or Lakatosian terms, the ‘New Economy’ claim
that Australia experienced a productivity surge in the 1990s, driven by
microeconomic reform in the preceding decade must be regarded as a refuted
hypothesis. In the Popperian approach, the crucial test of a hypothesis is
prediction and potential falsification.
The natural prediction of the New Economy hypothesis, put forward at
the time the hypothesis was formulated was that the further reforms of the
1990s would generate continued strong growth in measured multifactor
productivity. This prediction was refuted by the observed outcome. Subsequent
attempts either to explain away contradictory evidence or to ‘save the
12
phenomena’ by advancing the modified ‘light that failed’ hypothesis may be seen
as evidence, in the terminology of Lakatos, of a degenerating scientific research
program.
Considered in the rhetorical terms proposed by McCloskey (1983),
however, the ‘New Economy’ story and its variants remain highly successful. The
view that Australia’s long-running economic expansion, and the associated
growth in household wealth is the product of tough decisions in the past, rather
than a combination of asset inflation and adroit macroeconomic management has
obvious appeal.
This appeal may be found both in the optimistic ‘New Economy’ version
which projects a renewal of strong productivity growth as a result of reforms
already undertaken, and in the more pessimistic ‘light that failed’ story in which
we are in danger of losing the gains of the 1990s. Notably, while giving directly
opposed interpretations of the data for the most recent productivity cycle,
advocates of the two stories derive the same policy conclusion: more reform is
needed.
References
Australian Bureau of Statistics (various years), ‘Australian System of National
Accounts Cat No 5204’, ABS, Canberra.
Australian Bureau of Statistics (various years), ‘Indexes of productivity and
related measures spreadsheet 5204022’, ABS, Canberra.
Blaug, M. (1980) The Methodology of Economics : Or How Economists Explain,
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Dolman, B., Lu, L. and Rahman, J. (2006), ‘Understanding productivity trends’,
Treasury Economic Roundup, Summer, 35–52.
Friedman, M. (1953), ‘The methodology of positive economics’, pp. 3–43 in Essays
in Positive Economics, (Ed, Friedman, M.) University of Chicago Press,
Chicago.
Gruen, D. (2001), ‘Australia’s strong productivity growth: will it be sustained?’,
Reserve Bank of Australia Bulletin, February, 62-69.
13
Hancock, K. (2005), ‘Productivity growth in Australia 1964-65 to 2003-04’,
Australian Bulletin of Labour, 31(1), 28–32.
Krugman, P. (1998), "I Know What The Hedges Did Last Summer,”Fortune,
http://web.mit.edu/krugman/www/xfiles.html, visited 6/4/06.
Lakatos, I. (1970), ‘Falsification and the methodology of scientific research
programmes’, in Criticism and the Growth of Knowledge, (Eds, Lakatos,
I.M. & A.) Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
McCloskey, D. (1983), ‘The rhetoric of economics’, Journal of Economic
Literature, 21, 481–517.
McKenzie, M. (2005), ‘Microeconomic reform and productivity in Australia –boom
or blip’, Australian Conference of Economists, Melbourne.
Parham, D. (1999), ‘The new economy: A new look at Australia's productivity
performance’, Productivity Commission Staff Research Paper, Ausinfo,
Parham, D. (2000), ‘A more productive Australian economy’, 7(1), 3–16.
Parham, D. (2002), ‘Productivity growth in Australia: Are we enjoying a
miracle?’, Melbourne Institute and The Australian Conference, Towards
Opportunity and Prosperity, Melbourne.
Parham, D. (2005a), ‘Is Australia’s productivity surge over?’, Agenda, 12(3), 252–
66.
Parham, D. (2005), ‘Australia's 1990s productivity surge: a response to Keith
Hancock's challenge’, Australian Bulletin of Labour, 31(3), 295–303.
Popper, K. (1963) Conjectures and Refutations: The Growth of Scientific
Knowledge, Harper and Row, New York.
Quiggin, J. (2001), ‘The Australian productivity miracle: a sceptical view’,
Agenda, 8(4), 333–48.
Quiggin, J. (2005), The surge we didn't have, Australian Financial Review, 10
November.
Scargle, J. (2000), ‘Publication bias: The “file-drawer” problem in scientific
inference’, Journal of Scientific Exploration, 14(1), 91–106.
... Subsequent discussion has challenged this view, and the evidence now looks questionable: the rate of growth of multi-factor productivity has retreated in the subsequent years, in spite of the continuation of labour-market reforms. Critics suggest that even the growth in the earlier period is something of a statistical illusion (Hancock, 2005;Quiggin, 2006). Quiggin (2006) argues that it is at best a temporary blip, most plausibly related to temporary factors such as recovery from the recession and unsustainable increases in work intensity. ...
... Critics suggest that even the growth in the earlier period is something of a statistical illusion (Hancock, 2005;Quiggin, 2006). Quiggin (2006) argues that it is at best a temporary blip, most plausibly related to temporary factors such as recovery from the recession and unsustainable increases in work intensity. The debate on productivity extends into a discussion of the likely impact of current and prospective changes on productivity . ...
... Cross-country studies identified a very strong contribution of IT capital on economic growth in Australia during the 1990s -just behind the much-noted US and the largest among the OECD countries (Colecchia & Schreyer, 2002). However, sceptics view the productivity surge in Australia in the 1990s as just a statistical illusion (Dolman, 2009, Quiggin, 2006. Nevertheless, Australia's productivity performance has fallen short of expectations since the 2000s where the growth rates of multifactor productivity slipped down, on average, from 1.7% during the 1990s to 0.4% during the 2000s and to −1.3% in 2011 (ABS, 2012a). ...
Article
Full-text available
Nuclear power has been a topic of interest in Australia for many years, with proponents arguing that it could provide a reliable source of low-carbon energy to support the country's productivity and economic growth. However, Australia currently does not have any nuclear power plants in operation, primarily due to political, environmental, and public concerns. Proponents of nuclear power argue that it could help boost productivity in Australia by providing a stable and continuous source of electricity. Unlike renewable energy sources like wind and solar, nuclear power can generate electricity around the clock, regardless of weather conditions. This reliability could benefit industries that require constant power supply, such as manufacturing and mining, thus enhancing overall productivity. Moreover, nuclear power is a low-carbon energy source, which could help Australia reduce its greenhouse gas emissions and meet its climate change targets. By transitioning to nuclear power, Australia could decrease its reliance on coal-fired power plants, which are a major source of carbon emissions. This shift towards cleaner energy sources could also improve the country's environmental sustainability and productivity in the long run. Furthermore, nuclear power could create new job opportunities and stimulate economic growth. According to the Australian Nuclear Association, the nuclear industry could create up to 25,000 new jobs in Australia, ranging from construction and maintenance to engineering and research. This could help boost the country's economy and improve living standards. However, there are significant challenges and concerns associated with nuclear power in Australia. One major issue is the lack of public acceptance and political will to develop nuclear energy infrastructure. Many Australians have concerns about the safety and environmental impact of nuclear power, particularly considering high-profile nuclear accidents like the Fukushima disaster in Japan. Furthermore, building and operating nuclear power plants require significant investment and expertise, which may pose financial and logistical challenges for Australia. The country would need to invest in building new nuclear power plants, developing a skilled workforce, and managing nuclear waste, all of which could be costly and time-consuming. Additionally, the nuclear industry is heavily regulated, and Australia would need to develop a robust regulatory framework to ensure the safe and responsible use of nuclear power. In conclusion, while nuclear power has the potential to enhance productivity and reduce carbon emissions in Australia, there are significant hurdles that need to be addressed before it can become a viable energy option. Public acceptance, political will, and financial considerations will all play a crucial role in determining the future of nuclear power in Australia and its impact on productivity. Nevertheless, it is important for policymakers to consider all available energy options and weigh the potential benefits and risks of nuclear power in the context of Australia's energy needs and climate goals.
... 1. Apart from the adequacy of the economic modelling of production functions and labour productivity, the accuracy of "observed" values of variables relevant to the econometric estimation of these relationships requires special attention (e.g. Dolman, 2009;Quiggin, 2006). Differences in the way in which these variables are measured in different countries also complicates international comparisons. ...
Article
Purpose The purpose of this paper is to outline and examine existing economic findings about the effects of information and communication technology on economic productivity, welfare and social change. Design/methodology/approach Initially, existing findings about consequences of ICT for macro-level economic activity and productivity are outlined, and then this is correspondingly done for firms and for industries before a variety of welfare and social consequences of ICT are discussed. The industry-level discussion includes empirical data as well as analytical material. Findings Most studies indicate that ICT has significantly added to GDP and has been growth enhancing but these effects vary considerably between economies. The elasticity of aggregate production in relation to investment in ICT has risen with the passage of time. Reasons for this are suggested. The contribution of value added to the output of different industries varies substantially. At the micro-economic level, it is shown how ICT can increase technical and allocative efficiency, and how it can increase consumers’ surplus and producers’ surplus by lowering market transaction costs. Socioeconomic inequalities and concerns arising from the supply of e-commodities are discussed. Originality/value Provides a comprehensive but short overview of economic findings about the impact of ICT and brings attention to socioeconomic issues that have been overlooked or downplayed in that discussion. Includes new micro-economic analysis of the distributional impact of ICT and indicates areas requiring social policy intervention.
... 1. Apart from the adequacy of the economic modelling of production functions and labour productivity, the accuracy of 'observed' values of variables relevant to the econometric estimation of these relationships requires special attention (for example, Dolman, 2009; Quiggin, 2006). Differences in the way in which these variables are measured in different countries also complicates international comparisons. ...
... Even if a link existed between CEO pay and performance, this should not in itself create the recent divergence, unless it generated a substantial improvement in performance. The evidence is against such an improvement: Australian national productivity growth has been lower since the mid 1980s than in the 1960s and 1970s (eg Quiggin, 2006) and G7 nations' growth in GDP per hour was higher in the 1970s than from the 1980s onwards (OECD productivity database). ...
Article
Full-text available
This article develops a framework for understanding growth in executive remuneration and its increasing divergence from average earnings since a 1980s turning point, drawing on studies from a range of countries but with a special focus on Australian evidence. This framework emphasises the central roles played by company size, to which power is intrinsically related; the distinct, asymmetric nature of the ‘bargaining’ relationship in executive labour markets; and institutions that reflect seven rules. A corporation’s status depends in part on its chief executive officer’s status and pay. Chief executive officers’ ability to extract rents is influenced by their social capital. Chief executive officer pay is heavily influenced by relative pay deprivation. Institutions emerge to facilitate dual-asymmetric pattern bargaining. The incentive structure of executive pay adjusts over time to minimise downside risk, justify high growth and deflect shareholder concerns. Different norms shape pay in different segments, though cross-segment references will be made to justify increases. Finally, chief executive officers’ ability to ratchet pay upwards is contested, leading to cycles of asymmetries reflecting the social, political and economic climate and balance of power. © 2015, © Australian Labour and Employment Relations Association (ALERA), SAGE Publications Ltd, Los Angeles, London, New Delhi, Singapore and Washington DC.
... On the other hand, Quiggin (2001Quiggin ( , 2006 has questioned the 1990s 'productivity surge' in Australia, suggesting it as a 'statistical illusion'. Furthermore, Dolman (2009) has suggested that, even accepting measured estimates of the 1990s productivity surge, ICT played only a moderate role, being more of the nature of an enabler rather than the engine of growth. ...
Article
This paper revisits the so-called ‘ICT-productivity paradox’ from a long-run perspective by using annual Australian data for 1965–2013. It provides estimates of long-run and short-run elasticities of labour productivity with respect to ICT capital deepening, and explores the nature of long-run causality among productivity growth and ICT and non-ICT capital deepening. The estimates of long-run elasticities are derived by employing both time-series and panel data econometric techniques. The empirical results provide strong confirmatory evidence of the long-run impact of ICT capital deepening on labour productivity in Australia.
Article
The central theme of this article is the observation that improvements in information and communications technology (ICT) and in labour quality represent ‘embodied’ technological progress, as distinct from the ‘disembodied’ residual represented by multifactor productivity (MFP) growth. The seeming paradox of continued labour productivity growth combined with static MFP may be explained by the fact that technological progress is now mostly embodied in improved technology and better educated workers. The contribution from microeconomic reform has been, and is likely to remain, marginal.
Article
A prominent feature of recent Australian economic discourse is the assertion that there was a ‘productivity surge’ during the 1990s, resulting from the neoliberal microeconomic reforms inaugurated in the early 1980s. However, the evidence for the productivity surge is routinely overstated, thus undermining the rationale for many past and future microeconomic reforms. There is also substantial evidence that productivity growth can have perverse socioeconomic and/or environmental consequences. Nonetheless, many policymakers, economists and commentators remain preoccupied with increasing productivity growth. This article examines the Australian productivity debate and concludes that this is driven more by neoliberal norms than socioeconomic necessity. These are manifest in a disciplinary discourse that constructs productivity growth as a national imperative, unencumbered by negative social and environmental externalities.
Article
A plutonomy is an economy 'powered by the wealthy' and characterised by growing disparities between the top 1 % of society and the rest. Much of the recent increase in inequality in English-speaking Western societies has been due to very strong growth in incomes at the top. We consider the resurgence of the '1 %'-that elite group at the top 1 % of the income or wealth tree, featuring CEOs, key senior executives and top financier-speculators, often engaged in a project of capitalist globalization. We examine data, both internationally and from Australia, on their changing fortunes, as indicated by growing income and wealth shares (particularly amongst the even smaller group of the top 0.1 %), growth in executive remuneration and the profit share, and increasing concentration of ownership amongst finance capital. Recent developments have been in stark contrast to the post-war settlement that saw these indicators of inequality stable or slowly decreasing as the working class made gradual gains. We consider the links between plutonomies and the practice and ideologies of financialisation and neoliberalism. We also refer to the implications of the emergence of plutonomy, including political responses and resistance. © 2014 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg. All rights are reserved.
Article
Full-text available
The construction of national accounts by Colin Clark and others was a major contribution to, and assisted the documentation of, the prosperity of the second half of the 20th century. In the 21st century, the crucial problem is to account for the value of information. Information is, naturally a public good, even though it is costly to produce. Moreover, the distinctions central to the 20th century economy, such as those between primary, secondary and tertiary industry, and between households and the market economy are increasingly irrelevant. These changes bring new policy challenges and, with them, the need for new systems of national accounting.
Article
Full-text available
Market sector productivity — the output produced per hour worked — grew at an annual rate of 3.2 per cent during the five years to 1998-99, which was the fastest rate on record. In the five years to 2003-04, productivity growth eased to 2.2 per cent per year, which is around the average rate over the past four decades. On balance, business cycle fluctuations, international developments, investment in physical and human capital (including information and communication technology), and the movement of labour across industries did not cause this easing in productivity growth. Rather, these trends are apparent within a number of industries: mining, construction, utilities, wholesale trade, communications and finance and insurance. A closer inspection of these industries suggests that, with the exception of mining, the recent trends at least partly reflect an easing of growth rates towards their historical averages after the unusual productivity surge of the late 1990s. Tunny, the authors' colleagues in the Macro Dynamics Unit and participants at a number of internal Treasury presentations. The views in this article are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Australian Treasury.
Article
Publication bias arises whenever the probability that a study is published depends on the statistical significance of its results. This bias, often called the file-drawer effect since the unpublished results are imagined to be tucked away in researchers' file cabinets, is potentially a severe impediment to combining the statistical results of studies collected from the literature. With almost any reasonable quantitative model for publication bias, only a small number of studies lost in the file-drawer will produce a significant bias. This result contradicts the well known Fail Safe File Drawer (FSFD) method for setting limits on the potential harm of publication bias, widely used in social, medical and psychic research. This method incorrectly treats the file drawer as unbiased, and almost always miss-estimates the seriousness of publication bias. A large body of not only psychic research, but medical and social science studies, has mistakenly relied on this method to validate claimed discoveries. Statistical combination can be trusted only if it is known with certainty that all studies that have been carried out are included. Such certainty is virtually impossible to achieve in literature surveys.
Article
Increased aggregate productivity growth in the 1990s has been taken to indicate support for the success of microeconomic reform policy in Australia. The Productivity Commission / Australian Bureau of Statistics key estimates of peak to peak market sector multifactor productivity growth since the mid 1960s are examined in this paper. The peak to peak market sector measures are compared with five year averages. Series are reconstructed for the whole economy, and simple regression estimates obtained. The findings lend support to a spike in the measure in the 1990s rather than sustained increase and highlight the sensitivity of the estimates to cyclical and unknown factors.
Article
ustralia's productivity growth surged in the 1990s. Growth in both labour productivity (output per hour of labour input) and multifactor productivity (output per combined unit of labour and capital) lifted to record highs between 1993-94 and 1998-99 (Australian Bureau of Statistics, 2004). However, there have been signs that Australia's productivity growth has since slowed. The average rate of productivity growth is down markedly — although it still falls into line with the historical average. With declines in recent quarterly productivity estimates, some commentators have declared that Australia's productivity surge is now confirmed as over. That productivity growth would come off its record highs could well be expected. But does the evidence now available signal that Australia's productivity growth has 'permanently' dropped to unremarkable rates, somewhere around the long-term historical average or even below? The issue matters. A substantial and long-lasting drop in productivity growth would mean less growth in a major foundation for improvement in Australian living standards. From a policy point of view, it is now generally accepted that a series of policy reforms played an important role in driving and enabling the lift in productivity performance in the 1990s. A transitory surge would imply that the productivity payoff from policy reforms — whilst significant — has come as a 'step-up in levels' effect, rather than as a long-term increase in the rate of growth. Such a view has led some commentators to call for further policy reforms in order to reinvigorate productivity growth. This article presents a preliminary and partial examination of the topography of the productivity slowdown and the factors that have contributed to it. The objective is to determine whether or not Australia's experience of generally stronger productivity growth has drawn to a close.