ArticlePDF Available

Abstract and Figures

Using a new set of micro evidence from an original survey of 28 transition countries, we show that democracy increases citizens' support for the market by guaranteeing income redistribution to inequality-averse agents. Our identification strategy relies on the restriction of the sample to inhabitants of open borders between formerly integrated countries, where people face the same level of market development and economic inequality, as well as the same historically inherited politico-economic culture. Democratic rights increase popular support for the market. This is true, in particular, of inequality-averse agents, provided that they trust political institutions. Our findings suggest that one solution to the recent electoral backlash of reformist parties in the former socialist block lies in a deepening of democracy.
Content may be subject to copyright.
WORKING PAPER N° 2008 - 39
How populist democracy promotes market liberalization
Pauline Grosjean
Claudia Senik
JEL Codes: D63, H1, H53, I38, O1, P26
Keywords: Democracy, income inequality, redistribution,
market liberalization, trust
PARIS-JOURDAN SCIENCES ECONOMIQUES
LABORATOIRE D’ECONOMIE APPLIQUÉE - INRA
48, BD JOURDAN E.N.S. 75014 PARIS
TÉL. : 33(0) 1 43 13 63 00 FAX : 33 (0) 1 43 13 63 10
www.pse.ens.fr
CENTRE NATIONAL DE LA RECHERCHE SCIENTIFIQUE ÉCOLE DES HAUTES ÉTUDES EN SCIENCES SOCIALES
ÉCOLE NATIONALE DES PONTS ET CHAUSSÉES ÉCOLE NORMALE SUPÉRIEURE
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
1
How Populist Democracy Promotes Market Liberalization
Pauline Grosjean (University of California at Berkeley) and Claudia Senik (Paris School of Economics)
July 22, 2008
Abstract
Using a new set of micro evidence from an original survey of 28 transition countries, we show that
democracy increases citizens’ support for the market by guaranteeing income redistribution to inequality-
averse agents. Our identification strategy relies on the restriction of the sample to inhabitants of open
borders between formerly integrated countries, where people face the same level of market development
and economic inequality, as well as the same historically inherited politico-economic culture. Democratic
rights increase popular support for the market. This is true, in particular, of inequality-averse agents,
provided that they trust political institutions. Our findings suggest that one solution to the recent electoral
backlash of reformist parties in the former socialist block lies in a deepening of democracy.
JEL codes: D63, H1, H53, I38, O1, P26.
Keywords: Democracy, income inequality, redistribution, market liberalization, trust.
We thank participants in the UC Berkeley development lunch, the UC Berkeley Positive Political
seminar, the Midwest Political Science Association Annual National Conference. We are grateful to
Bryan Graham, Ethan Ligon, Daniel O’Neill, Robert Powell, Gerard Roland and Hiroki Takeuchi for
helpful comments and suggestions. All errors are ours. This research has benefited from the support of the
Institut Universitaire de France, the CEPREMAP and the Ciriacy-Wantrup Foundation.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
2
1. Introduction
Is democracy an obstacle to development, market liberalization and growth, or does it eventually appear
as a necessary condition to these evolutions? An important body of economic literature, largely inspired
by the example of China and other South-East Asian countries, claims that postponing political
liberalization gives more leeway to reformers when reform measures potentially hurt important groups of
the population (Aslund, Boone and Johnson, 2001; Dewatripont and Roland, 1992; Roland, 2001; Roland
and Verdier 2003). The belief that concentrating power in the hands of one party, forbidding the
expression of political opposition, is a more efficient way to conduct a development strategy is sometimes
referred as the Lee’s hypotheses, from the name of Singapore’s leader Lee Kuan Yew (Sen 1999). This
idea is also present in the “public choice” theory of the relationship between democracy and capitalism.
According to Dan Usher (1981), a disciple of Hayek, universal suffrage and majority rule endanger the
capitalist system, for the majority may vote to expropriate the rich minority.
By contrast, the idea that democracy can be a fertile ground for market liberalization is more rarely found.
An important channel through which democracy is supposed to help market development is via its
expected effects on income redistribution. More precisely, the contestability of the ruling party, put in
competition with other organized political groups, appears as the necessary condition for a party to
credibly commit to the provision of social insurance and income redistribution1. This is because political
1 For evidence that democracy actually improves distributional outcomes, see Rodrik (1999 and 2000).
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
3
competition creates the possibility that the ruling party loses his constituency in case he does not live up
to his promises. Acemoglu and Robinson (2000, 2002), Acemoglu, Bautista, Querubin and Robinson
(2007a) and Robinson (2006) have developed the idea that when economic development unlashes income
inequality, which itself triggers backlash against reforms, extending democratic rights appears as a
credible promise of future income redistribution. Absent such institutional safeguards, rising inequality, in
itself, would generate opposition to further market reform and may even impose a threat to the regime
(Alesina and Perotti 1996).
In the case of Latin America, for example, where economic liberalization has not been accompanied by
adequate social safety nets, the ensuing economic insecurity has been identified as one major cause of the
recent reform backlash (Rodrik 2000). This view also seems relevant to the experience of transition
countries. The rise in economic inequality that has been triggered by the transition from a planned to a
market economy is well-documented. Fleming and Micklewright (2000), Milanovic (1998, 1999) and
Keane and Prasad (2000), among other papers, have described how market forces have driven wage
differentiation and the rising share of income from self-employment and property. Rising inequality in
turn, has been shown to generate popular opposition to market reforms (Denisova, Eller, Frye and
Zhuravskaya, 2008; Desai and Olofsgard, 2006; Grosfeld and Senik, 2008; Krastev, 2007). The
denunciation of widespread corruption, of confiscation of power by the elite, and of lack of transparency
in the distribution of the aggregate gains from transition, has undermined popular adhesion to the process
of reforms and brought back to power former communist candidates or radically conservative anti-
European parties (Krastev 2007; Rupnik 2007). It thus seems that in transition countries, restoring
popular support to the strategy of development based on market liberalization now implies increasing
political transparency and the commitment of the government to keep income differentiation under
control.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
4
However, this supposes that democracy performs efficiently its instrumental role in keeping governments
responsible and accountable to the majority (Sen 1999), and is not subverted by the wealthy and
politically powerful (Glaeser, Scheinkman and Shleifer 2003). In a recent paper, Acemoglu, Ticchi and
Vindingli (2007b) present a model of democratic capture, where the rich, in young democracies, may
promote an inefficient state structure in order to limit income redistribution. Hence, not only does the
formal transition to democracy matter, but also the degree of capture of democratic institutions by the
elite and the bureaucracy, and more generally the degree of effectiveness and reliability of the procedures
associated with formal rights. This qualitative element can be captured by the trust that the majority of
people place in democratic institutions. Political trust has indeed been described as the link between
citizens and the institutions that represent them (Bianco, 1994). In sum, the subjective perception of the
quality of democracy depends on popular trust in the country’s institutions as much as on formal rights.
This is particularly true in new democracies, such as those of the former socialist bloc (Mishler and Rose
1997).
Accordingly, the present paper investigates the impact of democratic rights on citizens’ support for the
market, assuming that the relation is mediated by the degree of political trust that citizens place in
political institutions. It hinges on a new set of micro evidence from an original survey of 28 transition
economies, the Life in Transition Survey, which was implemented in 2006 (see EBRD, 2007a). In a
companion paper, Grosjean and Senik (2007) proposed a new identification strategy based on frontier-
zones, and found that democracy reinforces individuals’ belief in the market as a superior form of
economic system. This paper starts from this finding and proposes a mechanism explaining this
relationship.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
5
Recent empirical work points to a reinforcing effect of political liberalization on economic liberalization
at the macroeconomic level (Giavazzi and Tabellini 2005). Studies related to Central and Eastern Europe,
with the exception of Finifter and Mickiewicz (1992), find that democracy facilitates economic
liberalization (Fidrmuc, 2003; Hayo, 2004). However, demonstrating empirical relations of causality
between democracy and market liberalization is a daunting task (Persson and Tabellini, 2007). This is
because of the identification problem, which is contained in the very idea of the modernization theory
(Lipset 1959) that the same development dynamics favor both democracy and market development.
Subjective support to the market may be due both to the degree of democracy and to the degree of market
development itself, which are difficult to disentangle as they are likely to develop at a parallel pace.
Moreover, these subjective political attitudes altogether are likely to be influenced by common cultural
and historical factors which are difficult to capture. Hence, assessing the direction of causality between
the advancement of economic freedom and the degree of political freedom appears to be an almost
impossible exercise in the absence of a valid exogenous instrument. Example of such instruments are
legal origins (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer and Vishny, 1999) or colonial origins (Acemoglu,
Johnson and Robinson, 2001).
In order to overcome these difficulties, we propose an identification strategy based on the specificities of
frontier-zones. Our main assumption is that people who live in an integrated frontier-zone (in terms of
labor and product mobility) share the same experience of the market and, often, the same historically
inherited “cultural attitudes” towards the market and democracy, on both sides of the frontier. The
assumption that frontier-zones are culturally and economically highly integrated is particularly plausible
for the often artificial frontiers of the former USSR and for some formerly integrated regions such as the
Ottoman Empire or the Austro-Hungarian Empire. This allows us to identify the pure influence of
different levels of democracy across nations, avoiding the simultaneity and omitted variable bias.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
6
Our main focus is on the effect of a three way interaction between democracy, political trust and the
demand for income redistribution by the state. We find a positive and significant impact of this triple
interaction on the support for market liberalization. The main result of this paper is that inequality-averse
individuals are more supportive of the market when they live in more democratic states and trust
democratic institutions (even though the direct effect of inequality aversion is to reduce support to the
market).
This mechanism provides a possible explanation of the link between democracy and support for the
market that was identified by Grosjean and Senik (2007) in a companion paper, or by Giavazzi and
Tabellini (2005). Our interpretation is also consistent with the optimal sequencing of reforms as described
by Dewatripont and Roland (1995). The authors show that implementing a first reform that benefits a
majority with small gains increases the ex ante acceptability of a second reform that benefits a minority
with large gains. Reinterpreting the first reform as democracy and the second as market reform, our
results confirm this prediction. Our interpretation is also consistent with theoretical considerations of a
complementarity between democracy and the market (Lindblom 1995).
This paper suggests that democratic governance can play an instrumental role in overcoming
redistributive conflicts that could block the construction of a viable market economy. The same is true of
income redistribution. The first order negative effect of redistributive policies on growth (Persson and
Tabellini 1994; Alesina and Rodrik 1994) must be weighted by the further acceptance of market reforms.
2. Data
Our study hinges on the Life in Transition Survey (LITS), a survey conducted by the European Bank for
Reconstruction and Development and the World Bank in 2006, in 28 post-transition countries and
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
7
Turkey2. Respondents to the survey were drawn randomly, using a two stage sampling method, with
census enumeration areas as Primary Sampling Units (PSUs), and households as secondary sampling
units. The survey includes 1000 observations per country, making a total of 29000 observations.
Descriptive statistics are presented in Appendix.
Frontier zones
The Life in Transition survey is based on PSUs3, each containing 20 observations (surveyed persons). We
used the geographical map of the survey to identify groups of PSUs that are located on both sides and in
the immediate vicinity of a political frontier. We identified 36 valid frontier-zones that contain between
40 and 460 observations, concentrated in 2 (Slovak Republic-Ukraine) to 24 (Croatia-Slovenia) PSUs.
Because the validity of our identification strategy relies on the intensity of market integration on either
side of borders, we excluded frontiers that are impaired by geographical obstacles or restricted because of
political tensions and disputed territories. We thus excluded the frontiers between Georgia and Russia,
Armenia and Azerbaijan, Moldova and Ukraine, as well as all Uzbek borders. We verified that the degree
of market development is more similar between two adjacent frontier-zones than it is on average between
two adjacent countries. We constructed an index of market development that reflects the share in regional
2 Turkmenistan was not included in the survey, neither was Kosovo. We exclude Turkey from our sample
because its borders with the other countries were closed during the whole socialist period, which is in
contradiction with our identification assumption.
3 PSUs were selected randomly, with probability proportional to size.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
8
employment of small and medium sized, private and newly created enterprises (since 1989). On average,
the correlation between indices of industrial market development is twice as high between adjacent
frontier-zones as it is between adjacent countries. If one restricts the analysis to subsets of formerly more
integrated countries, the proximity between adjacent frontier-zones appears even higher. For instance, in
Central Asia, the correlation between two adjacent frontier-zones is 0.78 against 0.34 in two adjacent
countries. We also checked that the structure of industrial employment in terms of occupation and
industry is identical on either side of the borders, whereas this is not true of entire adjacent countries (for
more details see Grosjean and Senik 2007).
Support for the market and demand for income redistribution
Support for the market is proxied by the probability of choosing the first item of the following survey
question:
Which of the following statements do you agree with most?
- A market economy is preferable to any other form of economic system
- Under some circumstances, a planned economy may be preferable to a market economy
- For people like me, it does not matter whether the economic system is organized as a market
economy or as a planned economy
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
9
Support for the market is rather low in the region. Averaging across countries4 of the sample, support for
the market as defined above reaches 43% (see Denisova, Eller, Frye and Zhuravskaya 2008, for possible
explanations). Descriptive statistics based on our data confirm the negative association between income
inequality and support for the market at the country level (see figure 1).
We measure the demand for redistribution using the following question:
Do you think the state should be involved in reducing the gap between the rich and the poor?
Scale: not involved at all/let the market play =1; Somewhat/moderately involved =2; strongly involved=3
There is overwhelming support in favor of state intervention across the region. On average, 5% of
respondents favor no intervention, 26% support a moderate intervention and 69% desire a strong
intervention of the state to reduce income gaps. Support for the market is particularly low among those
who favor more state intervention, as can be seen in Figure 2. People are also particularly favorable to
strong state intervention in countries where inequalities are large, as can be seen in Figure 3. For example
in the FYR Macedonia, one of the most unequal countries of the region, with a Gini coefficient of 39 in
2003 (World Development Indicators), the market is thought to be “preferable to any other form of
economic system” by only 34% of respondents, and 85% of respondents are in favor of the state being
“strongly” involved in the reduction of inequalities. By contrast, in adjacent Serbia, where inequality is
lower (the Gini coefficient in 2003 was 30), 45% of respondents support the market and “only” 80% are
favorable to a strong state intervention to reduce income gaps.
4 In this section, averages correspond to the arithmetic sums of country averages.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
10
Indices of Democracy and Trust
In order to build a score of democracy, we mainly rely on the Freedom House Nations in Transit
democracy index (Freedom House, 2006a), which is constructed as an average of measures of the
electoral process, civil society, independent media, independence of the judicial system, and corruption. It
takes values from 1 to 7, with 1 representing the highest level of democratic progress and 7 the lowest.
(We have recoded it in order to present the score of democracy in an ascending order). This index of
democracy is the best suited for our purpose for several reasons. Firstly, it is the most comprehensive and
detailed indicator for the transition region. In particular, it is the only index that provides a separate score
for Serbia and Montenegro; it allows discriminating among countries of our sample better than other
indicators, such as Polity IV (CIDCM 2006). Secondly, it is more focused on democratic rights than many
other indices. For example, the Freedom in the World (Freedom House 2006b) indicator takes into
account such things as freedom of associational rights, and personal autonomy, which do not directly
assess the ability of the regime to satisfy the demand for redistribution of agents; while the Bertelsmann
Transformation Index (BTI) takes into account the development of the market economy, hence does not
fit our identification strategy.
Nevertheless, an important drawback of all these indicators is that they rely principally on expert ratings.
They may not reflect adequately the average opinion of citizens about the quality of democratic
institutions, in particular in young political regimes of the CIS. The quality of formal rights may not
matter without the actual feeling of empowerment and control by the majority over political institutions.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
11
We hence exploit, in addition to standard democracy scores, a measure of individuals’ trust in institutions
that are characteristics of a functioning democracy, using responses to the following question5:
To what extent do you trust the following institutions?
Scale: Complete distrust=1, Some distrust=2, Neither trust nor distrust=3, Some trust=4, Complete
trust=5, Difficult to say=6
- The government/cabinet of ministers
- The parliament
- Courts
- Political parties6
5 The question explores trust in a larger number of institutions, such as religious institutions, armed
forces, the police, foreign investors, etc. However, we only select those institutions that reflect a
functioning democracy.
6 The question explores trust in a larger number of institutions. The survey question also included other
political institutions, such as religious institutions, foreign investors, the presidency, the army or the
police. We only selected those institutions that reflect a functioning democracy, excluding the army and
the police, which are not directly related to a democratic regime, and not at all related to the ability of
such regimes to conduct redistributive policies. We also excluded the presidency because of the possible
ambiguity between the presidential institution and the man who takes up the position. Actually, because
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
12
We construct an index that takes value 1 if the respondent either has “some trust’ or ‘complete trust in any
of the above item. Our trust score is then the sum of these individual indices. It takes an average value of
1.21.
This measure of trust in institutions tends to be higher in countries of the CIS and, particularly in Central
Asia, although these countries fare rather badly in terms of political rights. It reaches a maximal value of
2.93 in Tajikistan; and a minimum value of 0.59 in Croatia. However, national differences are not central
to our identification strategy, which relies on the attitudes of individuals located in frontier-zones, inside
historically integrated cultural zones. Focusing on pairs of adjacent countries, the index of trust seems to
reflect more accurately the quality of institutions: it is higher in Slovenia (1.18), the Slovak Republic
(1.12) and Hungary (1.09) compared with their neighbors; Among Central Asian countries, Tajikistan has
made noticeable progress in terms of political accountability, as compared with its neighbors (EBRD
2007b)7.
Interacting the index of institutional trust and the Freedom House Nations in Transit (Freedom House
2006a) index of democracy, we intend to capture not only the formal quality of institutions, but also
people’s perception of their empowerment, which is what ultimately determines their belief in the
government’s ability to ensure redistributive justice.
of this confusion, the question was censored in Belarus. In addition, this would have raised comparability
problems.
7 Although Tajikistan ranks below Kyrgyzstan in the Freedom House indicator, the country has known
none of the political agitation that took place in Kyrgyzstan or Uzbekistan in the last few years.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
13
3. Empirical Strategy
The purpose of this paper is to investigate the link between democracy and the subjective support for
market development. We test the conjecture that there is a complementarity between popular support for
market development and the ability of a democratic system to correct the negative outcomes of the
market, ability that must be sanctioned by popular trust. There are three elements to this conjecture.
Firstly, it supposes that income inequality arises as a negative outcome of market development
(Milanovic 1999), and, in turn, undermines popular support for further market liberalization (Grosfeld and
Senik 2008). Secondly, it relies on the hypothesis that a democratic government provides a better
commitment to redistribution than an autocratic government (cf. Acemoglu and Robinson 2002). Thirdly,
it implies that not only formal rights matter but also the trust in the ability of democratic institutions to
channel the demands of the majority. We are thus specifically interested in the effect of a three way
interaction between democracy, political trust and attitudes towards the role of the state in reducing
inequalities. Finding a positive and significant impact of this interaction on the support for market
liberalization would show that when people trust that the government can correct the inequality generated
by market development, their subjective support for the market is enhanced.
We would thus like to estimate the following relation:
Support for market ij = a0 + a1 Democracy j + a2 Trustij + a3 Preferences for Redistributionij + a4
Democracyj*Trustij* Preferences for Redistributionij + a5 Xij + a6Cj + ui (1)
where pair-wise interactions between the three variables of interests are controlled for; Democracyj
corresponds to the level of democracy in country j, Trustij corresponds to the level of political trust of
individual i in country j, Attitudes to Inequalitiesij corresponds to individual preferences for redistribution
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
14
of respondent i in country j, Xijk stands for the socio-demographic characteristics of respondent i in
country j, Cj is a vector of country dummies and ui the error term.
We are particularly interested in the sign and significance of the coefficient of the above three way
interaction. Our hypothesis is that: a4 >0.
However, as detailed in the next paragraph, estimating equation (1) would run into serious identification
problems.
Empirical challenges: endogeneity and omitted variable biases
The identification of the relation sketched in equation (1) faces two major empirical challenges. Firstly,
omitted cultural factors are likely to be essential determinants not only of attitudes towards the market,
but also of attitudes towards inequality, as well as of political trust8. Second, all the variables under
consideration (political trust, subjective support for the market, as well as the current level of economic
inequality and consequently people’s attitudes to inequality) are certainly endogenous to the level of
market development itself.
In order to overcome this endogeneity bias, we need to find individuals, who, in an exogenous way, face
the same level of market development, and thus the same level of economic inequalities, but live under
8 Two main theories explain the origin of political trust (Mishler and Rose 1997). Cultural theories
consider that trust is mainly exogenous, in that it is deeply rooted in beliefs and cultural norms and is
generated though early-life socialization (Putnam 1993). By contrast, institutional theories consider that
political trust is endogenous to the performance of institutions.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
15
different democratic institutions, in terms of both formal and effective rights. In order to overcome the
cultural bias, we need to restrict our sample to people who also share a common cultural heritage. In other
words, the relation that we must consider is not equation 1 but the following system of equations:
Support for the Market ij = a0 + a1 Democracy j + a2 Trustij + a3 Preference for Redistributionij + a4
Democracyj* Trustij* Preference for Redistributionij + a6 Degree of Market Development j + a7 Cultural
Factors j +a8 Xij + a9Cj + ui (2.1)
Trustij= b0 +b1 Degree of Market Development j + b2 Cultural Factors j +b3 Xij + b4Cj + vi (2.2)
Preference for Redistributionij = c0 + c1 Degree of Market Development j + c2 Cultural Factors j +c3 Xij +
c4Cj + wi (2.3)
where Xij stands for the socio-demographic characteristics of respondent i in country j, Cj is a vector of
country dummies, ui, vi and wi are the error term and pair-wise interactions between the three variables of
interest are controlled for in equation (2.1).
Identification strategy
The idea is to match observations in frontier-zones. We assume that spatial economic integration across
open political borders and labor mobility imply that inhabitants of border zones share the same experience
of the market even when they live in different countries with different political institutions. We refer the
reader to Grosjean and Senik (2007) for a discussion of this assumption and empirical evidence. In a
nutshell, the arguments are the following: (i) the high level of inter-regional trade in frontier zones, (ii)
frequent migration flows across borders, (iii) the specific historical integration of the countries of the
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
16
former USSR. Clearly, the validity of the assumption relies on the level of market integration across the
borders of the surveyed countries. As stressed in Section 2, we only retain open borders.
The assumption of market integration at frontier-zones eliminates the risk that the support for market
liberalization that is measured reflects the actual market development and is contaminated by the level of
economic inequality. What about “cultural” omitted variables? We hinge on the idea that citizens of
countries that have belonged to formerly highly integrated zones (the USSR, the Ottoman empire, the
Austro-Hungarian empire, etc.) share a common culture, i.e. common inherited general attitudes towards
the market and democracy (cf. Alesina and Fuchs-Schundeln 2007). Beyond this remark, we rely on the
fact that current frontiers of many transition countries, especially countries of the Commonwealth of
Independent States (CIS), are more or less artificial divisions of formerly integrated jurisdictions, whose
citizens have developed common attitudes concerning both market development and political freedom.
Again, we refer to Grosjean and Senik (2007) for an extensive discussion of these assumptions.
As explained in section 2, using the LITS survey, we identify frontier-zones as groups of Primary Sample
Units (PSUs) that are quasi-adjacent and located on both sides of a frontier (less than 30 km from each
other). In order to measure the degree of democratization of a country, we use the democracy score
established by the Freedom House Nations in Transit survey (Freedom House, 2006a).
Our test therefore consists, for observations at frontier-zones between two countries, of regressing
individual support for the market on an interaction between the index of democratization, political trust
and demand for redistribution by the state, controlling for frontier-zone dummies and other socio-
demographic characteristics of respondents.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
17
Assuming that the level of market development and cultural factors are constant inside a given frontier-
zone, these two terms drop out of each equation of system (2), which can be rewritten as:
Support for Market ijk = a0 + a1 Democracy j + a2 Trust ijk + a3 Preferences for Redistributionijk + a4
Democracyj* Trustijk* Preferences for Redistribution ijk + a5 X ijk + + a6 Zk + ui (3)
where pair-wise interactions between the three variables of interest are controlled for; Democracyj
corresponds to the democracy score of country j, Trustijk is the level of political trust of individual i in
frontier-zone k of country j, Attitudes to Inequalitiesijk measures individual preferences for redistribution
of respondent i in frontier-zone k of country j, Xijk stands for the socio-demographic characteristics of
respondent i, Zk is a vector of frontier-zone dummies and ui is the error term.
Estimating equation (3) is thus a direct test of our main hypothesis (a4 >0), on the sub sample of frontier-
zones.
We check that pair-wise relations between demand for redistribution, democracy, trust and support for the
market are signed in the way we hypothesized. As a robustness test, we also verify that we do not obtain
the same result with another left-hand-side variable instead of support for the market. As possible
candidates, we consider the subjective support to alternative economic policies, such as state ownership of
large enterprises, price regulation or guarantee of employment by the state.
4. Results
We estimate equation (3) with a linear probability model. Despite some drawbacks of linear probability
models to estimate limited dependent variables, namely because they may give negative or higher than
unity predicted values, they make the estimation and analysis of interaction terms much more tractable
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
18
than non linear models (Ai and Norton 2003) 9. We checked that it makes little difference to estimate
equation (3) using a linear probability model or a logistic regression model10. This is in line with the
results of Ferrer-i-Carbonell and Frijters (2004) or Pohlman and Leitner (2003).
Table 1 presents the regression of support for the market on scores of democratization, political trust and
individual support for income redistribution for the sub-sample of respondents living in open frontier-
zones, controlling for frontier-zone dummies, and clustering at the frontier zone level (equation (3)).
Column (1) displays Grosjean and Senik (2007)’s earlier result that the direct effect of democratic rights
is to enhance support for the market, so that political liberalization may “cause” economic liberalization
(as in Giavazzi and Tabellini 2005). The quantitative effect is quite large: an increase in one standard
deviation of the Freedom House indicator increases the probability of supporting the market over any
9 In non linear models, in contrast to linear models, the interaction effect is different from the marginal
effect of the interaction term. Moreover, it is conditional on the independent variables, unlike in linear
models (Ai and Norton 2003).
10 Both models perform similarly in terms of overall goodness of fit and significance of individual
independent variables. Predicted values of the dependent variable by the two models are highly correlated
(correlation coefficient of 0.9964). One of the main drawbacks of the linear probability model is that it
may predict values below 0 or higher than 1. However, this is not an important issue in the linear
estimation of equation (3), where only four negative values and three values higher than 1 are predicted.
Figure 4 in the Appendix plots the predicted values for the logistic regression and OLS. Predicted means
of the dependent variable are reported in Table 1.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
19
other form of economic system by 7.6 percentage points (1.58*0.048). Columns (2), (3) and (6) show that
more democratic institutions and higher trust increase individuals’ support to the market. However, the
effect of political trust alone is hardly significant and quantitatively marginal: an increase in one standard
deviation of our trust index increases the probability of supporting the market by just over 1 percentage
point (column 2).
Column (3) shows that respondents who support income redistribution by the state are precisely those
who oppose the market: a one standard deviation increase in the demand for redistribution decreases the
probability of supporting the market by 4 percentage points. Columns (4) and (5) show that trust and
democracy alone are not enough to turn inequality-averse individuals in favor of the market. However, as
shown in column (7), among those agents who strongly favor income redistribution by the state and who
would thus otherwise oppose the market, those who live in a more democratic state and who trust their
political institutions, favor the market more. Here again, the effect is quite large: an increase in one
standard deviation of the interaction between the Freedom House indicator, political trust and the demand
for redistribution increases the probability of supporting a market economy by 7.6 percentage points
(0.005*15.15).
Table 1 also displays the effect of other covariates on support for the market. We distinguish three income
categories (the richest, middle and poorest quintiles inside each country), six educational levels, nine
occupational categories and employment status (self-employed versus employees). We also control for
age, age squared and residence in an urban, metropolitan or rural area. The only significant effects are
those of income, education, employment status and gender. Self-employed workers, male respondents and
those who hold a university degree tend to be more supportive of the market. Other levels of education
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
20
have no significant impact. The poorest third of respondents clearly oppose the market and the effect is
unaffected by whether preferences for redistribution are controlled for or not.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
21
Table 1: Democracy and Trust increases the Support for the Market of Inequality Averse Agents
Dependent variable Support for the Market
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)
Democracy 0.048*** 0.073** 0.049*** 0.084**
[0.012] [0.029] [0.014] [0.032]
Trust 0.010* 0.017* 0.006 0.013
[0.006] [0.008] [0.015] [0.016]
-0.069*** -0.041 -0.064*** -0.043 State intervention against
inequalities [0.018] [0.048] [0.018] [0.046]
-0.009 -0.012 Democracy*State intervention
against inequalities [0.011] [0.011]
-0.017** -0.022*** Trust*State intervervention
against inequalities [0.009] [0.008]
Democracy*Trust 0.001 -0.012*
[0.004] [0.006]
0.005** Democracy*Trust*State
intervention against
inequalities [0.002]
Poor -0.077*** -0.075*** -0.074*** -0.076*** -0.073*** -0.076*** -0.074***
[0.019] [0.019] [0.019] [0.019] [0.019] [0.019] [0.019]
Rich 0.011 0.006 0.003 0.009 0.004 0.012 0.008
[0.019] [0.019] [0.019] [0.019] [0.019] [0.020] [0.020]
Age -0.001 -0.001 0 -0.001 0 -0.001 -0.001
[0.003] [0.003] [0.003] [0.003] [0.002] [0.003] [0.002]
Male 0.045*** 0.050*** 0.048*** 0.042*** 0.048*** 0.045*** 0.043***
[0.011] [0.012] [0.011] [0.009] [0.011] [0.010] [0.009]
Compulsory education -0.04 -0.032 -0.036 -0.042* -0.034 -0.039 -0.039
[0.024] [0.024] [0.024] [0.024] [0.024] [0.025] [0.025]
Secondary education 0.007 0.022 0.014 0.002 0.018 0.01 0.006
[0.030] [0.032] [0.031] [0.029] [0.031] [0.030] [0.029]
Professional education 0.019 0.023 0.018 0.017 0.021 0.022 0.022
[0.028] [0.027] [0.027] [0.027] [0.026] [0.027] [0.026]
University degree 0.070** 0.078** 0.069** 0.063** 0.071** 0.072** 0.066**
[0.030] [0.029] [0.030] [0.029] [0.029] [0.029] [0.028]
Post graduate degree -0.036 -0.022 -0.023 -0.032 -0.019 -0.032 -0.026
[0.072] [0.073] [0.074] [0.072] [0.074] [0.071] [0.071]
Unemployed -0.008 -0.002 -0.003 -0.007 0.001 -0.006 -0.005
[0.025] [0.024] [0.025] [0.026] [0.024] [0.025] [0.025]
Self-employed 0.079*** 0.088*** 0.084*** 0.071*** 0.081*** 0.076*** 0.070***
[0.026] [0.027] [0.027] [0.025] [0.027] [0.026] [0.025]
White collar employee 0.044 0.045 0.037 0.038 0.04 0.046 0.04
[0.032] [0.031] [0.031] [0.032] [0.030] [0.032] [0.031]
Blue collar employee -0.005 -0.008 -0.01 -0.006 -0.007 -0.003 -0.005
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
22
[0.028] [0.028] [0.028] [0.028] [0.028] [0.028] [0.029]
Service sector employee 0.035 0.045 0.044 0.037 0.048 0.038 0.039
[0.029] [0.029] [0.029] [0.029] [0.028] [0.029] [0.028]
Farmer or farm worker 0.113* 0.118* 0.118** 0.116* 0.123** 0.116* 0.119*
[0.065] [0.061] [0.058] [0.062] [0.058] [0.065] [0.061]
Pensioner 0.011 0.016 0.017 0.012 0.018 0.011 0.013
[0.028] [0.027] [0.028] [0.028] [0.027] [0.027] [0.027]
Student 0.009 0.004 0.001 0.002 0 0.009 0
[0.052] [0.051] [0.050] [0.050] [0.050] [0.052] [0.051]
Housewife 0.033 0.041 0.038 0.031 0.038 0.034 0.03
[0.049] [0.049] [0.049] [0.049] [0.049] [0.049] [0.048]
Observations 5726 5916 5916 5722 5912 5722 5718
R2 0.096 0.097 0.102 0.103 0.103 0.097 0.105
Log likelihood -3790.5 -3932.98 -3916.43 -3766.54 -3908.78 -3784.88 -3755.07
Predicted mean of dep. variable 0.419 0.429 0.428 0.419 0.429 0.418 0.418
Notes to Table 1: Democracy is built on the basis of Freedom House (2006a). Controls: frontier zone
dummies, age squared, urban, rural or metropolitan areas. Omitted categories: young (17 to 34 years old),
middle income group, lowest education, employee, occupation in army. Robust standard errors adjusted
for clustering on frontier zones. *** Significant at 1%, ** significant at 5%, * significant at 10%.
The implications of our results are that, as suggested by Acemoglu and Robinson (2000, 2002),
democracy and trust in the institutions turn people in favor of market reform, by acting in the same way as
a credible commitment to compensating the negative outcomes of income differentiation. Nevertheless,
the transfer of formal political power from the elite to the majority during the process of democratization
is not sufficient. A crucial role is played by political trust, which reflects the feeling of confidence in the
ability of democratic institutions to perform their instrumental role in keeping governments responsible
and accountable to the majority.
Robustness
In order to go further in the attempt to overcome the omitted variable problem, we run the estimation of
equation (3) within formerly integrated cultural zones, as discussed in Section 3. This is meant to exclude
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
23
the influence of politico-economic attitudes inherited from the past, which would create an upward bias
on the estimation of the relation between democracy, trust and support for the market.
Table 2 replicates, within each cultural zone, the same regression as shown in column (7) of Table 1, with
a three way interaction between democracy, political trust and preferences for redistribution (controlling
for main effects and two way interactions). The (triple) interaction is positive and significant in the new
members of the European Union, the former USSR and the former Ottoman Empire.
Table 2: Support for the Market within Cultural Zones
Dependent variable Support for the Market
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Austro-
Hungarian
Empire
European
Union Polish
Lithuanian
Commonwealth
Ottoman
Empire USSR
Democracy 0.311* -0.008 0.024 0.337 0.119**
[0.153] [0.125] [0.048] [0.327] [0.044]
Trust -0.051 0.065 -0.032** -0.221* 0.013
[0.062] [0.112] [0.014] [0.105] [0.019]
0.001 -0.019 0.001 0.035 -0.012 State intervention against
inequalities [0.013] [0.021] [0.016] [0.029] [0.011]
0.004 0.005* 0.003 0.008* 0.006* Democracy*Trust*State
intervention against inequality [0.003] [0.002] [0.006] [0.004] [0.003]
Observations 1520 1825 1546 1694 2616
R2 0.112 0.154 0.173 0.118 0.135
Log likelihood -993 -1166 -956 -1107 -1672
Notes to Table 2: Controls: frontier zone dummies; income categories (rich, middle class, poor); age; age
squared; gender; occupation categories; self-employed; education categories; urban, rural or metropolitan
areas. Robust standard errors adjusted for clustering on frontier zones. *** Significant at 1%, **
significant at 5%, * significant at 10%. Democracy is built on the basis of Freedom House (2006a). Pair-
wise interactions between democracy, trust and demand for redistribution are controlled for.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
24
The central element of our interpretation of the link between democracy and support for the market is the
role of inequality and the demand for income redistribution. We thus try to check whether the effect of
democratic institutions that we observe actually relies on the redistributive ability of the state and not in
state intervention in general. The LITS survey contains other questions on state intervention that allow
distinguishing the demand for income redistribution by the state from other dimensions of state
intervention in the economy. We use the following set of questions:
Do you think the state should be involved in the following?
- Guaranteeing employment
- Guaranteeing low prices for basic goods and food
- Ownership of large companies in this country
- Ownership of gas and electricity companies
Scale: not involved at all/let the market play =1; somewhat/moderately involved =2; strongly involved=3
We run four independent regressions of a modified equation (3) where each item of the above question is
successively substituted to the demand for redistribution. Results are displayed in Table 3. Each column
presents the regression results for each of the above elements of economic policy. The three way
interactions between democracy, political trust and the chosen element of state intervention in the
economy are never significant. We conclude that the effect that we observe in section 4 lies specifically in
the redistributive ability of democratic institutions and not in other elements of state intervention.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
25
Table 3: Robustness: other element of state intervention rather than redistributive justice
Dependent variable Support for the Market
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Employment Low price
food Ownership
large
companies
Ownership
gas &
electricity
companies
Democracy 0.087** 0.083*** 0.015 0.057
[0.037] [0.023] [0.027] [0.035]
State guarantee employment 0.000
[0.054]
State guarantee low prices 0.004
[0.040]
State ownership large companies -0.092*
[0.049]
State ownership gas & electricity companies -0.065
[0.052]
Trust -0.023 -0.024 -0.015 -0.063**
[0.022] [0.023] [0.020] [0.029]
[0.009]
-0.001 Democracy*Trust*State guarantee employment [0.001]
-0.002 Democracy*Trust*State guarantee low prices [0.001]
-0.001 Democracy*Trust*State ownership large
companies [0.002]
-0.001 Democracy*Trust*State ownership gas &
electricity companies [0.001]
Observations 5717 5714 5713 5714
R2 0.104 0.104 0.103 0.105
Log likelihood -3759 -3757 -3759 -3754
Notes to Table 4:Controls: frontier zone dummies; income categories (rich, middle class, poor); age; age
squared; gender; occupation categories; self-employed; education categories; urban, rural or metropolitan
areas. Robust standard errors adjusted for clustering on frontier zones. *** Significant at 1%, **
significant at 5%, * significant at 10%. Democracy is built on the basis of Freedom House (2006a). Pair-
wise interactions between democracy, trust and each element of state intervention are controlled for.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
26
5. Discussion and Conclusion
This paper sheds light on the relationship between political democracy and economic liberalism.
Democratic rights increase popular support for the market. This is true, in particular, of inequality-averse
agents, provided that they trust political institutions. These findings are consistent with studies that find a
positive link from political to economic liberalization (Giavazzi and Tabellini 2005; Grosjean and Senik
2007), or claim that democracy makes economic growth more sustainable by delivering better
distributional outcomes (Rodrik 2000).
To be sure, this paper only illustrates a static relationship between democracy and income redistribution
on the one hand and support for market reforms on the other hand. Nevertheless, it is consistent with a
dynamic view of historical evolution. An example is nineteen century’s Europe, where the extension of
voting rights that led to unprecedented redistributive programs can be viewed as a strategy of the elite to
avoid political unrest and revolution, which in turn was fed by rising inequalities due to economic
development and industrialization (Acemoglu and Robinson 2000). This paper points to a strong
complementarity between democratization and market reforms. It sheds some light on the “death of the
liberal consensus” in central Europe: according to Krastev (2007) or Rupnik (2007), the latter is
attributable to the lack of democracy. The authors describe the transition period as one characterized by a
tight control by political elites and a lack of political debate or of any real alternative opposition: “voters
could change governments, but could not change policies” (Krastev, 2007, p59). For example, as
described by Krastev (2007), the reform of the welfare state was never really an issue of the political
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
27
debate; political elite colluded over strict liberal economic policies11. This conjunction between the lack
of real political alternative and the rising economic inequality has certainly reinforced the appeal of
populist policies.
However, the recent success of populist parties in many central European countries does not necessarily
imply the death of the reform process; it could also exert a positive impact, on both democracy and
market reform, by creating the formerly missing political debate (Schmitter 2006). In Ralf Dahrendorf’s
words: “one man’s populism is another’s democracy” (cited in Krastev 2007, p59). Furthermore, the
establishment of social safety nets and redistributive policies may in turn allow for a deepening of market
reforms, as is illustrated in this paper.
In sum, this paper suggests that democracy and market reforms are complementary; as better
distributional outcomes can be guaranteed by democracy. A possible counter-example is provided by the
experience of some East Asian countries, where market reforms were accomplished without
democratization. However, as noted by Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson (2001), development in many
Asian countries was not accompanied by rising inequalities, which is identified here as the main stall to
economic reform that has to be overcome by a deepening of democracy. Countries like Taiwan or South
Korea have developed along a non-democratic but egalitarian reform path, a strategy that is more the
exception than the rule in developing and transition countries.
11 Krastev (2007, p 60) describes the “victory of the anti-egalitarian consensus”, which united the ex-
communist elite, motivated by self-interest, and the anti-communist counter-elite, motivated by ideology.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
28
6. Annex
Table A1: Descriptive Statistics
Variable Mean Std. dev.
Market preferable 1 if resp. prefers market economy to other form of economic system 0.428 0.50
Democracy Freedom House Nations in Transit index. Min 1: least democratic. Max:
7: most democratic 4.01 1.58
Trust Sum of index of trust in government, parliament, courts and political
parties. Min: 1. Max: 4. 1.17 1.46
2.64 0.57 Demand for
redistribution Support for state intervention to reduce "the gap between the rich and the
poor". Min: 1. Max: 3.
Democracy*Demand for redistribution 10.62 4.83
Democracy*Trust 4.01 5.59
Trust*Demand for redistribution 0.46 1.06
Democracy*Trust*Demand for redistribution 10.39 15.15
Age 46.94 16.98
Age squared 2491 1691
Gender 1 if male 0.48 0.5
Self employed work as self employed at their main job (regardless occupation) 0.08 0.28
Education categories:
No education 0.05 0.22
Compulsory education 0.16 0.37
Secondary education 0.22 0.41
Professional education 0.37 0.48
University degree 0.19 0.39
Post-graduate education 0.01 0.09
Occupation categories
Unemployed Actively looking for a job. waiting for an answer or find no job available 0.09 0.29
White collar worker 0.17 0.38
Blue collar worker 0.18 0.38
Service worker 0.12 0.32
Farmer or farm worker 0.05 0.22
Pensioner 0.21 0.41
Student 0.03 0.16
Housewife 0.06 0.25
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
29
Figure 1: Support for the Market and Income Inequality
Latvia
Estonia
Slovenia
Czech Republic
Hungary
Lithuania
Romania
Slovak Republic
Montenegro
FYR Macedonia
Bulgaria
Bosnia and Herzegovina
Croatia
Serbia
Poland
Tajikistan
Georgia
Belarus
Kazakhstan
Azerbaijan
Moldova
Kyrgyz Republic
Ukraine
Uzbekistan
Armenia
Russia
.25 .3 .35 .4 .45 .5
Support for the Market
25 30 35 40
Gini coefficient
Central and eastern Europe and the Baltic states South-eastern Europe
Commonwealth of Independent states
Figure 2: Support for the Market and Preferences for Income Redistribution by the State
Slovak Republic
Slovenia
Latvia
Lithuania
Hungary
Romania
Czech Republic
Estonia
Bulgaria Croatia
Montenegro
FYR Macedonia
Poland
Bosnia and Herzegovina
Serbia
Russia
Armenia
Belarus
Moldova
Azerbaijan
Kyrgyz Republic
Ukraine
Kazakhstan
Tajikistan
Georgia
Uzbekistan
.25 .3 .35 .4 .45 .5
Support for the Market
.4 .5 .6 .7 .8 .9
Preferences for reducing inequalities
Central and eastern Europe and the Baltic states South-eastern Europe
Commonwealth of Independent states
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
30
Figure 3: Preferences for Redistribution and Income Inequality
Estonia
Romania
Hungary
Lithuania
Slovak Republic
Czech Republic
Latvia
Slovenia Serbia
Bosnia and Herzegovina FYR Macedonia
Croatia
Poland
Bulgaria
Montenegro Armenia
Ukraine Russia
Belarus
Georgia
Uzbekistan
Kazakhstan
Tajikistan
Moldova
Kyrgyz Republic
Azerbaijan
.4 .5 .6 .7 .8 .9
Reduce inequalities
25 30 35 40
Gini coefficient
Central and eastern Europe and the Baltic states South-eastern Europe
Commonwealth of Independent states
Figure 4: Plot of Predicted Values for OLS and Logistic Regression for the Estimation of
Equation (3)
0.2 .4 .6 .8 1
Pr(favmarket)
0.2 .4 .6 .8 1
Linear prediction
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
31
References
Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson (2000). Why Did The West Extend The Franchise?
Democracy, Inequality, And Growth In Historical Perspective," The Quarterly Journal of Economics,
MIT Press, vol. 115(4), pages 1167-1199, November.
Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson and James A. Robinson (2001). The Colonial Origins of Comparative
Development: An Empirical Investigation. The American Economic Review, vol. 91(5), pages 1369-1401.
Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson (2002). The Political Economy of the Kuznets Curve," Review
of Development Economics, Blackwell Publishing, vol. 6(2), pages 183-203, June.
Acemoglu, Daron, Maria Angelica Bautista, Pablo Querubin and James A. Robinson (2007a). Economic
and Political Inequality in Development: The Case of Cundinamarca, Colombia. Working paper, June
2007.
Acemoglu, Daron, Davide Ticchi and Andrea Vindingli (2007b). Emergence and Persistence of
Inefficient States, National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 12748.
Ai, Chunrong and Edward C. Norton (2003). Interaction terms in logit and probit models. Economics
Letters, Elsevier, vol. 80(1), pages 123-129, July.
Alesina, Alberto and Nicola Fuchs-Schundeln (2007), Goodbye Lenin (or Not?): The Effect of
Communism on People, The American Economic Review, Vol. 97(4), pages 1507-1528.
Alesina, Alberto and Roberto Perotti (1996). Income distribution, political instability, and investment.
European Economic Review, vol. 40(6), pages 1203-1228, June.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
32
Alesina, Alberto and Dani Rodrik (1994). Distributive Politics and Economic Growth, The Quarterly
Journal of Economics, MIT Press, vol. 109(2), pages 465-90, May.
Aslund, Anders, Peter Boone and Simon Johnson (2001). Escaping the Under Reform Trap. IMF Staff
Papers, International Monetary Fund, vol. 48(4).
Bertelsmann Stiftung (2005). Bertelsmann Transformation Index 2006: Political Management in
International Comparison, http://www.bertelsmann-transformation-
index.de/fileadmin/pdf/BTI_2006_Brosch_re_GB.pdf
Bianco, William T. (1994). Trust: Representatives and Constituents. Ann Arbor, MI.: University of
Michigan Press.
Centre for International Development and Conflict Management (CIDCM) (2006), Polity IV: Political
Regimes Characteristics and Transition: 1800-2004, University of Maryland
Desai, Raj M. and Anders Olofsgard (2006). Political Constraints and Public Support for Market Reform.
IMF Staff Papers, vol. 53, Special Issue.
Denisova, Irina, Eller, Markus, Frye, Timothy and Zhuravskaya, Ekaterina. (2008). Who Wants to Revise
Privatization and Why? Evidence from 28 Post-Communist Countries. CEFIR and NES working paper
n°113, available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1008212
Dewatripont, Mathias and Gerard Roland (1995). The Design of Reform Package under Uncertainty.
American Economic Review, vol. 85, Issue 5, pp 1207-1223.
EBRD (2007a). Life in Transition, a Survey of People’s Experiences and Attitudes.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
33
EBRD (2007b). Transition Report 2007.
Ferrer-i-Carbonell, Ada and Paul Frijters (2004). How Important is Methodology for the estimates of the
Determinants of Happiness? Economic Journal, Royal Economic Society, vol. 114(497), pages 641-659,
07.
Fleming, J.S. and John Micklewright (2000). Income distribution, economic systems and transition. In
A.B. Atkinson & F. Bourguignon (ed.), Handbook of Income Distribution, edition 1, volume 1, chapter
14, pages 843-918. Elsevier.
Fidrmuc, Jan (2003). Economic reform, democracy and growth during post-communist transition.
European Journal of Political Economy, vol. 19(3), pages 583-604.
Finifter, Ada and Ellen Mickiewicz (1992). Redefining the Political System of the USSR: Mass support
for Political Change. American Political Science Review, vol 23, pages 857-874.
Freedom House (2006a). Nations in Transit 2006: Democratization from Central Europe to Eurasia,
Rowman and Littlefield Publishers.
Freedom House (2006b). Freedom in the World 2006: The Annual Survey of Political Rights and Civil
Liberties, Rowman and Littlefield Publishers.
Giavazzi Francesco and Guido Tabellini (2005). Economic and Political Liberalizations. Journal of
Monetary Economics, Vol. 52(7), pp. 1297-1330.
Glaeser, Edward, Jose Scheinkman and Andrei Shleifer (2003). The injustice of inequality. Journal of
Monetary Economics, Vol 50, Issue 1, January 2003, pages 199-222.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
34
Grosfeld, Irena and Claudia Senik (2008). Does Inequality Spoil the Welfare Benefits of Growth?
Evidence from a Long Polish Survey. Paris School of Economics Working Paper n°2008-19.
Grosjean, Pauline and Claudia Senik (2007). Should Market Liberalisation Precede Democracy? Causal
Relations Between Political Preferences and Development. EBRD working paper no. 103, June 2007.
Hayo, Bernd (2004). Public support for creating a market economy in eastern Europe. Journal of
Comparative Economics, vol. 32(4), pages 720-744.
Keane, Michael P. and Eswar S. Prasad (2000). Poland: Inequality, Transfers and Growth in Transition.
Finance and Development, March 2001, Vol 38(1).
Krastev, Ivan (2007). The Strange Death of the Liberal Consensus. Journal of Democracy, vol. 18 (4),
pages 56-63.
La Porta Rafael, Fiorencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer and Robert Vishny (1999). The Quality of
Government. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 15(1), 1113-1155.
Lindblom Charles E. (1995). Market and Democracy. Obliquely. Political Science and Politics, Vol.
28(4), pages. 684-688.
Lipset, Seymour M. (1959). Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic Development and Political
Legitimacy. The American Political Science Review, vol. 53(1), pages 69-105
Milanovic, Branko (1998). Income, Inequality, and Poverty during the Transition from Planned to Market
Economy. Washington, DC: The World Bank, 1998. xiii + 237 pp.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
35
Milanovic, Branko (1999). Explaining the increase in inequality during the transition. Economics of
Transition, 7(2), 299-341.
Mishler, William and Richard Rose (1997). Trust, Distrust and Skepticism: Popular Evaluations of Civil
and Political Institutions in Post-Communist Societies, The Journal of Politics, Vol. 59(2), pages 418-
451, May.
Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini (1994). Is Inequality Harmful for Growth? American Economic
Review, Vol. 84 (1994), pages 600–621.
Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini (2007). Democratic Capital: The Nexus of Political and Economic
Change. NBER working paper 12175.
Pohlmann, John T. and Dennis W. Leitner (2003). A comparison of ordinary least squares and logistic
regression. The Ohio Journal of Science, Dec.
Przeworski, Adam and Fernando Limongi (1993). Political Regimes and Economic Growth. The Journal
of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 7(3), pages 51-69.
Putnam , Robert D . (1993). Making Democracy Work. With Robert Leonardi an d Raffaella Y. Nanetti.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
Robinson, James A. (2006). Economic Development and Democracy. Annual Review of Political
Sciences, Vol. 9, pages 503-27.
Rodrik, Dani (1999). Democracies Pay Higher Wages. Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 114(3),
pages 707-738.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
36
Rodrik, Dani (2000). Institutions for High Quality Growth: What They Are and How to Acquire Them.
Studies in International Comparative Development, vol. 35 (3), pages 3-31.
Roland, Gérard (2001). The Political Economy of Transition. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol.
16(1): 29-50.
Roland, Gérard and Thierry Verdier (2003). Law Enforcement and Transition. European Economic
Review, vol. 47(4): 669-685.
Rupnik, Jacques (2007). From Democracy Fatigue to Populist Backlash. Journal of Democracy, vol. 18
(4), pages 17-25.
Sen, Amartya K. (1999). Democracy as a Universal Value, Journal of Democracy, vol. 10(3), pages 3-17.
Schmitter, Philippe C. (2006). A Balance Sheet of the Vices and Virtues of Populism. Paper prepared for
“The Challenge of the New Populism” conference, 10-11 May 2006, Sofia, Bulgaria.
Usher, Dan (1981). The Economic Prerequisite for Democracy. New York: Columbia University Press.
halshs-00586284, version 1 - 15 Apr 2011
... Our paper is also related to the literature on determinants of perceptions in transition economies. This literature includes Alesina and Fuchs-Schü ndeln (2007), who show how the legacy of communism shaped the attitudes of East German residents about the paternalism of the state, Grosjean and Senik (2008) who show that democracy increases public support for the market in transition economies (based on LITS), Guriev and Tsyvinsky (2009), who study the determinants of the anti-Western attitudes of the Russian population, Grosfeld and Senik (2008), who identify and explain the change in the relationship between individual satisfaction with the state of the country's economy and income inequality in transition using data from Poland. Individual determinants of perceptions in Russia based on RLMS are studied by Ravallion and Lokshin (2000), who seek to explain support for governmental redistribution, and Senik (2004), who studies individual determinants of subjective life satisfaction. ...
Article
We use data from the 2006 round of the Russian Longitudinal Monitoring Survey to describe perceptions of the Russian population about the transition process and the role of the state compared with that of free markets. We find that about one-half of the Russian population is disappointed with transition and a large majority is in favour of high state regulation and state provision of goods and services. High demand for government regulation and increased state intervention coexists with a low level of trust in government institutions and recognition of high and rising levels of corruption. The findings are consistent with the theory developed by Aghion "et al." (2009) . In an environment with poor social capital, private business imposes negative externalities on the society and society chooses to demand more state regulation and tolerate corruption to reduce these externalities. We also find that individual perceptions of social capital and corruption co-vary with the demand for regulation, as predicted by the theory. Copyright (c) 2010 The Authors. Journal compilation (c) 2010 The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development.
Article
Full-text available
Using survey data from 28 transition countries, we test for the complementarity and substitutability of market-relevant skills and institutions. We show that democracy and good governance complement market skills in transition economies. Under autocracy and weak governance institutions there is no significant difference in support for revising privatization between high and low-skilled respondents. As the level of democracy and the quality of governance increases, the difference in the level of support for revising privatization between the high and low skilled grows dramatically. This finding contributes to our understanding of microfoundations of the politics of economic reform.
Article
Full-text available
This is a book about income, inequality, and poverty during the period of collapse of Communism and the 'construction' of capitalism in eighteen formerly socialist countries. It covers a period of almost ten years, from the time of the early Gorbachevian reforms of 1987-88 to approximately 1996. Two almost simultaneous revolutions took place in the late 1980s. The first, of course, was the collapse of Communism. The second was the opening up of information on income, inequality, and poverty. We now have relatively reliable and up-to-date information that allows us to follow and analyze the developments. This book describes what happened during the transition in eighteen countries - from the Czech Republic in the West to Kazakhstan and Russia in the East. Specifically, the book examine what happened to the real incomes of the population, to the inequality with which incomes and expenditures are distributed, and to poverty. It also attempts to find out why these changes occurred.
Article
Of the transition countries, Poland has achieved the highest rate of GDP growth along with the smallest increase in inequality. It implemented market liberalization at a more rapid pace than most of the other transition economies. The transition process did lead to great increases in labor earnings inequality and significant job destruction. However, through a generous and well-targeted system of social transfers-especially pensions-the government mitigated the rise in income inequality and facilitated enterprise restructuring and other market-oriented reforms. The cloud on the horizon is that this high level of social spending has also led to budget deficits of about 3 percent of GDP, a level that is probably not sustainable. Poland now faces the challenge of restoring fiscal balance while keeping the social security system effective and preserving the important gains of the 1990s.
Article
This paper compares ordinary least squares (OLS) and logistic regression in terms of their underlying assumptions and results obtained on common data sets. Two data sets were analyzed with both methods. In the respective studies, the dependent variables were binary codes of 1) dropping out of school and 2) attending a private college. Results of both analyses were very similar. Significance tests (alpha = 0.05) produced identical decisions. OLS and logistic predicted values were highly correlated. Predicted classifications on the dependent variable were identical in study 1 and very similar in study 2. Logistic regression yielded more accurate predictions of dependent variable probabilities as measured by the average squared differences between the observed and predicted probabilities. It was concluded that both models can be used to test relationships with a binary criterion. However, logistic regression is superior to OLS at predicting the probability of an attribute, and should be the model of choice for that application.
Article
Using data from a national public opinion survey carried out in the Soviet Union during November and December 1989, we explore two attitudes relevant to the revolutionary changes there: (1) attitudes toward change and political democracy and (2) attitudes toward a core component of socialist ideology, the locus of responsibility for social well-being (the state or individuals?). These variables are unrelated, with the sample relatively evenly divided among the intersecting cells of a cross tabulation. While social conflict may be mitigated by the small sizes of absolutely opposing groups, consensus may also be hard to reach. Ethnicity, education, income, age, party membership, and life satisfaction have important effects on these attitudes. We discuss how attitude patterns in our data may be related to the disintegration of the Soviet Union and to problems faced by the independent successor states as they develop new institutions and foster new values.
Article
The conditions associated with the existence and stability of democratic society have been a leading concern of political philosophy. In this paper the problem is attacked from a sociological and behavioral standpoint, by presenting a number of hypotheses concerning some social requisites for democracy, and by discussing some of the data available to test these hypotheses. In its concern with conditions—values, social institutions, historical events—external to the political system itself which sustain different general types of political systems, the paper moves outside the generally recognized province of political sociology. This growing field has dealt largely with the internal analysis of organizations with political goals, or with the determinants of action within various political institutions, such as parties, government agencies, or the electoral process. It has in the main left to the political philosopher the larger concern with the relations of the total political system to society as a whole.
Article
We exploit differences in European mortality rates to estimate the effect of institutions on economic performance. Europeans adopted very different colonization policies in different colonies, with different associated institutions. In places where Europeans faced high mortality rates, they could not settle and were more likely to set up extractive institutions. These institutions persisted to the present. Exploiting differences in European mortality rates as an instrument for current institutions, we estimate large effects of institutions on income per capita. Once the effect of institutions is controlled for, countries in Africa or those closer to the equator do not have lower incomes. (JEL O11, P16, P51).