ArticlePDF Available

Implied volatility skews and stock return skewness and kurtosis implied by stock option prices

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

The Black-Scholes* option pricing model is commonly applied to value a wide range of option contracts. However, the model often inconsistently prices deep in-the-money and deep out-of-the-money options. Options professionals refer to this well-known phenomenon as a volatility 'skew' or 'smile'. In this paper, we examine an extension of the Black-Scholes model developed by Corrado and Su that suggests skewness and kurtosis in the option-implied distributions of stock returns as the source of volatility skews. Adapting their methodology, we estimate option-implied coefficients of skewness and kurtosis for four actively traded stock options. We find significantly nonnormal skewness and kurtosis in the option-implied distributions of stock returns.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Implied volatility skews and stock return
skewness and kurtosis implied by stock
option prices
C. J. CORRADO and TIE SU1
Department of Finance, 214 Middlebush Hall, University of Missouri, Columbia,
MO 65211, USA and 1Department of Finance, 514 Jenkins Building, University of
Miami, Coral Gables, FL 33124, USA
The Black–Scholes* option pricing model is commonly applied to value a wide range of
option contracts. However, the model often inconsistently prices deep in-the-money
and deep out-of-the-money options. Options professionals refer to this well-known
phenomenon as a volatility ‘skew’ or ‘smile’. In this paper, we examine an extension of
the Black–Scholes model developed by Corrado and Su‡ that suggests skewness and
kurtosis in the option-implied distributions of stock returns as the source of volatility
skews. Adapting their methodology, we estimate option-implied coefficients of skewness
and kurtosis for four actively traded stock options. We find significantly nonnormal
skewness and kurtosis in the option-implied distributions of stock returns.
Keywords: Stock options, implied volatility, skewness, kurtosis
1. INTRODUCTION
The Black–Scholes (1973) option pricing model is commonly applied to value a
wide range of option contracts. Despite this widespread acceptance among
practitioners and academics, however, the model has the known deficiency of
often inconsistently pricing deep in-the-money and deep out-of-the-money
options. Options professionals refer to this well-known phenomenon as a
volatility ‘skew’ or ‘smile’. A volatility skew is the pattern that results from
calculating implied volatilities across the range of strike prices spanning a given
option class. Typically, the skew pattern is systematically related to the degree
to which the options are in- or out-of-the-money. This phenomenon is not
predicted by the Black–Scholes model, since, theoretically, volatility is a
property of the underlying instrument and the same implied volatility value
should be observed across all options on the same instrument.
The Black–Scholes model assumes that stock log-prices are normally dis-
tributed over any finite time interval. Hull (1993) and Nattenburg (1994) point
* Black and Scholes (1973)
Corrado and Su (1996)
1351–847X © 1997 Chapman & Hall
The European Journal of Finance 3, 73–85 (1997)
out that stock returns exhibit nonnormal skewness and kurtosis and that
volatility skews are a consequence of empirical violations of the normality
assumption. In this paper, we examine the empirical distribution of stock
returns implied by option prices and the resulting volatility skews. We use the
method suggested by Corrado and Su (1996) to extend the Black–Scholes
formula to account for nonnormal skewness and kurtosis in stock return
distributions. This method is based on fitting the first four moments of a
distribution to a pattern of empirically observed option prices. The mean of this
distribution is determined by option pricing theory, but an estimation pro-
cedure yields implied values for the variance, skewness and kurtosis of the
distribution of stock returns.
The paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we show how
nonnormal skewness and kurtosis in stock return distributions give rise to
volatility skews. This includes a review of Corrado and Su’s (1996) development
of a skewness- and kurtosis-adjusted Black–Scholes option price formula. We
then describe the data sources used in our empirical analysis. In the subsequent
empirical section, we compare the performance of the Black–Scholes model
with that of a skewness- and kurtosis-adjusted extension to the Black–Scholes
model. The final section summarizes and concludes the paper.
2. DERIVATION OF A SKEWNESS- AND KURTOSIS-ADJUSTED BLACK–
SCHOLES MODEL
Corrado and Su (1996) develop a method to incorporate option price adjust-
ments for nonnormal skewness and kurtosis in an expanded Black–Scholes
option pricing formula. Their method adapts a Gram–Charlier series expansion
of the standard normal density function to yield an option price formula that is
the sum of a Black–Scholes option price plus adjustment terms for nonnormal
skewness and kurtosis. Specifically, the density function g(z) defined below
accounts for nonnormal skewness and kurtosis, denoted by m3and m4,
respectively, where n(z) represents the standard normal density function.
g(z)=n(z)
3
1+m
3
3!(z3–3z)+m
4–3
4! (z4–6z
2+3)
4(1)
where
z=ln(St/S0)–(rs
2
/2)t
sÎt
and
S0is a current stock price;
Stis a random stock price at time t;
ris the risk free rate of interest;
tis the time remaining until option expiration, and
sis the standard deviation of returns for the underlying stock.
74 Corrado and Su
Notice that skewness m3and kurtosis m4for the density g(z) are explicit
parameters in its functional form. Under a normal specification, these co-
efficients are m3= 0 and m4= 3 (Stuart and Ord, 1987: 222–3).
Applying the density g(z) in equation (1) to derive a theoretical call price as
the present value of an expected payoff at option expiration yields the following
option price expression, where z(St) = (logStm)/sÎt, m= logS0+ (rs2/2)tand
Kis the option’s strike price.
CGC =e
rt e
K(StK)g(z(St))dz(St) (2)
Evaluating this integral yields the following formula for an option price based on
a Gram–Charlier density expansion, here denoted by CGC.
CGC =CBS +m3Q3+(m
4–3)Q
4(3)
where CBS =S0N(d)–KertN(dsÎt) is the Black–Scholes option price formula,
and
Q3=1
3!S0sÎt((2sÎtd)n(d)–s
2
tN(d))
Q4=1
4!S0sÎt((d2–1–3sÎt(dsÎt))n(d)+s
3
t
3/2N(d))
d=ln(S0/K)+(r+s
2
/2)t
sÎt
In equation (3) above, the terms m3Q3and (m4–3)Q
4measure the effects of
nonnormal skewness and kurtosis on the option price CGC.
Nonnormal skewness and kurtosis give rise to implied volatility skews. To
illustrate these effects, option prices are generated according to equation (3)
based on parameter values m3= –0.5, m4= 4, S0= 50, s= 30%, t= 3 months,
r= 4% and strike prices ranging from 35 to 65. Implied volatilities are then
calculated for each skewness and kurtosis impacted option price using the
Black–Scholes formula. The resulting volatility skew is plotted in Fig. 1, where
the horizontal axis measures strike prices and the vertical axis measures
implied standard deviation values. While the true volatility value is s= 30%, Fig.
1 reveals that implied volatility is greater than true volatility for deep out-of-the-
money options, but less than true volatility for deep in-the-money options.
Figure 2 contains an empirical volatility skew obtained from Telephonos de
Mexico (TMX) call option price quotes recorded on 2 December 1993 for options
expiring in May 1994. In Fig. 2, the horizontal axis measures option moneyness
as the percentage difference between a discounted strike price and a dividend-
adjusted stock price level. Negative (positive) moneyness corresponds to in-the-
money (out-of-the-money) options with low (high) strike prices. The vertical
axis measures implied standard deviation values. Each solid black marker
represents an implied volatility calculated using the Black–Scholes formula.
75Skewness and kurtosis implied by stock option prices
+
Each hollow marker represents an implied volatility calculated from a skewness-
and kurtosis-adjusted option price. The actual number of price quotes on this
day was 217, but because many quotes are unchanged updates made through-
out the day the number of visually distinguishable dots is smaller than the
actual number of quotes.
Figure 2 reveals that Black–Scholes implied volatilities range from about 36%
for deep in-the-money options (negative moneyness) to about 29% for deep out-
of-the-money options (positive moneyness). By contrast, the skewness- and
kurtosis-adjusted prices yield essentially the same implied volatility of about
33% regardless of option moneyness. Comparing Fig. 2 with Fig. 1 reveals that
the implied volatility skew for TMX options is consistent with negative skewness
and positive excess kurtosis in the distribution of TMX stock returns.* In the
empirical results section of this paper, we examine the economic impact of
these volatility skews.
* Excess kurtosis is defined as (m423), which is the difference between actual kurtosis of m4and
normal distribution kurtosis of 3.
Fig. 1. Implied volatility skew
Fig. 2. Implied volatilities for Telephonos de Mexico (TMX)
76 Corrado and Su
3. DATA SOURCES
We base this study on the Chicago Board Options Exchange (CBOE) market for
four actively traded stock option contracts: International Business Machines
(IBM), Paramount Communications Inc. (PCI), Micron Technology (MU) and
Telephonos de Mexico (TMX). Intraday price data come from the Berkeley
Options Data Base of CBOE options trading. Stock prices, strike prices and
option maturities also come from the Berkeley database. To avoid bid–ask
bounce problems in transaction prices, we take option prices as midpoints of
CBOE dealers’ bid–ask price quotations. The risk-free rate of interest is taken as
the US Treasury bill rate for a bill maturing closest to option contract
expiration. Interest rate information is culled from the Wall Street Journal.
CBOE stock options are American style and may be exercised anytime before
expiration. To justify the Black–Scholes formula for American-style options, our
data sample includes only call options for which either (1) no cash dividend was
paid during the life of the option, or (2) if a dividend was paid, it was so small
that early exercise was never optimal. The first condition is embedded in the
second, since both conditions are summarized by the following inequality:
D,K(1–e
rt) (4)
where Dis a dividend payment, Kis the strike price, ris the risk-free rate on the
ex-dividend date and tis the length of time between the ex-dividend date and
option expiration. Merton (1973) shows that an American-style option is never
optimally exercised before expiration where this inequality holds. When a
dividend payment is made, however, we use the method suggested by Black
(1975) and adjust the stock price by subtracting the present value of the
dividend. Stock dividend information is extracted from the Daily Stock Price
Record published by Standard and Poor’s Corporation.
Following data screening procedures in Barone-Adesi and Whaley (1986), we
delete all option prices less than $0.125 and all transactions occurring before
9:00 a.m. Obvious outliers are also purged from the sample; including recorded
option prices lying outside well-known no-arbitrage option price boundaries
(Merton, 1973).
4. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
In this section, we first assess out-of-sample performance of the Black–Scholes
option pricing model. Specifically, we estimate implied standard deviations on a
daily basis for call options on each of four underlying stocks, where on the day
prior to a given current day we obtain a unique implied standard deviation from
all bid-ask price midpoints for a given option maturity class using Whaley’s
(1982) simultaneous equations procedure. This prior-day out-of-sample implied
standard deviation becomes an input used to calculate current-day theoretical
Black–Scholes option prices for all price observations within the same maturity
class. We then compare these theoretical Black–Scholes prices with their
corresponding market-observed prices.
Next, we assess the out-of-sample performance of the skewness- and kurtosis-
adjusted Black–Scholes option pricing formula developed in Corrado and Su
77Skewness and kurtosis implied by stock option prices
(1986). Following their methodology, on the day prior to a given current day we
simultaneously estimate implied standard deviation (ISD), implied skewness
(ISK) and implied kurtosis (IKT) parameters using all bid–ask midpoints for a
given option maturity class. These prior-day out-of-sample parameter estimates
provide inputs used to calculate current-day theoretical option prices for all
options within the same maturity class. We then compare theoretical skewness-
and kurtosis-adjusted Black–Scholes option prices with their corresponding
market-observed prices.
4.1 The Black–Scholes option pricing model
The Black–Scholes formula specifies five inputs: a stock price, a strike price, a
risk-free interest rate, an option maturity and a return standard deviation. The
first four inputs are directly observable market data. The return standard
deviation is not directly observable. We estimate return standard deviations
from values implied by options using Whaley’s (1982) simultaneous equations
procedure. This procedure yields a value for the argument BSISD that minimizes
the following sum of squares.
min
BSID O
N
j=1 FCOBS.jCBS.j(BSISD)G2(5)
In equation (5) above, Ndenotes the number of price quotations available on a
given day for a given maturity class, COBS represents a market-observed call
price, and CBS (BSISD) specifies a theoretical Black–Scholes call price based on
the parameter BSISD. Using prior-day values of BSISD, we calculate theoretical
Black–Scholes option prices for all options in a current-day sample within the
same maturity class. We then compare these theoretical Black–Scholes option
prices with their corresponding market-observed prices.
Table 1 summarizes calculations for Telephonos de Mexico (TMX) call option
prices observed during December 1993 for options maturing in May 1994. To
maintain table compactness, column 1 lists only even-numbered dates within
the month and column 2 lists the number of price quotations available on each
of these dates. Black–Scholes implied standard deviations (BSISD) for each date
are reported in column 3. To assess the economic significance of differences
between theoretical and observed prices, column 6 lists the proportion of
theoretical Black–Scholes option prices lying outside their corresponding bid–
ask spreads, either below the bid price or above the asked price. In addition,
column 7 lists the average absolute deviation of theoretical prices from bid–ask
boundaries for only those prices lying outside their bid–ask spreads. Specific-
ally, for each theoretical option price lying outside its corresponding bid–ask
spread, we calculate an absolute deviation according to the following formula.
max(CBS(BSISD)–Ask, BidCBS(BSISD))
This absolute deviation statistic is a measure of the economic significance of
deviations of theoretical option prices from observed bid–ask spreads. Finally,
column 4 lists day-by-day averages of observed call prices and column 5 lists
day-by-day averages of observed bid-ask spreads.
78 Corrado and Su
In Table 1, the bottom row lists column averages for all variables. For
example, the average number of daily price observations is 225 (column 2), with
an average option price of $9.96 (column 4) and an average bid–ask spread of
$0.24 (column 5). The average implied standard deviation is 28.87% (column 3).
Regarding the ability of the Black–Scholes model to describe observed option
prices, the average proportion of theoretical Black–Scholes prices lying outside
their corresponding bid–ask spreads is 78% (column 6), with an average
deviation of $0.12 (column 7) for those observations lying outside a spread
boundary.
The average price deviation of $0.12 for observations lying outside a spread
boundary is equivalent to about a one-eighth price tick. While informative,
an overall average deviation understates the pricing problem since price
deviations are larger for deep in-the-money and deep out-of-the-money options.
For example, Table 1 shows that the Black–Scholes implied standard deviation
(BSISD) value for TMX options on 2 December was 30.80%, while Fig. 2 reveals
that Black–Scholes implied volatilities for TMX range from about 36% for deep
in-the-money options to about 29% for deep out-of-the-money options. Based on
2 December TMX input values, i.e. S= 57, r= 3.2%, T= 169 days, a deep in-the-
money option with a strike price of 45 yields call prices of $13.63 and $13.25,
respectively, from volatility values of 36% and 30.8%. Similarly, a deep out-of-the-
money option with a strike price of 65 yields call prices of $2.04 and $2.29,
respectively, from volatility values of 29% and 30.8%. Since a standard stock
option contract size is 100 shares, these prices correspond to contract price
Table 1. Comparison of Black–Scholes prices and observed prices of Telephonos de
Mexico (TMX) options
Date
Number
of price
observations
Implied
standard
deviation
(%)
Average
call price
($)
Average
bid–ask
spread
($)
Proportion of
theoretical
prices outside
the bid–ask
spread
Average
deviation of
theoretical prices
from spread
boundaries ($)
2/12/93 217 30.80 6.77 0.23 0.76 0.15
6/12/93 171 30.45 10.30 0.24 0.71 0.20
8/12/93 366 28.66 8.89 0.23 0.88 0.13
10/12/93 266 28.76 9.23 0.25 0.76 0.13
14/12/93 149 28.79 8.73 0.23 0.83 0.13
16/12/93 189 28.81 9.60 0.25 0.81 0.12
20/12/93 185 28.18 10.09 0.23 0.77 0.09
22/12/93 184 28.45 11.89 0.24 0.68 0.11
28/12/93 208 27.78 11.25 0.24 0.81 0.09
30/12/93 315 28.01 12.84 0.24 0.75 0.08
Average 225 28.87 9.96 0.24 0.78 0.12
On each day indicated, a Black–Scholes implied standard deviation (BSISD) is estimated from current price
observations. Theoretical Black–Scholes option prices are then calculated using BSISD. All observations
correspond to call options traded in December 1993 and expiring in May 1994.
79Skewness and kurtosis implied by stock option prices
deviations of $38 for deep in-the-money options and $25 for deep out-of-the-
money options.
Price deviations of the magnitude described above indicate that CBOE market
makers quote deep in-the-money (out-of-the-money) call option prices at a
premium (discount) compared to prices that can be rationalized by the Black–
Scholes formula. Nevertheless, the Black–Scholes formula does provide a first
approximation to deep in-the-money or deep out-of-the-money option prices.
Immediately below, we examine the improvement in pricing accuracy obtainable
by adding skewness- and kurtosis-adjustment terms to the Black–Scholes
formula.
4.2 Skewness- and kurtosis-adjusted Black–Scholes model
In the second set of estimation procedures, on a given day within a given option
maturity class we simultaneously estimate return standard deviation, skewness
and kurtosis parameters by minimizing the following sum of squares with
respect to the arguments ISD, ISK and IKT, respectively.
min
ISD,ISK,IKT O
N
j=1 FCOBS.j–(C
BS.j(ISD)+ISKQ3+(IKT–3)Q4)G2(6)
The resulting values for ISD, ISK and IKT represent estimates of implied standard
deviation, implied skewness and implied kurtosis parameters based on Nprice
observations. Substituting ISD, ISK and IKT estimates into equation (3) yields
the following skewness- and kurtosis-adjusted Black–Scholes option price:
CGC =CBS(ISD)+ISKQ3+(IKT –3)Q
4(7)
Equation (7) yields theoretical skewness- and kurtosis-adjusted Black–Scholes
option prices from which we calculate deviations of theoretical prices from
market-observed prices.
Table 2 summarizes calculations for the same Telephonos de Mexico (TMX)
call option prices used to compile Table 1. Consequently, column 1 in Table 2
lists the same even-numbered dates and column 2 lists the same number of
price quotations listed in Table 1. To assess out-of-sample forecasting power of
skewness and kurtosis adjustments, the simultaneously estimated implied
standard deviations (ISD), implied skewness coefficients (ISK) and implied
kurtosis coefficients (IKT) are all estimated from prices observed on trading
days immediately prior to dates listed in column 1. For example, the first row of
Table 2 lists the date 2 December 1993, but columns 3, 4 and 5 report standard
deviation, skewness and kurtosis values obtained from 1 December prices.
Thus, out-of-sample parameters ISD, ISK and IKT reported in columns 3, 4 and 5,
respectively, correspond to one-day lagged estimates. We use these one-day
lagged values of ISD, ISK and IKT to calculate theoretical skewness- and kurtosis-
adjusted Black–Scholes option prices according to equation (7) for all price
observations on the even-numbered dates listed in column 1. In turn, these
theoretical prices based on out-of-sample ISD, ISK and IKT values are then used
to calculate daily proportions of theoretical prices outside bid–ask spreads
(column 6) and daily averages of deviations from spread boundaries (column 7).
80 Corrado and Su
Like Table 1, column averages for Table 2 are reported in the bottom row of the
table.
As shown in Table 2, all skewness coefficients in column 4 are negative, with
a column average of –0.55. All kurtosis coefficients in column 5 are greater than
3, with a column average of 4.92. By comparison, normal distribution skewness
and kurtosis values are 0 and 3, respectively. Column 6 of table 2 lists the
proportion of skewness- and kurtosis-adjusted prices lying outside their
corresponding bid–ask spread boundaries. The column average proportion is
19%. Column 7 lists average absolute deviations of theoretical prices from bid–
ask spread boundaries for only those prices lying outside their bid–ask spreads.
The column average price deviation is $0.05, which is about one-fifth the size of
the average bid–ask spread of $0.24 reported in Table 1. Moreover, Fig. 2 reveals
that implied volatilities from skewness- and kurtosis-adjusted option prices
(hollow markers) are unrelated to option moneyness. In turn, this implies that
the corresponding price deviations are also unrelated to option moneyness.
Overall, we conclude that skewness- and kurtosis-adjustment terms added to
the Black–Scholes formula yield significantly improved pricing accuracy for
deep in-the-money or deep out-of-the-money stock options. Furthermore, these
improvements are obtained from out-of-sample estimates of skewness and
kurtosis. There is an added cost, however, in that two additional parameters
must be estimated. But the added cost is a fixed startup cost, since once the
computer code is in place the added computation time is trivial on modern
personal computers.
Table 2. Comparison of skewness- and kurtosis-adjusted Black–Scholes prices and
observed prices of Telephonos de Mexico (TMX) options
Date
Number
of price
observations
Implied
standard
deviation
(%)
Implied
skewness
(ISK)
Implied
kurtosis
(IKT)
Proportion of
theoretical
prices outside
the bid–ask
spread
Average
deviation of
theoretical prices
from spread
boundaries ($)
2/12/93 217 32.99 –0.71 4.41 0.08 0.07
6/12/93 171 30.59 –1.00 4.07 0.54 0.10
8/12/93 366 30.40 –0.66 4.68 0.15 0.04
10/12/93 266 30.62 –0.57 4.96 0.14 0.03
14/12/93 149 30.95 –0.60 5.15 0.14 0.04
16/12/93 189 30.87 –0.51 5.28 0.16 0.04
20/12/93 185 30.37 –0.32 5.38 0.17 0.03
22/12/93 184 28.89 –0.64 4.29 0.18 0.07
28/12/93 208 29.85 –0.28 5.55 0.16 0.03
30/12/93 315 29.94 –0.20 5.46 0.14 0.03
Average 225 30.55 –0.55 4.92 0.19 0.05
On each day indicated, implied standard deviation (ISD), skewness (ISK), and kurtosis (IKT) parameters are
estimated from one-day lagged price observations. Theoretical option prices are then calculated using these
out-of-sample implied parameters. All observations correspond to call options traded in December 1993
and expiring in May 1994.
81Skewness and kurtosis implied by stock option prices
4.3 Higher order moment estimates
It might appear that price adjustments beyond skewness and kurtosis could add
further improvements to the procedures specified above. For example, higher
order analogues to the terms Q3and Q4, say Q5and Q6, could be used to
augment the estimation procedure specified in equation (6). Unfortunately,
including additional terms creates severe collinearity problems since all even-
numbered subscripted terms, e.g. Q4and Q6, are highly correlated with each
other. Similarly, all odd-numbered subscripted terms, e.g. Q3and Q5, are also
highly correlated. Consequently, adding higher order terms leads to severely
unstable parameter estimates.
4.4 Further empirical results
We also applied all procedures leading to Tables 1 and 2 to options data for
three other stocks: International Business Machines (IBM), Micron Technology
(MU) and Paramount Communications Inc. (PCI). Table 3 summarizes results
obtained from option price data for these three stocks by reporting monthly
averages for all variables reported in Tables 1 and 2. Specifically, panel A in
Table 3 summarizes results obtained from the Black–Scholes formula. Similarly,
panel B in Table 3 summarizes results obtained from the skewness- and kurtosis-
Table 3. Comparison of theoretical option prices and observed option prices
Panel A: Black–Scholes model
Ticker
Number
of price
observations
Implied
standard
deviation
(%)
Average
call price
($)
Average
bid–ask
spread
($)
Proportion of
theoretical
prices outside
the bid–ask
spread
Average
deviation of
theoretical prices
from spread
boundaries ($)
IBM 276 30.89 6.13 0.29 0.57 0.11
MU 342 59.32 7.42 0.24 0.54 0.09
PCI 114 24.11 6.41 0.32 0.76 0.23
Panel B: Skewness- and kurtosis-adjusted model
Date
Number
of price
observations
Implied
standard
deviation
(%)
Implied
skewness
(ISK)
Implied
kurtosis
(IKT)
Proportion of
theoretical
prices outside
the bid–ask
spread
Average
deviation of
theoretical prices
from spread
boundaries ($)
IBM 276 32.39 –0.52 4.14 0.35 0.06
MU 342 61.58 –0.32 3.44 0.37 0.06
PCI 114 26.07 –1.09 5.27 0.48 0.13
Monthly averages of Black–Scholes implied standard deviation (BSISD), and implied standard deviation
(ISD), skewness (ISK), and kurtosis (IKT) parameters estimated daily from intraday price observations.
Theoretical option prices are calculated using out-of-sample implied parameters.
82 Corrado and Su
adjusted Black–Scholes formula. Each row in Table 3 reports monthly averages
for each stock.
Empirical results reported in Table 3 are qualitatively similar to results
reported in Tables 1 and 2. In particular, option-implied estimates of skewness
are all negative, ranging from –0.32 to –1.09, and estimates of kurtosis are all
greater than 3, ranging from 3.44 to 5.27. Table 3 also reports that adjustments
for skewness and kurtosis reduce substantially the proportions of theoretical
option prices lying outside observed bid–ask spreads and the average devia-
tions of theoretical prices from bid–ask spread boundaries.
Figures 3, 4 and 5 contain volatility skews for International Business Machines
(IBM), Micron Technology (MU) and Paramount Communications Inc. (PCI),
respectively. In all figures, horizontal axes measure option moneyness where
negative (positive) moneyness corresponds to in-the-money (out-of-the-money)
options with low (high) strike prices and vertical axes measure implied
Fig. 3. Implied volatilities for International Business Machines (IBM)
Fig. 4. Implied volatilities for Micron Technology (MU)
83Skewness and kurtosis implied by stock option prices
standard deviation values. Solid black markers represent Black–Scholes implied
volatilities and hollow markers represent implied volatilities calculated from
skewness- and kurtosis-adjusted option prices. Figures 3, 4 and 5 all reveal that
CBOE market makers quote deep in-the-money (out-of-the-money) call option
prices at a premium (discount) to Black–Scholes formula prices. Moreover,
implied volatilities from skewness- and kurtosis-adjusted option prices (hollow
markers) are unrelated to option moneyness, implying that corresponding price
deviations are also unrelated to option moneyness.
5. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
We have empirically tested an expanded version of the Black–Scholes (1973)
option pricing model suggested by Corrado and Su (1996) that accounts for
skewness and kurtosis deviations from normality in stock return distributions.
The expanded model was applied to estimate coefficients of skewness and
kurtosis implied by stock option prices. Relative to a normal distribution, we
found significant negative skewness and positive excess kurtosis in the
distributions of four actively traded stock prices. In summary, we conclude that
skewness- and kurtosis-adjustment terms added to the Black–Scholes formula
yield significantly improved accuracy for pricing deep in-the-money or deep out-
of-the-money stock options.
REFERENCES
Barone-Adesi, G. and Whaley, R.E (1986) The valuation of American call options and the
expected ex-dividend stock price decline, J. Financial Economics, 17, 91–111.
Black, F. and Scholes, M. (1973) The pricing of options and corporate liabilities, J.
Political Economy, 81, 637–59.
Black, F. (1975) Fact and fantasy in the use of options, Financial Analysts Journal, 31,
36–72.
Fig. 5. Implied volatilities for Paramount Communications Inc. (PCI)
84 Corrado and Su
Corrado, C.J. and Su, T. (1996) Skewness and kurtosis in S&P 500 Index returns implied
by option prices, J. Financial Research, 19, 175–92.
Hull, J.C. (1993) Options, Futures, and Other Derivative Securities. Englewood Cliffs, NJ.
Prentice Hall.
Merton, R.C. (1973) The theory of rational option pricing, Bell Journal of Economics and
Management Science, 4, 141–83.
Nattenburg, S. (1994) Option Volatility and Pricing, Chicago: Probus Publishing.
Stuart, A. and Ord, J.K. (1987) Kendall’s Advanced Theory of Statistics, New York: Oxford
University Press.
Whaley, R.E. (1982) Valuation of American call options on dividend paying stocks, J.
Financial Economics, 10, 29–58.
85Skewness and kurtosis implied by stock option prices
... The study of the IV curves and the IV surfaces has been deeply analysed in the last decades. Corrado and Tie (1997) focuses on the relation between the skewness and kurtosis of the underlying and of the IV. Skiadopoulos et al. (2000) applies the principal component analysis to identify those components that better explain the IV smiles. ...
Article
Full-text available
This work aims at studying the impact of the SARS-CoV-2 pandemic on the global financial markets. In particular, such impact is analysed through the changes of the shape of the implied volatility smile of the options written on several equity indexes and on several stocks. The implied volatility function is estimated using the market-based information of liquid options and applying a semi-parametric smoothing technique that exploits a kernel function and no-arbitrage conditions. Such approach is applied to an extensive set of data to study the evolution of the implied volatility functions through the months of the pandemic. We show, in several cases, a sudden and massive change in the shape of the implied volatility functions.
... However, the model postulates normally distributed returns and it also restricts the volatility to be constant with respect to strike values. Some modifications to account for non-normally distributed returns are proposed, for instance, in Corrado and Su (1997). In practice, however, the market agents adjust the former assumption changing the latter and an increasing volatility is quoted for strikes far from the current value of the underlying asset. ...
Preprint
Full-text available
This paper focuses on market changes due to exogenous effects. The standard implied volatility is shown to be insufficient for a proper detection and analysis of this type of risk. This is mainly because such changes are usually dominated by endogenous effects coming from a specific trading mechanism or a natural market dynamics. A unique methodological approach based on artificial options that always have a constant (over time) maturity is proposed and explicitly defined. The key principle is to use interpolated volatilities that can effectively eliminate instabilities due to the natural market dynamics while the changes caused by the exogenous causes stay preserved. Formal statistical tests for distinguishing significant effects are proposed under different theoretical and practical scenarios. Statistical theory, computational and algorithmic details, and comprehensive empirical comparisons together with a real data illustration are all presented in the paper.
... Hull (1993) and Nattenburg (1994) point out that stock returns exhibit nonnormal skewness and kurtosis and that volatility skews are a consequence of empirical violations of the normality assumption. Corrado and Su (1996) develop a method to incorporate option price adjustments for nonnormal skewness and kurtosis in an expanded Black-Scholes option pricing formula. Their method adapts a Gram-Charlier series expansion of the standard normal density function to yield an option price formula that is the sum of a Black-Scholes option price plus adjustment terms for nonnormal skewness and kurtosis. ...
... Troster [42,43] shows that while a mean-causality relationship must impact at least a significant number of quantiles in order to indicate causality; a tail (extreme event) causal relation does not necessarily imply a causality in the mean. Given the absence of normal (Gaussian) distribution in the time series under examination, nonlinear models such as quantile autoregression and quantile causality are preferable to adequately account for the asymmetric impact of uncertainty on the ethanol and palm oil markets studied [44]. And so, rather than only testing for the basic necessary conditions for Granger-causality, we analyze the full continuous space of conditional quantile functions in the distribution. ...
... Troster [42,43] shows that while a mean-causality relationship must impact at least a significant number of quantiles in order to indicate causality; a tail (extreme event) causal relation does not necessarily imply a causality in the mean. Given the absence of normal (Gaussian) distribution in the time series under examination, nonlinear models such as quantile autoregression and quantile causality are preferable to adequately account for the asymmetric impact of uncertainty on the ethanol and palm oil markets studied [44]. And so, rather than only testing for the basic necessary conditions for Granger-causality, we analyze the full continuous space of conditional quantile functions in the distribution. ...
Article
We investigate the impact of geopolitical risk, U.S. economic policy uncertainty, financial stress, and market volatility on prices of U.S. and Brazilian ethanol and Malaysian palm oil. We use quantile autoregressive and quantile causality methods and provide evidence of ethanol and palm oil prices being asymmetrically influenced in the downside and upside by each of the uncertainty measures considered. Malaysian palm oil prices are more attuned to increases in uncertainty measures. Increases rather than decreases in uncertainty more strongly impact ethanol and palm oil prices. Uncertainty causes large negative price fluctuations in the biofuel commodities, while moderate uncertainty changes only moderately influence prices. Large uncertainty increases cause large or extreme positive changes in ethanol and palm oil prices. Implications of the results are discussed.
Article
Full-text available
Model Black-Scholes merupakan salah satu model untuk menentukan harga opsi tipe Eropa dengan asumsi return dari saham harus berdistribusi normal. Pada kenyataannya return saham tidak mengikuti bentuk distribusi normal, dimana artinya skewness dan kurtosis saham tidak sama dengan 0 dan 3. Untuk mengatasi ketidaknormalan dari return saham dilakukan modifikasi model Black-Scholes dengan ekspansi Gram-Charlier dengan pendekatan polynomial untuk mengatasi bentuk data yang tidak berdistribusi normal. Harga opsi dengan ekspansi Gram-Charlier dipengaruhi oleh beberapa faktor yakni harga saham awal (), harga kontrak (), tingkat suku bunga bebas risiko (), waktu jatuh tempo (), volatilitas ( ), skewness dan kurtosis. Hasil dari studi menunjukkan bahwa dengan penentuan harga opsi dengan menggunakan metode Gram-Charlier sedikit lebih mendekati harga pasar dari pada menggunakan model Black-Scholes.Kata Kunci: Call option, Black-Scholes, Ekspansi Gram-Charlier, polinomial Hermite, kurtosis
Article
As a result of rapid socioeconomic development, the world is facing the simultaneous challenges of environmental pollution and resource depletion. How to promote the development of renewable, non-polluting energy is therefore essential. This could be achieved by supporting the rapid growth of a renewable energy financial market that includes various derivatives. To support such an effort, we designed an option contract model based on a renewable energy price index using data from the current development status of energy financial markets. To construct a renewable energy price index, we chose the daily electricity price value from the Nord Pool exchange system from January 2017 to August 2019. Next, we used an auto-regressive integrated moving average (ARIMA) model to predict this price index and estimate the model's parameters. We then used the true value and the predicted value for Nord Pool to perform Monte Carlo simulation pricing for electricity price index options in September 2019, and calculated the relative error. We found that the option contract's design for the renewable energy price index was designed reasonably. The ARIMA model predicted the renewable electricity price index accurately, and the Monte Carlo simulation pricing was reasonable and practical. The option contract for renewable energy price index can effectively explore the energy financial markets varieties and promote the global development of renewable energy sources.
Comparisons are made of the Chicago Board of Options Exchange (CBOE) skew index with those derived from parametric skews of bilateral gamma models and from the differentiation of option implied characteristic exponents. Discrepancies can be due to strike discretization in evaluating prices of powered returns. The remedy suggested employs a finer and wider set of strikes obtaining additional option prices by interpolation and extrapolation of implied volatilities. Procedures of replicating powered return claims are applied to the fourth power and the derivation of kurtosis term structures. Regressions of log skewness and log excess kurtosis on log maturity confirm the positivity of decay in these higher moments. The decay rates are below those required by processes of independent and identically distributed increments.
Article
Advanced stochastic approaches are often suggested as a solution to real-world derivative pricing inconsistencies like the non-linearity of the implied volatility smile. Using a novel high-frequency data set with over one million option trades and corresponding order books from the German market, we compare the normal distribution approach with a variance gamma process, which is – as a pure jump process – especially suitable for tick-by-tick data. We are able to report a flattened implied volatility smile with the variance gamma process. Other low-frequency results like time, information, and underlying moment dependencies for both stochastic processes are unchanged. All in-sample residuals of the normal distribution have a smaller variance below the 1% significance level compared to the variance gamma process. Additionally, we reveal a mean-reversion process. We show that the normal distribution is superior to the variance gamma process in an out-of-sample context and conclude that – even in a high-frequency environment – it is still “a country for old distributions”.
Article
Full-text available
With this study, we present a comparative analysis of the methodology and performance of three probability models for European style options evaluation. The differences in the calculation formulas and-in particular-the value factors for the option premium, included in the Black&Scholes, Corrado&Su and Boness models are highlighted. We test the three models empirically, comparing the results obtained from their application with the actual realized option premium. We apply statistics metods: absolut error (BIAS), quadratic error (SE), percentage error (PE) and average percentage error (APE), which determine models efficiency by the deviations recorded between the actual option premium and the price calculated, using the models applied. The empirical base includes thirteen call and thirteen put options, traded on the EURONEXT and based on shares of stock companies in Germany, France and the Netherlands. The results of the Corrado&Su model show the best and relatively reliable evaluation for calls. The call option results of the Black&Scholes model deviate more, and those of the Boness model are even weaker and can not be considered as reliable. The obtained distribution of the results of the three probability models proves the importance of the lognormal distribution of the price of the underlying shares, as well as of the asymmetry and excess in the valuation of call options. The Corrado&Su model gave equal reliability in evaluating both, call and put options. In general, each of the models gives some overestimation for most contracts, which is more common in put options.
Article
Full-text available
Author begins by deducing a set of restrictions on option pricing formulas from the assumption that investors prefer more to less. These restrictions are necessary conditions for a formula to be consistent with a rational pricing theory. Attention is given to the problems created when dividends are paid on the underlying common stock and when the terms of the option contract can be changed explicitly by a change in exercise price or implicitly by a shift in the investment or capital structure policy of the firm. Since the deduced restrictions are not sufficient to uniquely determine an option pricing formula, additional assumptions are introduced to examine and extend the seminal Black-Scholes theory of option pricing. Explicit formulas for pricing both call and put options as well as for warrants and the new ″down-and-out″ option are derived. Other results.
Article
This study focuses on the ex-dividend stock price decline implicit within the valuation of American call options on dividend-paying stocks. The Roll (1977) American call option pricing formula and the observed structure of CBOE call option transaction prices are used to infer the expected ex-dividend stock price decline as a proportion of the amount of the dividend. The relative decline is shown to be not meaningfully different from one, confirming some recent evidence from studies which examined stock prices in the days surrounding ex-dividend.
Article
This paper examines the pricing performance of the valuation equation for American call options on stocks with known dividends and compares it with two suggested approximation methods. The approximation obtained by substituting the stock price net of the present value of the escrowed dividends into the Black-Scholes model is shown to induce spurious correlation between prediction error and (1) the standard deviation of stock return, (2) the degree to which the option is in-the-money or out-of-the-money, (3) the probability of early exercise, (4) the time to expiration of the option, and (5) the dividend yield of the stock. A new method of examining option market efficiency is developed and tested.
Article
The Black-Scholes (1973) model frequently misprices deep-in-the-money and deep-out-of-the-money options. Practitioners popularly refer to these strike price biases as volatility smiles. In this paper we examine a method to extend the Black-Scholes model to account for biases induced by nonnormal skewness and kurtosis in stock return distributions. The method adapts a Gram-Charlier series expansion of the normal density function to provide skewness and kurtosis adjustment terms for the Black-Scholes formula. Using this method, we estimate option-implied coefficients of skewness and kurtosis in S&P 500 stock index returns. We find significant nonnormal skewness and kurtosis implied by option prices.