ArticlePDF Available

Heads and tails: both sides of the coin: an analysis of hybrid organizations in the Dutch waste management sector

Authors:

Abstract

In this thesis, Philip Marcel Karré argues that hybridity can only be fully understood and managed when one considers both sides of the coin, and sees benefits and risks as each other’s flipsides. By analyzing hybrid organizations in the Dutch waste management sector, he develops a perspective on hybridity that can be used by policy makers, professionals and academics to pinpoint those dimensions that could produce benefits or risks. Karré argues that hybridity is neither a catastrophe nor a panacea, but that it needs to be managed properly. The biggest challenge will be to prove in every single case that the expected opportunities created through hybridity far outweigh the costs of controlling the risks it poses.
209
Summary Heads and tails: Both sides of the coin
Introduction: The Netherlands as a hybrid society
Different types of hybrid organizations
I began my research by indicating that there are several possible types of hybrid
organizations, depending on which corner of the societal triangle devised by, among
others, Van de Donk (2001) they originate. In what I refer to as the hybrid realm and
Billis (2010) describes as nine hybrid zones, organizations can be found that originate
from either the state, the market or the community and which can be defined as
‘hetero-geneous arrangements, characterized by mixtures of pure and incongruous
origins, (ideal)types, “cultures”, “coordination mechanisms”, “rationalities”, or
“action logics”.’ (Brandsen et al., 2005, p. 750)
Examples of hybrid organizations originating from the community are the
environmental movement, trade unions, grassroots organizations in communities and
local mutual forms of insurance. The Dutch East India Company, a chartered company
with its own army and territorial sovereignty, is an example of a hybrid organization
originating from the market place. And quangos, or quasi-autonomous non-
governmental organizations, such as contract agencies, public bodies, voluntary of
charitable organizations that receive public funding and state-owned enterprises, are
examples of hybrid organizations originating from the state. The last is the type of
hybrid organizations I examined in my doctoral thesis.
Transitions in Dutch public service provision
When I looked into the history of public service provision in The Netherlands, I
came to the conclusion that the border between the realm of the state and the market
place was never strict and impenetrable, but always rather fuzzy, porous as well as
shifting over time, adjusting to societal and political preferences, necessities but also
fads and fashions. The country therefore has a long and rich tradition of producing and
using hybrid organizations in the delivery of public goods. Many of them were
established in the middle of the 19th century at the initiative of socially concerned
citizens, religious or ideological groups or entrepreneurs and later nationalised
(Brandsen et al., 2006a; Delden & Veraart, 2001; R. in ’t Veld, 2005; Veenendaal,
2004). By the 1980s, the Netherlands not only had one of the biggest public sectors in
Western Europe but also a high rate of unemployment and a gigantic national debt. To
tackle this crisis, state-owned companies were privatized. But the impact of this
210
operation was rather limited, as direct state intervention in industry was limited
compared to other European countries (Parris et al., 1987).
During the 1990s attempts were made to improve the service provision of public
sector organizations by introducing private sector management techniques and by
autonomizing agencies providing public services (Barzelay, 2001; Hood, 1991; Lane,
2000; Van Thiel, 2000; Walsh, 1995). In The Netherlands this New Public
Management (Osborne & Gaebler, 1992) was not inspired by ideas to hollow out the
state but rather by the belief that modern management techniques would make public
sector organizations more flexible and perform better. The managerialism in public
services had some positive effects but was also criticized as not being in tune with the
special characteristics of the public sector. Governance, the new main driving force for
Dutch public sector reform since the turn of the millennium, tries to address this
criticism (Pierre & Peters, 2000; Rhodes, 1997). It is based on the belief that the
wicked problems our network society faces can not be tackled by only one agency but
rather ask for a multi-stakeholder approach in which not only government but also
other actors, such as businesses, participate (Löffler, 2003). In this philosophy hybrid
organizations have an important function as boundary spanners.
A black and white and typically Dutch debate
In this dissertation I mainly focus on hybrid organizations in The Netherlands and
the Dutch discussion on hybridity. However, this does not imply that it is an
exclusively Dutch topic. All over the world various forms of hybrid organizations are
discussed from several theoretical and practical perspectives. But also on the
international level, there so far is no systematic body of research on hybrid
organizations.
In the United States, research on hybrid organizations is for example conducted by
Koppell (2003) who examined FannyMae and FreddyMac, two organizations now
linked to the credit crunch. In Germany, mixing public and private is seen as a means
to create a strong and robust civil society (referred to as Bürgergesellschaft or
Zivilgesellschaft) (cf. Evers et al., 2002; Meyer & Weil, 2002). International
organizations interested in the effects of hybridity include the OECD, which not only
discussed its effects on competition law and policy (OECD, 2004) but has also
developed guidelines on corporate governance of state-owned enterprises (OECD,
2005). And hybrid organizations are also mentioned in the organizational studies
literature that deals with the differences between ideal-typical public and private
organizations (see for example Emmert & Crow, 1988; Perry & Rainey, 1988; Rainey,
1997; Rainey & Chun, 2007), as well as in the literature about partnerships and
alliances between different organizations (see for an overview of this literature
Skelcher, 2005).
211
While there is international interest in hybridity, there is one characteristic that
distinguishes the Dutch debate from that in other countries. Whereas mixing public and
private is seen by many international commentators as a means to create a new form of
society or a new, more social kind of entrepreneurialism and to relieve the tax burden,
most Dutch commentators view hybridity as some sort of pollution which leads to
impure organizations that do not resemble ideal-typical ideas of what public and
private organizations should look like.
To a relative outsider this is in some ways difficult to comprehend, given the long
tradition and, arguably, success story of hybrid organizations in the Netherlands. But it
also means that the Dutch debate is an ideal starting point for an analysis of what
actually happens when a hybrid organization mixes public and private.
Research questions and outline
The following general research question is addressed in this dissertation: How do
hybrid organizations function in practice and what are the effects of their hybridity?
This general research question can be divided into five specific research questions, two
of an analytical and three of a more empirical nature.
The first analytical research question aims at providing a more nuanced definition
of hybridity and therefore is: On which dimensions can an organization be hybrid? The
second analytical research question is: What could be positive and negative effects of
hybridity? It aims at providing an overview of the various hypotheses mentioned in the
literature already available on hybrid organizations about what the positive and
negative effects of hybridity could be.
My three empirical research questions aim at describing hybridity and its effects in
organizational practice. My first empirical research question is: In which ways is the
case organization hybrid? My second empirical research question aims at describing
the effects their hybrid status had on my three case organizations. It is: Which positive
and negative effects of hybridity can be observed in the case study and how are these
dealt with? My third, and final, empirical research question is: What do the findings of
this study say about the overall viability of hybrid organizations?
My dissertation consists of ten chapters. After the introductory first chapter, chapter
2 describes the dichotomy between public and private and the differences between
agencies and enterprises as ideal-typical public and private organizations. It also
contains an overview of the various organizational dimensions on which organizations
can be classified as being public, private and hybrid.
Chapter 3 describes the hypotheses brought forward in the Dutch debate on hybrid
organization concerning the positive and negative effects of hybridity. In chapter 4
I outline my research strategy and specify my empirical research questions, based on
212
the answers of my two analytical research questions. Chapter 5 contains a description
of the Dutch waste management sector and the public, private and hybrid organizations
that operate in it. Its aim is to set the scene for my three case studies from this sector.
Chapters 6 through 8 contain my individual case studies and chapter 9 a comparison of
the three cases. And finally chapter 10 consists of my conclusions as well as
recommendations and ends with ideas for further research.
Defining hybrid organizations – Dimensions of hybridity
Public versus private as a normative dichotomy
The distinction between public and private is one of the most important dichotomies
of Western political thought (Bobbio, 1989) and has been so since antiquity. It divides
our world into two exhaustive and mutually exclusive spheres, subsumes all other
distinctions and makes them secondary (Weintraub & Kumar, 1997).
Since it has been at the core of our understanding of the world around us for such a
long time already, the grand dichotomy seems to be straightforward. But it is not
unitary but protean. Different definitions of public and private are possible (Geuss,
2001). As it determines what is perceived to be acceptable in which context and what is
not, the public-private dichotomy has a very normative character.
In the Dutch discussion about hybrid organizations the dichotomy between public
and private is most commonly defined as the one between state and market. This is
therefore also the definition employed in this dissertation.
Patterns of government-market interrelations
The normative character of the dichotomy of public versus private means that we
should handle it with care (Geuss, 2001). As it juxtaposes two ideal-types, the
dichotomy remains useful for normative discussions, but seems less relevant as a
descriptive tool, as there are now (and always have been) complex relations and
interplay between government and market (Dahl & Lindblom, 1953; Rainey, 1997;
Rainey & Chun, 2007).
Examples are (1) the emergence of several hybrid forms of organization, such as the
quangos described in this dissertation, (2) the complex interrelations between
government and business organizations through contracting out and other forms of
partnerships (cf. Skelcher, 2005) and (3) the various functional analogies that exist
between public and private organizations, as many specialists perform the same general
functions regardless of the kind of sector their organizations operate in.
In the light of these examples of interrelations between state and market, the
distinction between public and private is (at least in most of academia if not by the
213
general public) commonly seen as not a dichotomy but as a continuum of several
dimensions.
Ideal-typical public and private organizations
A first step in the construction of this continuum is to define its poles. I do this by
describing Dahl & Lindblom’s agency and enterprise and Simon’s task and market
organization as ideal-typical public and private organizations.
Dahl and Lindblom (1953) make a distinction between agencies as ideal-typical
governmental organizations on the one hand and enterprises, or ideal-typical business
firms, on the other (cf. Rainey, 1997, pp. 61-3; Rainey & Chun, 2007, pp. 75-6).
Agencies are subject to polyarchy (or governmental authority) which is based on
centralized rules and authoritative directions as the broad mode for organizing
economic and social activity. Economic markets are the alternative of polyarchy, and
the mode of social control determining the actions of enterprises, which grant
individuals a larger degree of choice about their transactions and relations.
This distinction between agencies and enterprises resembles that between task and
market organizations, which Simon, an influential voice in the Dutch debate about
hybridity (cf. chapter 3), developed in his dissertation (Simon, 1989). Task
organizations, on the one hand, are ideal-typical governmental organizations which are
heteronymous, as they are controlled by a superior body through authoritative
directions. They have what Simon calls a capacity function, as they produce goods and
services to the specifications of the principal. Market organizations on the other hand
are ideal-typical business firms. They are autonomous, as they lack a clear principal,
and have what Simon calls a product function, as they produce goods and services to
their own design.
Differences between public and private organizations
Many authors have refined the distinctions between ideal-typical public and private
organizations made by, among others, Dahl and Lindblom as well as Simon, by
contrasting agencies and enterprises with one another. Rainey & Chun (2007) have
drawn up a list of distinguishing characteristics of agencies as compared to enterprises
by summarizing the literature already written on this subject.
According to Rainey and Chun, agencies differ from enterprises with regard to their
environment, their organization-environment transactions and their organizational
roles, structures and processes.
The first set of possible differences concerns the setting or environment agencies
operate in. They lack economic markets for their outputs and rely on governmental
appropriations for their financial resources. Compared to enterprises, agencies operate
214
under greater external control by politically constituted authority and have to deal to a
greater extent with the presence of elaborate and intensive formal legal constraints as a
result of oversight by various branches of government as well as courts. A final
distinctive environmental factor distinguishing ideal-typical task from ideal-typical
market organizations, concerns the presence of more intensive external political
influences in the public sector. Agencies not only have to deal with greater political
influences on their decisions, they also are in greater need to acquire political support
for their actions from various other stakeholders, such as client groups and
constituencies.
A second set of differences between ideal-typical task and market organizations
refers to the nature of their interactions with their environment. Agencies often produce
public goods, which means that their outputs are not readily transferable to economic
markets at a market prize. Their activities are also often coercive, monopolistic and
unavoidable, given the unique sanctioning and coercive power of government as the
sole provider. They also often have a broader impact and greater symbolic significance
than the activities of ideal-typical enterprises, which leads to greater public scrutiny of
public managers and unique expectations concerning good governance, based on ideal-
typical public values such as fairness, responsiveness, honesty, openness, and
accountability.
A final set of differences between ideal-typical agencies and enterprises relates to
roles, structures and processes. Ideal-typical public organizations have to deal with
greater ambiguity, multiplicity and conflict than their private counterparts. Ideal-typical
public managers for a start have to play more political, expository roles than private
managers, which results in a greater challenge to balance external political relations
with internal management functions. They also have less decision making authority as
most important decisions about their organizations are made by politics. Ideal-typical
agencies are said to have more red tape and more elaborate bureaucratic structures than
agencies and are also said to be driven by different sets of organizational values.
It is worth elaborating on this, as the alleged differences in culture between the
public and the private sector and the tensions expected from mixing them, were a
central topic in the Dutch debate about hybrid organizations, especially based on
Jacob’s book SYSTEMS OF SURVIVAL (1992).
Jacobs distinguishes between two different ‘ethical systems’ or ‘moral syndromes’, a
commercial and a guardian one (Jacobs, 1992, pp. 23-4). Both are driven by different
sets of values. In the ethical system of the guardian, trading and other commercial
activities are shunned. It is a culture which thrives on tradition, obedience, discipline,
hierarchy and loyalty and in which expert knowledge gives power. The guardian
syndrome also has its dark side. Vengeance and deception are permitted, as long as
215
they are in the sake of the task at hand or, to put it differently, in the public interest.
Other values, which are not necessarily virtues but are core to the guardian syndrome,
are the rich use of leisure (or laziness, if one wants to be cruel), ostentation, exclusivity
and fatalism. Honour, largesse and fortitude also are important.
In the commercial moral syndrome the use of force is shunned. This culture is all
about cooperation, honesty and the abiding of contracts, as well as about competition,
initiative and enterprise, innovation and efficiency. Comfort and convenience are
important too, as are industry, thrift and optimism. It is alright to disagree as long as
that serves the task at hand. Financial investments are aimed at increasing productivity.
Dimensions of hybridity
Having defined the extremes of the public-private continuum as the agency and the
enterprise, I turned to models that arrange the different forms of organization in
between these two poles. Some of these models only use one dimension to range
organizations, while others are multidimensional.
I constructed the multidimensional continuum used in this study to describe the
hybrid character of my case organizations by synthesizing some of those already
available (Bozeman, 1987; Dahl & Lindblom, 1953; Fottler, 1981; Perry & Rainey,
1988; Van Thiel, 2000; Wamsley & Zald, 1973).
My version of the continuum between the agency and the enterprise (which is also
based on Algemene Rekenkamer, 2005) consists of ten dimensions that I clustered for
clarity’s sake into the following three groups: (1) structure and activities, (2) values
and strategy and (3) governance and politics.
The dimensions in the cluster structure and activities tell us more about the principal
as well as about the activities of the organization. They are:
- Legal form: this dimension deals with the degree to which an organization’s legal
form is governed by public or by private law.
- Ownership: this is the continuum between full governmental and full private
ownership.
- Activities: this is the continuum between a complete focus on statutory or public
tasks and one on private, commercial activities.
- Funding: this is the continuum between 100% governmental appropriation and
100% private funding.
- Market environment: this is the continuum between a monopolistic and a
competitive market environment.
The dimensions in the cluster strategy and culture deal with questions concerning
the organization’s overall strategic outlook and its value system. They are:
216
- Strategic orientation: the continuum between a strategic orientation totally aimed at
government and one totally aimed at the market.
- Value orientation: the continuum between a total orientation on the public values
of the guardian syndrome and a total orientation on the values of the commercial
syndrome.
The dimensions summarised in the cluster governance and politics deal with the
question of how the organization’s relationship with its public principal(s) looks like
and to which degree it possesses autonomy, both managerial as well as executive. They
are:
- Relationship with political principal: the continuum between a relationship based
on public and one on private law.
- Managerial autonomy: the continuum between political autonomy (a system in
which the management of an organization is influenced by politics) and economic
autonomy (a system in which the management of an organization is influenced by
the market).
- Executive autonomy: on this dimension I score whether an organization has little
or much autonomy in how it conducts its activities or to use Simon’s taxonomy,
whether it rather has a capacity function or a product function.
In my case studies, I described how my three case organizations could be scored on
the ten dimensions at the time I studied them. I used a spider chart to illustrate each
organization’s hybridness by using the following scores: completely public (0), mostly
public (2), somewhat public (4), halfway between public & private (5), somewhat
private (6), mostly private (8) and completely private (10).
A hypothetical organization, represented as only a dot at the centre of the chart,
would be 100 % public on all of the dimensions listed above. As the surface area
grows, the organization becomes more private to the maximum of covering the full
chart, which represents an organization that scores 100 % private on all dimensions:
the ideal-typical enterprise.
In my case studies, I not only used the spider charts as a descriptive but also as an
indicative-diagnostic tool to point me to those dimensions on which an organization’s
new hybrid status could be expected to be either beneficial or hazardous.
The effects of hybridity – An anatomy of the Dutch debate
Three states in the scientific debate on hybridity
The Dutch debate on hybrid organizations can roughly be divided into three stages
(Brandsen & Karré, 2010). During the first period, which about covers the 1990s,
217
several public agencies were autonomized and managerialism was introduced in public
service provision. Topics for discussion during this era were how to manage and
regulate these new autonomized organizations. Most commentators saw hybridity as a
nuisance as it made it more complicated for government to exert control on
organizations that operated at arm’s length. Hybridity was, in other words, seen by
many as a dangerous force undermining the primacy of politics.
During the second period, which spanned the first decade of the 21st century, hybrid
organizations had become a fait accompli. Besides being vilified by some, they now
were embraced by others, especially as the governance trend set in. Organizations in
the Third Sector were rediscovered as agents in the provision of public services. In
much of the literature dealing with hybridity from this angle, a certain nostalgia can be
read for the times when not government but the Third Sector was in charge of
providing many essential public services.
More recently hybrid organizations have become mainstream. The (scientific, if not
political and societal) debate about hybridity now focuses less on normative ideas but
rather on how hybrid organizations function in practice. This doctoral thesis can be
seen as part of this new trend in the debate on hybrid organizations.
In this debate two main arguments can be distinguished that oppose each other. I call
them the synergy and the corruption argument.
The synergy argument
Advocates of hybridity see hybrid organizations as effective boundary spanners that,
by bringing public and private together, create synergy and innovation, which leads to
economic, performance related, cultural and governance related benefits (Brandsen et
al., 2006b; Brandsen et al., 2005; Brandsen et al., 2005; Frissen, 2005; Meijerink,
2005; Van Montfort, 2008; Mouwen & Van Bijsterveld, 2000; Sociaal-Economische
Raad, 2005, 2010; R. in ’t Veld, 1995, 1997a, 1997b, 2003, 2005; Wetenschappelijke
Raad voor het Regeringsbeleid, 2004a).
- Economic benefits: Hybridity can benefit an organization’s financial and economic
position by for example getting access to new markets.
- Performance related benefits: Hybridity can also have a positive effect on an
organization’s performance, as it can serve as an incentive to increase effectivity.
- Cultural benefits: Hybridity is by its advocates seen as an incentive to combine the
best of both worlds by bringing the most prominent values of the public and the
private sector together. This, they expect, will help make public sector
organizations more customer-oriented.
218
- Governance related benefits Hybridity is by its advocates seen to have a positive
effect on an organization’s relationship with its political principals and, via these
representatives, also with society as a whole.
The corruption argument
Adversaries of hybrid organizations see introducing market elements into the
provision of public services as a form of corruption and warn that public interests will
not be able to hold their ground opposite commercial interests (Ankersmit & Klinkers,
2008; Gradus, 2005; De Jong, 1998; MDW-werkgroep markt en overheid, 1997;
Simon, 1989, 2005, 2008; Stevens, 1997, 1998). Hybridity leads in the critics’ view to
economic, performance related, cultural and governance related risks.
- Economic risks: These concern various forms of unfair competition, such as the
use of cross-subsidies, the use of confidential government data for commercial
means, the forming of public monopolies and the combination of conflicting roles.
- Performance related risks: Because of hybridity, the critics claim, organizations
will neglect their public tasks in favour of their commercial activities.
- Cultural risks: hybridity can lead to cultural conflicts as private sector values are
introduced which are commonly seen to be stronger than public sector values as
they are based on individual self-interests rather than on altruism. Conflicts can
arise when an organization attracts new employees with a commercial background
who (because of their expertise) earn more than its veteran staff.
- Governance related risks: Putting an organization at arm’s length and allowing it to
enter the market place, the critics claim, will lead to it developing an own identity
and opportunistic behaviour. As hybrid organizations mostly focus on their own
interests, they become less dependable partners for their political principals in the
provision of public services.
An evaluation of both approaches
The Dutch discussion on hybridity is peculiar on two counts. First, for most of its
course it was rather normative, as those believing in the benefits of hybridity were at
loggerheads with those that warned about its risks. Most arguments used both by
advocates and adversaries of hybrid organizations are based mainly on anecdotal
evidence and only for a limited part on scientifically collected and analysed empirical
data. Most of the discussion so far has centred about the question What do we have to
think about public organizations entering the market place? instead of on the more
fundamental question of What is actually happening when agencies start employing
commercial activities?
219
A second, quite intriguing peculiarity of the Dutch discussion is that opponents as
well as advocates of hybrid organization adopt a rather one-sided view. In their eyes,
hybridity will either have positive or negative effects, whereas I find they are often two
sides of the same coin. Each effect can be interpreted both as beneficial and as
hazardous depending on the author’s standpoint. The old adage, where one stands
depends on where one sits, also rings true here. Hybridity truly is a heads and tails
issue.
Research strategy
Literature overview and pilot study
My first step after deciding in 2002 that I wanted to research hybrid organizations,
was to conduct a literature review. The Dutch literature I found at this point proved
useful in understanding what the possible positive and negative effects of hybridity
might be, but lacked a firm conceptualisation of a hybrid organization. Concerning the
international literature I unearthed, I found much of the organizational sciences
literature and among this field especially those works dealing with the differences
between ideal-typical public and private organizations very useful for my own
understanding of the dimensions on which an organization could be a hybrid.
My literature overview gave me a first idea of what a hybrid organization might look
like and which positive and negative effects hybridity can produce. But it also made me
draw the conclusion that despite all the debate of the 1990s and afterwards our
understanding of hybrid organizations still is limited and, especially in a lot of the
Dutch literature on the subject, tainted by normative bias. That is why I decided not to
formulate and test hypothesis based on what I had learned in the literature, but rather to
develop a list of sensitizing concepts.
In 2004 I was fortunate to be able to test and add to my list of sensitizing concepts
by participating in a research project by the Netherlands Court of Audit on the benefits
and risks of public entrepreneurialism by three hybrid organizations. This project gave
me an invaluable insight in how hybrid organizations function in practice.
Case study research
Based on my experiences with the Court of Audit’s research project, I not only
added to my list of sensitizing concepts but also decided to use an exploratory case
study approach as research strategy. I based this decision on the idea that the Dutch
debate needed to be moved away from the ideological stalemate between advocates
and adversaries of the idea of hybridity, to a discussion about how hybridity effects
organizations in practice. This could, I was and am convinced, best be achieved by a
small number of in-depth case studies. Employing the case study method in my
220
research also seemed to be a good choice because of the research questions case studies
can answer (which are mostly, as are my own, how questions), the fact that I as a
researcher had no control over the phenomena I studied and that these were
contemporary, ongoing events (Yin, 1994).
After careful deliberations I opted against a cross-sectoral or even international
comparison. I made this decision in the belief that the differences between sectors as
well as political settings would make a comparison between case organizations more
difficult. This made it necessary to decide on a sector within which to conduct my
research as a first step in the selection process.
I decided to conduct my case studies in the waste management sector. This had two
main reasons. Firstly, there is a rich supply of organizations. Second, the organizations
in this sector have a researchable scale, which made it possible to include a whole
organization and not only parts or divisions of it in my research. Third, so far hardly
any research has been done on waste management organizations with a public
administration focus.
After several interviews, three hybrid waste management organizations were willing
to be my case studies. The first, which I gave the code name TOM to ensure its
anonymity, was the waste incineration and recycling plant of a big city. The second,
which I call DICK, was a company collecting waste on behalf of several smaller
municipalities in the west of the Netherlands. And the third, which I call HARRY, was a
waste collection and disposal company of one of the island areas of the Netherlands
Antilles.
At each organization, I gathered evidence from three sources: documentation,
interviews and direct observations. I composed an individual case study report for each
organization studied and discussed it with its chief executive. I also summarized my
findings and presented them to a panel of experts. This panel of experts consisted of
seven directors from waste management organizations. I asked them to reflect on my
observations and to tell me whether they sounded familiar to them. By doing so I also
collected data on how other waste management organizations dealt with hybridity,
though not on a level of detail comparable to my three individual case studies.
Validity issues
I dealt with possible validity issues by always using multiple sources of data,
combining documentation, interviews and (whenever possible) observations as sources
of evidence. Second, I strived to establish a chain of evidence by making it clear where
the data underlying my analyses came from. A third tactic I used was to ask every
interviewee to review the summary I made of our conversation and to alert me to
factual errors, misinterpretations and omissions. I did the same with my draft case
221
study reports, which I presented to the managing directors and my contact persons in
every organization.
Also the session with the managing directors of other waste management companies
mentioned above was aimed to make sure that what happened at my three case studies
was not unique to them but also representative to other organizations in the same
sector. I strived to achieve reliability by composing a case study protocol, which
included a list of the sensitizing concepts I paid attention to in all case studies. I also
developed electronic as well as analogue case study databases for my individual cases,
containing copies of all the materials collected during the cause of my research.
Hybrid organizations in Dutch waste management
Public and private interests
Waste management organizations fulfil very important tasks: the quality of their
services bears a direct connection to the state of our economy and our quality of life.
There are several public interests at stake in waste management, as it is generally
considered to be a an essential service to society. But taking care of our society’s trash
is big business too. Large internationally operating companies dominate the waste
management market, in which also many publicly owned companies participate. Until
recently the Dutch waste management sector was heavily regulated. It now has become
a dynamic market place.
Market segments
The waste management sector consists of several market segments. In my doctoral
thesis I mainly looked at two of them, the market for waste collection and the market
for waste disposal. Municipalities are obliged to ensure the collection of household
waste. In the past many municipalities did so by providing collection services
themselves but since then some have chosen to contract these services out to public and
private companies or to enter into a public private partnership with a commercial waste
management company. Municipalities are not obliged to collect industrial waste;
businesses have to take care of their waste themselves. Like municipalities in the
collection of household waste, they can choose from an array of arrangements. This
market segment is dominated by commercial and internationally active players.
The market for waste disposal (which in The Netherlands mainly means waste
incineration) is dominated by public companies.
Debate about hybridity
As in many other policy fields there also is a fierce debate in the waste management
sector about the commercial activities of hybrid organizations. Private waste
222
management companies regularly suspect them of unfair competition. Another
criticism often heard, concerns the fact that no tender is needed when a municipality
grants a contract to a public company it owns shares in. Commercial waste
management companies also argue that public companies use their protected status in
their home markets (their own municipalities) to win tenders elsewhere.
Managers from public waste management companies do not accept this criticism.
According to them there is no unfair competition and municipalities should be free to
also employ their own collection services if they wish to do so. They also claim that
their organizations pay more attention to the societal goals of the municipalities they
work for, compared to their private counterparts.
I find the debate about hybrid organizations in the Dutch waste management sector
remarkable on two grounds. First, also in this sector hybridity is a rather controversial
issue, with representatives of commercial and of hybrid waste management
organizations at loggerheads with each other about the possible effects of hybridity.
Many of the arguments they use seem to be based on hearsay and speculation but there
are hardly any hard verifiable facts. Independent research on what is actually
happening when hybrid organizations enter the market place seems to be needed.
Second, the old adage where one stands depends on where one sits is also true here.
There are many arguments in this discussion about possible positive and negative
effects of hybridity but they are all based on or tainted by the business interests of their
proponents. Again, this makes independent research necessary about what really
happens when hybrid waste management organizations enter the marketplace.
Conclusions of case study findings
History and background
Before they became hybrid organizations, my three case studies were traditional
public organizations or agencies, providing waste related services on behalf of a
government. TOM was a municipal enterprise, established to mainly burn the waste of
parties that had signed a covenant. Those were mostly municipalities but also included
one private waste management company which had its own facilities for storing waste.
This gave TOM the opportunity to compensate for fluctuations in the amount of
municipal waste. DICK was a group purchasing organization with the legal form of a
local joint venture that purchased capacity at an incineration facility on the behalf of
several municipalities. HARRY was the sanitation department of one of the island areas
of the Netherlands Antilles. Like TOM, HARRY also had some private customers. In
both cases these activities were merely a sideline and meant to support the activities the
organizations conducted for their public principals.
223
As agencies, TOM, DICK and HARRY had cultures dominated by values akin to those
of Jacobs’ guardian syndrome. They were hierarchical and bureaucratic organizations,
in which their operational staff played a leading role.
All three organizations provided their services to the specifications of politicians,
which were aldermen or the equivalent of this position. They were in turn responsible
for how the organizations fared to their respective legislative bodies, which were local
councils.
In the following sections I describe how the three organizations transformed due to
their new hybridness on these dimensions I identified earlier.
Developments on dimensions concerning structure and activities
All three of my case organizations had directors in charge who were not satisfied
with merely implementing the strategy set out for them and their organization by
politicians. They rather saw themselves as businessmen than as civil servants and were
eager to strengthen their organization’s position in the waste management market.
They were frustrated with the fact that the status of TOM, DICK and HARRY as parts of a
bureaucracy had led to inertia, making it impossible to react quickly to changing
market situations, as well as to citizens’ waste management needs in a flexible and
agile manner.
In all three cases, the initiative to grant the organization more autonomy and to run it
like a business, came from the managing director. In the case of DICK and HARRY this
involved putting the organizations at arm’s length. However, the politicians involved
were at first reluctant to do so. Both organizations were only autonomized after intense
lobbying by their managing directors.
In the case of TOM, similar doubts and fears made the alderman responsible for the
organization opt against an autonomization, but she still granted its managing director
more autonomy. This was achieved by labelling the organization a proactive service
provider, a hybrid of a traditional public service provider and a market organization.
In none of the cases did an increase in the autonomy of its managerial directors also
lead to a change in ownership of the organization. TOM and DICK were still owned by
municipalities and HARRY by the island area. There were no plans at any of the
organizations to change this.
Of all three of my case organizations only DICK did not yet provide services for
commercial customers, nor did it plan on doing so in the near future. However, this did
not mean that the organization did not have to operate in a competitive environment. In
contrast to the situation at TOM and HARRY, DICK’s shareholding municipalities were
not captive customers. This forced DICK to compete with other waste management
companies for their contracts.
224
So far only HARRY already conducted more activities for commercial customers than
before its autonomization. These were now not a sideline anymore but an increasingly
important source of income for the organization. In the case of TOM, most of the waste
it burnt still originated from municipalities. However, the municipal council had agreed
to nearly double TOM’s incineration capacity by constructing a new, highly innovative
plant, which was supposed to burn business waste only. TOM would now generate more
than 70 % of its turnover by burning waste delivered to its plant by commercial waste
management companies and by selling the electricity this created on the energy market.
Only a quarter of the organization’s turnover would then be generated by incinerating
municipal household waste.
With the new plant not only the share of TOM’s financial dependence on commercial
waste management companies would increase. So would the pressure of competition,
as all Dutch incineration plants were trying to get a big piece of the lucrative market
for incinerating business waste. It would also become more depended on the
developments on the commercial waste management market which is very cyclical.
Developments on dimensions concerning strategy and culture
The strategic outlook of all three organizations had changed. Their managing
directors no longer saw their organizations as mere executioners of a strategy devised
by politicians, aimed at providing goods and services to their exact specifications. They
now had the autonomy to make their own plans. The new strategy they followed was
more entrepreneurial, in the sense that the managing directors saw and managed TOM,
DICK and HARRY as businesses, with the strategic goal to grow and strengthen their
position in the waste management market.
One way of achieving this new strategic orientation was to bring new employees
with a commercial background into the organization, with the specific task to
professionalize the way it conducted its services, both on the managerial as well as on
the operational level. A second way to change TOM, DICK and HARRY into more
businesslike organizations was to tackle their organizational cultures, which, according
to several interviewees at each organization, were bureaucratic, hierarchical and not
businesslike. This included a new focus on values comparable to those of Jacobs’
commercial syndrome, such as initiative, enterprise and efficiency and had as an effect
that in all three organizations employees were now expected to work harder and longer.
Developments on dimensions concerning governance and politics
Their hybridness brought a change in governance for all three organizations. TOM
remained an agency on paper, with an alderman ultimately responsible for its actions,
but its managing director was granted more managerial and executive autonomy.
225
Contrary to TOM, DICK and HARRY were autonomized and the changes to their
governance arrangements therefore more radical. Their relationship with their public
principals, now the organizations’ shareholders, was based on private law rather than
public law. Their managing directors also had more managerial and executive
autonomy than TOM’s but still no full autonomy, as their decisions were subject to
oversight by not only the organization’s shareholders but also their supervisory boards.
These consisted of political appointees and non-politically appointed board members.
Their new hybrid status on these dimensions produced several positive and negative
effects for TOM, DICK and HARRY:
Economic effects of case organizations’ hybridness
The managing directors of TOM, DICK and HARRY described higher turnover and
profit as a positive economic effect of the new hybrid status of their organizations.
Their strategy to continue this positive trend was to stick to their entrepreneurial course
and to venture into new markets.
I indeed observed that all three organizations had increased both their turnover and
profit but find it difficult to share the directors’ enthusiasm, as the benefits of this
development often seemed to be limited to the organizations themselves. In TOM’s case
I was told that the organization used the revenues it generated from burning the waste
of commercial customers to subsidize its activities for the partners of the covenant,
mostly municipalities. But from the information available to me it was impossible to
tell whether TOM’s private activities really contributed to a low public tariff, as the
organization did not differentiate between takings from public and private sources in its
annual report.
Also in the case of DICK I find it difficult to verify positive economic effects. Its
increased turnover from the same customer base seems rather to indicate that these
customers had to pay more every year for the same services. DICK had no other
customers than its municipal shareholders and the dividends it paid out to them every
year were in reality nothing more than a restitution on an advance that turned out to be
higher than the actual cost. Whether this was due to increased efficiency or simply the
case because of an overpayment, can not be determined based on the data available to
me.
In HARRY’s case, its hybridity had made it immune from budget cuts by the island
area. This gave the organization more financial security to make long-term plans,
which in turn increased the organization’s stability. However, it also meant that the
government of the island area had to look at other public institutions when budget cuts
were necessary, as its choice was now limited. This might lead to a situation in which
226
other (and arguably more important) public services have their budgets cut, such as the
island area’s education or health services.
Another flipside of higher turnovers and profits as positive effects of hybridity, is
unfair competition. In my opinion, one could indeed speak of unfair competition in the
case of TOM, whose municipality had decided to build it a new, high-yield incineration
plant at a time when, according to interviewees at the organization, private companies
would shirk away from such an investment. The organization had another financial
advantage, as it was assured that it would be reimbursed by the signatories of the
covenant for any financial losses it made on the market place. This gave TOM in theory
carte blanche to operate less prudently on the market place than its private rivals. In
practice the organization had not yet suffered any losses and had not yet needed any
public financial subsidies.
In DICK’s case, European legislation was in the organization’s advantage, as it stated
that municipalities did not have to tender for waste collection if they were shareholders
of a waste management company. This was advantageous for DICK, as it could have
never won a tender based on price alone.
HARRY did not have much serious competition because of the special circumstances
of the island which made entering the market prohibitively expensive for any would-be
competitors. Because of this market failure HARRY had a near-natural monopoly and
there were no complaints of unfair competition.
Even though one can speak of unfair competition in the cases of TOM and DICK, I
am not sure whether this can be seen as an argument against their new hybrid status, as
it was not a disadvantage to society at large, but limited to commercial companies. In
TOM’s case it could be argued that it was positive that a municipality was willing to
invest in a clean and technically advanced incineration plant, while at the mean time
provide services at a price lower than any competitor could offer. In DICK’s case one
could argue that the organization did not do anything wrong but just used the
possibilities it was granted by European legislation.
Performance related effects of case organizations’ hybridness
Another strategic goal TOM, DICK and HARRY’s managing directors strived to
achieve with the hybridisation of their organizations was to create incentives to work in
a more professional and efficient manner. I was told that neither organization had been
terribly efficient as agencies, which according to my interviewees was due to two main
reasons. First of all, TOM, DICK and HARRY had been financed by a lump sum budget
in the past. This meant that they had lacked any incentive to save money by working
more efficiently. Another reason for their inefficient behaviour was a lack of
competition. The organizations only had captive public customers, who had no choice
227
but to have their waste processed by either TOM, DICK or HARRY. That meant that all
three organizations had guaranteed sales and had no incentive to excel.
From what I could observe in my three case studies, I am inclined to say that their
new hybrid status did indeed positively influence TOM, DICK and HARRY’s
performance. Their hybridity brought a change in funding. DICK and HARRY were now
no longer financed by lump sum, but rather on their output. TOM would also be funded
this way for burning commercial waste as soon as its new plant was operational. As
they could keep any money saved, this new way of funding stimulated the
organizations to increase their efficiency. In practice this meant that the employees of
all organizations were now expected to work longer and harder and save money.
As hybrid organizations, TOM, DICK and, to a lesser extent, HARRY also had to be
competitive, since they now had to outperform companies which were trying to
outperform them. The strategy their managing directors used to enhance TOM, DICK
and HARRY’s competitiveness was to professionalize the way they worked, partly by
bringing new employees with commercial backgrounds into their organizations. They
also embraced modern management techniques, such as performance management.
Also my case organizations’ positive performance related effects had their flipside,
at least for TOM and HARRY. Both organizations now had two kinds of customers:
captive, public customers, and private ones that were free to take their business
elsewhere. This made it tempting for the organizations to spend more attention on
private customers than on the public ones, as the latter were not going anywhere. TOM
was aware of this situation and already tried to react to it by engaging more with its
public customers to give them the idea that it valued their views and opinions the same
way as it did with its commercial customers.
Cultural effects of case organizations’ hybridness
A third goal the managing directors pursued through TOM, DICK and HARRY’s new
hybrid status, was to transform their organizations’ culture from one with the values of
the guardian syndrome to one with the values of the commercial syndrome. In my
opinion, only the cultural transition programme started by DICK’s managing director
had been successful. Even though they were expected to work harder and adhere to
more rules and procedures than before, DICK’s operational employees told me that they
appreciated these changes as they would make their organization sustainable and
future-proof. They also did not mind that there were strict rules regulating their work
and behaviour, as long as these rules applied to everyone and not only the operational
staff of the organization.
A possible flipside to the positive influence of new businesslike values on a hybrid
organization and its staff, are cultural clashes that can arise when one tries to combine
228
traditional public sector and traditional private sector values. I could witness this
negative effect in HARRY but especially at TOM.
TOM’s board put considerable time and energy into trying to change its political,
bureaucratic and task-focussed culture to the more entrepreneurial culture they
envisioned. This top-down cultural transformation project encountered the resistance of
the organization’s operational staff. TOM’s blue-collar workers interpreted the
directors’ claim that the organization had to be more professional and entrepreneurial
as a thinly-veiled criticism on their past performance. They saw their autonomy as a
source of pride, which was threatened by the introduction of strict rules and
procedures. Another source of conflict between TOM’s operational staff and its board
was the latter’s decision to bring new employees with commercial backgrounds into
the organization, which created jealousy and made the organization’s blue-collar staff
fear being marginalized.
Governance related effects of case organizations’ hybridness
A last reason why the managing directors of TOM, DICK and HARRY had lobbied
their public principals to allow them to run their organizations like businesses, was that
they expected positive governance related effects. They complained that as agencies,
their organizations had suffered from inertia, as their governance arrangements did not
facilitate the kind of quick decision-making they thought they needed in the market
place.
So far, only the governance arrangements of DICK and HARRY had been changed.
TOM remained a municipal organization but DICK and HARRY had already been
autonomized. Their public principals, municipalities in DICK’s case and an island area
in HARRY’s case, were now the organizations’ shareholders. I was told that in the past
both DICK’s municipalities as well as HARRY’s island area had not really been
interested in how the organizations conducted their services, which often meant crucial
decisions took a very long time. Their new hybrid status had not changed this. I
therefore have to conclude that DICK and HARRY’s new hybrid status had only a limited
positive effect on their relationships with their shareholders. In my opinion, the blame
for this situation has to be laid at the doorstep of both organizations’ shareholders who
failed to take their roles seriously.
A second change to DICK and HARRY’s governance arrangement was the
establishment of a supervisory board. The boards of both organizations had a number
of politically appointed members. The hybrid composition in my opinion rather led to
an undesirable situation. Loyalty issues could arise for the politicians who were board
members, in choosing between conflicting interests of the organization and their
constituents. According to the board members I interviewed, this problem had not yet
arisen at DICK, but they were aware of its potential. In contrast, some of HARRY’s
229
board members had decided not to take the interests of the organization into account at
all in the affaire concerning the appointment of its new deputy director, but to use
HARRY as a vehicle for nepotism.
Discussion of findings
I undertook two steps to test the validity of my findings. I first presented a draft
version of my case study reports to the organizations’ managing directors and asked
them to alert me on any factual errors and omissions. I then organized an expert
meeting to discuss my (anonymized) findings with the directors of seven hybrid waste
management companies. This was done to establish whether my observations were
more generally applicable in the waste management sector. Based on this I feel
comfortable to state that my research draws an adequate picture of hybrid organizations
in Dutch waste management.
Key conclusions
The key conclusions I drew from my case studies are:
- The hybridisation of an organization often starts with the initiative of an
enthusiastic and ambitious director of an agency who then tries to win over his
political principals. If the director plays his cards right, he can greatly increase his
autonomy.
- Managers rather focus on the opportunities due to hybridity and politicians rather
on the risks it poses. They focus on either side of the same coin while sometimes
forgetting about the flipside.
- An organization’s legal form is no decisive factor in its hybrid character or
hybridness.
- Whether an organization mixes activities for public and private customers and
therefore public and private sources of funding is also not a decisive factor in its
hybridness.
- An organization’s transformation into a hybrid is a process in which hard and soft
factors matter and which rather is an evolution than a revolution.
- Hybridity leads to a more businesslike relationship between an organization and its
public principals.
- The mere fact that an organization increases its turnover and profit after being
hybridized does not necessarily result in a benefit to the public.
- The threat of unfair competition is not necessarily an argument against hybridity. It
can be desirable from a public standpoint or be a matter of interpretation.
230
- Hybridity makes an organization more susceptible to market pressures. This will
be an incentive to increase its performance, eg, through a change in financing, by
introducing competition, by bringing employees with a commercial background
into the organization and by adopting private sector management techniques.
- Having both captive public and commercial customers, will make it tempting for
an organization to spend more attention on the latter. Hybridity will therefore only
have positive performance related effects for public customers if they are not
captive and the organization has to fight for their business.
- Public and private values do not necessarily clash but conflict will arise when an
organization’s management tries to force new values and new ways of conducting
business on its workforce.
- Hybridity can lead to a more professional governance, in the sense that there is a
better division of responsibilities, suiting the organizations’ new position as
players in the waste management market better than their former more bureaucratic
and politicised governance. However, the new governance arrangement will only
work if an organization’s political principals are willing to embrace their new roles
as shareholders.
- A supervisory board can compensate for the lack of interest and expertise hybrid
organizations often encounter at governments. But political appointment of
members of such a board can lead to loyalty conflicts for these board members.
- As hybrid organizations differ from one another and as there is not one dimension
that is in itself a prerequisite for hybridity, it is important to recognize their hybrid
fingerprint, or hybridness. My multidimensional model can help in this process.
- The model can also be used as an indicative-diagnostic tool to predict on which
dimensions hybridity might have positive or negative effects and to prepare for
them.
- Hybridity is as a process of organizational change no revolution but an evolution.
- Hybridity neither is a catastrophe, nor a panacea but needs to be managed properly.
The biggest challenge is to prove in every single case that the expected
opportunities created through hybridity far outweigh the costs of controlling the
risks it poses.
... Currently, to overcome these hurdles, many social entrepreneurs opt to work together in public-private partnerships (Bruin et al., 2007). There are, however, scholars who criticize this particular belief in the market, and the related use of new public management as a way for the state to deal with public service providers (Karre, 2011). Yet, the government seems to lack capabilities and willingness to become more active in tackling wicked problems that occur in the Dutch scene. ...
... Although government policies increasingly focus on fostering the social entrepreneurship ecosystem (Roy and Hazenberg, 2019;Witkamp et al., 2011), little is known about how municipalities contribute to it (Bozhikin et al., 2019). In the Dutch context to date, little research has been done on the relationship between local authorities and social entrepreneurs (Hogenstijn, 2018;Hogenstijn, 2019;Karre, 2011;Muftugil-Yalcin and Mooijman, 2023). However, various scholars show that social entrepreneurs in the Netherlands characterize the relationship with the municipality as far from optimal (Hogenstijn, 2018;Social Enterprise NL Jaarverslag, 2020;Muftugil-Yalcin and Mooijman, 2023). ...
... A consideration of the cultural, social and material aspects of municipality support, along with the discrepancies between these kinds of support, allows a critical analysis of the role municipalities play in social entrepreneurship in the Netherlands. It should also be noted that in the Netherlands, the government, both at the national and local levels, plays a crucial role in shaping the profile of social enterprises (Karre, 2011). A significant discussion in this context focuses on the role social enterprises can play in addressing major social problems (Brandsen et al., 2016;Head and Alford, 2015;Rittel and Webber, 1973) at the local level, particularly following the 2008 financial crisis. ...
Article
Purpose This paper aims to investigate how municipalities contribute to the ecosystem for social entrepreneurs, focusing on the four largest municipalities in the Netherlands, also known as the G4 municipalities (Amsterdam, Rotterdam, Utrecht and The Hague). Building on the ecosystem model of Spigel (2017), the findings focus on the cultural, social and material contributions of the municipalities to the ecosystem and how these contributions are perceived by the founders of social enterprises. Design/methodology/approach Focusing only on G4 municipalities, 39 semi structured interviews were carried, 15 of which were conducted with civil servants from G4 municipalities and the rest with social enterprises operating in G4 municipalities. Findings The results indicate that the G4 municipalities mainly contribute by helping build a positive image of social entrepreneurship and by facilitating the network of social entrepreneurs. However, municipalities often fail to substantiate their commitment by way of material resources such as financial inducements, resource provision or policies. Originality/value In the analysis, Spigel’s ecosystem model is adopted and by adopting this lens, the authors believe that the contribution of this exploratory study lies in analysing the relation of municipalities with social enterprises in a more comprehensive way. A consideration of the cultural, social and material aspects of municipality support, along with the discrepancies between these kinds of support, allows a critical analysis of the role municipalities play in social entrepreneurship in the Netherlands.
... Then we 8 provide an overview of the three forms of hybrid organising according to Battilana & Lee (2014) and introduce another form of hybrid organising that can be added to their concept through a fourth stream of literature. Building on our review of the literature on hybrid organisations in different variations, we discuss, through a practical example by Karré (2011), why the fourth literature stream is both highly relevant in practice and how it can be seamlessly integrated into the already existing concept. Using a descriptive framework, we suggest how the four forms of hybrid organising can be represented and how this can be used to categorise organisations into their appropriate forms. ...
... In order to share risks and investment costs, several companies or several municipalities often jointly establish a subsidiary. Karré (2011) presented an illustrative example of a waste disposal and infrastructure maintenance organisation he called "Dick". Karré identified the company as a hybrid organisation between the private and public sectors. ...
... The points proposed by Bamford, Ernst, & Fubini (2004) for hybrid enterprises as a combination of economic organisation can be applied to the organisation "Dick" put forth by Karré (2011) to underline the importance of the fourth dimension of hybrid organising. ...
Conference Paper
Full-text available
A fourth stream of literature has been added to the concept of hybrid organising as previously illustrated by Battilana and Lee (2014). Through this research and analysis of hybrid ventures, we aim to contribute to a better understanding of hybrid forms of enterprises. Thus, the concept illustrates the four dimensions of hybridity as a combination of several sectoral logics, hybridity as a combination of several institutional identities, hybridity as a combination of several forms of organisation and hybridity as a combination of economic organisation. It proposes a different, abstract approach to distinguishing between forms of hybridity. The concept can help identify and name hybridity in companies and can help in research to avoid mixtures of hybrid forms of organisation. The paper also makes the transition to research on the influence of hybrid forms of organisation on corporate governance issues. The findings are based on an extensive literature review of journals specialising in organisation, management, economics, and public administration. The paper presents a conceptual advancement of the concept due to the integration of different streams in the literature.
... Sociale ondernemingen zijn combinaties van botsende ideaaltypen. In de literatuur zijn de ideeën over dergelijke organisaties verdeeld (Dekker & Van de Donk, 2006;Karré, 2011;Verhoef & Simon, 2001). Zo zien Dekker en Van de Donk (2006) een risico in hybriditeit, doordat het uitnodigt tot verandering van de aard van de organisatie (betaald versus vrijwillig). ...
... Verder kan dit een uitdaging zijn in de conflicten die ontstaan in strategische, organisatorische en economische aspecten van de organisatie (Verhoef & Simon, 2001). Aan de andere kant ziet Karré (2011) het juist als een kans om een brug te slaan tussen economische waarden, culturele waarden en governance opvattingen. In huidig onderzoek is ervoor gekozen de discussie in een nieuw licht te zien. ...
Thesis
Full-text available
Waar voorheen het Bruto binnenlands product (BBP) de manier was om de welvaart van een land uit te drukken, blijkt nu de algemene gezondheid, inclusiviteit en duurzaamheid hierin te ontbreken. Daarom zetten partijen vanuit de overheid, markt en maatschappij in op een integrale visie die verder kijkt dan uitsluitend het BBP, via de Sustainable Development Goals (SDG’s) en de Monitor Brede Welvaart. Een specifieke groep, sociale ondernemingen, past deze integrale visie al toe. Sociale ondernemingen zijn hybride organisaties en combineren eigenschappen van overheid, markt en maatschappij. Hun hoofddoel is maatschappelijke impact. Hoewel zij bijdragen aan het verbreden van de welvaart, lijken zij onvoldoende (h)erkend te worden. Dit zorgt voor barrières die de performance van sociale ondernemingen belemmeren. Uitvoerig wetenschappelijk onderzoek naar maatschappelijke impact via sociale ondernemingen ontbreekt momenteel. In het verlengde hiervan ontbreekt onderzoek naar de rol van boundary organizations en boundary objects om maatschappelijke impact te effectueren. Dit onderzoek biedt met kwalitatieve onderzoeksmethoden via documentanalyse, diepte-interviews en participatieve observatie een verklaring voor de rol van een boundary organization en een boundary object om de barrières te helpen overkomen. Hier staat MAEX model voor de boundary organization en staat de Social Handprint model voor een boundary object. MAEX helpt in het meten van maatschappelijke impact en maakt dit meetbaar door deze impact te monetariseren met de Social Handprint. Het netwerk van sociale ondernemers wordt binnen dit onderzoek omschreven als sociaal kapitaal. Uit dit onderzoek blijkt dat een boundary organization bijdraagt aan de performance van sociale ondernemingen door het sociaal kapitaal te vergroten en het gesprek te faciliteren met het boundary object. Daarnaast bevestigt dit onderzoek dat sociaal kapitaal en een boundary object elkaar wederkerig versterken. Verder blijkt een boundary object het effectiefst, wanneer het de complexe eigenschappen van de brede welvaart reflecteert. Dit kan ook op lange termijn worden ingezet om cultuurverandering te realiseren en barrières af te breken, waarmee de performance van sociale ondernemingen vergroot. Een aanvulling vanuit dit onderzoek is dat de effectiviteit van een boundary object afneemt wanneer er een ongelijke positionering is tussen de actoren die het boundary object gebruiken. Sleutelwoorden: Sociale ondernemingen, maatschappelijke impact, boundary organizations, sociaal kapitaal, boundary object, barrières, performance
... In the core approach, a dichotomy is presented by distinguishing organizations solely on the basis of their ownership (publicly vs. privately-owned). In the publicness approach, every organization is considered to be public, but their degree of publicness is dependent on multiple factors, such as political control, funding, and task (Karré, 2011). In this dissertation, I will draw on both approaches to hypothesize on the differences in HRM practices and work-related attitudes and behaviors between agencies, central government, and businesses. ...
... Therefore, it is not a sufficient framework to investigate the claims regarding agencies. In order to close this gap, I will also adopt a publicness approach in this dissertation, which takes other factors into account besides ownership, such as political control and organizational task (Bozeman & Bretschneider, 1994;Karré, 2011). For goal ambiguity, red tape, and employee motivation, it is argued that agencies experience lower levels of goal ambiguity and red tape than central government, and that the type of employee motivation is more similar to that found in businesses (Pollitt & Bouckaert, 2011;Walker & Brewer, 2008). ...
Thesis
Full-text available
This dissertation starts by noting that agencies are of vital economic and societal importance, as they are responsible for delivering many public services. Agency employees play a key role in delivering these services and, to manage these employees effectively, policy makers believed that a business-like approach towards HRM is the way to go. Agencies were created with the idea that they can adopt this approach more easily, as they were expected to experience lower levels of bureaucracy typically associated with central government. The claims that underlie the creation of agencies have barely been tested empirically, particularly those related to HRM. This lacuna is the starting point of this dissertation for a systematic investigation into the way people are managed in agencies. Through multiple studies on between- and within-sector differences in HRM and work-related attitudes and behaviors in agencies, the conclusion is that a business-like approach towards HRM is not found in agencies nor do they seem to operate under lower levels of bureaucracy. While agencies are in some respects similar to central government and businesses, they should not be viewed as simply in between government and businesses. They are hybrid organizations that, on the one hand, constitute a fairly similar group when it comes to HRM and work-related attitudes and behaviors, but, on the other hand, also differ in what HRM entails and how it shaped.
... The influence of new public management (Hood, 1991), the privatisation of waste public companies and services, the outsourcing of public services towards public-private partnerships (PPPs) and the development of hybrid organisations (Karré, 2011; see also Chapter Seven) and other quasi-private organisations, have all favoured the hybridisation of waste management and the emergence of new actors such as waste incineration companies or citizens' recycling cooperatives (see Chapter Ten) to collect and handle household solid waste. The nature of these public-private hybrid waste management companies and their consequences for citizens, private waste operators, its political governance and internal staff also unfolds in this book. ...
... This article focusses on public/private hybrid organizations between state and market. Examples include state-owned enterprises, agencies, and other forms of quasi-non-governmental organizations (or quangos) that not only operate at arm's length from their political masters but also undertake commercial activities on behalf of government (Bruton et al., 2015;Karré, 2011;van Thiel, 2000). ...
Article
Full-text available
Hybridity has become a widely-used concept in public management theory and practice. Yet, there is limited insight in what constitutes a hybrid organization. This article argues that it is not enough to say an organization is hybrid; you need to say how an organization is hybrid, as organizations can mix the characteristics of state and market on several dimensions and with differing intensities. They all have, as it were, a distinctive hybrid thumbprint, which can influence an organization's performance and hence the quality of its service provision. Therefore, a model is presented to visualize this unique thumbprint.
... Researchers have examined their operations and influence (Evers, 2005;Koppell, 2006), the risks and accountability involved (Grossi & Thomasson, 2015;Vakkuri et al., 2021), the outcomes of hybrid organisational practices (Krøtel & Villadsen, 2016), and how models of hybridity are developed and treated in emerging economies (Khodachek & Timoshenko, 2017). The range of public services that such hybrids produce extends to healthcare (Turner et al., 2016), port operations (Grossi & Thomasson, 2015), social housing (Koffijberg et al., 2012), waste management (Karré, 2011) and much else. ...
Article
How should we understand the role of hybrid organisations in urban heritage governance? What explains their particular hybrid forms? Those questions were addressed by studying two Malaysian hybrids: George Town World Heritage Incorporated and Think City. They are in charge of urban renewal and heritage preservation in Malaysia’s Penang State. Interviews and participant observation revealed how different types of embeddedness influence the internal and external dynamics underpinning the organisations’ effectiveness. They are shaped by local historical and institutional conditions and staffed by individuals recruited through networks spanning different scales in society and government. The hybrid organisations’ networks involve collaborations with local and national governments, with other state-linked institutions, with international organisations, and with civil society. The hybrid organisations have arguably provided more dynamic protection of George Town’s heritage, but the gains have yet to be evenly distributed among the local community. The findings also suggest that hybrids in developing economies are less a product of austerity and more a reflection of local political, geographical, and social contingencies.
Book
Full-text available
This is the text of the valedoctory lecture of prof.dr. J.F.M. Koppenjan, dd. 29 June 2022. (in Dutch) Joop Koppenjan nam met deze rede op 29 juni 2022 afscheid als hoogleraar bestuurskunde aan de Erasmus Universiteit Rotterdam (EUR). De regel Van alles is weer waardeloos is een anagram van de befaamde ‘lichtregel’ van Lucebert, Alles van waarde is weerloos, die in neon op een Rotterdams bankgebouw prijkt. Deze zinnen zijn aanleiding voor een beschouwing over het beleidsfalen van de overheid in de afgelopen jaren, zoals bij de toeslagenaffaire, de Groningse aardbevingsschade en de jeugdzorg. Klopt de suggestie dat het instrumentele, management denken van politici en bestuurders ten koste gaat van kwetsbare burgers en maatwerk? En waarom schiet het achteraf compenseren van burgers te kort en resulteert dat vaak zelfs in een ramp na de ramp? Centraal in deze afscheidsrede staat de vraag of en zo ja onder welke condities meer aandacht voor publieke waarden het tij zal kunnen keren. Kan dat tot andere afwegingen in beleid en publieke dienstverlening leiden? En tot bestuurders en ambtenaren met een grotere sensibiliteit voor burgers en hun specifieke belangen en behoeften? Wat is daarvoor nodig? Ook wordt nagegaan wat dit voor de bestuurskunde als toegepaste wetenschap betekent. De bestuurskunde heeft een succesvolle trackrecord opgebouwd als kennisproducent en adviseur van de overheid. En heeft sinds de jaren tachtig van de vorige eeuw vele cohorten ambtenaren en publieke managers opgeleid. Hoe zit het met de waarden waardoor bestuurskundigen zich bij hun onderzoek en adviezen laten leiden en die zij op hun studenten overdragen? De claim een waardevrije wetenschap te zijn leidt ertoe dat niet nagedacht hoeft te worden over deze waarden. Maar de bestuurskunde is niet waardevrij. Wat is ervoor nodig om als waardevolle bestuurskunde geen onderdeel te zijn van het probleem, maar van de oplossing?
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any references for this publication.