ArticlePDF Available

The evolution of the check as a means of payment: a historical survey

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

Though checks' popularity is now waning in favor of electronic payments, checks were, for much of the twentieth century, the most widely used noncash payment method in the United States. How did such a relatively inefficient form of payment become so dominant? This article traces the historical evolution of the check, focusing on its relation to complementary and competing payment technologies. ; Originating in the eastern Mediterranean during the first millennium as a convenient form of payment between local merchants, checks became more versatile through the development of negotiability in sixteenth-century Europe. The suppression of banknotes in eighteenth-century England further promoted the use of checks. In the United States, nineteenth-century legislation discouraged other payment methods and eventually led to a nationwide check payment system. In the twentieth century, under the Federal Reserve's leadership, checks expanded rapidly and became the nation's default payment method. ; The authors discuss some persistent historical themes surrounding checks: checks' ease of use, which provides advantages over other payment methods but creates risk to businesses and banks; checks' sophistication, which evolved through centuries of legal precedent and operational experimentation; and checks' high costs relative to other forms of payment. ; Checks' traditional dominance of the U.S. payment system, the authors conclude, resulted from historical happenstances. These events gave the check relative advantages that are only now being overcome by electronic payment technologies.
Content may be subject to copyright.
1
The Evolution of the Check as a Means of Payment: a Historical Survey
December, 2007
Preliminary draft—please do not quote.
Stephen Quinn
Department of Economics
Texas Christian University
s.quinn@tcu.edu
William Roberds
Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta
william.roberds@atl.frb.org
Abstract: This paper surveys the history of the check, from its beginnings in the eastern
Mediterranean to its place atop the twentieth-century U.S. payment system. To under-
stand the check’s path to ascendancy, we identify three critical changes in the wider
payment system environment. The development of negotiability in the Low Countries
during the sixteenth century encouraged wider acceptance of checks. The suppression of
banknotes at various times in the Anglo-American world limited a key rival to checks.
Finally, the Federal Reserve standardized check processing and subsidized inter-regional
checking in the twentieth century.
2
In the early eleventh century, an Iranian traveler by the name of Nasir-i Khosrau
visited the city of Basra, in present-day Iraq. There, he recorded one of the first descrip-
tions of a form of payment known as the sakk, a merchant’s written instruction ordering
his bank to make a payment from his account (Ashtor 1972).1 The U.S. economy contin-
ues to rely on the payment instrument favored in medieval Basra. Although the number
of checks written in the U.S. peaked in the mid-1990s,2 Americans still wrote about 33
billion checks in 2006 (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System 2007b). Only
cash was used more often to make payments.
This ongoing reliance on checks is unique among developed countries and creates
some inefficiency in the U.S. payment system (Humphrey and Berger 1990, Wells 1996).
For example, Garcia-Swartz, Hahn, and Layne-Farrar (2006) put the social cost of a typi-
cal grocery store check payment at $1.21 versus $.78 for the cheapest electronic alterna-
tive (payment with a PIN debit card). Much of the difference derives from checks’ higher
processing cost, which in turn stems from the cost of physically moving and storing pa-
per. Recent moves toward “electronifying” check processing, most notably the Checking
for 21st Century Act of 2003, reduce these costs, but the check clearing system still proc-
esses many checks in paper form (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
2007a, b).
While awareness of the inefficiency of checks is widespread, how checks came to
dominate the U.S. payment system may be less appreciated. In this article, we survey the
historical evolution of the check by focusing on the wider payment system environment.
1 Ashtor (1972) derives the English word check from the Arabic sakk. But most etymologies (e.g., the Ox-
ford English Dictionary) assert that the term check (or cheque) was originally applied to a counterfoil of a
financial document, retained as a safeguard or “check” against fraud or forgery.
2 Surveys conducted by the Federal Reserve System indicate that the number of checks written in the U.S.
each year in the mid-1990s was close to 50 billion (Gerdes and Walton 2002); see Figure 6 below.
3
We hope to better understand the future role of this ancient form of payment by under-
standing how checks have related to complementary and competing payment technolo-
gies.
Our survey identifies three critical changes that ushered the check to ascendancy.
In the sixteenth century, the development of negotiability in the Low Countries enhanced
the versatility the check and opened the door for inter-bank acceptance. Next, the regula-
tory suppression of banknotes in England in the eighteenth century and in the U.S. after
the Civil War promoted the use of checks in the Anglo-Saxon world. Finally, the entry of
the Federal Reserve into check processing created a unified, nationwide check payment
system in the twentieth century.
We also identify some persistent themes in the history of the check. From the be-
ginning, ease of use has been an important advantage for checks relative to other means
of payment. For checks, however, convenience also creates risk to businesses and banks,
so checks have often been limited to local transactions and to the wealthiest customers.
As a result, innovation in checking focuses on ways to manage these risks: legal doctrines
standardize check clearing procedures, banks create formal relationships to mitigate im-
balances, and electronic check processing increases the speed of information flows.
Over the centuries, innovations increased the sophistication of checks. This so-
phistication is perhaps surprising given the check’s apparently simple nature: a piece of
paper with a few “magic words” such as “pay to the order of” written across it. But this
seeming simplicity belies the hundreds of years’ worth of legal precedent and operational
experimentation that underlie the check payment system available to Americans today.
4
A final theme is cost. The downside of checks’ versatility has been that checks
have been, and remain, a relatively costly form of payment in many situations. Techno-
logical, regulatory, and legal changes over the years have markedly reduced cost of check
payments. A recent byproduct of this trend has been a blurring of some of the distinctions
between checks and other types of payment. Still, the cost disadvantage of using checks
persists, and, historically speaking, checks have dominated payments only when rival in-
struments have been suppressed.
We conclude that the check’s traditional dominance of the U.S. payment system
must be seen as highly path dependent, a consequence of a long series of historical hap-
penstances. These events have conferred on the check some noteworthy advantages over
its competitors, advantages that are only now being overcome by advances in electronic
payment technologies.
1. Definition and early origins
A check is a written order to a bank by a depositor at that bank (known as the
drawer or maker). The order instructs a bank to pay a third party (known as the payee) a
certain sum of money from the depositor’s account when the check is presented to the
bank.3
Today, the idea that a bank depositor can transfer funds by check seems natural
and obvious. But for much of recorded history, checks were unknown. The Roman Em-
pire, for example, had many bank-like institutions known as argentarii, but there is no
3 For the purposes of this survey we ignore the possibility of the check being payable to bearer or being
postdated. Also, there are a number of technical details as to what legally constitutes a check, some of
which are discussed below. A check is negotiable, which has a specific legal meaning. A modern check
must also have a MICR line, a line of numbers that facilitate its electronic processing.
5
evidence that argentarii depositors used checks, at least in the western part of the Empire
(Andreau 1999).
Checks appear in common use in the eastern Mediterranean during the first mil-
lennium. By the tenth century, checks were widely used in the Muslim world (Ashtor
1972). In contrast, monetary systems in Europe at this time were extremely primitive.
There were few coins of reliable value and no banks, much less checks (Usher 1934,
Spufford 1988).
During the Crusades, Europeans came into increased contact with the Muslim
world and came to adopt, with modifications, the banking and monetary systems they en-
countered in the eastern Mediterranean. During thirteenth century, rudimentary banks ap-
peared in commercial cities such as Barcelona, Florence, Genoa, and Venice. The pri-
mary purpose of these banks was to facilitate payments among local merchants rather
than to provide credit. Payments were made by oral order rather than written order. To
make a payment, the payor and payee both walked to the bank, and the payor instructed
the banker to pay the payee and debit the payor’s account. The banker made an entry of
the transaction in his journal, which served as a notarial record that the payment had ac-
tually taken place.
Payees commonly preferred payment in the form of a credit with the bank over
coin, for the quality of medieval coinage was usually poor, and large amounts of coin
were heavy and difficult to protect. Medieval banks would also occasionally make credit
available to their depositors by allowing them to overdraft their accounts (de Roover
1948, Mueller 1997, Kohn 1999).
6
The first European banks did not allow the use of checks. Written orders to trans-
fer bank funds were regarded with extreme suspicion due to the possibility of fraud on
the part of payor, payee, or banker (Usher 1934, 418; de Roover 1948, 263-264). By re-
quiring the presence of all three parties at each transaction, medieval banking practice
guaranteed that the actions of each party had at least two eyewitnesses. In order to make
deposit accounts checkable, the payment system had to design sufficient legal processes
to control risk. That legal tradition, however, developed with a different payment instru-
ment, called the bill of exchange. Bills of exchange communicated remittances between
cities, so bills had to take a written form because bills handled situations where an order
to pay occurred at a different time and place than the actual payment.4
2. The predecessor of the check—the bill of exchange
Medieval banks were municipally chartered institutions and could only offer
payment services within their home city. Other means were required to transfer funds
from one place to another. One possibility was to simply transport coin, but movements
of coin were subject to theft, confiscation, and loss at sea. Faced with these hazards, me-
dieval merchants made frequent use of bills of exchange to transfer funds over distance.
The first bills of exchange were probably modeled after a document used in the Muslim
world, known in Arabic as the suftadja (Ashtor 1972). Like the more familiar check, a
bill of exchange consists of a written instruction by a drawer to have someone give funds
to a payee.
4 Even when used for payments in the same location, such as at medieval fairs, bills of exchange need to be
written because the acts of ordering and the paying were separated by time.
7
Early bills of exchange differ from modern checks in several ways, however. The
first of these is that most medieval bills were not used locally; a bill was written (or
drawn) in one city, but paid in another. The second is that the instruction in a bill (“pay to
the order of”) was rarely to a bank, but instead to another merchant, known as the
drawee. The drawee was often a business partner, a customer, or even a relative of the
drawer. A third key difference is that medieval bills were not payable on demand, but
only after some agreed-upon period of time (known as usance, which varied by distance)
has passed. Actual payment would usually be accomplished by the drawee transferring
funds in his local bank account to the payee. Finally, a bill of exchange is not necessarily
an order to pay from an account, but simply an order to pay.5
Bills of exchange were viewed as a secure means of payment. The lag between
the drawing of a bill and its payment meant there was plenty of time for the payee to find
out whether a bill was genuine. To help guard against fraud, multiple copies of bills were
usually sent, often by different ships. Only merchants known to and trusted by the drawee
were allowed to draw bills. When presented with a bill, a drawee indicated that he would
pay the bill by signing or accepting it.
Eventually, the major commercial centers in Europe were tied together by a pay-
ment system based on bills of exchange. The term “system” is used quite loosely here
since each city had its own coinage and its own unit of account, and there was no central-
ized clearing or settling of transactions. The functioning of this system was heavily de-
pendent on mutual trust of the parties involved in each transaction. But, by the standards
of the time, it was remarkably efficient at securely moving large sums of money over
5 There are many technical aspects of the medieval bill of exchange that are beyond the scope of this article.
See Mueller (1997) for an introduction to the subject of medieval bills.
8
thousands of miles without the physical transfer of coin.6 Also, the system made mer-
chants, and the supporting legal systems, familiar with written payment orders similar to
checks.
3. The first European checks
Checks began to appear in Europe around the year 1400, or roughly 200 years af-
ter the advent of bills of exchange, in cities that had both deposit banks and familiarity
with bills of exchange. Gradually, the convenience of check payment began to overcome
the widespread distrust of banks in general and written transfers of bank funds in particu-
lar. A Venice ordinance of 1421 allowed nonresidents to make payments by check, rec-
ognizing that for them a personal appearance at a Venetian bank was often an impractical
requirement. There were many instances of fraud and abuse, however, and checks re-
mained controversial. A Barcelona ordinance of 1527 prohibited the use of checks at a
city-owned bank, and a 1526 ordinance in Venice banned checks outright (Usher 1934).
Despite such setbacks, checks continued to gain ground. Research by Marco Spal-
lanzani (1978) has shown that checks were commonly employed in Florence by the fif-
teenth century. Spallanzani (1978, 164) argues that the ability to make check payments
increased the attraction of keeping one’s money in a bank:
The main reason which led such men [men of very modest commercial
status] to deposit their money with a merchant banker was not the need for
security, nor even the hope for some reward in the form of interest, but
more simply the convenience of an effective means of making payment.
6 One of the most enthusiastic users of this system was the Church, which routinely made use of bills of
exchange to transfer funds collected as tithes to Rome (de Roover 1948, 60-61).
9
In other words, while only prominent merchants could pay using a bill of exchange, ordi-
nary businessmen could make payments using checks. This was possible since checks,
being payable on demand, functioned principally as instruments of payment rather than
instruments of credit.7 Some of the early checks that survive were written for small sums
and were apparently written to make routine payments.
It should be emphasized that early checks in no way substituted for bills of ex-
change, for they served different needs. A check functioned locally, while a bill of ex-
change could move money from one locality to another. In many countries, bills and
checks continued to play these complementary roles until the early part of the twentieth
century. Also, the use of paper for payment was restricted to the relatively well to do:
most everyday purchases were still made with coin or commercial credit.
4. The advent of negotiability
Perhaps the single most important development in the history of the check is the
introduction of negotiability (roughly defined as an ability to circulate among various
parties).8 The usefulness of early bills and checks was limited by a lack of negotiability.
That is, once written, a bill (or check) could often only be collected by the party who it
was made out to—the payee. If a payee transferred a bill to a creditor, for example, me-
dieval law often would not recognize the creditor as having a legitimate claim on the
drawee. This meant that once someone received a bill or check, they had to personally
ensure that it would be presented to the drawee for timely payment. For checks, the lack
7 Anyone who has written a check the day before payday knows that a check can also function as an in-
strument of credit. Such credit is generally quite short term, however.
8 The formal concept of negotiability is somewhat involved. Here we present a brief sketch of some the key
features of negotiable instruments such as checks and bills of exchange. Readers interested in the contem-
porary law of negotiable instruments should consult a legal text.
10
of negotiability meant that a second bank could not be used to clear a check on behalf of
a customer.
The situation began to change around the turn of the sixteenth century, when mer-
chants in the Low Countries created a legal framework by which paper payments could
circulate. The instrument of that change was yet a third means of payment called the
promissory note. Promissory notes are IOUs, and these were often used as a means of
payment before banks or bills of exchange. In Antwerp, however, necessity was the
mother of invention, for a series of restrictive ordinances had effectively abolished all
banks. Merchants wanting to pay using something other than coin then began to circulate
promissory notes among themselves. Transfer of these notes, however, was hindered by
adverse selection, i.e., parties in the know had an incentive to pass on the notes of risky
debtors and retain the notes of safer debtors.
To mitigate the problem, courts began to hold people responsible for the promis-
sory notes they passed on. If the debtor failed to pay, then the merchant who passed on
the debt became liable. Such contingent liability (the liability being contingent on the
debtor not paying) diminished the incentive to knowingly pass on bad notes. In practice,
the chain of transfers became recorded by a signature on the back of the debt, and so the
practice of transfer by endorsement began. An endorsement indicated both (a) a transfer
of the note with full rights to the person receiving the note (the endorsee) and (b) liability
on the part of the endorser, should the debtor fail to pay the note.9
Beginning in 1570, this method of payment was codified in a famous body of law
known as the Antwerp Costuymen (Van der Wee 1977). By the early seventeenth century
9 Other historical economies developed similar payment systems. Ashtor (1972) notes that endorsement and
circulation of suftadjas was already common in the tenth century. Edo-era Japan also developed a payment
system based on endorsement and circulation of rice-warehouse receipts; see Tamaki (1995).
11
these laws were adopted in Amsterdam (Dehing and ‘t Hart 1997, 42), the dominant
commercial center of the time, and similar laws eventually came to be adopted through-
out Europe. This legal technology would prove very useful for checks and bills of ex-
change. For example, the holder of a bill of exchange could then transfer the bill by sim-
ply endorsing it, or sell it on the secondary market. A bill could subsequently be endorsed
many times. A bill became a stronger claim each time it was endorsed, since it became a
liability of both the drawee (provided that the drawee had accepted the bill) and each per-
son who had endorsed it. Bills of exchange that circulated through endorsement were said
to be negotiable.
Negotiability allowed what amounted to private debt (originally notes and bills of
exchange, and eventually, checks) to function as a sort of circulating money. In the ab-
sence of any centralized recordkeeping of what was owed by who (such as provided by a
modern banking system), minimizing the likelihood of fraud or default was essential for
private debt to play this role. Negotiability accomplished this by embodying the drawee’s
obligation in the bill itself. A bill, once accepted by a drawee, had to be honored when it
was presented, no matter how many hands it passed through—a default on a bill
amounted to commercial suicide, for the defaulter would be expelled from the circle of
credit essential to early modern commerce. Circulating bills thus functioned as a sort of
portable record-keeping system, when no centralized one was available.
Inevitably, of course, a certain number of bills were not paid, or “dishonored,” for
reasons ranging from forgery to bankruptcy. But even a dishonored bill still had value,
because it could be passed back along the chain of endorsements as evidence of default,
12
thereby strengthening the legal claims of each creditor in the chain.10 In modern termi-
nology, the record-keeping function associated with negotiability worked along the “for-
ward” chain of endorsements, but when necessary also worked in reverse.
A payment system based on circulating bills was effective but often inefficient.
Bills could change hands many times before they were finally paid, creating uncomforta-
bly long chains of mutual indebtedness. A 1602 Amsterdam ordinance complains of bills
commonly being transferred nine times before redemption. Drawees would routinely pay
a bill drawn on them by drawing another bill, since there was no easy way of netting out
obligations against one another (Van Dillen 1964, 346). Frustration with this situation led
to the 1609 founding of a municipal bank in Amsterdam to facilitate the settlement of
bills of exchange, foreshadowing what would become an important role for the Federal
Reserve roughly 300 years later.11 All bills payable in Amsterdam were required to be
settled through the municipal bank, which limited the indefinite circulation of bills and
led to more efficient and predictable settlement cycles.
Today, negotiability remains a guiding principle of check payments. Although
checks do not circulate from hand to hand, the present-day check clearing preserves many
customs derived from the seventeenth-century commercial practice. By endorsing a
check, for example, someone who deposits a check at a bank provides his bank a war-
ranty that the check is good. As a check is processed, it may pass through many hands
before it finally reaches the bank it is drawn on (known in the industry as the paying
10 Although at first there was much ambiguity about who should be sued first in the event of nonpayment,
the drawer or the endorser. For bills of exchange, English courts eventually resolved this in favor of the
former (Rogers 1995). For a formal model of the evidentiary role of dishonored bills, see Kahn and
Roberds (2007).
11 The merchant community in Amsterdam proposed a nationwide system of government-sponsored settle-
ment banks throughout the Netherlands. Again foreshadowing later events in the U.S., this proposal was
rejected due to resistance from rural interests (Van Dillen 1964, 343-344).
13
bank), each party providing a warranty to the next party in the processing chain. And, un-
til quite recently, a bank was not obliged to pay a check until it was physically presented
for payment: just as in seventeenth-century Amsterdam, the record-keeping function of
the negotiable instrument was bound to the paper instrument itself.12
5. The rise of checks in England
It took some time for Continental payment systems to be adopted in England.
Bills of exchange were used from the fifteenth century onwards (Munro 2000; Holden
1955, 21) but at first these did not circulate. Contemporary merchant manuals indicate
that the endorsement of bills of exchange became commonplace in England by the mid-
seventeenth century (Holden 1955; Van der Wee, 1977; Rogers 1995).
Checking also came rather late to England, as deposit banking first appeared in
London in the 1650’s. The first English banks were not, as on the Continent, conceived as
specialized clearing institutions, but instead arose as a sideline to the business of London
“goldsmiths,” i.e., people who might nowadays be called pawnbrokers. The London
goldsmiths offered deposit accounts and allowed depositors to transfer funds by check.
By the 1660s, London used negotiability to develop a system of check-based deposit
banks (Mitchell 1995; Quinn 1997). The banks were a system, rather than just a collec-
tion of rivals, because they accepted checks drawn on each other. For example, one gold-
smith-banker had clearing accounts with at least seventeen other bankers (Quinn 1997,
414). Mutual acceptance meant that goldsmiths had checks due on each other, so bilateral
clearing relationships also developed. Arrangements were also made so that checks could
12 Classical concepts of negotiability as applied to checks have been modified somewhat in recent years;
see the discussion in section 12 below.
14
be used to pay taxes. By expanding the acceptance of checks, the young English banking
system encouraged customer demand for deposit accounts, and the “banking habit” was
promoted.
The use of checks was limited, however, by the fact that there were no British
banks outside of London. Deposit banking did not spread to the West End of London un-
til the 1680s, and even then sophisticated banking services developed slowly (Quinn
2001; Temin and Voth 2006). Banks outside of London grew numerous only after 1750
(Pressnell 1956, 4-11).
Seventeenth-century England also saw the transformation of two traditional forms
of payment into new instruments that would come to compete with checks. The tradi-
tional international or “foreign” bill of exchange generated the domestic or inland bill of
exchange. Also, the traditional promissory note, when issued by a bank, became the
banknote. The new forms competed directly with the check: inland (domestic) bills of
exchange for inter-regional payments and banknotes for local payments.
The term “inland” bill of exchange was used to designate bills that were both
drawn and paid within England. Court records indicate that these were in use by the mid-
seventeenth century (Holden 1955, 53). Often, English merchants who shipped goods to
London would draw a bill on a business partner or factor in London and sell the bill to a
country banker. In this way, merchants avoided having to move coin from London to
their localities. Local bankers also avoided moving coins by subsequently drawing a new
bill on the balances in London and selling the bill to customers who desired purchasing
power in the capital.
15
Negotiability made inland bills highly liquid: a London merchant receiving an
inland bill, but needing cash, could easily sell it at a discount by endorsing it over to a
London bank. For the time, this was a revolutionary innovation that greatly accelerated
the development of the English economy (Rogers 1995, 101-108). As with the more tra-
ditional foreign bills, inland bills were instruments of credit as well as payment, and the
purchase or “discounting” of inland bills became the predominant means by which banks
provided commercial credit (Pressnell 1956, Hudson 1986).
Despite their evident popularity, historical evidence indicates that the use of
inland bills remained restricted to the merchant class. Frank T. Melton (1986) examines
the records of Robert Clayton and John Morris, seventeenth century bankers in London,
and finds that the use of checks, but not bills, was fairly common among their clientele of
wealthy landowners (Melton 1986, 112). Bills drawn by non-merchants, no matter how
wealthy, were seen as being too difficult to collect on. Just as in fifteenth-century Flor-
ence, the availability of checks appears to have expanded the reach of written instruments
as means of payment.
The first banknotes in England were modest issues of promissory notes by Lon-
don goldsmiths.13 These notes contained “bearer clauses” that allowed them to circulate
without endorsement. For example, the goldsmith-banker shop Sir Francis Child issued
the following note to the partnership of North and Grey:14
13 Banknote-like instruments had seen sporadic use before this time. DeRosa (2001), for example, docu-
ments the issue of “banknotes” by Neapolitan public banks in sixteenth century—although these generally
circulated only by endorsement. According to Heckscher (1934), the Swedish central bank issued bearer
notes in small amounts as early as 1661.
14 This note is from bundles of checks and notes retained by the Royal Bank of Scotland, London.
16
November 28, 1684
I promise to pay unto ye Right Honorable Lord North & Grey or bearer
ninety pounds at demand.
for Mr Francis Child & my self John Rogers
£90:-
The use of banknotes, however, appears quite limited until the chartering of the Bank of
England in 1694 (Quinn and Roberds 2003). As is well known, the Bank of England was
originally conceived as a sort of combination commercial bank and government finance
agency. From its inception, it held large amounts of government debt, while simultane-
ously issuing large quantities of notes that were in most cases, redeemable in coin on de-
mand and freely transferable “to bearer” without the formality of endorsement (Richards
1934, 219-230, Holden 1955, 91). While some of the early note issues bore interest,
about half did not, indicating that their primary purpose was for payments (Horsefield
1983, 264). Bank of England notes were a success and quickly came into wide use as
payment instruments, though they did not attain legal tender status until 1833 (Holden
1955, 196).
The large-scale adoption of banknotes was another revolutionary development in
the world of payments. However, in the English case, a number of factors served to limit
their use. Parliamentary Acts in 1697, 1707, and 1709 granted the Bank of England a
monopoly on corporate banking in England, and forbade banking partnerships of more
that six members from issuing banknotes payable on demand (Horsefield 1983, 134-139).
Smaller banks could issue notes, but these could not effectively compete on a nationwide
17
basis with the Bank of England. The Bank of England only issued and redeemed notes at
London, meaning that outside of London they often circulated at a discount. In 1777, the
minimum banknote denomination was raised to £5 (a considerable sum at the time),
which restricted the use of banknotes to large transactions (Pressnell 1956, 140).
The restrictions effectively guaranteed a continued role for check payments within
England, particularly in London. From 1760 to 1800, the number of banks in London
doubled, and checks gained increased prominence (Clapham 1944, 165). When Parlia-
ment finally permitted new corporate banks in London in 1833, Parliament protected the
Bank of England by prohibiting corporate banks that did operate in London from issuing
banknotes. The importance of the London market meant that England’s largest banks
chose the metropolis and checking accounts rather than remain outside and offer bank-
notes. Finally, the consolidation of English banking during the last quarter of the Nine-
teenth Century left few banks still issuing banknotes.
In contrast, Scotland had no special restrictions on banknote issue until 1845. As a
result, the Scottish system was dominated by banknotes, and checks were rarely used. In
1845, note issue in Scotland was regulated, in that each note issued, after an exempted
base amount, had to be fully backed by gold (Checkland 1975, 384-5). Even with this
constraint on note issue, checking was slow to gain market share. Not until the late 1870s
did checking become common in Scotland, and checks did not come to dominate retail
purchases until the eve of World War I (Checkland 1975, 487, 510).
As regulations increased the volume of check payments, banks sought to reduce
the costs of processing them. In 1773, thirty-one London banks formed a clearing organi-
18
zation, the London Clearing House (Joslin 1954). 15 The London Clearing House was to
become a model for future check clearing arrangements.16 Members of the Clearing
House reduced clearing costs by agreeing to meet and exchange checks in a single loca-
tion—a significant improvement over earlier, decentralized clearing arrangements (Nor-
man et al. 2006). Operational procedures were put in place to detect fraudulent items and
to resolve disputes. Initially, clearing was done bilaterally, but, after 1841, costs were fur-
ther reduced by setting off obligations against one another in a multilateral fashion. At
first net amounts due were settled in coin or Bank of England notes, but settlement
switched to accounts at the Bank of England in 1854 (Matthews 1921, 35-36).
By the time Walter Bagehot published Lombard Street in 1873, checking accounts
were the largest element of the British payment system. Table 1 shows the composition
of the British payment system in 1873, and commercial bank deposits had grown to sur-
pass bills of exchange. Deposits were five times larger than coins and more than ten times
larger than Bank of England notes. Private banknotes in England continued to decline and
disappeared entirely in the early Twentieth Century.17 The suppression of banknotes in
Britain had made the check dominant.
15 Because of its late adoption of checks, Scotland did not introduce a check clearinghouse until 1865, and
that process began as an add-on to the existing system of note clearing (Checkland 1975: 486).
16 In addition to checks, the London Clearing House cleared bills of exchange.
17 In Scotland, banknote levels did grow after 1873, but regulatory constraints would cause banknotes to
become a declining share of the faster growing Scottish payment system.
19
Table 1. Elements of the British Payment System in 1873, in millions
Commercial Bank Deposits £498
Bills of Exchange £445
Coins in Circulation £95
Bank of England Notes £37
All other English Banknotes £5
Scottish Banknotes £6
Sources: The bill of exchange value is derived from Nishimura (1971, 93) by as-
suming an average usance of three months. All other values are from Capie and Weber
(1985, 325-6, 432).
6. Payments in the United States before the Civil War
While Britain suppressed banknotes in England, British mercantile policies sup-
pressed banks in the American colonies, so neither checks nor banknotes were an impor-
tant source of payment instruments until after the Revolution. In this vacuum, individual
colonial governments directly issued notes called bills of credit that became an important
medium of exchange (Grubb 2003; Michener and Wright 2005). Massachusetts first in-
troduced bills of credit in 1690 and other colonies soon followed, so the American colo-
nies were leaders in the development of state-issued currency. In response to the infla-
tionary monetary policies of some colonies, Massachusetts and Rhode Island in particu-
lar, the British government prohibited the issuance of paper money by the New England
colonies in 1751 and all colonies in 1764. Monetary restrictions thus became an impor-
20
tant grievance against Britain, and the Revolutionary War brought a return to currency
finance by individual states and by the Continental Congress (Calomiris 1988).
Wartime inflation and especially the collapse in value of the Continental paper
dollar reversed the regulatory pendulum, for the U.S. constitution explicitly forbade states
from issuing paper money and implicitly granted states the power to charter banks
(Grubb 2006; Michener and Wright 2006). Once formed, the Federal government took a
laissez-faire attitude to state banking and did not limit the state banknotes the way the
British government restricted English banknotes (Sylla 2006). Instead, regulations varied
from state to state, but each state did impose some restrictions on banknotes, such as re-
quiring banks to hold state bonds as backing.
The Federal government did adopt an English tradition, however, by directly
chartering two banks whose structures were similar to the Bank of England: the First
Bank of the United States from 1791 to 1810 and the Second Bank of the Unites States
from 1817 to 1836.18 Whereas the Bank of England’s key privilege was being the sole
corporate bank in England, the two federal banks had the privilege of being the sole
banks with interstate branches.19 Individual states could, and did, charter note-issuing
corporate rivals. The other major difference between the English and American experi-
ences was that the federal banks proved short lived. While both banks were created in the
image of the Bank of England, the two banks were ended by presidents, first Jefferson
and then Jackson, opposed to the British-style concentration of moneyed power.
During the early decades of the nineteenth century, a combination of geographic
expanse and financial underdevelopment combined to put checks at a disadvantage rela-
18 At the end of its Federal charter in 1836, the Second Bank of the United States was rechartered as a state
bank called the Bank of the U.S. of Pennsylvania.
19 In 1835, out of 24 states with banks, 14 states had some in-state branching (Weber 2006, 30-35).
21
tive to banknotes. With limited urbanization and few banks, it was difficult and costly to
collect on a check, and, while these might be negotiable in principle, difficulties in col-
lecting meant that these could not be sold to another party. This environment tended to
initially favor the use of banknotes, which could circulate away from a bank before re-
demption. In 1819, the amount of banknotes issued by chartered banks in the U.S. ex-
ceeded their deposits by 75 percent.
Both checks and banknotes were most useful for local payments. For interregional
payments, the early decades of the nineteenth century saw increased use of inland bills of
exchange. Inland bills were known as “trade acceptances,” and these evolved into the
predominant form of business-to-business payment between different communities.
Documentary bills were especially popular. A documentary bill of exchange was one
drawn against the value of goods that had been shipped, attached to bill of lading, as
proof that the shipment had taken place. For example, a cotton merchant in New Orleans
could borrow money or make purchases in New Orleans, by drawing a documentary bill
on his wholesaler in New York. The attached bill of lading would indicate that the mer-
chant had in fact shipped a sufficient amount of cotton to New York to cover the amount
of the bill (Bodenhorn 2003). Documentary bills could be drawn on banks, but were more
commonly drawn on wholesalers, business partners, and various types of middlemen.
Once a bill was accepted by its drawee, it became known as “two-name” paper and was
eligible for discount (purchase at less than face value) by a bank. Discounting was the
principal means by which antebellum banks extended commercial credit.
The development of the inland bill of exchange was greatly facilitated by the ac-
tivities of the Second Bank of the United States. The Second Bank, modeled after the
22
Bank of England, was founded in 1817, again as a combination commercial bank and
government finance agency. As the sole federally chartered bank, and having an exten-
sive nationwide branch network,20 the Second Bank enjoyed an important advantage over
its state-chartered rivals in the clearing of both banknotes and bills of exchange. During
the 1820s and early 1830s, it put together a national clearing system (Knodell 1998,
Bodenhorn 2000, Weiman and James 2005). Again paralleling developments eighteenth-
century England, negotiability of bills and notes was a critical prerequisite for this proc-
ess.
The impact of the Second Bank’s activities can be measured using historical data
on domestic exchange rates. A characteristic feature of the nineteenth-century American
payments environment, domestic exchange rates reflected the value in one city of funds
held in another city. While every locality in the U.S. came to share a common coinage
and a common unit of account, the value of bank funds and bills of exchange varied by
location.21 In other words, the value of a dollar in a bank account in New Orleans to
someone in New Orleans could be greater or less than the value to that same person of a
dollar held in a bank in New York, according to the time of year and business conditions.
20 Catterall (1902) lists 28 branches and 3 agencies, though not all of these remained open for the life of the
Second Bank.
21 For the congealing of the early US monetary union, see Sylla (2006).
23
Table 2. Spreads on Domestic Exchange, 1830
Intercity bid-ask spread
at the Second Bank of the
Unties States
(% of face value)
Interurban Travel Time
(days)
Within eastern seaboard 0.04 0.76
NY and Lake Erie 0.25 4
NY and South Atlantic 0.28 4
NY and Ohio River 1.2 10
NY and Gulf Coast 1.5 13
Source: Knodell (2003): 23.
Table 2 gives some domestic exchange rates offered by the Second Bank of the
United States in 1830. The rates were largely driven by the travel time between cities.
Information on domestic exchange rates is provided by the prices of a payment instru-
ment known as the sight draft. A sight draft was a specialized type of bill of exchange
that functioned as a sort of “hybrid” between traditional bills of exchange and checks.
Like checks, sight drafts were payable on demand, or “on sight.” Like traditional bills of
exchange, sight drafts were general orders to pay, the drawee of a sight draft did not have
to be a bank, and sight drafts were drawn in one city and paid in another. By selling a
sight draft, a merchant could move his money around the country, by trading funds held
in one city for funds in another.22 The relatively low bid-ask spreads in Table 2 attest to
the development of the domestic exchange system.
22 Another way of making payments over distance was simply to ship coin. The possibility of making pay-
ments in this way kept domestic exchange rates from deviating too much from a value of one-for-one or
“par.”
24
Ironically, the very efficiency of the Second Bank’s clearing operations contrib-
uted to its demise. Through its ability to promptly return banknotes through its branch
network, the Second Bank could and did influence the national money supply, by limiting
the stock of circulating banknotes (Catterall 1902). Prompt redemption was especially
unpopular in the South and West, since it served as a brake on the credit activities of rural
banks. Dissatisfaction with the Second Bank’s activities in this regard led to its dissolu-
tion in 1836 (Green 2003).
The system of interregional payments based on bills of exchange continued to
grow after the closure of the Second Bank. Without the federal bank and its branches, the
system relied on state banks and specialized brokers, and the new system saw domestic
exchange rates decrease. As Table 3 shows, rates were usually lower in the 1840s than in
the early 1830s. The expansion of railroads reduced the time needed to move bills and
information. Also, some scholars argue that competition squeezed margins on exchange,
as a more competitive system replaced the system built on the Second Bank’s privileged
position (Bodenhorn 1992).
25
Table 3. Comparison of Rates of Domestic Exchange (Percent of Face Value)
Bills Drawn on
Second Bank of the United
States, Philadelphia, 1833
Banks and Brokers in New
York City, 1844
Boston 0.25 0
New York 0.25 ---
Philadelphia --- 0
Baltimore 0.25 0
Charleston 1 0
New Orleans 1 0
Nashville 1.5 2
Louisville 1.5 1
Cincinnati 1.5 1
Source: Bodenhorn (1992, 595).
The same interregional system was also supporting the movement of banknotes.
For example, Warren Weber (2003) finds that country (rural and small-town) banks in
Pennsylvania established correspondent banks in Philadelphia, New York and Pittsburgh
that followed trade routes. A correspondent gave the notes of a country bank par accep-
tance in a commercial center. The overall effect of correspondents, note brokers, rail-
roads, and a maturing banking system was a decline in the discounts assigned to bank-
notes due to distance and risk (Gorton 1996).
Checks, in contrast, remained local and concentrated in the larger eastern com-
mercial centers (Spahr 1926, 60-66). Even so, the amount of bank deposits grew as the
number of state banks grew threefold from 378 in 1830 to 1,559 in 1860 (Weber 2006,
30-35)—which suggests a marked increase in the use of checks, at least within local mar-
kets. Gibbons (1859, 114) puts the daily value of check payments within New York at
26
$25 million, as compared to $7 million in circulating banknotes and only $200,000-
$300,000 in bills of exchange.
New York remained something of a special case, however. For the country as a
whole, Figure 4 shows that banknotes in particular remained competitive with deposit
accounts up until outbreak of the Civil War. Nonetheless, while the antebellum era casts
banknotes and bills as rival technologies to checks, the postbellum expansion of checks
would build on the arrangements for interregional clearing created by banknotes and bills
before the Civil War.
Figure 4. Deposits and Notes, 1832-1859
0
50
100
150
200
250
300
1832
1833
1834
1835
1836
1837
1838
1839
184 0
1841
184 2
1843
1844
18
45
1846
18
47
1848
18
49
1850
18
51
1852
18 53
1854
1855
1856
1857
1858
1859
$ Milli on
Deposits
Currency
Source: Historical Statistics of the United States, Table CJ7-21.
7. The post-Civil War rise of checks
The decades following the Civil War witnessed a decisive shift in the American
payments landscape, away from the use of banknotes and bills of exchange, and towards
the use of checks. In a recent paper, John A. James and David F. Weiman (2005) investi-
27
gate the driving factors behind this transition, and find that the key impetus for this
change occurred during the Civil War itself.
Legislation passed by Congress in 1863, 1864 and 1865 placed strong restrictions
on the issue of banknotes (Rockoff 2000, 652). These laws, called the National Banking
Acts, allowed for federally chartered banks called national banks and effectively re-
stricted the issue of banknotes to such banks.23 At the same time, the U.S. Treasury be-
came an active issuer of circulating notes. During the Civil War, the Treasury issued un-
redeemable notes known as “greenbacks” as a war finance measure, which in some
measure displaced private banknotes. Although private banknotes returned after the war,
by the 1880s the U.S. was issuing large quantities of a competitive paper currency in the
form of “silver certificates” (Champ and Thomson 2006). The net result of these actions
was the elimination of state banknotes, and a long decline in the issue of national bank-
notes from 1870 until the turn of the twentieth century.24
Qualitatively, the suppression of privately issued banknotes in the late nineteenth-
century U.S. had much the same effect as in eighteenth-century London, which was to
encourage the use of checks. The decades after Civil War also saw diminished use of bills
of exchange as a payments medium. James and Weiman (2005) note that the outbreak of
the war disrupted markets for bills, and forced many businesses to operate on a cash ba-
sis. A preference for cash was reinforced by the subsequent wartime inflation, which un-
dermined confidence in the value of bills received.
23 See Redenius (2007, 208). To promote par acceptance, the Treasury guaranteed national banknotes, and
each national bank had to maintain par redemption facilities correspondent major-city national bank that
was approved by the Comptroller of the Currency (Redenius 2007).
24 Economists have puzzled over the decline in national banknote issue over this period. National banks
often held government bonds without issuing notes against them, seemingly passing up an arbitrage oppor-
tunity. Champ, Wallace, and Weber (1994) argue that this was due to banks’ difficulties in circulating the
notes, which would have limited the profitability of their issue. Calomiris and Mason (2006) argue that
regulatory constraints and other opportunity costs were more important factor in banknotes’ decline.
28
The National Banking Acts further discouraged the use of bills of exchange by
not allowing national banks to serve as the drawee or “acceptor” of a bill of exchange.
Such bills were known as bankers’ acceptances. By accepting a merchant’s bill of ex-
change, a bank could provide what now might be called “credit enhancement” to that
merchant. With the bank’s credit behind it, an accepted bill could freely circulate as form
of quasi-money. In contemporary England and in other European economies, bankers’
acceptances were a favored instrument for international trade, “wholesale” (business to
business) payments, and short-term commercial credit more generally (Ferderer 2003,
James and Weiman 2005).25
While discouraging the use of banknotes and bills of exchange, the National
Banking Acts laid the groundwork for a national check clearing system through their
regulations on required reserves. All national banks were required to hold reserves
against deposits, but country banks could hold reserves in the form of deposits in national
banks located in larger cities designated as reserve cities by the Office of the Comptroller
of the Currency (Watkins 1929). All banks could hold reserves in the form of deposits on
national banks located in New York. The structure of these requirements encouraged
banks to form correspondent relationships with banks in larger cities and with banks in
New York in particular.26 Such relationships allowed for easier settlement of obligations
between banks. Instead of having to ship coins or notes, obligations between country
banks (“respondents”) and city banks (“correspondents”) could be settled by simply
transferring funds held with the correspondent.
25 Bankers’ acceptances were made legal again by the 1913 Federal Reserve Act. They subsequently be-
came an important vehicle for the finance of international trade, but saw only limited use in the domestic
economy (Ferderer 2003).
26 For example, by 1880 about 90 percent of banks in Georgia had a New York correspondent, and by 1910
this figure had increased to 95 percent (Odell and Weiman, 1998, 112).
29
Improvements in transportation (railroad) and information technology (tele-
graphs) also aided the formation of correspondent networks. The development of a na-
tionwide rail system, in particular, meant that coin and currency could move quickly and
relatively cheaply from place to place, which helped to lower settlement costs and narrow
the range of domestic exchange rates. (Garbade and Silber, 1979).
Another important development during this era was the formation of specialized
organizations for the clearing and settlement of checks among banks in the same city,
known as bank clearinghouses. The first U.S. clearinghouse, the New York Clearing
House, was founded in 1853 and was modeled after the London Clearing House. Banks
in each clearinghouse would meet on a regular basis, exchange checks, and settle net
amounts due by exchange of coins, notes, or drafts (Cannon 1900). By 1915 there were
some 229 bank clearinghouses throughout the United States (James and Weiman 2006).
During this period, a specialized type of check known as the bank draft became
the favored form of interregional payment. A merchant needing to make a payment in
another city could go to his local bank and purchase a bank draft, a check drawn by his
local bank on that bank’s account with its correspondent in a larger city. When presented
with the draft by the payee (or the payee’s bank), the correspondent would then debit the
country bank’s account. The use of bank drafts lessened the need to ship coin or notes to
settle long-distance payments, and allowed for easy extension of business credit by local
banks.
Domestic exchange rates during this period can be measured by the cost of bank
drafts drawn on remote cities, in terms of local funds. Ongoing improvements in inter-
bank relationships led to a gradual decrease in domestic exchange rates. Kenneth D. Gar-
30
bade and William L. Silber (1979) have estimated the average cost of (drafts in) New
York funds in New Orleans from the time of the Civil War to 1920. Table 4 shows some
of their estimates; a clear downward trend can be seen in both the average cost and vari-
ability of New York funds.
Table 4. Cost of New York funds in New Orleans
($ in New Orleans per $1000 New York funds)
Year Average cost Standard deviation
1870 0.76 3.00
1880 1.25 1.30
1890 0.67 0.49
1900 0.67 0.49
1910 0.98 .05
Source: Garbade and Silber (1979, 12-13)
For this period, there are few direct measures of check or draft usage. An excep-
tion is a nationwide survey of bank drafts conducted by the Comptroller of the Currency
for the years 1890, 1891, 1892, cited in Weiman and James (2006). This survey reports
the volume of a subset of drafts, those drawn for settlement purposes by national banks in
outlying areas on their correspondent accounts in banks in larger cities. For 1891 the total
amount of draft transactions was about $12.8 billion, or about four times total U.S. com-
mercial bank deposits for that year (Friedman and Schwartz 1970). The total volume of
bank drafts was doubtless much larger.
31
The strongest evidence for the increased use of bank drafts and checks during this
period is the changing composition of the U.S. money supply (see Figure 5). In 1867, the
ratio of commercial bank deposits to currency (coins, banknotes, and greenbacks) was
equal to about 1.9. By 1890, total deposits were more than three times the stock of cur-
rency, and by 1914, deposits were in excess of seven times currency (Friedman and
Schwartz 1970). Such an increase would not have been possible without a concomitant
increase in the liquidity of bank deposits.
Figure 5. Deposi ts and Cu rrency, 1867-1929
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
1867
1870
1873
1876
1879
1882
1885
1888
1891
1894
1897
1900
1903
1906
1909
1912
1915
1918
1921
1924
1927
$ Billion
Deposits Currency
Source: Historical Statistics of the United States, Table CJ42-48.
32
8. Checks go national, 1890-1914
Up until the Civil War, checks had functioned as a purely local form of payment.
This began to change after the war, as improvements in correspondent relationships,
transportation facilities, and communication networks lessened the cost of long-distance
check payments. Over time checks began to displace both bank drafts and bills of ex-
change as the favored instruments for long-distance payments.
During this time no single entity was in a position to offer nationwide clearing
and settlement of checks. Banks could rarely branch beyond their home cities and there
were other obstacles, such as state-by-state variations in payments law. Collecting on a
long-distance check could be a complicated process. Consider a hypothetical example of
a Mississippi bank wishing to collect a check drawn on a bank in Georgia.27 In some in-
stances, the two banks might share a common correspondent. Clearing and settlement
could be quite straightforward in such cases: the Mississippi bank could forward the
check to the correspondent, and the correspondent could then present the check to the
Georgia bank. Settlement would occur by means of the common correspondent debiting
the account of the Georgia respondent, and crediting the books of the Mississippi respon-
dent.
Quite often, however, the two banks would not share a correspondent. The Mis-
sissippi bank could then, for a fee, make use of the services of another Georgia bank, one
that was a correspondent of the paying bank, and have the check presented through that
correspondent. This type of check, known as an “irregular” check, could pass through
27 We assume for the purpose of this example that the check drawn on the Georgia bank is payable at the
town where the Georgia bank is located. In reality, it was common at this time for checks to be drawn in
one location but payable at another (Chang, Evans, and Garcia-Swartz 2005).
33
many banks before it was finally presented. In the example, the Mississippi bank might
first send the check to its usual correspondent for collection, which would then pass it to
another correspondent, and so on. Sometimes the routing of a check was driven more by
respondent-correspondent relationships and fee structures, than by physical proximity.
Cannon (1900, 74) discusses the infamous case of an irregular check drawn on a
bank in Sag Harbor, New York, and received in Hoboken, New Jersey. Despite the rela-
tively short distance between the payee and the paying bank (about 100 miles), the check
changed hands ten times during its collection, taking at least 11 days in the process. Such
circuitous routing, however, was probably not normal. A recent detailed study of the
1910 records of a rural Illinois bank (Chang, Evans, and Garcia Swartz 2005) finds that
even this isolated bank was usually able to present checks by direct routes, without resort
to the meandering type of routing described in Cannon’s example.
The settlement of irregular checks could be accomplished by shipment of coin,
currency, or through a bank draft drawn on a correspondent. In the case of many rural
banks, payment was often not for the full amount of the check. The difference between
the face value of the check and the amount actually paid, known as a remittance charge
or exchange charge, was supposed to cover the cost to the paying bank of either shipping
currency or coin, or obtaining the necessary bank draft (Jessup 1967, 6) for settlement.
Banks that levied remittance charges were known as nonpar banks. According to Spahr
(1926, 102), most remittance charges varied between one-fourth to one-tenth of the face
value of the check. This amount was small for each individual check, but potentially large
in the aggregate, given the ever-growing volume of checks.
34
The pre-1914 check processing system tended to concentrate costs of collecting
checks on banks in larger cities, both in terms of the costs of presenting checks drawn on
rural banks, and also in terms of the explicit pass-through of settlement costs via remit-
tance charges. This allocation of costs was the subject of frequent complaints on the part
of the city banks. Nonetheless, competitive pressures often forced city banks to accept
their customers’ checks at par, even if these were drawn on a bank in remote location and
costly to collect (Spahr 1926, 113).
Much has been written on the U.S. check payment system during this era. The
traditional view of this system, from writers such as Cannon (1900), Hallock (1903), and
Spahr (1926), is of a haphazard arrangement riddled with inefficiencies. In more recent
analyses, this assessment has been echoed by some writers (e.g., Duprey and Nelson
1986), while others (e.g., Lacker, Walker, and Weinberg 1999) have challenged this
characterization, arguing instead that the system allotted the costs of check clearing and
settlement in a reasonable fashion, given the fractured nature of the U.S. banking system
at that time.
While this debate continues, it must be recognized that the formation of the early
twentieth-century check payment system represented a considerable achievement. By this
time, it had become the world’s largest (noncash) payment system,28 tying together more
than 27,000 individual banks throughout the U.S.29 Those with access to demand deposit
accounts (meaning at the time, mostly businesses and wealthy individuals) could, for the
28 Riesser (1911, 148-149) cites the following figures for payments turnover in 1907/8: RM 260 billion for
England (payments through London Clearing House), RM 305 billion for Germany (Reichsbank), and RM
366 billion for the U.S. (New York Clearing House). We convert those into $61.5 billion for the London
Clearing House, $72.2 billion for the Reichsbank, and $86.6 billion for the New York Clearing House. We
calculate the exchange rate of 0.2367 $/RM using the following observations collected by Neal and Wei-
denmeir (2003): on 4 January 1908 the Berlin short on London was 20.495 RM/ and the bid rate in Lon-
don of demand bills on New York was 4.852 $/.
29 Bank numbers are from Bodenhorn and White (2006).
35
first time, reliably send a payment virtually anywhere in the country by simply mailing a
check. For most situations, there was no longer a need to make long-distance payments
by drawing or purchasing a bill of exchange or banker’s draft. Kinley (1910, 200) esti-
mates the contemporary share of checks in business-to-business transactions, or “whole-
sale trade,” at 90 percent. The success of the check payment system was all the more re-
markable for its decentralization: each bank was connected to this system only through
correspondents of its own choosing (James and Weiman 2006).
A downside was cost. Irregular check clearing cycles and decentralized settlement
required banks to hold high levels of reserves, and long check clearing times inconven-
ienced both banks and their customers. Restrictions on bank branching made it difficult to
construct more coordinated clearing arrangements. Several regional clearing systems
were put into place, most notably a New-England wide system sponsored by the Boston
Clearinghouse (Hallock 1903, ch. 5), but these were special cases. There was consider-
able resistance to even modest attempts at coordination, such as the standardization of
remittance fees nationwide (Duprey and Nelson 1986).
One area where improvements did take place was in the harmonization of state
laws on checks and other types of negotiable paper. This harmonization was initiated
through the actions of a voluntary association, the National Conference of Commission-
ers on Uniform State Laws (NCCUSL). The NCCUSL drafted a model negotiable in-
struments law that was adopted by most state legislatures by 1916 (Freyer 200, 478).30
The reports prepared for the National Monetary Commission, published in 1910-
11, offer some illuminating comparisons of the early twentieth-century U.S. payment sys-
30 This law has subsequently been updated, most significantly in the 1950s with the creation of the Uniform
Commercial Code (UCC) which, in modified form, continues to govern check payments today (NCCUSL
2007). Modern check payments are also governed by Federal Reserve Regulations J and CC.
36
tem to contemporary counterparts in other countries. Below we briefly review the cases
of England and Germany.
Payments in early twentieth-century England, like the U.S., depended heavily on
the use of checks. However, bankers’ acceptances were legal in England, and these were
used for large-value commercial payments up until the First World War (Holden 1955).
As in the U.S., check processing was organized around a network of regional clearing-
houses (Withers 1911).
Nonetheless, interregional clearing arrangements in England were much more
straightforward than in the U.S. Large London banks had nationwide branches and could
clear many checks internally. Bank of England notes or accounts were a universal me-
dium of settlement (Hallock 1903, Holland 1911, Matthews 1921) and domestic ex-
change rates did not exist. Nonpar banking had been abandoned in 1858 (Hallock 1903,
38-39) when the London Clearing House initiated a specialized arrangement (“Country
Cheque Clearing”) for the clearing of checks drawn on banks outside of London. The
practice of par clearing was enforced by an agreement among participating banks, not to
accept checks drawn on banks that refused to clear at par.
The early twentieth-century payment system in Germany had its own system of
seventeen regional clearinghouses, but these were relatively unimportant since Germany
made little use of checks. Banknotes were used more widely than in England, although
the issue of these was effectively restricted to the central bank, the Reichsbank. Bills of
exchange and bankers’ acceptances were used in commercial transactions. More com-
monly, however, commercial payments were made through a type of payment system
known as a giro system. In a giro system, the payor initiates the payment by sending an
37
instruction directly to his bank, rather than sending an order to pay (say, in the form of a
check) to a payee.
The German giro system was initiated by the Reichsbank in 1876, and it allowed
its users to make payments nationwide (to a network of nearly 500 branches) by transfer-
ring balances held with the Reichsbank. In its original conception, this system was open
to anyone subject to the restriction that they keep at least 1000 marks on deposit with the
Reichsbank, which tended to limit its use to banks, governmental entities, and large
commercial enterprises. This service was soon extended to allow non-account holders to
make payments, although the payee had to have an account with the Reichsbank. Eventu-
ally, this convenient and popular system was made available to individuals and smaller
firms through the banking arm of the post office (Riesser 1911, Wittner and Wolff 1911).
In short, at the beginning of the twentieth century payment arrangements in other
leading industrialized countries were noticeably more streamlined than in the United
States. Congressional dissatisfaction with this situation contributed to the passage of the
Federal Reserve Act in 1913.
9. Checks and the Federal Reserve, 1914-1945
The Federal Reserve Act of 1913 created the first truly national “player” in the
payments industry since the demise of the Second Bank of the U.S. Not surprisingly, the
Federal Reserve’s entry into the payments business resulted in major changes in the U.S.
payments environment. The Fed’s impact can best be described as evolutionary, however.
The Fed did not displace the existing check payment system, but it did move this system
towards a more unified national structure.
38
The first change implemented by the Fed was the elimination of domestic ex-
change rates. Section 16 of Federal Reserve Act enabled Federal Reserve Banks to settle
obligations among themselves by transferring reserves through what became known as
the “Gold Settlement Fund” (Kemmerer 1920, 75-76; Spahr 1926, ch. 8). In 1918 the
Leased Wire System (later called Fed Wire, and more recently, Fedwire) was created to
allow the Reserve Banks to easily transfer their holdings of the Gold Settlement fund by
telegraph (Spahr 1926, 209). Fed Wire was also be used to settle obligations between
banks that were members of the Federal Reserve System. For these banks, the ability to
send funds by wire eliminated the need to settle check payments by shipping notes, bank
drafts, or coin. Domestic exchange rates, already quite close to par, quickly became ir-
relevant and quotations for bank drafts disappeared by 1920 (Garbade and Silber 1979,
7). James and Weiman (2006, 26-27) note that the use of Fed Wire also sharply reduced
the average time to collect checks received in New York that were drawn on banks in re-
mote cities. Based on contemporary surveys, the average time to collect such checks fell
from 5.3 days in 1912 to 2.4 days in 1918, with quicker settlement via Fed Wire account-
ing for most of the difference.31
The second change implemented by the Fed was to be more controversial. Sec-
tions 13 and 16 of the Federal Reserve Act authorized the Fed to directly enter the check
clearing business. The Fed quickly set up a nationwide clearing system, participation in
which was mandatory for banks that were members of the Federal Reserve System. Sec-
tion 16 of the Federal Reserve Act also directed each Reserve Bank “… to receive on de-
31 Gilbert (2000) shows that the post-Federal Reserve drop in check collection times coincided with a drop
in banks’ “cash assets” (cash, deposits with other banks, and checks in the process of collection). This was
in part due to a reduction in statutory reserve requirements, but was probably also due to increased effi-
ciency of check clearing.
39
posit at par …” checks or drafts from other Reserve Banks or member banks. Federal Re-
serve officials interpreted this instruction as a general mandate to eliminate the practice
of nonpar banking, not only among member banks, but among all banks more generally.
Almost immediately the Fed began a forceful campaign against remittance charges, fre-
quently sending messengers directly to rural banks to collect checks over the counter, at
par (Spahr 1926, 250).
In rural areas, the Fed’s aggressive presentment practices met with a hostile re-
ception, much as did the Second Bank’s prompt presentment of banknotes almost a cen-
tury earlier. Rural banks, many of whom depended on redemption fees for a substantial
portion of their profits, responded through legislative action. Laws were passed in a num-
ber of predominantly agricultural states,32 entitling banks to charge redemption fees of
one eighth or one tenth of a percent (Jessup 1967, 11). The passage of these laws, in turn,
led to extensive litigation, culminating in a 1923 Supreme Court decision that validated
the state laws and prevented the Fed from mandating universal payment at par (Spahr
1926, 269-276). The Federal Reserve responded by ceasing to accept checks drawn on
nonpar banks, leaving the processing of such checks up to the nonpar banks’ correspon-
dents.
Despite this setback, the Federal Reserve came to dominate the check clearing in-
dustry during the 1920s. This was in part due to the Fed’s forceful promotion of its ser-
vices, but also partly by default. Commercial banks faced legal obstacles to branching
beyond their home states and could not have established a competitive nationwide check-
clearing network. Correspondents and regional clearinghouses continued to be important
32 Including all the states in the Sixth Federal Reserve District.
40
for local check clearing, while the Federal Reserve Banks tended to specialize in the
clearing of interregional checks (American Bankers Association 1954).
Although use of the Federal Reserve’s services was not compulsory, clearing
through the Fed was an attractive option. Settlement of checks cleared through the Fed
was free to member banks, prompt and at par. Moreover, the Fed was often willing to
credit a bank that submitted a check for collection, before it had received funds from the
paying bank, thus subsidizing banks through the creation of “Federal Reserve float”
(Spahr 1926, 542). For member banks, already low service charges for check collection
were abolished in 1918 (Spahr 1926, 212). Nonmember banks were also eligible to use
the Fed’s services (so long as they agreed open settlement accounts and to clear at par),
and by 1920, over 26,000 banks were clearing some checks through the Fed (Spahr 1926,
225). Aided by these enticements, the Fed’s share of check clearing grew throughout the
1920s (see Table 5 below).
Table 5. Volume of Checks Processed by the Reserve Banks
Year Millions of
checks
Dollar value of
checks (billions)
Value of checks processed by Reserve Banks
as a percentage of checks cleared through
clearing houses
1915 8.8 $4.7 2.9%
1920 452.1 156.5 35.6
1925 716.5 247.2 49.4
1929 852.1 351.7 49.1
1934 754.7 171.9 65.1
Source: Gilbert (2000, 131)
Under the Fed’s leadership, par clearing of checks quickly became the norm. By
1928, only 15 percent of banks were nonpar, and the assets of these banks amounted less
41
than 4 percent of total bank assets (Duprey and Nelson 1986, Stevens 1998). Nonpar
banks persisted in outlying areas, but continued to dwindle in importance.33
The general effect of the Fed on check payments was to transform the fragmented
pre-1914 check payment system to something more closely resembling the prewar Eng-
lish system. There were both winners and losers in this transition. Large urban banks
were the clear winners, while rural banks who had formerly been able to levy remittance
charges, and in some cases their correspondents, were clearly disadvantaged. But checks
indisputably became more prevalent. In 1929, the Federal Reserve Banks cleared 834
million checks with a value of $311 billion (see Table 5), a figure representing over seven
times the value of all deposits held at commercial banks. By the end of the 1920s, Ameri-
cans were writing well over a billion checks a year: the check had arrived.
The events of the Great Depression worked to reinforce the Fed’s dominance in
check clearing, in two ways. First, failures of some prominent correspondents under-
mined banks’ confidence in private clearing arrangements. Recent research by Gary
Richardson (2005) indicates that the failure of correspondents lead to the closure of 247
respondent banks between 1929 and 1933.34 Second, the outbreak of the Depression saw
a massive overall contraction in the banking industry. Between 1929 and 1933, over
10,000 commercial banks in the U.S. went out business (about 40 percent of the total
number in 1929), largely for reasons of insolvency (Richardson 2005). These failures
were disproportionately concentrated among small, rural banks that did not use the Fed-
33 When nonpar banking was finally eliminated in 1980, only fifteen nonpar banks remained, all in Louisi-
ana (Baxter 2003, 74).
34 Almost 100 of these failures can be traced to the 1930 failure of a single correspondent bank in Nash-
ville, Caldwell and Company (Richardson 2005, 18).
42
eral Reserve for check clearing. The net effect was a drop in the overall level of checks
written, but a marked increase in the Fed’s share of the clearing market (see Table 5).
10. Postwar expansion, 1946-1979
The strong postwar growth in the U.S. economy led to an extraordinary increase
in the demand for payments services. Over much of this period, this demand was met pri-
marily through the increased use of checks. The check payment system simultaneously
underwent a number of noteworthy changes that, though again evolutionary in nature and
largely invisible to the check writer, greatly improved the overall scope and efficiency of
the system. These improvements led to an unprecedented expansion in check use, as can
be seen in Figure 6.
Figure 6. Number of check payments in the U.S., selected years
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
Billions of payments
43
Sources: American Bankers Association (1954, 1981), Powers (1976), Gerdes and
Walton (2002), Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2007b).35
A critical development was the mechanization of check processing through the
introduction of MICR (magnetic ink character recognition) technology. By the early
1950s, the check payment system had almost become a victim of its own success. Post-
war prosperity had expanded the use of checking accounts by middle-class households,
leading to a “crisis” in check processing. The overall number of checking accounts in the
U.S. almost doubled between 1939 and 1952, from 27 million to 47 million, while the
annual number of checks written increased at an even more rapid rate, from 3.5 to 8 bil-
lion (American Bankers Association 1954). While there was some use of automation, in
the 1950s most check processing was still done by hand. A check that moved across
banks was manually sorted and tallied six times on average (McKenney 1995, 41), and
continued restrictions on bank branching guaranteed that 80 percent of checks fell in the
latter category (American Bankers Association 1954).
In response to this situation, researchers at Stanford University, working in coop-
eration with the Bank of America, developed the MICR processing technology that is
now the industry standard. MICR encodes the information necessary for processing a
check—the bank’s identifying number, the bank account number, the check amount,
etc.—on a single line at the bottom of the check, printed in magnetic ink. A model of
“backward compatibility,” the MICR line did not alter the basic appearance of the check,
which now became readable by both machines and humans. MICR did not completely
eliminate the role for labor in check processing, since someone still had to enter the
35 Check numbers shown in Figure 6 represent available estimates, with no claim to statistical consistency
of estimates across years.
44
amount of the check on the MICR line. By reducing the costs of check processing, how-
ever, it paved the way for massive expansion in check volume that was to follow.
Following the Bank of America’s successful pilot program in 1954, in 1956 the
American Bankers Association designated MICR as the standard for automated process-
ing of checks in the U.S. (McKenney 1995, 50-51). Although the cost advantages of this
technology soon became apparent, adoption took some time. By 1962, 97 percent of
banks were encoding some checks with MICR (American Bankers Association 1962), but
many checks continued to be processed by hand. MICR did not become the full industry
standard until 1967, when all checks routed through the Federal Reserve were required to
contain the MICR-coded identification of the bank on which they were drawn (Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 1967).
In 1972, the Fed initiated another significant change in the check payment system
when it opened a number of Remote Check Presentment Centers (RCPCs) throughout the
country. RCPCs are specialized check processing facilities located in areas without a
Federal Reserve Bank or branch. With the creation of the RCPC network, the Federal Re-
serve was able to directly present checks to over 70 percent of the nation’s banks. In
some cases, the RCPCs also became important local check processing centers, displacing
local clearinghouses in the process. During the 1970s, nationwide average check process-
ing times dropped by about one-half day to 1.9 days, due in part to the expansion of the
Fed’s network (American Bankers Association 1981).
With the postwar improvements in processing, checks were increasingly used for
everyday consumer payments. The annual number of checks written in the U.S. quadru-
pled between 1952 and 1979 to 32.7 billion, a more than 5 percent average annual rate of
45
increase (American Bankers Association 1981). The term “check” became virtually syn-
onymous with “payment other than by cash.”
This period also saw the development of some new alternatives to check pay-
ments: credit cards, which began to be extensively used in the 1960s (Evans and
Schmalensee 1999) and direct electronic payments from bank accounts (automated clear-
inghouse or ACH payments), which were available on a nationwide basis beginning in
1978 (NACHA 2007). But checks continued to dominate, comprising an estimated 85.7
percent of noncash payments in 1979 (Gerdes and Walton 2002).
11. Rationalization of the U.S. check payment system, 1980-1995
Despite ever-increasing volume, by the 1970’s certain limitations of the check
payment system were becoming apparent. The advent of MICR and advances in informa-
tion technology lowered processing costs, and allowed banks to transmit and receive in-
formation about checks in transit. However, the process of check collection continued to
be governed by the rules of negotiable instruments law, which required that a check be
presented to the paying bank before it can be paid. A transition to fully electronic proc-
essing could not begin without some modification of this principle.36
During the 1970’s this legal inflexibility, combined with near-universal par bank-
ing and high inflation rates, worked to foster inefficient use of the check payment system.
This inefficiency arose through a phenomenon known as check float. Check float refers to
the lag between the time a check is deposited at the payee’s bank, and the time the check
is paid by the paying bank. An extra day of float means that the paying bank, and perhaps
36 As is the case now, during this period banks could have voluntarily agreed to presentment of checks in
electronic form. But this was uncommon since it was not to any single bank’s advantage to do so.
46
the drawer of the check, gains an extra day’s interest on the funds in question. As interest
rates began to rise in the 1970s, check float became a material concern. Banks and their
corporate customers discovered that by paying bills with checks drawn on banks at re-
mote locations (engaging in “remote disbursement”), and conversely, by collecting
checks as quickly as possible (“expedited collection”), they could generate significant
interest savings.
Incentives to engage in these practices were exacerbated by the Federal Reserve’s
traditional practice of granting “Federal Reserve float” for checks deposited at the Fed,
but not yet collected. Federal Reserve float had declined in the 1940s and 1950s with the
greater use of air transportation, but grew through the 1960s and 1970s. As shown in Fig-
ure 7, by December 1978 the average daily value of such “items in the process of collec-
tion” had ballooned to $7.5 billion.
Figure 7. Federal Reserve Float, 1950-1990
(daily average figures for December)
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
1950
1952
1954
1956
1958
1960
1962
1964
1966
1968
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
$ Billion
47
Source: Federal Reserve Bulletin, various issues.
In a purely theoretical sense, float should not have been costly to the U.S. econ-
omy. Float effectively lowers the (nominal) price of goods purchased by check, but over
the longer run one would expect this effect to “wash out” as the prices of other goods ad-
justed (McAndrews and Roberds 2000). In practice, however, float generated two signifi-
cant costs. The first cost derived from the activities of banks, corporations, and individu-
als “playing the float game,” that is, engaging in costly practices such as remote dis-
bursement and expedited collection in an attempt to capture float benefits, including the
benefits of Federal Reserve float (Lacker 1997). The second cost arose from distortions in
the choice of payment method, since check float can generate a private benefit to the
writer of a check, even if there is no corresponding social benefit.
As a result of this divergence, the presence of check float can induce people to use
checks for payment when other methods of payment might be more efficient. David B.
Humphrey (1984) estimated that the private cost (to payor and payee) of the typical check
payment in 1983 was actually negative (-$.15), once the benefits of float were taken into
account. The corresponding social cost was estimated at $.68. For other payment meth-
ods, the situation was reversed. For example, due to the payor’s foregone interest on the
cash, Humphrey estimated that the 1983 private cost of a typical cash payment ($.19) eas-
ily exceeded its social cost ($.07).37
The Monetary Control Act of 1980 sought to correct this situation by requiring
the Federal Reserve to charge interest for float. More generally, it sought to rationalize
the Federal Reserve’s provision of financial services, including check collection, by re-
quiring the Fed to charge for such services in a way that recovered the costs of providing
37 Similar estimates are reported in Humphrey and Berger (1990).
48
them. As a result the Federal Reserve began to price many aspects of check collection
that had previously been financed through seigniorage (the collection of interest on bonds
held against currency and bank reserves). Federal Reserve float declined rapidly, to a
daily average of $1.5 billion by 1983 (Humphrey 1984). Explicit pricing of the Fed’s ser-
vices reduced its share of the “interbank” check processing market (processing of checks
drawn on an account at one bank and payable at another) from about 50 percent to 30
percent, but also increased efficiency in the Fed’s check-clearing operations (Bauer and
Hancock 1993).
The 1980’s also witnessed the relaxation of restrictive bank branching laws and
the beginning of a wave of bank mergers (Rhoades 2000). Between 1980 and 1995, the
total number of banks fell in the U.S. contracted by about 5,000 to just under 10,000
banks, while the number of branches rose by over 15,000 to 68,000. The increasingly
consolidated nature of the U.S. banking industry meant that more checks could be cleared
within individual banks (or “on-us”), thereby limiting the demand for Fed check clearing
services.
Operational advances in check processing over this period revealed another short-
coming in traditional check-payment law, which was the procedure for dealing with
checks returned by the paying bank (say, for insufficient funds). Again, the traditional
rules of negotiable instruments determined how a returned check went back to the bank
where it was first deposited, known as the depositary bank. This meant that the returned
check had to follow, in exactly the reverse order, the chain of endorsements that occurred
during the original, or “forward” attempt to collect on the check. This lengthy process, so
well suited to the pace of seventeenth-century commerce, was clearly out of touch with
49
the demands of a modern economy. Lags in the return process meant that banks were re-
luctant to grant prompt access to deposited funds, as this would have exposed them to
risk of nonpayment (Allison 1982). Such delays were frustrating for depositors, however,
and public dissatisfaction with this situation led to the 1987 passage of the Expedited
Funds Availability Act (EFAA).
The EFAA offered two important reforms. The first was the creation, for the first
time in U.S. history, of standardized nationwide schedules for the availability of funds
from deposited checks.38 Second, to speed the return of unpaid checks and to safeguard
banks against the risks of nonpayment, EFAA allows for “expeditious return” of unpaid
checks. This means that a paying bank may directly return a check to the depositary bank,
bypassing the chain of endorsements in forward collection (Board of Governors 2007a).
12. Check payments after 1995
The number of check payments in the U.S. is estimated to have peaked at 49.5
billion in 1995. By the 1990s, checks had begun to lose significant market share to alter-
native payment systems such as credit cards, debit cards, and automated clearinghouse
payments (see Figure 8). Quantitative evidence suggests that the erosion has been great-
est for checks written by consumers (Gerdes and Walton 2002), and especially among the
young, wealthy, and well educated (Klee 2006). This downward trend continues. By
2003, checks were outnumbered by electronic competitors for the first time (Gerdes et al.
2005), and by 2006, checks’ market share had fallen to a “mere” 33 percent of noncash
payments in the U.S. (Board of Governors 2007b). A byproduct of the falloff in check
38 Generally these require availability of funds in two business days for local checks, and five business days
for non-local checks Detailed schedules are described in Federal Reserve regulation CC, which implements
EFAA.
50
volume has been a contraction of the Fed’s check processing network—many RCPCs
have been closed and checks are no longer processed at many Federal Reserve Bank
branches (Financial Services Policy Committee 2007).
Figure 8. Composition of U.S. Retail Payments, selected years
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
1979 1995 2000 2006
Billions of payments
ACH
Debit Card
Credit Card
Check
Sources: Gerdes and Walton (2002), Board of Governors (2007b).39
As check volumes continue to fall, two significant policy initiatives have sought
to further rationalize the U.S. check payment system. The first of these, check conversion,
allows certain categories of checks to be converted to automated clearinghouse transac-
tions.40 This often occurs, for example, in retail checkout situations where a check is
scanned for its MICR information and handed back to the customer. Once converted,
such checks are considered electronic payments, and do not enter the traditional check
39 Check figures for 2006 do not include the estimated 2.6 billion checks that were converted to ACH trans-
actions.
40 Some types of checks, such as business checks, are not eligible for conversion.
51
collection system (Board of Governors 2001). An estimated 2.6 billion checks were con-
verted in 2006 (Board of Governors 2007b).
A second policy initiative has been the 2003 passage of the Check Clearing for
the 21st Century Act, known in the industry as “Check 21.” This law was passed partly in
response to the events of September 11, 2001, which disrupted the air transport of checks
to paying banks (Ferguson 2002). Check 21 allows a check payment to be collected
through the use of a “substitute check,”41 i.e., a certified paper copy of an electronic im-
age of the check. For example, a check deposited at a bank in San Francisco might be
scanned, transmitted electronically across the country, then printed out and presented to a
paying bank in New York. Optionally, the paying bank may decide to allow checks to be
presented as electronic images or simply as computer files containing the relevant MICR
information.42
The practical effect of these policy initiatives was initially somewhat modest—a
March 2006 Fed survey found that 90 percent of checks were still being cleared by tradi-
tional means (Board of Governors 2007a), but a more recent survey found that 40 percent
of checks are being “electronified” at some stage in the clearing process (Board of Gov-
ernors 2007b). Industry observers widely predict that traditional paper processing will be
phased out over the next few years.43 We would also argue that these initiatives are mo-
mentous in the history of the check, since they diminish what has historical been the key
principle of check payments, the binding of an order to pay with the (original) paper
41 Known as an image replacement document or IRD.
42 Additional information on Check 21 can be found at the Federal Reserve Board’s website,
www.federalreserve.gov/paymentsystems/truncation/default.htm.
43 See, for example, “Financial Insights Sees Image Networks Becoming Victims of Their Own Success,”
Businesswire, June 26, 2007. The Federal Reserve plans to eliminate traditional paper processing at most
locations, and will instead offer electronic scanning of checks and printouts of IRDs (Financial Services
Policy Committee 2007).
52
check itself. In other words, by allowing for ACH conversion, and payment of substitute
checks and images, the U.S. check payment industry has taken some decisive steps away
from the very feature—negotiability—that allowed it to flourish in the first place.
Such measures are clearly necessary if checks are to continue to exist in an elec-
tronic world. In the not-so distant future all checks U.S are likely to be processed in
purely electronic form. At one level, this would tend to blur the distinctions between
checks and other forms of payment—why is an electronic file containing information
about a check fundamentally different from an electronic file of an ACH or card pay-
ment?
Nonetheless we would argue that even a fully electronified check industry would
likely retain a distinctive, relatively decentralized character. Especially in contrast to card
payment systems, check payments are not organized into proprietary networks, where the
owner(s) of the network determine(s) rules for clearing, settlement, and pricing for all
payments that flow over that network. And, for the time being, a bank may still insist on
presentation of a paper document—in the form of a check or its IRD—before it pays a
(non-converted) check. In this essential characteristic, a check written in the U.S. today
still resembles a check written in eleventh-century Basra.
13. Summary and conclusion
The check has a long and varied history. Originally functioning as a convenient
form of payment between local merchants, checks were in common use in the eastern
Mediterranean by the tenth century. In sixteenth-century Europe, the versatility of checks
was enhanced by development of negotiability. Eighteenth-century suppression of bank-
53
notes in England helped to further promote the use of checks. In the United States, checks
assumed a new importance when nineteenth-century banking legislation discouraged the
use of other forms of payment, eventually leading to the formation of a nationwide check
payment system. The twentieth century saw a rapid expansion of check payments under
the leadership of the Federal Reserve, and checks became the “default” mode of non-cash
payment within the U.S.
From this history we can draw at least two broad inferences concerning the future
of checks. On the negative side, the late twentieth-century predominance of checks in
U.S. payments clearly represents something of an anomaly, more attributable to historical
vicissitude than underlying economics. Without limitations on bank branching and on
alternative forms of payment, it is unlikely that checks would have come to so completely
dominate the nation’s payments landscape. Technological innovation and legal reforms
have now removed much of the force of these restrictions, and there is no reason to be-
lieve that people will continue to use checks where other forms of payment are cheaper or
more suitable.
On the positive side, the features of the check that have contributed to its sur-
vival—its versatility and legal certitude—persist today. Checks still offer a reasonably
low-cost, well understood, and widely accepted method of payment accessible to anyone
with a bank account. And in many situations, for example in informal payments between
individuals and in many real estate transactions, there remain few convenient alternatives
to using a check. It is unlikely that a form of payment with a more than thousand-year
history will vanish overnight.
54
References
Allison, Theodore W., 1982. Statement before the U.S. Senate, Committee on Banking,
Housing, and Urban Affairs, Subcommittee on Consumer Affairs, March 10.
American Bankers Association (joint with the Association of Reserve City Bankers and
the Conference of Presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks), 1954. Study of Check
Collection System.
American Bankers Association, 1962. “97% of Banks Encode Checks,” Banker, April,
47-48.
American Bankers Association (joint with Bank Administration Institute and the Federal
Reserve System), 1981. A Quantitative Description of the Check Collection Sys-
tem.
Andreau, Jean, 1999. Banking and Business in the Roman World. Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press.
Ashtor, Eliahu, 1972. “Banking Instruments between the Muslim East and the Christian
West.” Journal of Economic History 1, 553-573.
Bauer, Paul W. and Diana Hancock, 1993. “The Efficiency of the Federal Reserve in
Providing Check Processing Services.” Journal of Banking and Finance 17, 287-
311.
Baxter, William F., 1983. “Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper: Legal and Regula-
tory Perspectives.” Journal of Law and Economics 26, 541-588.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 2001. Revisions to Staff Commentary
on Regulation E. March 13.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 2007a. Report to the Congress on the
Check Clearing for the 21st Century Act of 2003. April.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 2007b. The 2007 Federal Reserve
Payments Study. December.
Bodenhorn, Howard, 1992. “Capital Mobility and Financial Integration in Antebellum
America.” Journal of Economic History 52, 585-610.
Bodenhorn, Howard, 2000. A History of Banking in Antebellum America, New York,
Cambridge University Press.
Bodenhorn, Howard, 2002. State Banking in Early America: A New Economic History.
New York: Oxford University Press.
Cannon, James G., 1900. Clearing-houses: Their History, Method, and Administration.
New York, D. Appleton and Company.
Catterall, Ralph C.H., 1902. The Second Bank of the United States. Chicago, University
of Chicago Press.
Calomiris, Charles W. 1988. "Institutional Failure, Monetary Scarcity, and the Deprecia-
tion of the Continental," Journal of Economic History 48, 47-68.
55
Calomiris, Charles W. and Joseph R. Mason, 2006. “Resolving the Puzzle of the Underis-
suance of National Bank Notes.” Working paper, Columbia University.
Capie, Forrest and Alan Weber, 1985. A Monetary History of the United Kingdom, 1870-
1982. Volume I: Data, Sources, Methods. London, George Allen & Unwin.
Champ, Bruce and James B. Thomson, 2006. “National Bank Notes and Silver Certifi-
cates.” Working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Champ, Bruce, Neil Wallace, and Warren E. Weber, 1994. “Interest Rates under the U.S.
National Banking System.” Journal of Monetary Economics 34, 343-358.
Chang, Howard H., David S. Evans, and Daniel D. Garcia-Swartz, 2005. “The Econom-
ics of Market Coordination for the Check-Clearing System in the Late 19th Cen-
tury United States.” Manuscript.
Checkland, S.G. 1975. Scottish Banking a History, 1695-1973. Glasgow.
Clapham, J. 1944a. The Bank of England: A History. Volume 1 1694-1796. Cambridge.
De Roover, Raymond, 1948. Money, Credit, and Banking in Mediaeval Bruges. Cam-
bridge, Mass., the Mediaeval Academy of America.
DeRosa, Luigi (2001). “The Beginnings of Paper Money circulation and Neapolitan Pub-
lic Banks (1540-1650),” Journal of European Economic History Winter 30(3):
497-532.
Evans, David S. and Richard L. Schmalensee 1999. Paying with Plastic: The Digital
Revolution in Buying and Borrowing. Cambridge, MIT Press.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 1967. “Automated Check Processing: September 1,
1967 Deadline Approaching.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, May,
15-16.
Ferderer, J. Peter, 2003. “Institutional Innovation and the Creation of Liquid Financial
Markets: The Case of Bankers’ Acceptances, 1914-1934.” Journal of Economic
History 44, 175-178.
Financial Services Policy Committee, 2007. “Federal Reserve Banks Announce Changes
To Increase Check Service Efficiency,” Press release, June 26. Washington, D.C.,
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Freyer, Tony A., 2000. “Business Law and American History.” In Stanley L. Engerman
and Robert E. Gallman, eds., The Cambridge Economic History of the United
States, Vol. II: the Long Nineteenth Century, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press, 435-482.
Ferguson, Roger W. 2002. Statement before the U.S. House of Representatives, Commit-
tee on Financial Services, Subcommittee on Financial Institutions and Consumer
Credit, September 25.
Garbade, Kenneth D. and William L. Silber, 1979. “The Payment System and Domestic
Exchange Rates: Technological versus Institutional Change.” Journal of Mone-
tary Economics 5, 1-22.
Garcia-Swartz, Daniel D., Robert W. Hahn, and Anne Layne-Farrar, 2006. “The Move
56
Toward a Cashless Society: A Closer Look at Payment Instrument Economics,”
Review of Network Economics 5(2), 175-198.
Gerdes, Geoffrey R. and Jack K. Walton II, 2002. “The Use of Checks and Other Non-
cash Payment Instruments in the United States.” Federal Reserve Bulletin 88,
360-74.
Gerdes, Geoffrey R., Jack K. Walton II, May X. Liu, and Darrel W. Parke, 2005. “Trends
in the Use of Payment Instruments in the United States.” Federal Reserve Bulletin
91, 180-201.
Gibbons, James S., 1859. The Banks of New-York: Their Dealers, the Clearing-House,
and the Panic of 1857. New York, D. Appleton and Company.
Gilbert, R. Alton, 2000. “The Advent of the Federal Reserve and the Efficiency of the
Payments System: The Collection of Checks 1915-1930.” Explorations in Eco-
nomic History 37, 121-148.
Gorton, Gary, 1996. "Reputation Formation in Early Bank Note Markets," Journal of Po-
litical Economy 104, 346-397.
Green, Edward J., 2003. “Economic Perspective on the political history of the Second
Bank of the United States.” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Economic Perspec-
tives 27: 59-67.
Grubb, Farley, 2003. “Creating the U.S. Dollar Currency Union, 1748-1811: A Quest for
Monetary Stability or a Usurpation of State Sovereignty for Personal Gain?”
American Economic Review 93, 1778-1798.
Grubb, Farley, 2006. “The US Constitution and Monetary Powers: an Analysis of the
1787 Constitutional Convention and the Constitutional Transformation of the US
Monetary System.” Financial History Review 13, 43-71.
Heckscher, Eli. F., 1934. “The Bank of Sweden in its connection with the bank of Am-
sterdam.” In History of the Principal Public Banks, J.G. van Dillen, ed., the
Hague, Martinus Nijhoff.
Holden, J. Milnes 1955. The History of Negotiable Instruments in English Law. London,
The Athlone Press.
Holland, Robert Martin, 1911. The London Bankers Clearing House. Volume VIII of the
Report by the National Monetary Commission to the U.S. Senate, 61st Congress,
2nd session, Doc. 492. Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office.
Hudson, Patricia, 1986. The Genesis of Industrial Capital: A Study of the West Riding
Wool Textile Industry, 1750-1850. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Humphrey, David B., 1984. “The U.S. Payments System: Costs, Pricing, and Risk.”
Monograph, Salomon Brothers Center for the Study of Financial Institutions, New
York University.
Humphrey, David B. and Allen N. Berger, 1990. “Market Failure and Resource Use:
Economic Incentives to Use Different Payment Instruments.” In David B. Hum-
57
phrey, ed., The U.S. Payment System: Efficiency, Risk, and the Role of the Federal
Reserve. Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers.
James, John A. and David F. Weiman, 2005. “Towards a More Perfect American Pay-
ments Union: The Civil War as a Political Economic Watershed.”
James, John A. and David F. Weiman, 2006. “From Drafts to Checks: The Evolution of
Correspondent Bank Networks and the Formation of the Modern U.S. Payments
System, 1850-1914.” Manuscript.
Kahn, Charles M. and William Roberds, 2007. “Transferability, Finality, and Debt Set-
tlement.” Journal of Monetary Economics 47, 299-319.
Kemmerer, Edwin W., 1920. The ABC of the Federal Reserve System. Princeton, Prince-
ton University Press.
Kinley, David, 1910. The Use of Credit Instruments in Payments in the United States.
Volume VI of the Report by the National Monetary Commission to the U.S. Sen-
ate, 61st Congress, 2nd session, Doc. 399. Washington, D.C.: Government Print-
ing Office.
Klee, Elizabeth, 2006. “Families' Use of Payment Instruments during a Decade of
Change in the U.S. Payment System,” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System Finance and Economics Discussion Paper 2006-01.
Kohn, Meir, 1999. “Early Deposit Banking.” Working paper, Dartmouth College.
Knodell, 2003. “Duty and Profit in the Second Bank of the United States Exchange Op-
eration,” Financial History Review 10, 5-30.
Lacker, Jeffrey M., 1997. “The Check Float Puzzle.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Quarterly 83(3), 1-25.
Lacker, Jeffrey M., Jeffrey D. Walker, and John A. Weinberg, 1999. “The Fed’s Entry
into Check Clearing Reconsidered.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Eco-
nomic Quarterly 85(2), 1-31.
Matthews, Philip W., 1921. The Bankers’ Clearing House: What it is and what it does.
London, Sir Isaac Pitman & Sons.
McAndrews, James J. and William Roberds, 1999. “A General Equilibrium Analysis of
Check Float,” Journal of Financial Intermediation.
McKenney, James L., 1995. Waves of Change: Business Evolution through Information
Technology. Boston, Harvard Business School Press.
Melton, Frank T. 1986. Sir Robert Clayton and the Origins of English Deposit Banking.
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Michener, Ronald and Robert Wright, 2005. “State "Currencies" and the Transition to the
U.S. Dollar: Clarifying Some Confusions.” American Economic Review 95, 682-
703.
Michener, Ronald and Robert Wright, 2006. "Development of the US Monetary Union."
Financial History Review 13, 19-41.
58
Mitchell, D. 1995. “Mr. Fowle Pray Pay the Washwoman: The Trade of a London Gold-
smith-Banker, 1660-1692.” Business and Economic History 23, 27-38.
Mueller, Reinhold C., 1997. The Venetian Money Market: Banks, Panics, and the Public
Debt 1200-1500. Baltimore.
Munro, J. 2000. “English ‘Backwardness’ and Financial Innovations in Commerce with
the Low Countries, 14th to 16th centuries.” In Stabel, P., Blondéé, B. and Greve
A. eds. 2000, International Trade in the Low Countries (14th - 16th Centuries):
Merchants, Organisation, Infrastructure. Leuven-Apeldoorn: 105-67.
NACHA (The Electronic Payments Association). History of NACHA-The Electronic
Payments Association. Accessed online at www.nacha.org, June 29, 2007.
NCCUSL (The National Conference of Commissioners on Uniform State Laws). History.
Accessed online at www.nccusl.org, July 9, 2007.
Neal, Larry and Marc D. Weidenmier, 2003. "Crises in the Global Economy from Tulips
to Today: Contagion and Consequences." Globalization in Historical Perspective,
Michael D. Bordo, Alan M. Taylor and Jeffrey G. Williamson, editors. NBER
Conference Report series, Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 473-510.
Nishimura, S. 1971. The Decline of Inland Bills of Exchange in the London Money Mar-
ket 1855-1913. Cambridge.
Norman, Ben, Rachel Shaw, and George Speight (2006). The evolution of payment ar-
rangements and central banks. Mimeo, Bank of England.
Powers, R. William, 1976. “A Survey of Bank Check Volumes.” Journal of Bank Re-
search 6, 245-256.
Pressnell, L. 1956. Country Banking in the Industrial Revolution. Oxford.
Quinn, Stephen, 1997. “Goldsmith-Banking: Mutual Acceptance and Inter-banker Clear-
ing in Restoration London.” Explorations in Economic History 34, 411-32.
Quinn, Stephen and William Roberds 2003. “Are On-Line Currencies Virtual Bank-
notes?” Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review 88, 1-15.
Redenius, Scott, 2007. “Designing a National Currency: Antebellum Payment Networks
and the Structure of the National Banking System.” Financial History Review 14,
207-228.
Rhoades, Stephen A., 2000. “Bank Mergers and Banking Structure in the United States,
1980-1998.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Staff Study 174.
Richards, R.D., 1934. “The first fifty years of the Bank of England (1694-1744).” In His-
tory of the Principal Public Banks, J.G. van Dillen, ed., the Hague, Martinus Ni-
jhoff.
Richardson, Gary, 2005. “Bank Distress during the Great Contraction, 1929 to 1933,
New Data from the Archives of the Board of Governors.” Working Paper, Uni-
versity of California at Irvine.
Riesser, J. 1911. The German Great Banks and Their Concentration in Connection with
the Economic Development of Germany. Volume XIV of the Report by the Na-
59
tional Monetary Commission to the U.S. Senate, 61st Congress, 2nd session, Doc.
593. Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office.
Rockoff, Hugh, 2000. “Banking and Finance, 1789-1914.” Cambridge Economic History
of the United States Volume II, edited by Stanley Engerman and Robert Gallman.
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 643-684.
Rogers, James S., 1995. The Early History of the Law of Bills and Notes: A Study of the
Origins of Anglo-American Commercial Law. Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press.
Spallanzani, Marco, 1978. “A Note on Florentine Banking in the Renaissance: Orders of
Payment and Cheques.” Journal of Economic History 7, 145-68.
Spufford, Peter, 1988. Money and Its Use in Medieval Europe. Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press.
Sylla, Richard, 2006. "The Transition of Monetary Union in the United States, 1787-
1795." Financial History Review 13, 73-95.
Tamaki, Norio, 1995. Japanese Banking: A History 1859-1959. Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press.
Temin, Peter and Hans Joachim Voth, 2006. "Banking as an Emerging Technology:
Hoare's Bank, 1702-1742" Financial History Review, 149-78.
Usher, Abbot P., 1934. “The Origins of Banking: the Primitive Bank of Deposit, 1200-
1600.” Economic History Review 4, 399-428.
Usher, Abbot P. 1943. The Early History of Deposit Banking in Mediterranean Europe.
Cambridge.
Van der Wee, H. 1977. “Monetary, credit and banking systems.” In E.E. Rich and C.H.
Wilson, eds., The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, Volume V. Cam-
bridge, Cambridge University Press, 290-393.
Van der Wee, H. 1997. “The Influence of Banking on the Rise of Capitalism in North-
West Europe, Fourteenth to Nineteenth Century.” In Alice Teichova, Ginette
Kurgan-van Hentenryk, and Dieter Ziegler, eds., Banking, Trade, and Industry:
Europe, America, and Asia from the thirteenth to the twentieth century. Cam-
bridge, Cambridge University Press, 173-190.
Van Dillen J.G., 1964. “Oprichting en Functie der Amsterdamse Wisselbank in de zeven-
tiende Eeuw 1609-1686” [Establishment and functioning of the Amsterdam ex-
change bank in the seventeenth century]. In J.G. van Dillen, ed. Mensen en
Achtergronden, Studies uitgegeven ter gelegenheid van de tachtigste jaardag van
de schrijver. Groningen, J.B. Wolters, 336-384.
Watkins, Leonard, 1929. Banker’s Balances: A Study of the Effects of the Federal Re-
serve System on Banking Relationships. Chicago.
Weber, Warren, 2003. “Interbank Payments Relationships in Antebellum America: Evi-
dence from Pennsylvania,” Journal of Monetary Economics 50, 455-74.
60
Weber, Warren, 2006. “Early State Banks in the United States: How Many were there
and Where did they Exist?” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Re-
view 30, 28-40.
Wells, Kirsten E., 1996. “Are Checks Overused?” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Quarterly Review 20(4), 2-12.
Withers, Harley, 1911. The English Banking System. Volume VIII of the Report by the
National Monetary Commission to the U.S. Senate, 61st Congress, 2nd session,
Doc. 492. Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office.
Wittner, Max and Siegfried Wolff, 1911. The Method of Payment by Means of Bank-
Account Transfers and the Use of Checks in Germany. Volume XI of the Report
by the National Monetary Commission to the U.S. Senate, 61st Congress, 2nd
session, Doc. 508. Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office.
... Medieval merchants and bankers took advantage of this benefit of paper checks (Quinn and Roberds, 2008), yet it seems that Potterians have yet to discover this technology. ...
Preprint
Full-text available
Recent studies in psychology and neuroscience offer systematic evidence that fictional works exert a surprisingly strong influence on readers and have the power to shape their opinions and worldviews. Building on these findings, we study what we term Potterian economics, the economic ideas, insights, and structure, found in Harry Potter books, to assess how the books might affect economic literacy. A conservative estimate suggests that more than 7.3 percent of the world population has read the Harry Potter books, and millions more have seen their movie adaptations. These extraordinary figures underscore the importance of the messages the books convey. We explore the Potterian economic model and compare it to professional economic models to assess the consistency of the Potterian economic principles with the existing economic models. We find that some of the principles of Potterian economics are consistent with economists models. Many other principles, however, are distorted and contain numerous inaccuracies, contradicting professional economists views and insights. We conclude that Potterian economics can teach us about the formation and dissemination of folk economics, the intuitive notions of naive individuals who see market transactions as a zero-sum game, who care about distribution but fail to understand incentives and efficiency, and who think of prices as allocating wealth but not resources or their efficient use.
... Correlativamente, sólo 10% de los documentos movilizó altos valores unitarios (desde 5 525 pesos hasta la excepcional suma de 111 204.87 pesos registrada por un cheque). Ello indica que los montos no se circunscribían a transacciones de alto valor unitario(Quinn y Roberds, 2008). ...
Article
El propósito del artículo consiste en evidenciar que todo medio de pago admitido como dinero conlleva tanto la materialización de un compromiso asumido por su emisor como beneficios potenciales resultantes de la provisión de instrumentos transaccionales admisibles. Consecuentemente, los cambios materiales e institucionales experimentados en el largo plazo por los medios de pago han implicado modificaciones en los modos de formular aquellos compromisos y en la manera de negociar la distribución de los beneficios reportados. El caso del Río de la Plata, una economía carente de producción metalífera local, ofrece un observatorio para comprender el modo en que distintos gobiernos materializaron sus compromisos en medios de pago y distribuyeron los beneficios obtenidos de su provisión, lo que demuestra los cambios experimentados entre el periodo hispánico y el posrevolucionario a fin de focalizar, entonces, en el cambio que abrió la puerta a un periodo cuya matriz se sostiene desde entonces: la irrupción del sistema bancario y sus instrumentos de pago.
... The cheque paper first emerged in the early 11th century by Iranian backpacker Nasir-i Khosrau in Basra, Iraq. It recorded one form of payment known as the cheque as a written order from a merchant to his bank to m and make a payment from his account (Quinn & Roberds, 2007). The use of cheques in the eastern Mediterranean in the Islamic World area began in the first millennium (Ashtor, 1972). ...
Article
Full-text available
The study aimed to determine the relationship between returned cheques, GDP, bank credit, and public spending in Jordan during 2000-2021. The research developed the econometric model using the ARDL for co-integration. The study found several outcomes: returned cheques have a strong positive impact on GDP in the short term, public spending has a short-term positive effect on returned cheques, and bank credit negatively affects returned cheques in Jordan. The Granger causality test proves causal relationships between bank credit to public spending and from the returned cheques to the GDP in Jordan. Finally, it found that returned cheques affected economic growth in the long term. The long-term effect of public spending, bank credit, and GDP on returned cheques is not proved. The study presents that returned cheques as a financial phenomenon and must be purely resolved from an economic perspective rather than the legislative and legal view.
Chapter
Full-text available
Means of exchange holding legal tender are not the unique means of payment that materialize currency. Any device accepted by the creditor enables exchanges, even when different instruments have different scope of liquidity and diverse broadness of acceptance. Therefore, admission by economic actors appears to be the ultimate criteria to embody monetary attributes into a material instrument, conferring its function as means of payment. In this sense, the agency of involved actors is critical to understand the emergence of new financial devices derived from institutional changes. This chapter aims to examine the appearance and diffusion of a new means of payment, the bank check, in the early nineteenth-century economy of South America, specifically Buenos Aires. As the main issuers of checks gained leverage in using this means of payment, they contributed to enhancing its acceptance in the local economy. To demonstrate this hypothesis, this chapter employs Social Network Analysis tools to understand the relational structure of the check’s flows and elucidate the position of the actors within that web.
Article
Kıymetli evrak bugünkü anlamını son yüzyılda kazanmıştır. Ancak ilk dönemlerinden bu yana İslâm hukukunun benimsendiği toplumlarda çeşitli kıymetli evrak türleri kullanılmaktadır. Modern hukuktaki sınırlı sayı ilkesi ve katı şekil kurallarının aksine, İslâm hukukunda kıymetli evrak ve düzenlenme biçimine dair dar bir çerçeve çizilmemiştir. Dolayısıyla evrensel hukuki düzenlemelere konu olan bütün kıymetli evrak türleri, düzenleme biçimi itibariyle İslâm hukukunun hiçbir ilkesi ile çelişmemektedir. Bu itibarla İslâm hukukunun farklı dönemlerinde kullanılan değişik kıymetli evrak türlerinin, modern hukukta öngörülen şekillere göre tanzim edilmesi mümkün görülmektedir. Türklerin İslâmiyet’i kabulüyle birlikte Türk devletlerinde hukuk sisteminin temelini İslâm hukuku oluşturmuş; Osmanlı Devleti’nde de bazı hukuk dallarında yüzyıllarca İslâm hukuku esasları benimsenmiştir. Bu kapsamda İslâm hukukundaki kıymetli evrak türleri de Türkler tarafından kullanılmaya başlanmıştır. Bu husus tarihi gelişim süreci içerisinde Türk hukuk tarihi açısından büyük öneme sahip olup İslâm hukukunda kıymetli evrakın incelenmesi günümüz kıymetli evrak hukukunun temellerinin anlaşılması, uyuşmazlıkların Türk toplumuna yerleşmiş olan hakkaniyet ve adalet anlayışı çerçevesinde çözülmesi bakımından da önem arz etmektedir.
Chapter
This handbook aims to provide a comprehensive (though obviously not exhaustive) picture of state-of-the-art international scholarship on the history of money and currency. The chapters of this handbook cover a wide selection of research topics. They span chronologically from antiquity to nowadays and are geographically stretched from Latin America to Asia, although most of them focus on Western Europe and the USA, as a large part of the existing research does. The authors of these chapters constitute, we hope, a balanced sample of various generations of scholars who contributed to what Barry Eichengreen defined as "the new monetary and financial history" – an approach that combines the analysis of monetary aggregates and policies with the structure and dynamics of the banking sector and financial markets. We have structured this handbook in ten broad thematic parts: the historical origins of money; money, coinage, and the state; trade, money markets, and international currencies; money and metals; monetary experiments; Asian monetary systems; exchange rate regimes; monetary integration; central banking and monetary policy; and aggregate price shocks. In this introduction, we offer for each part some historical context, a few key insights from the literature, and a brief analytical summary of each chapter. Our aim is to draw a map that hopefully will help readers to organize their journey through this very wide and diverse research area. Link to accepted version: http://hdl.handle.net/10016/38214