ArticlePDF Available

Abstract and Figures

Alchian and Allen’s “third law of demand” states that as a fixed cost increases by the same amount for low- and high-quality goods, the ratio of the prices of high- to low-quality goods will fall and the quantity demanded of high quality goods relative to low quality goods will increase. We examine the more general hypothesis by estimating the ratio of the quantities of sales of premium to regular grade gasoline using the ratio of premium to regular prices, controlling for supply and demand factors. We find moderate evidence for the more general hypothesis.
Content may be subject to copyright.
The Pricing of Gasoline Grades and the Third Law of Demand
R. Morris Coats, Nicholls State University;
Gary M. Pecquet, Shenandoah University;
and Leon Taylor, Tulane Universitya
Abstract:
Alchian and Allen’s “third law of demand” states that as a fixed cost increases by the same
amount for low- and high-quality goods, the ratio of the prices of high- to low-quality goods will
fall and the quantity demanded of high quality goods relative to low quality goods will increase.
We examine the more general hypothesis by estimating the ratio of the quantities of sales of
premium to regular grade gasoline using the ratio of premium to regular prices, controlling for
supply and demand factors. We find moderate evidence for the more general hypothesis.
JEL Codes: D120 - Consumer Economics: Empirical Analysis
Keywords: Third Law of Demand, Price Ratios, Gasoline Grades
a Correspondence for this article should be addressed to R. Morris Coats, Department of Finance and Economics,
Nicholls State University, Thibodaux, LA 70310, or to his email address: morris.coats@nicholls.edu. We thank
participants in an industrial organization session of the Southwestern Economics Association meetings for 2005,
especially Seung Mo Choi.
1. Introduction
Alchian and Allen’s (1967, pp. 62-64) famous “third law of demand” suggested that a
cost change that adds the same amount to the price of both low- and high-quality goods will
lower the price of the higher quality (and higher price) good relative to the lower quality good.
A decrease in the price ratio increases the quantity demanded of the higher quality good relative
to that of the lower quality good. Of course, perverse income effects could wipe out any
substitution effects, leaving the total effect ambiguous; but we will present evidence that the
income effect in the relative demand for premium is likely weak.
Earlier studies of Alchian and Allen’s third law” of demand have depended upon adding
a fixed per unit shipping cost to both high-quality and low-quality substitute products. The
results have produced some confusion. Gould and Segall (1969) show that Alchian and Allen’s
theorem only holds in a two-good world, and may not hold in a world of more than two goods.
Borcherding and Silberberg (1978) show that if two goods are close substitutes, the Alchian and
Allen result still holds. Some ambiguities arose over the interpretation of “fixed charge.” Cowen
and Tabarrok (1995) pointed out that the “fixed charge” must be applied on a per unit basis.
Consequently, it mattered whether the goods were shipped to the consumers or the consumers
shipped to the goods.
Other articles have used the “third law” to examine the effects of quantity-based excise
taxes upon the quality consumed (James and Alston, 2002). Barzel (1976) applied the “third law”
to the per unit excise taxation of cigarettes, gasoline and alcoholic beverages. In the case of
cigarettes, he found that such taxes could be more than fully passed forward to consumers
because a tax increase lowered the ratio of prices of high-quality to low-quality cigarettes, so that
2
the higher quality and more expensive cigarettes would be substituted for the cheaper smokes.
With regard to gasoline and alcoholic beverages, Barzel found nothing of significance.
Razzolini, Shughart and Tollison (2003) have argued that the “third law” could not be
properly tested without considering the supply side. They argued that adding a fixed per unit cost
(i.e. transportation or taxes) to goods will affect the relative prices of high and low quality goods
depending upon whether or not the different qualities are produced in competitive or monopoly
markets and also upon the nature of long-run cost for each of the qualities (increasing, decreasing
or constant cost industries). While it is certainly true that these supply considerations affect the
relative prices of the two qualities, their interpretation of the “third law” recasts it from a demand
theorem to a hypothesis about markets.
We also believe that supply conditions should be taken into account, but only as controls.
In this paper, we examine the basic premise of the “third law” by analyzing the effect of relative
prices of premium to regular grades of gasoline upon the relative consumption of the grades after
controlling for other demand and supply influences. As the prices of both grades increase by the
same amount, the relative price of premium falls. To non-economists, focused only upon the
income effect, higher prices would induce people to switch towards the cheaper grades. On the
other hand, the “third law” (or substitution effect) suggests that people would switch towards the
higher quality premium grades. Our method of testing for the “third law” also avoids the pitfalls
of including transportation cost mentioned above. We put the “third law” to the test, not by
considering some common incremental change to prices (as in Nesbit, 2005), but by looking at
the more general case of changes in price ratios of high- and low-quality goods and the effect of
such changes on consumption ratios of high- to low-quality goods.
3
2. Basic Theory
Gasoline is one item out of many that people buy. Of course, in the short run, people are
stuck living a certain distance from work, schools, shopping areas and friends, and they can do
little to change those distances. They are also stuck with their current means of transportation
and will have difficulty switching between alternative fuels. To some degree, a household may
switch between alternative grades of gasoline, and it can make these substitutions more easily
with certain vehicles than with others and more easily if it owns more than one vehicle.
The choice between gasoline (in general) and all other goods involves only a little
substitutability, as we observe long-run estimates of price elasticity of demand around -0.86 and
short-run estimates around -0.26 (Dahl and Sterner 1991, pp. 210).
While gasoline and all other goods are not close substitutes, one grade of gasoline should
be a relatively close substitute for another grade, if people are at least able to substitute gasoline
grades across the vehicles they drive. Substitution across grades is more likely to occur when
there is a change in price ratios across grades, as is the case when the price spread between two
grades of gasoline stays the same, yet the prices of both rise, cutting the ratio of high- to low-
priced grades. With such price ratio changes, the ratio of purchases of high- to low-priced grades
should increase.
3. Empirical tests
3.1 Data
The dependent variable, prgas, is the ratio of the number of gallons of premium gasoline
sold to the number of gallons of regular gasoline sold in a given month and in a given state in the
United States. The first difference of this variable is prgasdiff.
4
The current price variable is prprice, the ratio of the price of a gallon of premium
gasoline to the price of a gallon of regular gasoline in a given month and state. The prices
include local, state and federal fuel taxes. An n-month lag of a variable is denoted with the
prefix Ln. For example, the one-month lag of the dependent variable is L1.prgas. The
differenced variable is prpdiff.
Data on sales and prices excluding taxes come from the Web page of the U.S. Energy
Information Administration (http://tonto.eia.doe.gov/STEO_Query/app/papage.htm). Data on
state fuel taxes were collected from the Highway Statistics
(http://www.fhwa.dot.gov/policy/ohpi/hss/hsspubs.htm) and Monthly Motor Fuel Reported by
States (http://www.fhwa.dot.gov/ohim/mmfr/mmfrpage.htm) series of the Federal Highway
Administration; corrections were provided by e-mail or by phone by the transportation or finance
departments of the state governments. The state governments also provided data on local fuel
taxes, which we weighted by population when adding them to fuel prices. The state taxes
include sales taxes, environmental taxes (such as fees for a Leaking Underground Storage Tank
fund), and inspection fees based on gallons used. The local and federal taxes are excise taxes
that are quantity-based or (for many local taxes) sales-based.
A control for cost factors is Crude, which measures the real acquisition cost of crude oil
per barrel to the U.S. refineries each month, based on a composite of foreign and imported oil,
and deflated by the producer price index for oil refineries (in 1982 dollars). The cost data were
collected from various issues of the Monthly energy review of the U.S. Energy Information
Administration (http://tonto.eia.doe.gov/FTPROOT/monthlyhistory.htm). The deflator is from
the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (http://data.bls.gov/cgi-bin/surveymost). The differenced
variable is crudediff.
5
Income represents disposable personal income per capita in a given month and state,
expressed in the number of gallons of regular gasoline that the income could purchase. It was
constructed from quarterly income and tax data as well as from annual population data, and it
was deflated by the monthly price of regular gasoline from the U.S. Energy Information
Administration.a Population data were from the Census Bureau’s Statistical abstract of the
United States (http://www.census.gov/prod/www/statistical-abstract-04.html). Income data were
from State quarterly personal income of the Bureau of Economic Analysis
(http://www.bea.gov/bea/regional/sqpi/). Tax data were from the Census Bureau’s Quarterly
summary of state and local tax revenues (http://www.census.gov/govs/www/qtax.html) and from
its Federal tax collections by state, based on the Internal Revenue Service data book for various
years (http://www.irs.gov/taxstats/article/0,,id=102174,00.html). Differenced income is
incomediff.
Time series of 75 months from January 1998 through March 2004 were collected for
each of the 50 states.
Summary statistics are presented in Table 1. The price of premium gasoline exceeds the
price of regular gasoline by only 13 percent, but Americans buy only a sixth as much of premium
as of regular. The relative price of premium varies from 1.3 (Georgia, February 1999) to 1
(North Dakota, October 2001). Relative purchases of premium vary from .51 (New Jersey,
February 1999) to .035 (North Dakota, March 2000). Annual per capita disposable income
a This method of estimating monthly income has the advantage of using all available information; but, because we
lack direct data for monthly income, we have likely introduced a measurement error. Let our measure of monthly
income be Income; and let actual monthly income be Income*. Then it is likely that Income = Income* + e, where e
is a measurement error. Because income tends to rise over time, our measure of income likely underestimates actual
income. This implies that the measurement error has a negative mean and is correlated negatively with actual
income. OLS estimators are thus biased and inconsistent. However, as we see it, the main problem with the
measurement error is that it biases the Income coefficient toward zero; this coefficient is not the main concern of our
analysis.
6
averages 16,283 gallons of regular gasoline, ranging from 9,928 gallons in Georgia (January
2001) to 29,600 gallons in Florida (February 1999).
[Table 1 here]
3.2 Empirical Results
We estimated the model by three-stage least squares in order to disentangle the effects of
supply and demand. The model is in first differences, rather than levels, in part because our
variables for the relative consumption of premium gasoline and for its relative price, prgas and
prprice, may follow random walks and thus induce a spurious correlationb; and in part because
we wished to remove the effects of unobservable variables that were fixed over time and that
may correlate with explanatory variables, since this could render the coefficient estimators
biased and inconsistent. We calculated robust standard errors (White, 1980; Wooldridge, 2003)
because tests indicated heteroskedasticity in the 3SLS equations. Serial correlation is also
present, but it is not significant in magnitude.c
We first discuss the demand model. Generally, the evidence for the third law of demand
is moderate. In differences, the relative sales of premium gasoline respond negatively and highly
significantly to an increase in the relative price of premium gasoline (prprice) with a two-month
lag; the negative coefficient on the three-month lag is significant at the 10% level for a one-tailed
test but not at the 5% level. (The current relative price, and its one-month lag, were dropped
from the model for statistical insignificance.) The price elasticity of demand for premium
gasoline, relative to regular gasoline, is -.097 with a two-month lag and -.05 with a three-month
lag.d
b A regression of each variable on its lag produces a coefficient over .93.
c A regression of the residual of each equation on its lag turned up a coefficient of about -.1.
d Elasticities were estimated from a 3SLS model of the first differences of natural logs.
7
The relative demand for premium may be falling over time. Large vehicles today may be
more likely to use regular gasoline than they were before 1998. Figures 1 and 2 suggest a fall in
the relative demand for premium gasoline: Relative sales of premium gasoline have fallen along
with its relative price.
The fall in the relative price of premium gasoline is not due to the reduction, through
inflation, in the effective tax rate on gasoline, which is indicated by Figure 3. The bulk of the
gasoline tax consists of per-gallon taxes that are the same for premium and regular gasoline (as
opposed to ad valorem taxes). Since 1998, the per-gallon taxes, relative to the untaxed price of
gasoline, have dropped fairly steadily (Figure 3): While few states have lowered their nominal
taxes, few have raised them as rapidly as the rise in gasoline prices. The relative reduction in the
effective tax rate has been greater for regular gasoline than for premium gasoline, since the price
of regular has risen relative to the price of premium. Instead, the fall in the relative price of
premium gasoline seems due either to the fall in relative demand for premium or to the rise in the
cost of crude oil. If the cost of crude is about the same to manufacture a gallon of regular
gasoline as for a gallon of premium gasoline, then a rise in oil costs will raise the relative price of
regular gas that is, lower the relative price of premium gas.
[Figure 1 here]
[Figure 2 here]
[Figure 3 here]
8
The coefficient on per capita personal disposable income, Incomediff, expressed in
gallons of regular gasoline, is positive but not significant. The income elasticity of relative
demand for premium gasoline is .668.
We turn now to the supply model. The coefficients on price and its one-month lag are
positive and highly significant: Measured in differences, the relative supply of premium gasoline
rises with the relative price. Producers are quite sensitive to price: The price elasticity of relative
supply for premium gasoline is 7.85 in the current month and .615 with a one-month lag. The
coefficient on Crude is negative but insignificant. The elasticity of relative supply of premium
gasoline with respect to crude costs is small, as expected: -.03.
The results of the basic model are shown in Table 2.e The constants, Cons, indicate that
the relative quantity of premium gasoline may have fallen over time, holding prices, income and
crude costs constant.
[Table 2 here]
Since 3SLS estimates coefficients by using instrumental variables, it may introduce
noise. For comparison, we provide in Table 3 an OLS model of the relative demand for
premium gasoline.f Lags of the dependent variable are highly significant, and the price
coefficients are positive. We suspect that this model reflects supply factors.
[Table 3 here]
e One can show that the linear demand function used here derives from an indirect money metric utility function
that is quasi-linear and quasi-exponential, in which “income” denotes the budget allocation to purchases of premium
and regular gasoline. We use personal disposable income per capita as a proxy for the budget allocation.
9
Conclusions and discussion
Overall, we find moderate support for the third law of demand in the market for premium
gasoline, in a simultaneous-equations model of demand and supply. We thus avoid conflating
demand and supply factors.
We cannot claim to have isolated the substitution effect, since in theory the income effect
may also increase the relative quantity demanded of premium gasoline. For example, if premium
and regular gasoline are both normal goods, and the absolute price of premium gasoline drops,
then the consumer may spend relatively more of the resulting increase in real income on
premium than on regular gasoline. But we believe that the income effect in the relative demand
for premium gasoline is likely weak: The estimated income elasticity of relative demand is .66,
and the income coefficient in the demand function is statistically insignificant. Also, the usual
$0.20 per gallon price spread between regular and premium is unlikely to have much effect on
most Americans’ buying power. We believe that we are observing primarily the substitution
effect.
f A regression of the residual upon its lag did not indicate serial correlation in this model. The dependent lags have
probably controlled for much of the innate serial correlation.
10
References
Alchian, A.A. and W. R. Allen, 1967, University Economics, 2nd ed. (Wadsworth, Belmont,
Calif.).
Barzel, Y., 1976, An alternative approach to the analysis of taxation, Journal of Political
Economy 84, 1177-97.
Borcherding, T. E. and E. Silberberg, 1978, Shipping the good apples out: The Alchian and
Allen theorem reconsidered, Journal of Political Economy 86, 131–38.
Cowen, T. and A. Tabarrok, 1995, Good grapes and bad lobsters: applying the Alchian and Allen
theorem, Economic Inquiry 33: 253-256.
Dahl, C. and T. Sterner, 1991, Analyzing gasoline elasticities: a survey. Energy Economics 13,
203-210.
Gould, J. P. and J. Segall, 1969, The substitution effects of transportation costs, Journal of
Political Economy 77, 130–37.
James, J. S. and J.M. Alston, 2002, Taxes and quality: a market-level analysis, The Australian
Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 46, 417-445.
Nesbit, T.M., 2005, Taxation and product quality: The gasoline market, working paper (West
Virginia University, Morgantown, W.V.).
Razzoni, L., W.F. Shughart II and R.D. Tollison, 2003, On the third law of demand, Economic
Inquiry 41, 292-298.
U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis, 2005, State quarterly personal income, available at URL:
http://www.bea.gov/bea/regional/sqpi/ (downloaded 5/1/2005).
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, 2004, Consumer price index, available at URL:
http://www.bls.gov/cpi/home.htm (downloaded 10/10/2004).
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, 2004, Producer price index for petroleum refineries, available at
URL: http://data.bls.gov/cgi-bin/surveymost (downloaded 7/1/2004).
U.S. Census Bureau, 2005, Quarterly summary of state and local tax revenues, available at URL:
http://www.census.gov/govs/www/qtax.html (downloaded 5/1/2005).
U.S. Census Bureau, 2005, Statistical abstract of the United States, available at URL:
http://www.census.gov/prod/www/statistical-abstract-04.html (downloaded 5/1/2005).
U.S. Energy Information Administration, 2004, Monthly Energy Review, available at URL:
http://tonto.eia.doe.gov/FTPROOT/monthlyhistory.htm (downloaded 7/1/2004).
11
U.S. Energy Information Administration, 2004, Monthly petroleum data, available at URL:
http://tonto.eia.doe.gov/STEO_Query/app/papage.htm (downloaded 10/10/2004).
U.S. Highway Administration, 1996, Highway statistics, available at URL:
http://www.fhwa.dot.gov/ohim/1996/index.html (downloaded 11/1/2004).
U.S. Highway Administration, 2004, Monthly motor fuel reported by states, available at URL:
(http://www.fhwa.dot.gov/ohim/mmfr/mmfrpage.htm (downloaded 7/1/2004).
U.S. Internal Revenue Service, 2005, Internal Revenue Service data book, available at URL:
http://www.irs.gov/taxstats/article/0,,id=102174,00.html (downloaded 5/1/2005).
White, H., 1980, A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for
heteroskedasticity, Econometrica 48, 817-838.
Wooldridge, J., 2003, Introductory econometrics: A modern approach, 2nd edition (South-
Western, Mason, Ohio).
12
Table 1. Summary Statistics
Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max
prprice 3727 1.129 .0353 1.002 1.299
prgas 3705 .176 .082 .036 .508
crude 3750 23.31 2.24 18.63 27.77
income 3750 16283.0 2896.0 9297.7 29600.2
prgdiff 3644 -.0012 .0129 -.0974 .294
prpdiff 3655 -.00029 .0218 -.0675 1.135
incomedif 3700 -34.8 972.8 -4065.4 4937.8
crudediff 3700 .044 1.26 -3.03 3.45
13
Relative sales of premium gas drop
0
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
0.25
0.3
Mar-97 Jul-98 Dec-99 Apr-01 Sep-02 Jan-04 May-05
Figure 1
14
Relative price of premium gas falls
1.08
1.1
1.12
1.14
1.16
1.18
1.2
Mar-97 Jul-98 Dec-99 Apr-01 Sep-02 Jan-04 May-05
Premium price/relative price
Figure 2
15
Gas tax rates fall
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
Mar-97 Jul-98 Dec-99 Apr-01 Sep-02 Jan-04 May-05
Tax/Untaxed gas price
Tax/reg Tax/prem
Figure 3
16
Table 2. Estimates of the 3SLS model
Equation Obs Parms RMSE "R-sq" chi2 P
qDemand 3409 3 .009826 0.2824 1341.000 0.0000
qSupply 3409 3 .011652 -0.0091 1028.583 0.0000
Coef. Std. Err. Rob. Std. Err.
qDemand
prpdiff
L2 -.1049 .0111 .0101
L3 -.0151 .0053 .0107
incomedf 5.99e-06 1.67e-07 .0114
_cons -.0011 .0002
qSupply
prpdiff
-- .9641 .0317 .0250
L1 .0845 .0126 .0141
crudedff -.0003 .0001 .0109
_cons -.0005 .0002
17
Table 3. Estimates of an OLS model
Number of obs = 3325
F(9, 3315) = 167.61
Prob > F = 0.0000
R-squared = 0.3682
Root MSE = .00909
Robust
prgdiff Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval]
prgdiff
L1 -.1161 .025 -4.65 0.000 -.165 -.0671
L2 -.1215 .021 -5.76 0.000 -.1629 -.0801
L3 -.0717 .0189 -3.80 0.000 -.1087 -.0348
L4 -.0482 .0186 -2.59 0.010 -.0847 -.0117
prpdiff
-- .2657 .0237 11.22 0.000 .2192 .3121
L1 .1661 .0235 7.08 0.000 .1201 .2121
L2 .0005 .0198 0.03 0.979 -.0383 .0394
L3 .0206 .0167 1.24 0.217 -.0121 .0534
Income 4.12e-06 2.34e-07 17.61 0.000 3.66e-06 4.58e-06
Constant -.0012308 .000165 -7.46 0.000 -.0016 -.0009
... Many researches on AA phenomenon have confirmed that the high quality items will be chosen when the difference in relative prices between high and low quality goods is decreasing in various topics (Barzel 1976;Bertonazzi, Maloney, and McCormick 1993;Brown and Ressler 2017;Cowen and Tabarrok 1995;Emlinger and However, some researchers disagree that consumers will move the preference to high-quality goods when there is a change in relative price for substitution goods with different qualities (Hastings and Shapiro 2012;Lawson and Raymer 2006;Sumner and Ward 1981). In addition, a research conducted by Razzolini, Shughart, and Tollison (2003) stated that in two substitute goods, the phenomenon of A-A should include supply and the demand sides, which were lately adopted by Coats, Pecquet, and Taylor (2005). ...
... When the price is added with the fixed cost, the relative price becomes smaller than before which proves the existence of A-A phenomenon. Referring to Coats et al. (2005), Equation (6) can be rewritten into a relative consumption of gasoline to the relative price of gasoline difference as follows: (7) where i = 1,2 and 3 illustrates the lag of month; is the amount of high-quality gasoline realization, and is the amount of low quality gasoline realization. ...
... The used estimation method refers to a research conducted by Coats et al. (2005). The reason for choosing this research is that the study focuses on the relative consumption changes of high to low quality gasoline due to the relative price changes of high to low quality gasoline. ...
Article
Full-text available
In Indonesia, consumers can choose to consume high or low quality gasoline based on their preferences. It might be influenced by the price difference between the two qualities. Changing preference to a higher quality that is affected by the declining relative price can lead to an A-A phenomenon. This study aims to determine whether the A-A Phenomenon occurs on the behavior of consumers before and after the existence of Pertalite. The regression model used are the panel data regressions and the regression result proves that there is an A-A phenomenon in market share in Indonesia before and after Pertalite. This indicates that the high difference of relative prices between high and low quality gasolines has a negative impact towards their relative consumption. Prior to Pertalite, consumers continued changing preference into high quality gasoline in the 2nd and 3rd month intervals when relative price difference decreased. After the existing of Pertalite, consumers did not quickly transfer their preferences from Premium to Pertalite when the relative price declined, so that the A-A phenomenon did not occur in this low and middle grade gasoline consumption pattern. However, Pertamax's consumption to Pertalite increases when the relative price between them declines; thus raising the A-A phenomenon.
... > 0 must hold in this case. Also, Coats, Pecquet, and Taylor (2005) find moderate support for the Alchian-Allen theorem, claiming from their estimates that the income effect in the relative demand for premiumgrade gasoline is likely to be weak. price-dependent income (the market value of the initial endowment): I ≡ q · + m. ...
Article
We generalize the Alchian–Allen theorem so as to account for income and endowment effects and provide two versions of a Generalized Alchian–Allen theorem: one for a unit cost component and one for a proportional cost component. Both versions provide a decomposition of an uncompensated change in the demand ratio of two goods into a substitution effect and an income-endowment effect—and may thus be regarded as extensions of the familiar Slutsky equation for relative demand. Finally, we apply our results to the choice of real estates and to parental time allocation decisions, the latter providing implications for child care policies. (JEL D11, H21, J22, R21)
... First, a literature following Barzel (1976) exploits tax changes to test the Alchian-Allen conjecture that higher category prices result in substitution to higher quality varieties (Sobel and Garrett 1997). In the context of gasoline, Nesbit (2007) and Coats, Pecquet and Taylor (2005) find support for the Alchian-Allen conjecture; Lawson and Raymer (2006) do not. Second, a literature in psychology and economics examines "relative thinking" in which consumers focus on ratios when normative decision theory implies that they should focus on differences (Azar 2007 and. ...
Article
We formulate a test of the fungibility of money based on parallel shifts in the prices of different quality grades of a commodity. We embed the test in a discrete-choice model of product quality choice and estimate the model using panel microdata on gasoline purchases. We find that when gasoline prices rise consumers substitute to lower octane gasoline, to an extent that cannot be explained by income effects. Across a wide range of specifications, we consistently reject the null hypothesis that households treat “gas money” as fungible with other income. We evaluate the quantitative performance of a set of psychological models of decision-making in explaining the patterns we observe. We also use our findings to shed light on extant stylized facts about the time-series properties of retail markups in gasoline markets.
Article
Collecting information on prices is a costly endeavor. The cost depends on the relative ease with which those prices can be collected, and in many retail gasoline markets, there is a substantial divide in the ease of collecting information with regular grade gasoline on one side of the divide and midgrade and premium grade gasoline on the other. Regular grade prices are prominently displayed on large signboards in front of gasoline stations while the prices of higher octane grades, except where required by law, are rarely displayed. In this article, the effects of differential-by-grade price information on search and gasoline price dispersion are examined. A rank reversal test is used to test whether the observed grade-specific price dispersion is consistent with search or non-search related causes and, finding the former, a series of tests are presented to test for the effect of price information and other leading hypotheses. A significantly concave curvature in the price dispersion coefficients across the three grades supports a price information hypothesis. Detailed socioeconomic data on consumers, spatially matched to the stations they are most likely to patronize, shows that income is a secondary factor. Implications for policy are discussed.
Article
We conduct a laboratory experiment that tests two fundamental predictions unique to salience theory. If an agent purchases one of two vertically differentiated products, salience theory makes the following two distinct predictions. First, it hypothesizes that a higher expected price level for both products shifts demand toward the more expensive, high-quality product. Second, it predicts that demand for the high-quality product is larger if the price level is expectedly high than if it is unexpectedly high. In our experiment , subjects purchased fast or slow internet access at different price levels. Our results strongly support both predictions of salience theory. JEL-Classification: D03. We are grateful to Alexander Cappelen, Hans-Theo Normann, Theo Offerman, Gerhard Riener, Bertil Tungodden, Achim Wambach, the editor and three anonymous referees for very helpful comments and suggestions. We also thank conference participants at ESA 2015 (Heidel-berg), NCBEE 2015 (Tampere) as well as seminar participants at University of D ¨ usseldorf and at Michigan State University. In addition, we are grateful to Mats K ¨ oster and Dmitrij Schneider for excellent research assistance.
Article
We formulate a test of the fungibility of money based on parallel shifts in the prices of different quality grades of a commodity. We embed the test in a discrete-choice model of product quality choice and estimate the model using panel microdata on gasoline purchases. We find that when gasoline prices rise, consumers substitute to lower octane gasoline, to an extent that cannot be explained by income effects. Across a wide range of specifications, we consistently reject the null hypothesis that households treat “gas money” as fungible with other income. We compare the empirical fit of three psychological models of decision making. A simple model of category budgeting fits the data well, with models of loss aversion and salience both capturing important features of the time series. JEL Codes: D12, L15, Q41, D03.
Article
Essays on the effects of state and local public policy: Gasoline taxes, clean indoor air regulations, and gross receipts taxes
Article
Full-text available
Following Barzel (1976), product quality increases in response to unit taxation but remains unchanged by ad valorem taxation. While many tax theorists agree this argument is theoretically sound, empirical support of Barzel’s theory is limited to the cigarette market. This paper tests and confirms his theory in the gasoline market, a market in which Barzel failed to find supporting evidence in his original article. Using a direct test proposed by Sobel and Garrett (1997) and improved data, I find the market shares of premium and mid-grade gasoline rise in response to per-unit taxation but are unaffected by ad valorem taxation.
Article
Full-text available
The Alchian and Allen theorem predicts that it will be harder to find "good" apples in the State of Washington, a prime apple-growing region, than in, say, New York City, where the addition of shipping charges makes "bad" apples comparatively more expensive. We recast the theorem as a testable proposition by explicitly taking the supply side into account and identifying plausible scenarios in which a fixed cost either has no effect on the relative prices of high and low quality grades of the same good in distant markets or, indeed, causes more of the bad apples to be shipped out. Copyright 2003, Oxford University Press.
Article
This paper is survey of studies on gasoline demand. Although there are very many different studies in this field which sometimes appear to arrive at contradictory results, we find that with proper stratification of studies by model and data type much of the conflict turns to consensus. In this survey we classify studies by data type and by ten different categories of model and with the exception of estimates on seasonal data, which tend to be unstable, and of certain inappropriate model formulations, we find a fair degree of agreement concerning average short-run and even long-run income and price elasticities.
Article
A conventional assumption of product homogeneity when the commodity of interest is actually heterogeneous will lead to errors in an analysis of the incidence of policies, such as taxes. In this article, an equilibrium displacement model is used to derive analytical solutions for price, quantity, and quality effects of ad valorem and per unit taxes. The results show how parameters determine the effects of tax policies on quality. The potential for tax-induced distortions in quality, and the distributive consequences of those distortions, are illustrated in a case study of the market for Australian wine.
Article
Gould and Segall argued that the introduction of a third, composite good vitiates the Alchian and Allen (A-A) theorem that a common charge on two substitute goods leads, real income held constant, to a relative increase in the consumption of the higher to lower quality commodity. Using Hicks's third law, however, it is demonstrated that the direct substitution effect tends to dominate the interaction effect with the third good, if the two substitutes are close. Absolute changes are also investigated and some operational propositions offered with casual supporting observations. A-A's proposition is shown to be a useful price-theoretic construction, though not a direct implication of the law of demand.
Article
This paper offers an extention of the traditional approach to the analysis of taxation capable of explaining observations attributable to taxation which were not previously explicable. Underlying the change in approach are the premises that every commodity is composed of a set of characteristics whose levels are economically determined and that no tax will be so comprehensively specified as to control all the characteristics of a commodity. Market adjustments to a tax will take place not only in the quantity of the good but also in the make-up of its characteristics. Let us briefly summarize the thrust of the argument. Commodities as transacted in the market are complex, and the margins with respect to which optimization takes place are numerous. Because commodity tax statutes will not generally cover all these margins, any tax will induce multiple changes not only in resource allocation away from the taxed commodity and into others but also in the "quality" of the commodity and how it is transacted, a substitution away from the taxed attributes and into the others. Adjustment in the face of incomplete specification of commodities implies upgrading of quality in the case of a unit tax and downgrading in that of an ad valorem tax. A test of the effect of taxes on cigarettes refutes the conventional hypothesis that quality will not change with a tax. The results are rather consistent with our model, which claims that the effects of unit and of ad valorem taxes will differ both from each other and from those predicted by the conventional model.
Article
The authors consider the well-known theorem of A. Alchian and W. Allen (1964) that adding a per unit charge to the price of two substitute goods increases the relative consumption of the higher price good. The current literature misspecifies the conditions under which the theorem holds. When applying the theorem, the fixed cost should be applied on a per unit basis, rather than in terms of an entry fee for consumption. The authors state the necessary conditions for the theorem to hold when the consumers are shipped to the goods. Copyright 1995 by Oxford University Press.