ArticlePDF Available

Analyzing the impact of legislation on child labor in Pakistan

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

This paper exploits a natural experiment approach to identify the impact of legislation (Employment of Children Act 1991) in Pakistan on participation of children in the labor markets. The law prohibits employment of children less than 14 years of age in sectors other than agriculture or household enterprises. With micro-data, making use of regression discontinuity data design, the study finds some evidence that the Employment of Children Act 1991 helped in reducing the employment of children immediately after its implementation.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Po l i c y Re s e a R c h WoRking Pa P e R 4399
Analyzing the Impact of Legislation on
Child Labor in Pakistan
Tazeen Fasih
The World Bank
Human Development Network
Education Team
November 2007
WPS4399
Produced by the Research Support Team
Abstract
The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development
issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the
names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those
of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and
its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent.
Policy ReseaRch WoRking Pa P e R 4399
This paper exploits a natural experiment approach
to identify the impact of legislation (Employment
of Children Act 1991) in Pakistan on participation
of children in the labor markets. The law prohibits
employment of children less than 14 years of age in
sectors other than agriculture or household enterprises.
This paper—a product of the Education Team in the Human Development Network—is part of a larger effort to estimate
the impact of child labor on schooling outcomes. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://
econ.worldbank.org. The author may be contacted at tfasih@worldbank.org.
With micro-data, making use of regression discontinuity
data design, the study finds some evidence that the
Employment of Children Act 1991 helped in reducing
the employment of children immediately after its
implementation.
Analyzing the Impact of Legislation on Child Labor in Pakistan
Tazeen Fasih*
JEL Codes: I28, J13, J18, J88
Keywords: child labor, legislation, Pakistan
*The World Bank 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC. Email: tfasih@worldbank.org. Earlier
version of the paper has benefited from useful comments from Felipe Barrera, Harry Patrinos
(World Bank), Furio Rosati (UCW), Jonathan Wadsworth, Marco Manacorda and Reza
Arabsheibani (LSE and University of London).
The findings, interpretations conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the author.
1
1 - Introduction
Child labor is a complex socio-economic issue that not only violates the basic human
rights of individual children by hindering their educational, physical and psychological
development, but also impedes the development and equitable growth of economies by
generating an uneducated and relatively unskilled labor force in the long run and thus helping to
perpetuate poverty. Grimsrud (2002) proposes that the endogenous growth theories assume that
individuals maximise lifetime welfare in the form of an inter-temporal utility function, which
allows the perception of child labor as lost investment in one time period. He argues that
according to Lucas’s (1988) theory the more human capital society as a whole accumulates, the
more productive each single member will be. Thus in endogenous growth theory human capital
formation is essential for economic growth.
Historically, no region has ever been completely free of this problem, and over the 1990s
there has been a worldwide movement for the eradication of the worst forms of child labor.
Countries and governments have moved from a complete denial of the existence of the problem
to legislation and positive action for tackling the issue. Pakistan, in this regard, provides an
interesting case study. It implemented few minimum working age laws and labor legislation in
general over the years until the 1980s, and considered child labor to be negligibly small.
However, after ratifying the United Nation’s Convention on the Rights of the Child 1989, the
Government of Pakistan, in April 1991 implemented its most comprehensive nationwide law
against child labor yet, in the form of the Employment of Children Act 1991. The Act provides
that “no child below the age of 14 years shall be employed in any factory or mine or any
2
hazardous employment or in specific occupations, making employment of children a cognizable
offence punishable by fine and imprisonment”.1
The minimum age for work laws target child labor by reducing the demand and/or supply
(depending on the provisions of the Act and how it is implemented) of child labor. This could
help address labor market distortions by raising adult wages and reducing the need for
households to send children to work for financial reasons (Basu 2000). There have been attempts
to theoretically explain the impact that legislation might have on children’s work. Rogers and
Swinnerton (2002) develop a model of exploitative child labor. A key feature of the model is that
the exploitative labor occurs because parents have imperfect information about whether the
employment opportunities available to their children are exploitative or not. In such a model, a
ban on exploitative child labor is desirable and leads to Pareto efficiency since it resolves the
problem of imperfect information faced by parents. Basu (2005), on the other hand, cautions
against imposition of fines for employing child labor since it might increase children’s work in
the short run. In his model a household sends a child to work to attain a particular subsistence
level of consumption. A fine on firms for employing children would mean that a firm that does
so is taking a risk of incurring a punishment cost if caught by the authorities. The firm thus
transfers that cost to the household by reducing wages paid to children. In response, the
households would have to send more children to work to attain the particular subsistence level of
consumption in the presence of lower wages.
Betcherman et al (2004) suggest that child labor and compulsory education laws can be
effective tools for reducing child labor in a number of scenarios. First, in the lines of Roger and
1 The occupations and processes specified in the Act are given in appendix A.
3
Swinnerton (2002) they suggest that it can be effective if the parents do not have full information
about the benefits of education or if the parents are not altruistic and exploit children for their
economic benefit. In Pakistan we expect the former to exist, in particular because of the high
unemployment rates of educated youth which can act as a deterrent for the motivation of both
children as well as parents towards education. The latter scenario may be true for Pakistan as
well, not necessarily because of a lack of altruism, but rather since the concept of childhood in
developing countries is one where the children also hold some responsibility to help the
household adults in a number of ways, one of which usually is helping on household farms or
enterprise, but can also extend to working in the labor market to help the household maintain a
minimum subsistence level of consumption. The second scenario they suggest in which
legislation can be effective id if child labor arises due to market failure such that the employers
preferring to hire lower cost children rather than higher cost adults. This scenario will exist in
economies where the demand for low/unskilled labor is high such as in low income countries
like Pakistan, and children can easily be substituted for adult workers for much lower wages
without much loss in productivity. At the same time, legislation may not be very effective unless
it is implemented properly.
In Pakistan there has been a decrease in the proportion of children involved in work over
the 1990s (Fasih, 2004) and against this background, it is important to investigate how this
decrease has been affected by the Employment of Children Act 1991 (EoCA). This paper aims to
do so by exploiting a quasi-experimental approach to analyze the extent to which the EoCA 1991
affected the decrease in child labor in Pakistan. Since the EoCA specifies a minimum age of 14
years for work, it is expected that it would affect employment rates primarily of children less
4
than 14 years old. Thus, in this paper using regression discontinuity data design, we use the
difference-in-difference estimator to isolate the effect of legislation from the effects of other
factors influencing the child labor market. We analyze the change in probability of work
participation of children affected by the law over the periods immediately before and after the
implementation of the EoCA compared to the change in participation of selected control groups
over the same period. The results appear to suggest that the law reduced the employment of
children less than 14 years of age in Pakistan, and the law appears to be a tool in helping to
reduce the employment of children.
To the best of our knowledge, this paper is one of the first attempts to analyze the impact
of legislation on child labor for one of the present day developing countries after the recent
movement for the eradication of child labor. Basu (2005) in his theoretical paper recommends
empirical research to investigate the effects of anti-child labor legislation, since the impact of
such laws has not been rigorously evaluated.
Economic historians have studied the effect of child labor laws and compulsory education
laws in countries other than Pakistan, on the labor participation rates of children and educational
enrolment. For instance Solmon et al. (1972) study the issues of law and social change by
analyzing the effectiveness of compulsory schooling laws in the United States in the late 19th and
early 20th century. Their study takes into account both, compulsory schooling laws and child
labor laws enacted during that period. The results indicate that the increase in the level of
schooling during the period studied was not caused by the enforcement of laws. Similarly
Moehling’s (1999) study of the impact of state child labor laws at the turn of 19th and 20th
5
century United States also concludes that legislation was not the major factor contributing to the
dramatic reduction in the magnitude of child labor witnessed during the period. These studies
attribute the decrease in child labor to a change in societal attitudes towards children’s work and
rights and also to the improvement in technology which reduced the demand for unskilled labor.
A similar study by Margo et al. (1996) (using data from the 1900 Census of the United States)
does not find a significant effect of the compulsory school laws on school attendance. However,
they find a significant positive effect on the school attendance of children in the states where
compulsory school laws were combined with child labor laws. Lleras-Muney (2001) also
analyses the legislation on compulsory education and child labor in the United States (period
1915-1939). She studies the effect of changes in laws on compulsory education and child labor;
such changes include, for example, increasing the minimum legal requirement for a child to be in
school by increasing minimum age to obtain work permit or decreasing school entrance age. The
results suggest that such changes significantly increased the education attainment of children.
Results show, however, that the impact was not consistent over all races. For instance there was
no impact on African American men.
Manacorda (2003 and 2006) analyses the effect of child labor on household labor supply,
using the 1920 US Census data, to study the degree of parents’ altruism towards their children.
He uses State specific child labor laws to identify a source of exogenous variation in child labor.
As a part of his analysis of labor supply responses of different household members to changes in
the proportion of working children Manacorda finds a strong impact of child labor laws on
children’s labor market participation in the USA in 1920, such that children below the minimum
age were found not to participate in work but the participation increased once the child reached
6
the legal working age. However, this effect is seen only for children involved in market work and
not on household farms, as the minimum age laws did not affect work on household farms.
Therefore, the current literature focuses on late 19th and early 20th century USA. In most
cases the analysis exploits differences in minimum age laws over the various states in the US and
also on the change in minimum age specifies over the years to try to identify the impact of
legislation on child labor. The evidence of the effectiveness of these laws, however, is mixed
with no clear trend appearing.
The rest of the paper is organized as below; the introduction and literature review in this
section is followed by section 2 which discusses the provisions of the Employment of Children
Act 1991. Data and methodology is discussed in section 3. Section 4 presents the results, and the
paper concludes with our main findings in section 5.
2 - Labor Laws in Pakistan
The previous labor laws enacted in Pakistan since the 1920s (in pre-partition India), were
not consistent in defining a particular cut-off age for work/employment of children and applied
only to a few occupations (a brief summary of the laws is given in appendix A, table A1).2 For
instance the Factories Act 1934 (amended 1997) applied only to Factories, where a factory is
defined as a premises where at least 10 or more workers work on a manufacturing process.
Similarly, in Pakistan, these labor laws did not apply to the establishments in the un-organised
sector of the economy (Grimsrud 2002). The EoCA 1991 specifies the minimum age for work
2 For example the Factories Act 1934, the Employment of Children Act 1938, the Mines Act 1923 (see Hyder,
1998).
7
and also specifies the particular occupations and processes where children can not be employed
(see appendix A for details). As such it is applicable and enforceable even in the un-organised
and informal sector, and to establishments that do not come under the definition of a factory.
The EoCA 1991 is also considered more comprehensive because in terms of penalising
the offenders, that is the employers, it is more severe than the other minimum age laws. For
instance, the maximum penalty in case of a contravention of the Factories Act (1997) in terms of
employing an underage child for work is only Rs.500; whereas, under the EoCA 1991 the
penalty can extend to imprisonment for up to a year or a fine of Rs.20000 or both.3
The EoCA 1991 does not prohibit work in establishments or enterprises that are not
related to the occupations and processes specified in the Act. It also does not prohibit children’s
work in the agriculture sector (except where hazardous chemical sprays are used), or work in the
family business, farm or enterprise. However, the Act lays out strict regulations of conditions of
work for children in these occupations.4 For instance a child can not work for more than a period
of 3 hours without a break of at least 1 hour, and the hours of work with the intervals can not
exceed 7 hours a day. Also no child is allowed to work between 7p.m to 8a.m. Thus the EoCA
1991 aims to eliminate the employment of children in the most hazardous occupations and to
regulate the conditions of work for children in other less hazardous occupations.
3 In terms of minimum wages, the minimum wage is fixed at approximately Rs.4000 per month ($66), so Rs.500 is
almost 1/8 of the minimum wage.
4 In order to better regulate the working conditions of adolescents and children more than 12 years of age who are
willing to work (with permission of their legal guardians and a health certificate from a medical practitioner – see
Annex A), the government introduced the Employment of Children Rules in 1995 on the basis of the EoCA 1991.
These rules lay out the working conditions for children in detail and require the maintenance of a register of child
workers.
8
The implementation of labor laws in Pakistan is the responsibility of the Ministry of
Labor and Manpower (MoL).5 The Federal Laws of Pakistan are published by the Government in
a document called the Gazette of Pakistan (The Employment of Children Act 1991 was
published in “Gazette of Pakistan, 1991-04-06, Extraordinary, pp. 69-77”). The notification and
implementation is also reported in the Ministry of Labor’s “Labor Gazette”. Notification of a
new labor Act is sent to the firms operating in a province by the provincial MoL, and district
level labor officers/inspectors are responsible to monitor the implementation of labor regulations
in the various establishments. In the case of EoCA 1991, in addition to the labor
officer/inspector, any person or police officer is allowed to file a complaint of an offence under
the Act in any court of competent jurisdiction. It is expected that given the provisions of the
EoCA 1991, the immediate impact would be on the demand of child labor since it specifies the
employers to be the offenders.
The monitoring and implementation capacity of the provincial and district level officials
might have been low in the early 1990s.6 Thus, we do not claim that the Act was perfectly
implemented in 1991. However, given that the implementation capacity is expected to be low in
any developing country, it would be instructive to see if the legal system can operate to achieve
the desired objectives in a less than perfect scenario.
5 Since under the national constitution labor is regarded as a ‘concurrent subject’, which means that it is the
responsibility of both the Federal and Provincial Governments. However, for the sake of uniformity, laws are
enacted by the Federal Government, stipulating that Provincial Governments may make rules and regulations of
their own according to the conditions prevailing in or for the specific requirements of the Provinces
(http://www.ilo.org/public/english/dialogue/ifpdial/info/national/pak.htm).
6 With the devolution of authority in the early 2000, the government is gradually transferring more authority to the
local councils but even this process has been slow to-date and the capacity of officials at the district level is not
strong.
9
3 - Data and Methodology
3.1 - Data
The empirical analysis in this paper makes use of micro-level data from the Pakistan
Integrated Household Survey 1991, (PIHS 1991). The data set consists of 35,774 individuals of
all ages, of which 4480 are aged 10-14 with 2348 boys and 2132 girls.7 The PIHS 1991 was
conducted throughout the year 1991, with approximately equal number of households from each
region of the country interviewed each month. Thus, the data has a unique quality which can help
in exploiting the regression discontinuity design and is ideal for the use of the identification
strategy. Another reason for the selection of the year 1991 for such an analysis is that it was a
year that was relatively free of much lobbying and international pressure against child labor in
the country. This helps identify the true impact of the law, which is the main aim of the paper.
Identifying the households interviewed by months enabled the division of the data set
into two groups; the households interviewed during January to April and those interviewed
during May to December, giving the pre-intervention and the post-intervention periods
respectively. Since the EoCA 1991 was introduced in April and implemented the same month,
the two sub-groups of the data may provide suitable comparison groups for the study of post-
intervention child labor situation in Pakistan. For our study different age and/or occupation
groups are used from this pool of data as robustness checks for our findings.
Table 1 gives employment rates for children age 10-14 years in the months January-April
and May-December in 1991. There appears to be a statistically significant decrease in the
7 A few individuals (12 individuals) reported age more than 100, but we exclude these observations from our
analysis.
10
employment rates of 13 year olds in the post-intervention period. For most other ages there is an
increase in employment rates in the months of May-December, but the increase is statistically
insignificant. The exceptions to this are among 10 year old boys and 14 year old girls where
there is a slight decrease in employment rate for these children in the months following the
implementation of the Act.
Table 1: Employment rate for children age 10-148
1991 Jan-April May-Dec.
Age Boys Girls Total Boys Girls Total Boys Girls Total
10 12.6
(1.4) 20.6
(1.8) 16.4
(1.1) 14.1
(2.9) 14.1
(2.9) 14.1
(2.0) 12.0
(1.6) 23.2
(2.2) 17.3
(1.3)
11 14.7
(1.7) 19.9
(2.2) 17.0
(1.4) 12.2
(3.1) 20.0
(4.2) 15.7
(2.6) 15.6
(2.1) 19.9
(2.6) 17.5
(1.6)
12 22.4
(1.6) 24.7
(1.9) 23.4
(1.2) 20.2
(3.1) 23.0
(3.6) 21.5
(2.3) 23.2
(1.9) 25.3
(2.3) 24.1
(1.5)
13 26.4
(2.4) 25.5
(2.3) 25.9
(1.6) 34.4
(5.0) 32.2
(5.0) 33.3
(3.6) 23.5
(2.7) 23.3
(2.6) 23.4
(1.8)
14 33.7
(2.4) 33.1
(2.3) 33.4
(1.7) 25.2
(4.4) 36.6
(4.8) 31.0
(4.8) 36.4
(2.8) 31.9
(2.6) 34.1
(1.9)
Note: figures in parentheses are standard errors
Figure 1 shows the monthly employment rates by age. Except for 13 year old children,
there does not appear to be much decrease in employment rates of the children in the months
following the implementation of the EoCA 1991. The monthly employment rates of children in
the four main occupation groups (figure 2) shows some seasonal decrease in employment in
agriculture in the months of June, July, and August which increases again in last four months of
the year, this is not surprising since the agriculture sector is not a prohibited sector of work under
the EoCA 1991. As opposed to agriculture sector, the manufacturing sector shows a slight
reduction in employment rates in the post-implementation months. Similarly participation in
other the other two sectors is also either steady or decreasing for all ages.
8 The reference period for work in PIHS 1991 is 7 days.
11
The sectoral distribution of working children by area of residence (given in table2)
suggests that during the months of May-December the proportion of children employed in the
agriculture sector in rural areas increased and there was a decrease in employment in all other
sectors consistent with figure 2. In urban areas there was an increase in the proportion of children
working in the personal services sector and shops, hotels and transport sectors. In both areas
there is a decrease in the proportion of children in the manufacturing sector, however, the
magnitude of the fall is smaller in urban areas. This pattern seems to be reflective of the fact that
children’s work in the agriculture sector as well as the domestic services sector is not prohibited
by the EoCA 1991 (detailed tables showing the employment rates of children in different
occupations in the year 1991 are given in Appendix B).
Table 2: Sectoral distribution of working children by region (age 10-14)
(Percent of employed children working in each sector)
Rural Urban Total
Sector Jan-April May-Dec. Jan-April May-Dec. Jan-April May-Dec.
Agriculture 55.1 70.7 17.1 13.0 39.9 56.8
Manufacturing 12.2 6.3 26.7 23.9 18.0 10.5
Personal and consumer
services 8.3 2.6 10.5 15.8 9.2 5.8
Construction 2.6 2.4 5.7 1.6 3.8 2.2
Shops/hotels and
transport 17.3 12.9 32.4 38.6 23.4 19.1
Undefined 4.5 5.2 7.6 7.1 5.7 5.6
100 100 100 100 100 100
3.2 - Methodology
The objective of this paper is to test whether the EoCA 1991 has been effective in
reducing the employment of children using a quasi-experimental approach. A quasi-experiment
(or natural experiment) is caused by an external exogenous effect, which changes the
environment in which individuals operate (Stock et al 2003; Meyer, 1995). Such natural
experiments may be induced by introduction of, or changes in legislation, or a policy change.
Thus a particular policy change may give rise to treatment and control groups and the variation
12
in the individual circumstances generates the randomness in the treatment assignment. A
necessary condition for a quasi-experiment analysis is that there should be no systematic
variation in the unobservable characteristics between the pre and post-treatment groups.
The natural experiment approach employed in this paper is based on the use of cross-
sectional data from two time periods to compare the employment of children who would have
been affected by the implementation of the EoCA 1991, with that of a similar group who were
not affected by it. The identification strategy relies on a regression discontinuity framework
applied to the pre and post-treatment period and the data used, with two pre-treatment and two
post-treatment groups allows us to control for the differential trends by structuring the regression
discontinuity design on a difference-in-difference approach to isolate the effect of the law on
employment of children from other factors determining the labor supply decision. A direct
comparison of the two groups would not be appropriate to identify the causal effect of the law
since even in the absence of the law, younger children have a lower probability of working than
older children, or there may be age-specific unobservables that could affect the results. The
difference-in-difference estimator compares the difference in the employment probability of
children in the two groups in a period after the implementation of the Act with the equivalent
difference in an earlier period when the EoCA 1991 was not introduced.
To be more specific, assume that Di=1 if a treatment is introduced and zero in the
absence of the treatment. Let Y0i be the outcome for individual i in the absence of the treatment
and Y1i be the outcome for the individual in the presence of the treatment. However, for any
single individual only one of these outcomes is ever observed. Since both Y0i and Y1i are never
13
observed for the same individual, the basic idea behind the natural experiment is that by careful
selection of treatment and control groups the average treatment effect on the treated group can be
estimated. So if we are interested in estimating E[Y1i | Di = 1] – E[Y0i | Di =1], we can estimate
the counterfactual by replacing the unobserved E[Y0i | Di =1] with the experience of individuals
in control group j who did not experience treatment E[Y0j | Di =0].9
For our analysis, let yit be the employment status of a child, which equals 1 if the child
works and zero otherwise. In time period *
ta law is introduced which directly affects only one
group of children. Let the groups be indexed by g, such that in time period *
1tt , there is no
law that affects the employment decision of children in any group, but in *
2tt >, only group g=1
is directly affected by the introduction of the policy and g=2 is not. We observe
(
)
1
,1
1ttgyE it == only in time period *
1tt and
(
)
2
,1
2ttgyE it == only in *
2tt >. The
objective is to estimate the counterfactual, i.e., what would have been the employment
probability of group g=1 in time period 2
t in the absence of the law; in other words, to estimate
(
)
2
,1
1ttgyE it == when *
2tt >. Suppose there is a constant effect,
β
, on the employment
probability in group 1 resulting from the implementation of the law, then:
(
)
(
)
β
+=== 11 12 gyEgyE itit (1)
(
)
(
)
22 12 === gyEgyE itit (2)
where 2
*
1ttt <
9Here, conditioning on observables X helps the identification process i.e., E[Y0i | Di =1, X]= E[Y0j | Di =0, X].
14
The key assumption in the difference-in-difference estimate is that in the absence of a
policy intervention the change in employment rate of the two groups would have been the same.
Under this assumption the raw difference-in-difference estimator can be given as equation (1) –
(2):
()()
[]
()()
[]
1212
^,2,2,1,1 tgyEtgyEtgyEtgyE itititit =====
β
(3)
and it is an unbiased and consistent estimator of the causal effect of the treatment if the treatment
is truly randomly assigned.
Using micro-level data pooled for the two time periods of before and after the
implementation of the law, the raw difference-in-difference estimator given in equation (3) can
be written as a regression equation.
ititiit GDGDy *
21
βδδα
+++= (4)
where Dt is a time dummy variable which takes value 1 for the post policy implementation
period, Gi takes value 1 if the individual belongs to the group effected by the law and zero
otherwise. The interaction term Dt*Gi takes the value 1 if the individual is in the treatment group
in the post-intervention period. Thus the coefficient on this variable gives the difference-in-
difference estimate.
This study analyses the probability of work for children affected by the EoCA 1991, so
the dependent variable is dichotomous. As such the use of the linear regression model of
equation (4) might have certain disadvantages. The more appropriate model to use in such an
15
empirical model is a logit or probit model.10 Thus, this study estimates a difference-in-difference
estimator using the following logit model
()
(
)
()
*
*
exp1
exp
1
i
i
iy
y
yprob +
== (5)
where yi is a dichotomous dependent variable taking the value 1 if the child works and 0
otherwise, and yi* takes the following form:
ϕβββα
iititii XAGEDAGEDy ++++= *
321
* (6)
In equation (6), Dt is a binary variable taking the value 1 in the period after the law has
been implemented, and 0 otherwise. Thus in this study it takes the value 1 for the months of
May-December 1991. The discontinuity is captured by the binary variable AGEi which is 1 if the
individual belongs to the treatment age group and 0 otherwise. The variable Dt*AGEi is 1 if an
individual is in the treatment group in the post-treatment period and 0 otherwise, and Xi is a
vector of other factors effecting the work decision. The marginal effects from the logit estimates
offer a simple interpretation. The marginal effect of Dt represents the time series change in the
employment rate of the control group, while that of AGEi gives the difference in the probability
of working between the control and treatment groups in the base period (i.e., the months of
January-April). The variable of particular interest is Dt*AGEi whose marginal effect gives the
causal effect of the law, as it estimates the additional employment effect of being in the treatment
group in the post-treatment period.
The EoCA 1991 specifies a minimum age of 14 years to be able to work. In addition, it
also specifies certain occupations to which the law applies (for details see Appendix A). As the
10 The logit model is used here, but the use of probit model gives similar results.
16
law affects only those children who are less than 14 years old, thus the treatment group in this
study is children under 14 years of age. The study examines the affect of the law on two
treatment groups of children less than 14 years of age, one who work in all sectors of the
economy and the other where the treatment group is restricted to the exact definition of child
work as given in the EoCA 1991.
The results could depend on the definition of the pre- and post-implementation periods
and also on the choice of the treatment and control groups. To address the first issue, since the
EoCA was introduced in April 1991, the pre-intervention period is taken as the first four months
of the year. For a robustness check, we excluded April 1991 from our analysis and the results did
not change significantly.
The second issue is the choice of the treatment and control groups. Whereas in the
evaluation literature the treatment group is often a well-defined group, the comparison groups
selected usually need some justification since the results might be sensitive to the choice of the
comparison groups. In our study, the treatment and control groups depend on age. A wider age
band for the control group reduces the threat of the results picking up the spillover and
substitution effects. A spillover effect might arise when parents decide to take their 14 year old
children off the labor market because the 13 year olds are forced by law not to work. The
substitution effect would work in the opposite direction with more 14 year old children being
employed as 13 year olds are taken off the labor market. Both these effects become less likely
when a wider age band is used as comparison group. On the other hand, a narrow definition of
the comparison group is needed to keep the treatment and comparison groups as similar to each
17
other as possible. In view of this, we conduct our analysis using a range of treatment and
comparison groups. The results (discussed in section 5) appear to be fairly robust to the
alternative definitions of the groups used. However, the main focus is on the model where the
control group is chosen to be children aged 14 years. This is so because in terms of both supply
and demand, labor of 13 and 14 year olds can probably be considered close substitutes.11 The
models given in equation (5) and (6) are estimated using different sub-samples from the data set,
according to the control and treatment groups used.12
In addition to the above specification issues, concern is that since the data used is from
household survey, any introduction of a minimum age law might prompt households to
systematically misreport the age of working children to avoid children from being out of work.13
We checked the data set for any systematic decrease in children of age 13 and an increase in
children age 14 after the introduction of the law. As can be seen in figure 3, the proportion of
children for age 10-14 does not show any systematic shift over the months, in particular over the
pre and post intervention periods.
4 - Results
4.1 - Comparing children’s and adult employment over January-April and May-December
1991
11 Our analysis uses other control groups as robustness checks to identify if there has been a similar systematic
decrease in other age groups.
12 All of the regression results are clustered by province age and time (months or years).
13 The age comes from actual reported age in the survey and not from the year of birth.
18
We start our analysis by first comparing the employment rate of children age 10-13 and
age 14-17 with all adults i.e., age 18 and above.14 The difference-in-difference estimate helps to
determine if there is a significant difference in the probability of working for children age 10-13
and also 14-17 in the period May-December 1991. Marginal effects from the estimated logit
model for all Pakistan are reported in table 3 which also reports the marginal effects for the
models estimated for the male and female population separately.15
Table 3: Marginal Effects from Logit Estimates of Work – all Pakistan (individuals 10-13
years and 14-17 years vs. all adults)16
Total Male Female
May-Dec. 0.002 -0.026 0.020
(0.009) (0.014) (0.012)
Age 10-13 -0.476** -0.658** -0.193**
(0.021) (0.027) (0.027)
Age 14-17 -0.267** -0.429** -0.067*
(0.020) (0.024) (0.027)
May-Dec * Age 10-13 0.008 0.018 0.006
(0.025) (0.030) (0.032)
May-Dec * Age 14-17 0.010 0.057* -0.038
(0.023) (0.028) (0.031)
Observations 23769 12448 11321
Pseudo R2 0.08 0.22 0.02
Log Likelihood -15138.3 -6083.6 -7225.6
Robust standard errors in parentheses
*significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%
The results suggest that there was little change in the relative and absolute probabilities of
work over the two time periods. Children age 10-13 as well as 14-17 are less likely to be
involved in work, however, the magnitude of the marginal effect at around 48 percentage points
is much larger for the age group 10-13. The models estimated by gender show similar results,
14 In this case we can not use controls in the logit model because the controls are different for children and adults, so
we estimate the regression without controls.
15 Since our data sets are not random samples we tried using the weights (provided with the data sets) for our
analysis and the results appeared quite robust to whether weights are used or not. So all our analysis uses un-
weighted logit analysis. For details about using weights for regression analysis see Deaton (1997) and Angrist and
Krueger (1998). In the models where we use sub-samples of particular age and occupation groups, we were unable
to use the weighted analysis because of small sample sizes, since weighted analysis requires at least two or more
PSU in each strata.
16 We use an upper age-limit of 70 years for our analysis.
19
however, the probability of work for boys age 14-17 increased by almost 6 percentage points in
the period from May-December.
Rural and urban labor markets differ significantly in Pakistan. The rural areas are
predominantly agricultural, whereas the urban regions are more industrial with the formal sector
mainly operating in these regions, and thus we might expect impact of the Act to be stronger in
the urban areas. We estimate separate logit models for rural and urban regions, and also by
gender within each region.17 The results are reported in table 4.
Though there did not seem to be any change in the probability of work for adults in the
period of May-Dec. in the case of all Pakistan (table 3), the rural-urban divide (table 4) shows
that for rural areas, the probability of work participation for adults is almost 3 percentage points
higher in the months from May-December. Children in both age groups are much less likely to
be involved in work, but the magnitude of the marginal effect is again much higher for younger
children. There does not appear to be any effect of the law, using this level of aggregation.
Looking at the gender divide, women are almost 6 percentage points more likely to work in the
months of May-December in the rural areas. This could be because agriculture is the major
occupation in rural areas where women are often employed during the harvesting and sowing
seasons when there is a need for low skilled extra labor on the farms. There are two cropping
seasons in Pakistan, rabi and kharif. For the rabi crops, sowing starts from October to January
17 Using the log-likelihood ratio test, the test of the hypothesis of no difference between the coefficients for rural and
urban regions, is rejected at the 5 percent significance level with a value of 970.6~
(
)
5
2
χ
and the hypothesis of no
difference by gender for rural and urban regions is rejected at the 5 percent significance with a value of 1108.8
~
()
5
2
χ
and 2920.4 ~
()
5
2
χ
respectively.
20
and they are harvested between April and June. The kharif crops are sowed from April to
September and harvested in October to March.
Table 4: Logit Estimates of Work – Rural and Urban (individuals 10-13 years and 14-17
years vs. all adults)
Rural Urban
Total Male Female Total Male Female
May-Dec. 0.027* -0.012 0.058** -0.034** -0.046* -0.036**
(0.013) (0.019) (0.018) (0.012) (0.019) (0.013)
Age 10-13 -0.418** -0.527** -0.236** -0.519** -0.829** -0.120**
(0.027) (0.031) (0.042) (0.032) (0.048) (0.029)
Age 14-17 -0.243** -0.344** -0.129** -0.269** -0.516** -0.005
(0.028) (0.031) (0.043) (0.026) (0.037) (0.026)
May-Dec * Age 10-13 0.012 -0.005 0.047 -0.061 0.041 -0.093*
(0.031) (0.036) (0.047) (0.040) (0.055) (0.038)
May-Dec * Age 14-17 0.027 0.029 0.044 -0.022 0.083 -0.104**
(0.032) (0.036) (0.049) (0.032) (0.043) (0.033)
Observations 11610 6058 5552 12159 6390 5769
Pseudo R2 0.08 0.22 0.02 0.10 0.24 0.03
Log Likelihood -7143.6 -2809.9 -3779.3 -7509.4 -3177.8 -2871.6
Robust standard errors in parentheses
*significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%.
The estimated model for urban females shows a significant negative effect on the
difference-in-difference estimate. In particular the probability of work for 10-13 year old girls
relative to women (the control group) in urban areas decreased by 9.3 percentage points after the
introduction of the EoCA in April 1991. However, a similar effect is seen for girls in age group
14-17 where the probability of work decreased by 10.4 percentage points. This result might
indicate a spill over effect of the implementation of the EoCA 1991. However, we have to be
cautious while drawing conclusions from these results because the regression does not control
for other factors determining the supply of labor.
4.2 - The difference-in-difference estimate – age 10-13 and 14 years
Pakistan
21
The EoCA 1991 specifies the minimum age of work as 14 years, and effective
implementation of the law would mean a decrease in the employment of children in the age
group 10-13 in the months following April 1991. To find the alternative difference-in-difference
estimate, equation (6) is estimated only for children in the age group 10-13 and of their,
assumed, closest substitutes, those aged 14 years. The results of the logit model are given in table
5. The models are estimated both with and without controls with separate models by region of
residence and gender (the means and standard deviations of the control variables for the sample
of children age 10-14 are given in Appendix C).18
Panel A in table 5 reports the results of the logit estimates for all Pakistan and for boys
and girls separately (results reported in table 5, panel A).19 The results show that for all Pakistan
for children age 14 there is no significant difference in the probability of work in the two time
periods and the children age 10-13 are less likely to be involved in work than the 14 year old
children even in the base time period. There does not appear to be a significant impact of the
EoCA 1991 on the treatment group for all Pakistan because the marginal effect on the interaction
term is insignificantly different from zero. The regression estimated with controls gives similar
results.
18 The controls used in all of our models include, head of household’s child, female head of household’s child,
gender of child, mother’s age, literate and employed mother, illiterate and employed mother, father’s age, literacy
and employment, region of residence including the four provinces and rural and urban regions, and the number of
siblings in age groups 0-4, 5-9, 10-14, 15-17.
19 A log-likelihood ratio test for no significant difference in the coefficients by gender is rejected at the 5 percent
significance with 14.4 ~
()
3
2
χ
for the regression without the controls, and 191~
(
)
28
2
χ
for the regression model
estimated with the control variables.
22
Table 5: Marginal Effects of Logit Estimates of Work (Children 10-13 and 14years)
PANEL A Pakistan
Without controls With controls
Total Male Female Total Male Female
May-Dec. 0.025 0.087* -0.039 0.018 0.079* -0.021
(0.031) (0.043) (0.044) (0.029) (0.039) (0.042)
Age 10-13 -0.100** -0.057 -0.141** -0.096** -0.066 -0.104*
(0.030) (0.042) (0.044) (0.029) (0.038) (0.042)
May-Dec. * Age10-13 -0.020 -0.096* 0.059 -0.024 -0.093* 0.025
(0.035) (0.048) (0.051) (0.032) (0.043) (0.046)
Observations 4480 2348 2132 4480 2348 2132
Pseudo R2 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.18 0.12 0.30
Log Likelihood -2380.1 -1190.6 -1182.3 -1983.6 -1067.1 -826.1
PANEL B Urban
Without controls With controls
Total Male Female Total Male Female
May-Dec. -0.052* 0.054 -0.131** -0.021 0.081* -0.055**
(0.026) (0.044) (0.033) (0.022) (0.041) (0.019)
Age 10-13 -0.098** -0.061 -0.111** -0.080** -0.046 -0.050**
(0.025) (0.044) (0.030) (0.021) (0.040) (0.017)
May-Dec. * Age10-13 0.010 -0.056 0.054 -0.008 -0.080 0.023
(0.031) (0.050) (0.040) (0.025) (0.046) (0.019)
Observations 2328 1195 1133 2328 1195 1133
Pseudo R2 0.03 0.02 0.05 0.15 0.11 0.37
Log Likelihood -850.4 -455.2 -383.9 -741.0 -414.8 -256.8
PANEL C Rural
Without controls With controls
Total Male Female Total Male Female
May-Dec. 0.137* 0.101 0.174 0.119 0.058 0.232*
(0.058) (0.074) (0.089) (0.064) (0.074) (0.110)
Age 10-13 -0.064 -0.060 -0.067 -0.067 -0.091 -0.017
(0.057) (0.072) (0.088) (0.064) (0.072) (0.111)
May-Dec. * Age10-13 -0.104 -0.130 -0.069 -0.102 -0.100 -0.137
(0.064) (0.082) (0.099) (0.070) (0.081) (0.120)
Observations 2152 1153 999 2152 1153 999
Pseudo R2 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.14 0.09 0.22
Log Likelihood -1362.7 -686.8 -660.6 -1192.1 -633.7 -520.4
Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses; * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%
For boys, there appears to be an increase in probability of work in the control group, in
the post-intervention period, where they are almost 8 percentage points more likely to work in
the months of May-December. The difference-in-difference estimate, however, is significant and
negative, suggesting that as a result of the enactment of the EoCA 1991, the relative probability
of working fell by more than 9 percentage points and the actual probability of working for
children in the age cohort 10-13 decreased by almost 0.9 percentage points (i.e., the difference in
23
the coefficients on time and the interaction term). Once we estimate the model controlling for
other factors affecting the supply of child labor, the magnitude of the marginal effect, relative to
the control group of 14 year old children, decreases slightly to 9.3 percentage points leading to a
net decrease of 1.4 percentage points. The model for girls does not show a significant effect of
the implementation of the law. There are more girls employed in sectors that are not prohibited
by the Act (table B2 Appendix B), for example in the agriculture sector. The traditional and
cultural set-up of the country also is such that girls are more likely to be involved in household
chores or work in the household enterprises. Thus it appears that the EoCA 1991 affected mainly
the employment of boys, because they were employed in the sectors or processes prohibited in
the Act.
The rural-urban divide
As mentioned earlier, rural and urban labor markets in Pakistan differ significantly from
each other. The model is thus estimated with sub-samples of urban areas and rural areas. The
results for urban and rural areas are reported in table 5, panel B and C respectively.20 Table 5
shows that during the period of May-December 1991, urban children were relatively less likely
to work than during January-April, whereas rural children have a higher probability of working.
However, once we add controls in our model, this effect becomes statistically insignificant.
Urban children age 10-13 have a lower probability of work than children age 14 in the base
period. No such effect appears in the estimation of the rural model.
20 We test the hypothesis of no difference between the coefficients of rural and also the urban sub-samples by
gender. Using the log-likelihood ratio test we reject the hypothesis with 30.6 ~
χ
2(3) and 102.2 ~
χ
2(27) for the with
and without controls models respectively for the rural region and 22.6 ~
χ
2(3) and 142 ~
χ
2(27) respectively for the
with, and without control models in the urban regions.
24
The results with controls suggest that 14 year old boys in urban areas are more likely to
work in the period of May-December. However, the probability of work for urban girls in this
period is negative. Rural girls aged 14 years, on the other hand, have a 23.2 percentage point
higher probability of working in the period of May-December than in the first four months of the
year. Thus there appears to be seasonality in the labor market as reflected for rural women in
table 4 above). In terms of the EoCA 1991, there does not appear to be any impact on
employment of children once the data is disaggregated to the rural and urban level.21
4.3 - The difference-in-difference estimate – age 13 and 14 years
In the last section we used a treatment group of 10-13 year old children against a control
group of 14 year olds. However, in terms of ability, a 10 or 11 year old child might not be the
same as a 14 year old child. In other words, they cannot be considered close substitutes in the
labor market. Though adding control variables in our analysis of the treatment group of children
age 10-13 and control group of 14 year olds, helps in controlling for other factors effecting labor
market for children, it may be that a more precise estimate of the effect of the EoCA 1991 can be
found by using a treatment group of only 13 year old children and control group of 14 year olds.
This is so because we assume that there is very little difference in the unobserved characteristics
of 13 and 14 years old children and, if so, they can be considered a very close substitute of one
another in terms of employment opportunities.
Pakistan
Equation (6) is now estimated using the sub-sample of children aged 13 and 14 years.
The results are reported in table 6. Panel A of the table gives the marginal effects of the logit
21 This may in part be because of sample size limitations. So the difference-in-difference for boys only becomes
significant in the pooled rural and urban sample.
25
model for all Pakistan with and without the control variables. In case of the model estimated
without controls, the test of no significant difference between the coefficients of the models for
boys and girls, using the log-likelihood ratio test, is accepted at the 5 percent significance with a
value of 4.5 ~
()
3
2
χ
. Thus we do not estimate separate models for boys and girls in case of the
equation without controls. However, in the case of the models with the control variables, we find
that the coefficients of the male and female models are significantly different as the test gives a
value of 78.7 ~
()
27
2
χ
.
Interesting results emerge from our analysis of the treatment group of 13 year olds as
opposed to a control of 14 year olds in the full sample for Pakistan. Both the models estimated
with and without controls show a significant impact of the Act in terms of a lower probability of
work for boys in the treatment group. The results suggest that the probability of working for 13
year old children in the post-intervention period has decreased by 13.2 percentage points (and by
around 10 percentage points in absolute terms), relative to the control group of 14 year olds. The
estimated model controlling for other factors gives an even greater effect for the interaction term
of almost 15 percentage points. Thus, the results point to some impact of the EoCA 1991 in
reducing the magnitude of child labor of those at the upper age limit.
26
Table 6: Marginal effects from logit estimates of work (Children 13 and 14 years)
PANEL A Pakistan
Without controls With controls
Total Total Male Female
May-Dec. 0.030 0.040 0.116* -0.027
(0.037) (0.038) (0.054) (0.054)
Age 13 0.022 0.027 0.079 -0.024
(0.046) (0.048) (0.068) (0.067)
May-Dec. * Age13 -0.132* -0.146** -0.238** -0.055
(0.054) (0.055) (0.079) (0.074)
Observations 1514 1514 743 771
Pseudo R2 0.01 0.18 0.14 0.32
Log Likelihood -915.2 -758.8 -391.4 -318.2
PANEL B Urban
Without controls With controls
Total Total
May-Dec. -0.070* -0.020
(0.035) (0.031)
Age 13 -0.036 -0.019
(0.045) (0.041)
May-Dec. * Age13 -0.066 -0.085
(0.056) (0.051)
Observations 802 802
Pseudo R2 0.03 0.16
Log Likelihood -365.1 -314.8
PANEL C Rural
Without controls With controls
Total Total
May-Dec. 0.150* 0.131
(0.064) (0.073)
Age 13 0.100 0.121
(0.079) (0.093)
May-Dec. * Age13 -0.224* -0.251*
(0.090) (0.104)
Observations 712 712
Pseudo R2 0.01 0.14
Log Likelihood -482.1 -419.7
Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses
* significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%
Disaggregating our sample of 13 and 14 year olds by gender shows no impact of the Act
on girls but suggests that the probability of work for 13 year old children decreased by almost
12.8 percentage points. This difference between the estimates for boys and girls might be due to
the fact that 13 year old girls are less likely to be involved in occupations that are prohibited by
law (see appendix B for summary tables of employment in different occupations).
27
Rural and urban regions
Since rural and urban labor markets are assumed to be significantly different in terms of
employment opportunities, so the models for 13 and 14 year olds are again estimated on sub-
samples of rural and urban regions. Because of small sample sizes we do not estimate the rural
and urban models by gender. The results of the estimation are reported in table 6, panel B and C.
The model estimated for urban children, without controlling for other factors, shows that
14 year old children are 7 percentage points less likely to work in the time period of May-
December. This effect, however, becomes insignificant once the control variables are added.
Results for the rural model in Panel C suggest that the employment of 13 year old
children in the rural areas fell by almost 25 percentage points, relative to the control group of 14
year olds after the implementation of the law. Children are more often employed in the informal
and un-organised sectors of the economy and formal sector offers little opportunities for working
children. The informal sector is mainly concentrated in rural areas of Pakistan in small villages
and towns. The significant impact of the EoCA 1991 in the rural areas appears to suggest that
there was a decrease in employment of children in these sectors. Rural areas are mainly
agricultural areas with farms and agro-based industries. This strong effect could suggest a
decrease in children’s work in the sectors other than agriculture, since the percentage of working
children in the agriculture sector had actually increased in the rural areas in the months of May-
December (table 2), thus pointing towards a significant impact of the law on child labor.
28
It is interesting to observe such an immediate decrease in labor participation for children
after the imposition of the law; and though it is not unique (there is anecdotal evidence of
children being laid-off from work in Bangladesh when the threat of import sanctions was
introduced by the US in 1994), it certainly is unexpected for a law that did not involve
international lobbying and pressure. We therefore try to untangle the possible pathway or the
theory of change behind this immediate effect. It is interesting to note that Basu (2005) in his
theoretical model suggests that the imposition of fines might increase child labor in the short run,
but we do not find such an effect. We assume that in the case of Pakistan the effect worked in the
following way. The employers were informed of the imposition of a law against child labor,
where employing children age 13 or less would lead to a fine being imposed on the employer.
The employers react by substituting 13 year old children by 14 year old children. The physical
and mental capabilities of the two ages are assumed to be marginally different and can easily be
used as perfect substitutes. We also assume that the supply of 14 year old laborers would not be
limited to prevent the employers from substitution (based on the fact that only 49.5 percent of 14
year olds report being enrolled in the 1991 PIHS). Further assumption is that since it is too soon
for the households to be aware of the legislation (see section 2 for mechanism of introduction
and information on laws passed), the supply would not be effected in terms of the wages
demanded. In other words, if households know that it is illegal to let a 13 year old work, but legal
to send a 14 year old to work, they would demand higher wages for their 14 year olds. But just
one month after the creation of the legislation, information might not have trickled down to
individual households. Thus, as opposed to reduction in wages by employers as punishment cost,
it appears that when there is excess supply of child labor, in the short run the effect could be
positive by reducing children’s work for the prohibited age group and increasing it for the age
29
that is legal to be employed - given that the minimum age is low enough (14 years in the case of
Pakistan) such that the employers do not have to pay adult wages.22 (Basu (2005) also suggests
that the wages of children will decrease in the short run. Unfortunately, we do not have the wage
data to verify this claim since very few working children in our data set report earning any wages
whether in cash or kind.
5 - Conclusions and certain policy implications
The objective of this paper is to try to identify whether the Employment of Children Act,
implemented in April 1991, had the desirable impact of reducing children’s employment.
Exploiting a quasi-experimental approach, we use regression discontinuity design generated by
the legislation defining 14 year of age as the minimum age for work and use the difference-in-
difference estimation to isolate the effect of law from other factors affecting the employment of
children. Our empirical analysis uses micro-level data from the Pakistan Integrated Household
Survey 1991 and the data is divided in pre-intervention (January-April) and post-intervention
(May-December) periods. Since the EoCA 1991 specifies the minimum age of work as 14 years,
so a treatment group of less than 14 year old children is compared against various control groups.
The results, using a treatment group of children age 10-13, shows a significant decrease
in work for boys in the sample. Since the socio-economic set-up of the country is such that girls
are less likely to be involved in work outside the household (the law does not prohibit children
working with the family on family enterprise), so the results suggest that the law affected only
boys. The model estimated taking control group of 14 year old children and treatment group of
22 In other words, if the minimum work age was 17 years, substituting 17 for an 18 year old would mean paying the
18 year old adult wages, thus increasing the cost of hiring that person. In such case Basu’s punishment cost appears
to be the model that might be followed by the employers.
30
13 year olds shows a stronger decrease. For all Pakistan there appears to be a significant decrease
in the probability of working for 13 year old children in the months after the implementation of
the law. This effect is again concentrated among boys. Since we assume that the children age 13
and 14 are close substitutes in terms of work ability in the labor market, we consider this result to
be an indication of the effectiveness of the law.
The Employment of Children Act 1991 appears to affect boys more than girls. This
suggests a need of a more comprehensive legislation, which includes domestic services as well
since it is the sector where young girls are more often employed. This paper points towards the
importance of more in depth research on the impact of anti-child labor legislation by identifying
some impact of such legislation in the short run.
31
Appendix A
Table A1: Laws and Legislations in Pakistan restricting employment of children
Act/Law Minimum age
for work Occupations Special provisions
Children (pledging of
labor) Act 1933 15 years Any occupation, but applies
only to pledging of labor of a
child in return for payment or
benefit received by the parent
or guardian
Allows children to work
in return for regular and
reasonable wages
Mines Act 1923 15 years and a
child age 15-17
considered as a
young person
Work in mines and for
children even the presence of
children in parts of mines that
are underground
A young person can work
in a mine only if he/she
has a certificate of fitness
from a medical
practitioner
Factories Act 1934 15 years for a
child and a
person age 15-
17 years is
considered an
adolescent
Any kind of work in factories Allows work if the
child/adolescent can get a
certificate of fitness for
work by a certified
medical practitioner. A
child can not work more
than 7 ½ hours a day and
after 7p.m or before 6a.m
Shops and
Establishments
Ordinance 1969
14 years Work in shops and
establishments (where the
term establishments
encompasses a wide range of
businesses, firms and
commercial establishments)
Employment of
Children Act (1938)
1991
14 years and
person age 15-
18 is considered
an adolescent
Work in or near railway lines
and station, on ports and in a
wide range of production
processes which can be
deemed harmful for the health
of a child and include work
with chemicals and weaving
etc. However, it does not
include any establishment
where work is done by the
family members (household
enterprise).
A child can work on a
family establishment or a
school recognised by the
government, if s/he or
parents/guardians seek
work for him/her, only if
a medical practitioner
gives a certificate of
fitness and certifies that
the child has attained 12
years of age (or 14 years
in case of adolescents).
The child can not work
for more than a period of
3 hours without a break of
at least 1 hour, and the
hours of work with the
intervals can not exceed 7
hours a day. Also no child
is allowed to work
between 7p.m to 8a.m
Source: Shafi, M and P. Shafi (2000)
32
Prohibited Occupations and Processes as specified in the Employment of Children Act
1991:
Any occupation connected with:
- transport of goods, passengers or mails by railway
- cinder picking, cleaning of an ash-pit or building operation in a railway premises
- work in a catering establishment at a railway station
- work relating to the construction of a railway station or any other such work where such work
is done in close proximity to or between railway lines
- a port authority within the limits of any port
- work relating to selling of crackers and fire-works in shops with temporary licences
Processes
- Bidi making
- Carpet weaving
- Cement manufacture including bagging of cement
- Cloth printing, dyeing and weaving
- Manufacture of matches, explosive and fireworks
- Mica-cutting and sploting
- Soap manufacturing
- Wool-cleaning
- Building and construction industry
- Manufacture of slate pencils, including packaging
- Manufacture of products from agate
- Manufacturing processes using toxic metals and substances such as lead, mercury, manganese,
chromium, pesticides and asbestos
33
Appendix B
Table B1: Percentage Distribution of Children working in different occupations (age 10-17
years)
Occupation 1991
Children as percent of total
employees in each sector % of working children
Agriculture 20.1
(0.5) 62.9
(1.1)
Manufacturing 25.9
(0.8) 16.1
(0.8)
Electricity/gas/water 20.2
(1.9) 0.6
(0.2)
Construction 13.2
(1.0) 4.2
(0.5)
Trade/restaurants etc 27.2
(0.7) 15.4
(0.8)
Transport/communication 23.6
(1.1) 6.7
(0.6)
Business/self-employed 21.2
(2.5) 0.4
(0.1)
Community/social/personal
services 14.9
(0.7) 7.0
(0.6)
Note: standard errors in parentheses
Table B2: Percentage Distribution of Children working in different occupations (age 10-17)
Occupation 1991
Boys as % of
total working
children in each
sector
Girls as % of
total working
children in each
sector
Boys as % of
total working
boys
Girls as % of
total working
girls
Agriculture 50.1
(1.8) 49.9
(1.8) 54.4
(1.5) 73.3
(1.5)
Mining etc. 100 0 0.4
(0.2) 0
Manufacturing 64.3
(4.0) 35.6
(4.0) 19.3
(1.2) 12.1
(1.1)
Electricity/gas/water 75.6
(8.3) 24.4
(8.3) 0.9
(0.3) 0.3
(0.2)
Construction 95.2
(2.2) 4.7
(2.2) 6.8
(0.8) 0.9
(0.3)
Trade/restaurants etc 69.5
(3.3) 30.5
(3.3) 18.8
(1.2) 11.0
(1.1)
Transport/communication 68.2
(5.3) 31.8
(5.3) 8.1
(0.8) 5.0
(0.8)
Business/self-employed 79.6
(19.3) 20.3
(19.3) 0.3
(0.2) 0.5
(0.2)
Community/social/personal
services 67.4
(7.1) 32.6
(7.1) 9.3
(0.9) 4.4
(0.7)
Note: standard errors in parentheses
34
Table B3: Percentage Distribution of Children working in Different Occupations by
Province
Occupation % of total children - 1991
Punjab Sindh NWFP Baluchistan
Agriculture 19.3
(0.7) 18.9
(0.9) 18.3
(1.1) 8.2
(1.2)
Mining etc. 0.01
(0.04) 0 0.2
(0.1) 0.2
(0.2)
Manufacturing 14.6
(0.6) 5.8
(0.6) 6.5
(0.7) 9.2
(1.3)
Electricity/water 1.6
(0.2) 0.8
(0.2) 0.9
(0.3) 0.8
(0.4)
Construction 1.9
(0.2) 1.6
(0.3) 2.7
(0.5) 3.6
(0.8)
Trade/restaurants etc 18.2
(0.7) 13.3
(0.8) 17.8
(1.1) 6.4
(1.1)
Transport/communication 6.2
(0.4) 3.6
(0.4) 6.5
(0.7) 1.4
(0.5)
Finance and business 0.5
(0.1) 1.5
(0.3) 0 3.0
(0.7)
Community/social/personal
services 6.6
(0.1) 4.2
(0.5) 6.1
(0.1) 3.8
(0.8)
Note: standard errors in parentheses
35
Appendix C
Table C1: Means and Standard Deviations of Control variables (for children age 10-14)
1991 January- April May-December
Boys Girls Total Boys Girls Total Boys Girls Total
Head of household’s child 0.84 0.84 0.84 0.84 0.86 0.85 0.84 0.84 0.84
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Female Head of Household’s child 0.04 0.03 0.04 0.03 0.04 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.03
(0.004) (0.003) (0.003) (0.007) (0.007) (0.005) (0.004) (0.004) (0.003)
Mother’s age 38.1 37.1 37.6 37.2 36.7 37 38.4 37.2 37.8
(11.4) (12.1) (11.8) (11.8) (11.6) (11.7) (11.3) (12.2) (11.8)
Literate and Employed Mother 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.04 0.02 0.02 0.02
(0.004) (0.003) (0.004) (0.008) (0.01) (0.01) (0.003) (0.004) (0.003)
Illiterate and Employed Mother 0.41 0.39 0.40 0.40 0.38 0.39 0.42 0.40 0.41
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.02) (0.02) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
No Mother 0.05 0.06 0.05 0.05 0.06 0.06 0.04 0.06 0.05
(0.004) (0.005) (0.003) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.005) (0.006) (0.004)
Father’s age 42.4 41.4 41.9 41.4 41.5 41.5 42.7 41.3 42.0
(14.6) (15.6) (15.1) (15.8) (16.2) (16.0) (14.1) (15.4) (14.8)
Literate Father 0.15 0.16 0.16 0.17 0.16 0.16 0.15 0.17 0.16
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Employed Father 0.86 0.84 0.85 0.84 0.83 0.83 0.87 0.84 0.86
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.02) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Fathers Occupation
Technical worker 0.08 0.09 0.09 0.10 0.10 0.10 0.08 0.09 0.08
(0.006) (0.006) (0.004) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.005)
Service workers 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.04 0.05 0.06 0.06 0.07 0.07
(0.005) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.004)
Skilled agriculture worker 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.05 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.03 0.04
(0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.004) (0.005) (0.003)
Craftsmen 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.04 0.03 0.04 0.03 0.03 0.03
(0.004) (0.004) (0.002) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.004) (0.004) (0.003)
Elementary occupations 0.10 0.10 0.10 0.11 0.10 0.11 0.10 0.10 0.09
(0.01) (0.01) (0.004) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.005)
36
1991 January- April May-December
Boys Girls Total Boys Girls Total Boys Girls Total
No Father 0.07 0.09 0.08 0.09 0.10 0.10 0.09 0.07 0.08
(0.01) (0.01) (0.004) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.005)
Log household income (excluding child labor) 6.72 6.85 6.79 6.77 7.16 6.95 6.70 6.75 6.72
(4.7) (4.6) (4.7) (4.6) (4.4) (4.5) (4.7) (4.7) (4.7)
Number of children age 0-4 1.14 1.12 1.13 1.05 1.2 1.12 1.17 1.10 1.14
(1.3) (1.3) (1.3) (1.2) (1.5) (1.3) (1.4) (1.3) (1.3)
Number of children age 5-9 1.61 1.64 1.63 1.6 1.7 1.63 1.62 1.62 1.62
(1.4) (1.4) (1.4) (1.3) (1.5) (1.4) (1.4) (1.3) (1.4)
Number of children age 10-14 1.25 1.25 1.25 1.20 1.29 1.24 1.27 1.23 1.25
(1.05) (1.1) (1.06) (1.0) (1.1) (1.05) (1.1) (1.1) (1.1)
Number of children age 15-17 0.96 0.94 0.95 0.93 0.94 0.94 0.97 0.94 0.95
(0.82) (0.78) (0.80) 0.80 0.77 (0.79) (0.78) (0.81) (0.83)
Rural 0.49 0.47 0.48 0.46 0.41 0.44 0.50 0.49 0.49
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.02) (0.02) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Punjab 0.49 0.49 0.49 0.52 0.54 0.53 0.47 0.48 0.45
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.02) (0.02) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Sindh 0.26 0.26 0.26 0.24 0.26 0.25 0.27 0.26 0.26
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.02) (0.02) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
NWFP 0.17 0.17 0.17 0.17 0.16 0.16 0.17 0.18 0.18
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.02) (0.02) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Baluchistan 0.08 0.07 0.07 0.06 0.07 0.06 0.08 0.07 0.08
(0.01) (0.01) (0.004) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Note: standard errors in parentheses
37
Figure 1: Monthly Employment Rates by Age
Age 10
Months
1 4 8 12
10
20
30
40
50
Age 11
Months
14 8 12
10
20
30
40
50
Age 12
Months
14 8 12
10
20
30
40
50
Age 13
Months
1 4 8 12
10
20
30
40
50
Age 14
Months
14 8 12
10
20
30
40
50
38
Figure 2: Monthly Employment Rates in different Occupations by Age
Employment rate
Month
Agriculture Manufacturing
Shops and transport Consumer and personal services
1 4 8 12
1
20
40
60
80
100
Month
Agriculture Manufacturing
Shops and transport Consumer and personal services
14 8 12
1
20
40
60
80
100
Month
Agriculture Manufacturing
Shops and transport Consumer and personal services
1 4 8 12
1
20
40
60
80
100
Month
Agriculture Manufacturing
Shops and transport Consumer and personal services
1 4 8 12
1
20
40
60
80
100
Month
Agriculture Manufacturing
Shops and transport Consumer and personal services
14 8 12
1
20
40
60
80
100
39
Figure 3: Proportion of children age 10-14 in the months Jan - Dec.
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
Jan Feb March April May Jun Jul Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec
Age 10
Age 11
Age 12
Age 13
Age 14
40
References
Angrist, Joshua, D and Alan B. Krueger (1998) “Empirical Strategies in Labor Economics”
Working Paper, 98-7, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Department of Economics.
Basu, Kaushik and Pham Hoang Van(1998). “The Economics of Child Labor” American
Economic Review. 88(3) 412-427
Basu, Kaushik(2000). “The Intriguing Relationship between Adult Minimum Wage and Child
Labor” The Economic Journal. 110(March) C50-C61
- (2002). “A Note on Multiple General Equilibria with Child Labor”. Economic Letters
74(2002) 301-308
- (2005). “Child Labor and the Law: Notes on Possible Pathologies”. Economic Letters
87 (2005) 169-174
Burki, Abid and Tazeen Fasih (1999) “Household’s non-leisure Time Allocation for Children
and Determinants of Child Labor in Punjab, Pakistan” The Pakistan Development
Review. 37:4, 899-914
Betcherman, G; Fares, Jean; Luinstra, Amy; and Prouty, R (2004) “Child Labor, Education and
Children’s Rights”. Social Protection Discussion Paper Series No. 0412. Social
Protection Unit, The World Bank, Washington D.C.
Deaton, Angus (1997) “The Analysis of Household Surveys: A Microeconometric Approach to
Development Policy” Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore. World Bank,
Washington D.C.
Fasih (1998) “Determinant of Child Labor and their Earnings Profiles in Punjab, Pakistan”
M.Phil Thesis. Quaid-i-Azam University Islamabad, Pakistan.
Fasih (2004) “Analysing the Impact of Child Labor and Education Laws on Education in
Pakistan During the 1990s” Mimeo, University of London.
Government of Pakistan (1998) Pakistan Labor Gazette. Ministry of Manpower and Overseas
Pakistanis
Government of Pakistan (2000) “National Policy and Action Plan to Combat Child Labor” Child
Labor Unit, Ministry of Manpower and Overseas Pakistanis.
Government of Pakistan (2003) “Labor Force Survey of Pakistan 2001-2002”. Federal Bureau of
Statistics, Statistics Division. Available at
http://www.statpak.gov.pk/depts/fbs/publications/lfs2001_2002/lfs2001_2002.htm
41
Grimsrud, B (2002) “The Next Steps: Experiences and Analysis of How to Eradicate Child
Labor.” Fafo, Oslo. Norway.
Grootaert, Christiaan and Harry Patrinos (1999) “The Policy Analysis of Child Labor: A
Comparative Study”. St. Martin’s Press N.Y. World Bank, Washington D.C.
Hyder, S.N (1998) “Child Labor in Pakistan: Problems, Policies and Programmes” Asia-Pacific
Development Journal, 5(1) 121-132
Lleras-Muney, A (2001) “Were Compulsory Attendance Laws Effective? An Analysis from
1915-1939”. Working Paper 8563, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge.
Lloyd, Cynthia (1994) “Investing in the Next Generation: The Implication of High Fertility at the
Level of Family.” Research Division Working Paper 63. New York Population Council.
Lopez-Calva, Luis Felipe (1999) “A Social Stigma Model of Child Labor”. CAE Working Paper
No. 99-13, Cornell University
Manacorda, M. (2006) “Child Labor and the Labor Supply of Other Household Members,
Evidence from 1920 America”, forthcoming, American Economic Review
Margo, R.A and T.A.Finegan (1996) Compulsory Schooling Legislation and School Attendance
in Turn-of-the Century America: A natural experiment approach”. Economic Letters.
53(1996) 103-110.
Meyer, Bruce (1995) “Natural and Quasi-Experiments in Economics.” Journal of Business and
Economic Statistics. 13(2) 151-161
Moehling, C.M (1999) “State Child Labor Laws and the Decline of Child Labor.” Explorations
in Economic History. 36, 72-106.
Rogers, Carol Ann and Kenneth A. Swinnerton (2002). “A Theory of Exploitative Child Labor”
U.S. Department of Labor mimeo
Shafi, M and P. Shafi (2000) “Labor Code of Pakistan” Bureau of Labor Publications, Karachi
Siddiqi, Faraaz, and Harry A. Patrinos (1995) “Child Labor Issues, Causes and Interventions”.
Human Resources Development Working Paper No. 56. World Bank, Washington D.C.
Solmon, L.C and W. Landes (1972) “Compulsory Schooling Legislation: An Economic Analysis
of Law and Social Change in the Nineteenth Century”. The Journal of Economic History,
32(1) 54-91
Stock, J and Mark Watson (2003) “Introduction to Econometrics” Addison Wesley. USA
42
Tzannatos, Zafiris, A.Cigno and F.Rosati (2000) “Child Labor, Nutrition and Education in Rural
India: an Economic Analysis of Parental Choice and Policy Options”. World Bank
Conference on Child Labor, Washington D.C 11-13 April.
- (2002) “Child Labor Handbook”. Social Protection Discussion Paper Series No.0206.
Social Protection Unit, Human Development Network. The World Bank. Washington
D.C.
World Bank (2002) World Development Indicators. Washington D.C.
World Bank (2003). http://devdata.worldbank.org/genderstats/
... According to them, working outside home is usually exposed to environmental hazards which may affect their health and safety. Fasih (2007) has started that child labour creates unskilled and uneducated labour which affects country"s development and economy. ...
Article
Full-text available
Abstract : Child labour is a serious problem from many decades and a challenge for many developing countries. It has existed over the centuries not only in the impoverished areas of developing countries but also in developed countries until the beginning of the 20th century. Many countries have enacted various laws and have taken serious initiative to eradicate child labour, yet still the problem is very widespread throughout the world. The problem of child labour appears in severe form and various factors are involved with it. The causes for the incidence of child labour in India are complex and deeply rooted into the society. Poverty seems to be the main cause. Child labour can be found in both urban and rural areas. However the vast majority of child labour occurs in rural areas since poverty is more rampant. Although many poor rural families struggle for a better life in urban areas, this pushes families to force their children to work in order to increase the family income and ensure survival. This paper analysis the various responsible factors for child labour and attempts to find out those areas where there is discrimination in child labour. In addition the objective of this paper is to make a critical analysis of child labour in India. The findings reveal that child labour was a serious evil for the developing country -India. But now as per census report 2011, The total number of working children in the country has declined from 1.26 crore as per the census 2001 to 43.53 lakh as per census 2011 which shows 65 percent reduction. Keywords: child labour, forms, factors, discrimination, critical analysis
... Children under the age of 12 will be allowed to work in overtime. I agree that in movies and dramas, children under the age of 12 are allowed to use (Fasih, 2012). ...
... The relationship between the child work and agriculture sector in the GDP is positive and significant due to the strong association of income. Fasih (2007) analyzed the impact of legislation on child labor in Pakistan. The core objective of the article is to study whether ECA 1991 has played an effective role in falling child labor. ...
Article
Full-text available
The aim of this study is to explore the impact of Governance on Child Labor. We all know, child labor is most pressing issue in developing countries and illiteracy, less per capita income, malnutrition and lack of development has added the impact. In article, we discussed the types of Governance and explores some other factors which impede and promote the public sector responsibilities towards children. We also highlighted the methodologies of assessment and performance of governments as protectors of children rights according to international commitments i.e. SDG’s, In study, the dependent variable is Child Labor, while the independent variables are Governance, Population Growth Rate, Literacy Rate, Gross Domestic Product and Number of Schools. Time series data is used in range of 1990 to 2018. Augmented Dicky Fuller test is used to check the stationarity of the data. ARDL technique is applied on variables to check the long and short run relationship. The result shows an inverse relation between child labor and Governance, GDP, Literacy and number of schools as improvement in these indicators will decrease child labor. However, Population and child labor has a positive impact, by increasing population child labor will be increased. Impactful policies, good governance and better leadership are the only tools that can be helpful to tune child labor problem in developing countries.
... In Pakistan, the 1991 Employment of Children's Act similarly appears to have lowered child employment, though not in agriculture (Fasih, 2007). ...
Thesis
Full-text available
The main focus of present study was to focus on the role of mass-media in raising awareness and motivating relevant people against child labour. To meet the aim of the study, current scenario of child labour, scenario of people's awareness concerning child labour and impact of mass-media, impact of mass media at present to raise awareness against child labour and recommendations for effective utilization of mass-media were assessed. Data were collected from parents of 50 working children and 50 non-working children; 50 employers who recruited child labour; 20 working children and 20 journalists. Different semi-structured questionnaires for 4 types of participants were used to collect information. This study found differences between socio-demographic status of working and non-working children where statuses were better for non-working children. School dropout rate of working children was higher than that of non-working children. Family members and peers of working children were less likely to attend the schools compared to non-working children. Both parents and working children were less interested about education compared to non-working children group. Most common reason of school dropout and children's joining in work was poverty. Interestingly, indifferent attitude towards education was reported as second common cause of school dropout and children's joining in work. As reported, Television was the most popular mass-media being watched by participants and Indian TV channels were most popular to watch. Very few of participants were become aware of child labour through mass media but most of them believed that mass-media could play vital role to create awareness against child labour. The top recommendation came from the participants was that the government should proclaim their steps to prevent child labour and the opportunities given for the poor children through the advertisement and daily news on private TV channels.
... 016). While in the other countries of the world the ratio is decreasing dramatically. Ayub. (July1, 2016) explained Punjab restriction of employment of children act 2015, is soon to be tabled for legislation and become an act from the provincial assembly. Under this act children and adolescents are restricted to be employed in certain occupations. Fasih. (Nov, 2007) discussed that there has been a considerable reduction in Pakistan with respect to children involved in work, over the 1990's. This can be taken in view of the employment of children act 1991. The EOCA limits the smallest age for work as Fourteen years. When participation of selected control groups was being compared over a time period, ...
Article
Full-text available
The aim of this research was to evaluate child labor issue in the news coverage of in mainstream Pakistani press. The study also examined the news about awareness and education of the public towards the child labor issue. Quantitative content analysis was done for collection of data. A comparative study was conducted, where the news of the front and back page of the daily Dawn (English) and daily Jang (Urdu) were analyzed through purposive sampling technique from January 1st, 2016 to June 30th, 2016. The study revealed that the issue had not given more coverage, the newspapers had published more news single column, the government organizations had given more information instead of non-government organizations, and both newspapers had given more news about the violation of the child labor rights. While to educate and aware the public less coverage had been given.
... Teenagers are working in this industry due to lack of job opportunities and education. Section 3 of the Employment of Children Act (ECA), 1991 bans employment of children under-14 in occupations connected with hazardous labor works that seems being widely not complied with in this industry (Fasih, 2007). Majority of the work force involved in the CWM are having primary level. ...
Article
Full-text available
Electronic-waste (E-waste) management is one of the global emerging issues. The current study has been carried out to evaluate the existing computer waste management (CWM) in the twin cities of Rawalpindi and Islamabad, Pakistan. Study focuses on managerial gap analysis and determination of potential occupational impacts from current CWM practices. System observation and waste quantification are the tools used in field, while interviews and questionnaire based surveys were also conducted. The results reveal that approximately 624.15 tons of computer waste (CW) is generated in the twin cities per year. Approximately 825kg of monitors and 1125kg of CPUs wastes are generated in Twin cities per day. Associated authorities like CDA, Ministry of Climate Change and EPA were interviewed for legal compliance. There is the lack of rules implementation on E-waste management. However, legislations made by concerned authorities exist in the country but are not practically enforced. Further concerns observed during the study include lack of using basic PPEs and employing child labor in their adolescence. Implementation of existing laws along with basic occupational health and safety rules in the system may play a better role to attenuate the load of waste from the very important cities of Pakistan.
Article
Children are considered to be the group in society that are most vulnerable to abuse and exploitation. He is viewed as the man's father. We ensure the future of the country by securing his present and ensuring that he has access to the fundamental freedoms required for growth and development. More than 10 million children in India are employed as child labourers in both industrial and domestic settings. These children are vulnerable to workplace physical and psychological abuse as well as working in dangerous factory environments for little to no pay. The kid labourer lacks the education, health, and strength necessary for their development. Such pursuits prevent the growth of the mind and personality. Lack of income for families, migration, social situations, etc. forces a youngster to be made to labour under abusive circumstances. The government has a responsibility to recognise the terrible condition of the child and to take action to protect their fundamental human rights. The implementation of constitutional protections, proper enactment of laws, the involvement of the judiciary and the public at large, as well as recognition of the abhorrent conditions of child labourers' workplaces, have all contributed to efforts to alleviate their predicament.
Article
Full-text available
This study was undertaken to identify the socio, economic factors, which are responsible to enforce the child to do work in auto car repairing workshops in Tehsil: Ferozwala, District: Sheikhupura-Pakistan. For this purpose, 100 respondents under 18 years of age were randomly selected from all over the Tehsile. A comprehensive interviewing schedule was designed to collect the required information. Almost two third respondents were under 16 to 18 years, belonged to the rural areas. Almost one and half respondents had attained middle education. Majority of the respondents' father were alive but with low income and living in combine / joint family system. Majority of the respondents were not willing to work, but their parents motivated / forced them for working due to financial problems. There is a need to enhance educational facilities of children and employment opportunities for the head of family as well as possible. So that child labour would be controlled and our society put forward towards development. Finally, some suggestions are given at the end of paper for the better future of the children.
Article
Full-text available
The present study was conducted in Quetta district Balochistan province so as to determine the perception of the respondents about causes and consequences of child labor in Balochistan province. The sample size was 100 family units selected by using the simple random sampling. Somehow (40%) of the respondents fall in the age categories of 41 to 50 years, followed by 30% of the family units who were in the age categories of 50 and above years. More than half 52% of the respondents were illiterates and the other (14%) of the respondents had primary level of education. The result is further expressed that the other 20% of the male respondents were of the view that the retail trade, cycling repairing and carpet business important child labor route respectively. While 20% of the female respondents revealed that they are cycling repairing and carpet business important child labor route respectively at Quetta district. Children are the assets of any nation without their contribution in the developmental process can be null and void, therefore it should be recommended that government must take stern action against the child labor at grass-root level to eliminate the child labor in the community or society.
Article
Purpose Nearly every country has committed to protect children from work that could be harmful or interfere with their education by ratifying the International Labour Organization Minimum Age Convention (C138). Yet there is little transparency and accountability around whether countries have followed through on these commitments by passing legislation to protect children from work. The paper aims to discuss these issues. Design/methodology/approach This paper reports on analyses conducted of child labor legislation from all 193 United Nations member states to determine whether countries that have committed to ending child labor have taken the first step by passing legislation to protect children and youth from: work that is likely to be hazardous, work that is likely to interfere with their education and work that is harmful to their healthy development. Findings Findings show one in five ratifiers legally allow children to do hazardous work, and a similar number permit admission to employment at a young age. Moreover, legislative loopholes significantly undermine the protections that do exist in many countries. Originality/value Existing reporting mechanisms sometimes obscure whether central legal protections are in place, make cross-country comparisons difficult and impede the analysis of possible relationships between policies and outcomes across countries. This paper illustrates a novel approach to provide transparency and accountability on whether countries are meeting child labor commitments by using quantitative, globally comparable policy indicators.
Article
Full-text available
The causes and consequences of child labor are examined within a household decision framework with survival uncertainty and endogenous fertility. The data come from a nationally representative survey of Indian rural households. The complex interactions uncovered by the analysis suggest that mere prohibition of child labor, or the imposition of school attendance, would make things worse, and would be difficult to enforce. Beneficially reducing child labor requires changing the economic environment to which the work of children constitutes, in the great majority of cases, the rational response. Suitable policies include capillary provision of schools, and public health improvements. The effects of these policies go far beyond direct impacts. They have favorable indirect repercussions on the school attendance, educational expenditure, labor participation, and nutritional status of children. They also discourage fertility. Women's education, and income re-distribution are also helpful, but land re-distribution may be counterproductive.
Article
Using research designs patterned after randomized experiments, many recent economic studies examine outcome measures for treatment groups and comparison groups that are not randomly assigned. By using variation in explanatory variables generated by changes in state laws, government draft mechanisms, or other means, these studies obtain variation that is readily examined and is plausibly exogenous. This article describes the advantages of these studies and suggests how they can be improved. It also provides aids in judging the validity of inferences that they draw. Design complications such as multiple treatment and comparison groups and multiple preintervention or postintervention observations are advocated.
Article
This paper provides an up-to-date review of the evidence, primarily from developing countries, on families' experiences with fertility and family size and their implications for investments in young people. It looks at the experience of children collectively as well as individually and explores the ways in which boys' and girls' experiences differ. It explores implications for children's access to opportunities beyond the home and for their socialization into adult roles. The links between fertility, the extent to which children are wanted, and equity among siblings are also explored. The chapter first outlines the conventional wisdom on the relationship between "family size' and child investment and offers a context for analyzing influences on the family size-child investment relationship. -from Author
Article
This book is about the analysis of household survey data from developing countries and about how such data can be used to cast light on a range of policy issues. Much of the analysis works with household budget data, collected from income and expenditure surveys, though I shall occasionally address topics that require wider information. I shall use data from several different economies to illustrate the analysis, drawing examples of policy issues from economies as diverse as Cote d'Ivoire, India, Pakistan, South Africa, Taiwan (China), and Thailand. I shall be concerned with methodology as well as substance, and one of the aims of the book is to bring together the relevant statistical and econometric methods that are useful for building the bridge between data and policy.
Article
The role of law in relation to social change is not well understood. One reason for our ignorance is the lack of evidence on the causal role of legislation. Too often the efforts at social reform and the intended consequences of legislation are accepted as proof that behavior has been significantly altered. A case in point is legislation that compels children to attend school. Although it is commonly believed that such laws have been effective in increasing the participation of children in schooling systems in the United States over the last 100 years, there is little evidence to support or reject this belief. Some persons have questioned whether these laws have been the cause or the result of observed increases in school attainment. Still others have doubted the degree to which compulsory schooling laws have been enforced. Reports of widespread truancy in urban schools today call into question not only present enforcement difficulties but also whether these laws were effectively enforced from their inception in the nineteenth century. Yet, in spite of the contemporary and historical interest in compulsory school attendance laws, the basic question remains unanswered: what has been the effect, if any, of these laws on school enrollment and attendance?