BookPDF Available
QUICK
GUIDES
FOR
POLICY
MAKERS
7RENTAL HOUSING:
A MUCH NEGLECTED HOUSING
OPTION FOR THE POOR
Cities Alliance
CITIES WITHOUT SLUMS
Quick Guide 7: Rental Housing
Copyright © United Nations Human Settlements Programme
(UN HABITAT), 2011
All rights reserved
United Nations Human Settlements Programme (UN-HABITAT)
PO Box 30030, Nairobi, Kenya
Tel: +254 2 621 234
Fax: +254 2 624 266
www.unhabitat.org
DISCLAIMER
The designations employed and the presentation of the material
in this publication do not imply the expression of any opinion
whatsoever on the part of the Secretariat of the United Nations
concerning the legal status of any country, territory, city or area,
or of its authorities, or concerning delimitation of its frontiers
or boundaries, or regarding its economic system or degree of
development.
The analysis, conclusions and recommendations of the report do
not necessarily reflect the views of the United Nations Human
Settlements Programme, the Governing Council of the United
Nations Human Settlements Programme or its Member States.
HS Number: HS/193/10E
ISBN Number: (Volume) 978-92-1-132322-1
ISBN Number (Series): 978-92-1-131926-2
Cover photos ©: A Grimard
The publication of the Housing the Poor in African Cities series was
made possible through the financial support of Cities Alliance.
Published by
United Nations Human Settlements Programme (UN-HABITAT)
Training and Capacity Building Branch (TCBB)
E-mail: tcbb@unhabitat.org
Printing and Prepress: UNON/Publishing Services Section/Nairobi, ISO 14001:2004-certified
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS
Cities Alliance
CITIES WITHOUT SLUMS
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
2
This series of Quick Guides has been inspired by and prepared on the basis of a similar series on
Housing the Poor in Asian Cities, which was published jointly by UN-HABITAT and UNESCAP in
2009. The series is the adaptation of the Asian version to the realities and contexts of the sub-
Saharan African countries, and will be available in English, French and Portuguese. This has been
made possible through the financial contributions of Cities Alliance and UN-HABITAT.
The guides have been written by the team of experts from the African Centre for Cities (ACC)
led by Edgar Pieterse, with the substantive contributions of Karen Press, Kecia Rust and Warren
Smit.
The experts in the team who have contributed to invaluable background reports for the guides
are: Sarah Charlton, Firoz Khan, Caroline Kihato, Michael Kihato, Melinda Silverman and Tanya
Zack. Project management support was provided by Bruce Frayne, and design was ably handled
by Tau Tavengwa. A number of colleagues from UN-HABITAT’s Training and Capacity Building
branch, Shelter branch, and the Regional Office for Africa and Arab States, have contributed
to the design, development, and review of the guides. They include Gulelat Kebede, Cynthia
Radert, Claudio Acioly, Jean D’Aragon, Rasmus Precht, Christophe Lalande, Remy Sietchiping
and Alain Grimard. The guides have benefited from the contributions made by a range of ex-
perts who participated in the Expert Group Meeting held in November 2009 in Nairobi, Kenya:
Benjamin Bradlow, Malick Gaye, Serge Allou, Barbra Kohlo, Ardelline Masinde, Esther Kodhek,
Jack Makau, Allain Cain, Sylvia Noagbesenu, Kecia Rust, Babar Mumtaz, Alain Durand Lasserve,
Alan Gilbert and Tarek El-Sheik.
All these contributions have shaped the Quick Guides series, which we hope will contribute to
the daily work of policy makers in the sub-Saharan Africa region in their quest to improve hous-
ing and access to land for the urban poor.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
3
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
HOUSING IN AFRICAN CITIES: TO OWN IT OR RENT IT? 5
RENTAL HOUSING: HOW PEOPLE EXPERIENCE IT IN CITIES 6
URBAN RENTAL STATISTICS ARE UNRELIABLE 7
FOUR REASONS WHY RENTAL HOUSING IN CITIES TENDS TO BE INVISIBLE 8
HOW DO PEOPLE ACCESS RENTAL HOUSING? 9
EIGHT COMMON MYTHS ABOUT RENTAL HOUSING 10
WHO ARE THE LANDLORDS? 11
WOMEN AS LANDLORDS 12
WHAT MAKES FOR GOOD RENTAL ACCOMMODATION? 13
HOW DO LANDLORDS AND TENANTS WORK OUT THEIR RENTAL ARRANGEMENTS? 17
HOW THE DURATION OF RENTAL AGREEMENTS IS NEGOTIATED 18
LANDLORD-TENANT RELATIONSHIPS 19
WHEN TENANTS ARE THEIR OWN LANDLORDS 20
THE SUPPLY OF RENTAL HOUSING 21
MIGRANTS AND RENTAL ACCOMMODATION 23
HOW MUCH RENT TO CHARGE? 24
RENT CONTROL: IS IT AN OPTION? 25
POLICIES WHICH REGULATE RENTAL HOUSING IN AFRICAN CITIES 26
SIX WAYS TO PROMOTE RENTAL HOUSING THROUGH HOUSING POLICIES 27
REFERENCES 33
SUGGESTED FURTHER READING 34
WEBSITES 35
CONTENTS
CONDITIONS
CONCEPTS
APPROACHES
TOOLS AND GUIDELINES
RESOURCES
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
4
RENTAL HOUSING: A MUCH NEGLECTED HOUSING
OPTION FOR THE POOR
Millions of people in African cities are tenants. Rental housing may be only a partial answer to
urban housing problems, but it is an important housing option – especially for the urban poor, and
particularly in situations where people are not ready or able to buy or build houses of their own.
Rental housing is an integral part of a well functioning housing market. In spite of this, govern-
ments in Africa have done little to support the improvement of rental housing which already exists
or the expansion of affordable rental housing.
Rental housing markets are influenced by, and respond to, local economic and political conditions
and regulatory frameworks, and operate very differently from city to city. Landlords and tenants
develop and use rental housing in flexible and inventive ways to maximize the asset value of their
properties and to satisfy their accommodation needs.
It is important that policy makers understand the intricacies of their cities’ rental housing (both for-
mal and informal) and know how to formulate effective, flexible policies to promote and regulate
it. This guide presents the nature of rental housing markets and how they function. The issues of
demand and supply of rental housing are discussed, including the concept of rent-free housing.
The Guide considers the characteristics of good quality rental housing and sound landlord-tenant
rental arrangements, and presents policy options to promote and regulate the expansion of rental
housing – especially for the urban poor.
This Guide is not aimed at specialists, but aims to help build the capacities of national and local
government officials and policy makers who need to quickly enhance their understanding of low-
income housing issues.
QUICK GUIDE FOR POLICY MAKERS NUMBER 7
It is a common
misperception that
everyone wants to
own a house. For many
people, rental housing
is a better option at
some stage in their
lives.
5
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
CONDITIONS
HOUSING IN AFRICAN CITIES:
TO OWN IT OR RENT IT?
In the past few decades, African govern-
ments have actively promoted homeown-
ership through various means: subdividing
new land, extending infrastructure and
transport grids into new areas, making
housing finance easier to access and more
affordable to more people and smoothing
the way for private sector housing develop-
ers. Expanding a city’s stock of owned hous-
es and apartments creates employment,
stimulates local economies and is seen as
contributing to social and political stability.
In most places, homeownership has come
to be seen as the most secure and most de-
sired housing option and therefore ideal for
Africa’s urban citizens.
At the same time, rental housing suffers
from a negative reputation: landlords are
often perceived as being exploitative and
only too happy to offer crowded and sub-
standard housing at the highest price they
can squeeze from the vulnerable poor.
Rental housing, especially at the lower end
of the market, has also often been seen
as being shrouded in illegality and as con-
tributing to inner-city decay. The frequent
eviction of tenants and their mobility have
likewise been seen as potential sources of
civic unrest.
But even so, great numbers of people who
live in Africa’s cities rent the housing they
live in. In Kisumu, Kenya, 82% of house-
holds were living in rental accommodation
in 1998; in the same year, 60% of house-
holds in Addis Ababa and 57% of those
in Kumasi were also renting their homes.1
Rental housing today makes up a large pro-
portion of the urban housing stock in many
African countries and in many other coun-
tries around the world.
For many people, the decision to rent their housing is a deliberate, reasoned choice. One reason
may be because they can’t afford to buy a house, but there are other, equally important reasons
why they may choose to rent:
s Renting lets people stay mobile and move away when work is available elsewhere, without
being tied down to any particular place or to regular house payments.
s Renting gives people flexibility in how they manage their household budgets, moving to
cheaper housing when times are hard and to better housing, when their incomes increase,
or freeing up more of their earnings for more essential needs like food, education, medical
care or emergencies.
s Renting suits people during transitory periods of their lives, when they are not yet ready to
settle down in one place.
s Renting is convenient for households who may not want to make the long-term financial
commitment that comes with buying a house, or to face the long-term costs involved in
repairing and maintaining their own house.
s Renting allows people to send more of their city earnings home to relatives, or to invest in
buying land or building a house or business back in the village.
WHY DO PEOPLE RENT?
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
6
CONDITIONS
In a well functioning housing rental market,
people can make rental choices based on
one or more of these reasons, to suit their
current needs and priorities. But where the
rental options in a city are too limited or
inflexible, the struggle to find affordable
rental housing can lead to great economic
and social hardship for urban dwellers.
RENTAL HOUSING: HOW PEOPLE
EXPERIENCE IT IN CITIES
Rental housing is an important part of the
housing market in all African cities. For
large-scale property developers and inves-
tors, one way to earn money from the prop-
erties they own is to rent them out to short-
term or long-term tenants. Landlords who
operate in this market need to have access
to major sources of finance for initial pur-
chase of land and construction costs. Ongo-
ing costs such as maintaining the buildings
and paying managing agents are usually
covered by the rentals charged for units in
these properties.
The housing that small-scale landlords sup-
ply may come in the form of cheap rental
rooms, apartments of various sizes, or
rooms built with substandard construction
on illegally subdivided land or partitioned
within dilapidated older buildings. It could
be a shack, a room built in a slum or behind
the owner’s house with shared services. It
could be rented space within a shared room,
or even the right to store one’s belongings
and occupy a certain space within a shared
room for part of the day, according to the
occupants’ working times.
7
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
CONDITIONS
URBAN RENTAL STATISTICS
ARE UNRELIABLE
It is difficult to collect and compile compara-
ble data on rental housing. Many countries
keep records which do not separate rental
housing from non-rental forms of housing
which are not ownership, such as sharing.
Sometimes the distinction is also hard to
make, especially in some African countries
where extended family households are still
common, in which relatives and grown-up
children with households of their own still
live in the parental home. National rental
statistics can also be misleading, since they
may suggest overall national patterns of
rental housing which hide local realities.
The proportion of rental housing tends to be
much higher in cities than in rural areas, and
also vary greatly between cities within the
same country. Official statistics also do not
capture the numbers of informal rentals in
cities, where landlords make private arrange-
ments with tenants. These arrangements
can be exploitative, as tenants desperate for
accommodation may need to agree to pay
very high rentals for poor quality housing,
and without tenure security. The difficult
situations that these tenants experience are
not recorded in the official picture of rental
accommodation in the city.
Hundreds of millions of people in poor countries rent their homes.2
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
8
CONDITIONS
FOUR REASONS WHY RENTAL
HOUSING IN CITIES TENDS TO BE
INVISIBLE
In many parts of West Africa, poor housing conditions are related to social ties and affiliations
– many people rely on their relations to provide them with shelter. A homeowner in most West
African societies is expected to accommodate every member of the extended family, rent free in
‘family houses’. In Nigeria, traditionally, it is taboo to sell a family house, or indeed any house,
compound or residential plot, where a head of family was buried. To sell such a property would
be disregarded as a humiliation by members of the extended family.
The big advantage of the system, of course, is that few West Africans are homeless. Migrants
have somewhere to stay when they move to the city. Adult children have somewhere to live
when they grow up and raise their own children. In poor societies, this is a major advantage. As
such, family houses provide accommodation for many of the poor and disadvantaged members
of long-established families at almost no cost to themselves or to the state; they are thus a major
resource in social welfare.
But sometimes the price paid for this is the poor quality of the accommodation. In Ghana,
family houses form part of the “most neglected housing”. However, in general it is recognised
that such non-paying households are relatively well provided for: a higher proportion of people
needing housing obtain it through this form than through commercial rental arrangements.
Policy makers should therefore be mindful of the major contribution which family houses make
in housing those on low incomes, and act to encourage and enable maintenance and provision
of such housing rather than acting as if it is a vestige of a bygone age, of little relevance to the
modern city.3
THE HIDDEN NEED FOR RENTAL HOUSING: ‘FAMILY HOUSES’ IN WEST AFRICA
1. It is often hard to distinguish rental
housing from owner-occupied hous-
ing. Even in large purpose-built rental
complexes, some units may get sold off
to individual owners. There are people
renting in densely built old city quar-
ters, in public housing estates, in hous-
ing schemes for civil servants, in private
sector subdivisions and condominiums.
There are also many renters in slums
and squatter settlements, in peri-urban
land subdivisions and in semi-rural com-
muter settlements.
2. Rental housing is dispersed all over
the city. Rental arrangements exist in
all parts of a city’s housing market. As
housing markets mature and housing
options multiply, the possibilities for
tenancy also multiply. In many cities,
as the supply of rental housing for the
poor increases, the role of exploitative
slumlords tends to diminish.
3. It is hard to distinguish landlords
from their tenants. Many urban land-
lords tend to be small-scale entrepre-
neurs who live on the same premises as
their tenants and who share a similar
social and economic status. Poor land-
lords tend to rent out rooms to poor
tenants, whereas better-off landlords
9
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
CONDITIONS
HOW DO PEOPLE ACCESS
RENTAL HOUSING?
rent to better-off tenants. It is often the
case that the tenant earns more than
the landlord, for whom renting out one
or several rooms in his or her house may
be the only source of income.
4. Both landlords and tenants often
keep their rental relationship quiet.
This is to avoid taxes or government
planning or zoning policies which put
restrictions on renting. Because the
rental agreements between landlord
and tenant are personal in nature, the
details are often kept secret from out-
siders or even from other tenants on
the same property.
A well kept secret: Because it is often hard to
tell when housing is actually rental housing, policy
interventions that specifically target rental housing tend
to be
In some cities, access to rental housing may
be linked to conditions such as income
level, gender or enrolment as a student.
Some public housing, for example, may be
purpose-built for low-income tenants, but
allotted conditionally to specific groups,
such as slum evictees or shack-dwellers
who have lost their houses through natural
disasters. Some rental housing built by uni-
versities, charities or NGOs may be reserved
for students, for women or for specific
low-income groups. More generally, urban
rental housing is usually accessed in one of
these ways:
s Housing access based on open mar-
kets: In an open housing market, rental
housing is accessed directly by anybody
who can afford the rent the landlord is
asking, and agrees to abide by what-
ever occupancy conditions the landlord
stipulates.
s Housing access based on relationships:
In many African cities undergoing rapid
urbanization, urban poor households
still have roots in villages, and many
continue to provide temporary, rent-
free (or low-rent) shelter to relatives and
friends coming in from the village. This
kind of arrangement is crucial for sea-
sonal migrants who may stay and work
for only part of the year.
s Housing access based on occupation:
Construction labourers are often provid-
ed with basic housing on the construc-
tion site, domestic workers often stay
with their employers and factory work-
ers are sometimes provided with hous-
ing near the factory. Some government
jobs also come with rental or rent-free
accommodation.
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
10
CONDITIONS
EIGHT COMMON MYTHS ABOUT
RENTAL HOUSING
1. Everyone owns their homes in rich
countries. There is little relationship be-
tween a country’s economic development
and its levels of homeownership. Hom-
eownership is actually lower in many rich
European countries where well developed
rental markets cater to the needs of all
income groups who prefer to rent rather
than to own.
2. Everyone wants to be a homeowner.
All over the world, people are bombarded
from every direction with the message that
homeownership is the best and the most
desired housing option. There are big ad-
vantages to owning your own home, but
renting also offers its own benefits such as
mobility, flexibility, lower investment and
reduced commitment.
3. Homeownership offers people a bet-
ter life. Ownership is often presented as
more natural than renting — a form of
tenure which makes people legitimate citi-
zens, grounded in their neighbourhoods
and their country’s economic life. Rental
housing, on the other hand, is presented
as exploitative, sub-standard and tempo-
rary places where poorer citizens stay. But
homeownership has its problems, just as
rental housing has its advantages. Good
quality rental housing with secure tenure
agreements can provide the most favour-
able living conditions for many urban citi-
zens.
4. Nobody invests in rental housing. In-
vesting in rental housing may not be as
attractive to private sector businesses and
public sector agencies as it once was. But
at the same time, in many African cities, in-
vestments by individual landlords in small,
scattered, independent rental units have
increased dramatically. Tenants are also
often willing to invest in upgrading their
rental homes, if they know that their ten-
ure agreements are secure.
5. Renting is inequitable. In the days when
most landlords were the rich elites and
most tenants were poor, rental housing
was indeed inequitable. Today, however,
rich landlords tend to rent to rich tenants,
and poor landlords to poor tenants. Espe-
cially among the poor, the landlord-tenant
relationship is often one of mutual depen-
dence. Exploitative landlords do exist, but
it is possible for laws and policies to be
implemented to protect tenants from bad
landlords.
6. Governments should prohibit poor
quality rental housing. Many tenants
live in crowded, under-serviced and di-
lapidated housing, because that is all they
can afford. Often, governments respond
by demolishing this housing, but that only
makes housing problems worse and leads
to even greater overcrowding elsewhere.
A much better approach is to facilitate im-
provement and the expansion of existing
rental housing.
7. Mobility is bad for the poor. Low-in-
come tenants are often people who need
to be free to move from one place to an-
other, to take advantage of job possibili-
ties and better economic conditions that
become available in different places. For
them, mobility means survival, and flexible
rental housing is essential.
8. Homeownership encourages the emer-
gence of a politically stable society. In
the USA, tenants were not allowed to vote
until 1860, because homeowners were
considered to be better citizens, better
neighbours and even better persons. This
kind of thinking influences many policy
makers as well, who see tenants as people
who are transient, poor, unsettled and un-
desirable, not as valuable workers and citi-
zens who need flexibility and mobility.
4
11
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
CONCEPTS
WHO ARE THE LANDLORDS?
Landlords in African countries include com-
panies and individuals, rich and poor per-
sons operating both in the formal and infor-
mal sectors, private sector and public sector
housing agencies, as well as government de-
partments. Private sector landlords include:
investors who build rental units on vacant
land and rent them out; investors who buy
developer-built houses and rent them out;
and owner-occupants who provide rental
units on part of their land or within their
own houses. The only difference between
formal and informal sector landlords is that
formal sector landlords have acquired own-
ership and building rights within the state’s
regulatory framework, whereas informal
sector landlords have not.
Landlords can also be classified according
to the scale of their operations. Some land-
lords with access to big capital may develop
hundreds of rental units on various pieces
of land, while others may be individual
households or retired persons who oper-
ate on a very small scale, with one or two
rental rooms inside or at the back of their
own house. Small-scale landlords provide a
large proportion of rental housing in Afri-
can cities. Many landlords tend to gradually
make more and more money through their
rental businesses, but shift back and forth
between the various categories described
below, which also describe different invest-
ment scenarios.
Four types of landlords
1. Household landlords may have inher-
ited some vacant land, or have spare
rooms available because the household
separated, relatives died or children
moved elsewhere. Or they may have
left their own house and moved into
employer-provided housing. The income
from rental housing may help them to
meet basic needs, to pay instalments on
their property, or cover the expense of
repairs, maintenance or improvements.
Rental income may serve as a safety net
against their unstable employment. It
may also serve as a substitute pension
after retirement, or as an investment for
the next generation.
2. Commercial landlords are similar to
household landlords, but they oper-
ate in a more professional way. They
have more capital to invest, their rental
business is on a larger scale and they
may employ professional staff to man-
age their rental units. They may target
middle- or high-income tenants rather
than low-income groups, and operate
in a formal way, using written rental
contracts and following the building
and safety standards.
They may use different strategies to
maximize return on their investments
and to minimize their taxes. These are
not necessarily tycoons, but could be
people who want to secure the future
for themselves and their children. Com-
mercial landlords also include the ex-
ploitative “slum lords” operating in in-
formal settlements in Nairobi and other
large African cities.
3. Public sector landlords may include
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
12
CONCEPTS
WOMEN AS LANDLORDS
Both men and women act as landlords in
the African context, sometimes in partner-
ship and sometimes on their own. Whether
male or female landlords dominate the rent-
al housing market depends greatly on local
custom and on the demography of the city.
In Nairobi, for example, more men are land-
lords than women, probably because many
more men are found among the political
and administrative class that control land-
lordism in that city. However, “slum landla-
dies” are also a common phenomenon.
Elsewhere, there are often more landla-
dies than landlords. In Botswana, there are
more female than male landlords in offi-
cial housing projects, and in South Africa
more women rent out accommodation in
the backyards of council houses, mainly be-
cause so many men have died or forsaken
their families.
Where women handle domestic affairs, they
also tend to deal with tenants in small-scale
rental situations, even if a man is the official
owner of the property. Many widows and
separated women also opt to rent out part
of their houses or develop new rental units
to supplement their incomes. Divorce set-
tlements and lines of inheritance can play
government departments and land-
owning agencies, and their rental ar-
rangements may cover purpose-built
social housing for low-income tenants
and institutional housing provided as a
fringe benefit to civil servants in various
government departments.
4. Employer landlords are landlords
whose motive is not profit. They might
include factories and large companies
providing rental rooms for their work-
ers, hospitals providing rental rooms for
their nurses, or universities providing
rental housing for students and faculty
members.
13
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
CONCEPTS
WHAT MAKES FOR GOOD
RENTAL ACCOMMODATION?
a role here, as does age: because women
tend to live longer than men, they often
rent out the property they inherit.
Small-scale landlordism is sometimes the
only available source of income for women,
either because they have not been able to
acquire the training to take on other in-
come-generating activities, or because they
do not have access to finance that would
allow them to set up a small business in the
settlement where they live. For women who
need to be at home to take care of children,
elderly or sick members of the family, rent-
ing out part of the property to tenants can
be an economic lifeline, especially where
there is no other income source for the
household.5
Although low-income tenants may choose
not to own their homes, or not be able
to afford to do so, in many other respects
their accommodation needs are the same as
those of homeowners. This section exam-
ines how rental housing needs to respond
to these needs in order to provide good
quality accommodation for tenants.
FACTOR 1: Quality of the rental
housing
s The quality and durability of the build-
ing materials: Most of the rental hous-
ing available to the urban poor is not
of high quality, since the materials that
went into these housing units tend to
be the cheapest available. As a con-
sequence, the rental units are weak,
low-quality and prone to maintenance
problems.
s The level of maintenance: The theory
goes that lack of proper maintenance
makes the quality of rental housing
inferior to owner-occupied housing.
Timely maintenance depends a lot on
where the landlord lives and how good
the landlord-tenant relationship is.
Landlords who live on the premises and
have friendly relations with their tenants
tend to take better care of their rental
units than absentee landlords do. Pub-
lic sector social housing managers, for
example, tend to be slower to react to
maintenance needs than private estate
managers.
s The level of crowding: It is common
that low-income rental units (whether
single rooms, apartments or houses)
have many persons squeezed into small
spaces. High rents often mean that poor
tenants can only afford accommodation
by crowding more people into a small
space and sharing the rent. Different
cultures have different conceptions of
what constitutes crowding. In some
cultures, living with many family mem-
bers is preferable to living in small fam-
ily units, or at least tolerated. But it is
clear that overcrowding is often a prob-
lem, especially in situations where ten-
ants have different needs – for example
women with young children having to
live in crowded rental units with other
people.
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
14
CONCEPTS
FACTOR 2: Access to jobs and public
services
Another attribute of rental housing which
can have a considerable effect on its value is
its proximity to places of employment, trans-
port, schools, health care, markets, places of
worship and other neighbourhood-level so-
cial infrastructure. If residents have to travel
long distances to earn money or to resolve
other essential household needs, it means
time lost and extra money spent. And that
can easily unbalance precarious household
expenditure and seriously compromise a
household’s ability to survive.
Public services and neighbourhood ame-
nities are usually more accessible and in
greater variety in inner-city locations. That
is why the rent for units in central areas of
the city is usually higher than in peripheral
areas where jobs and public services are
farther away. Investors and property devel-
opers understand very well the importance
of location in determining the value of and
demand for housing. For the urban poor,
as well, location is probably the single most
important factor in the choice of housing
— whether it is owner-occupied or rental
housing. The problem is that market pres-
sures on inner-city land make it difficult to
sustain low-income rental housing in city-
centre locations, when more commercial
uses of the same land offer both private and
public landowners the attraction of higher
incomes.
Informal settlements in peripheral areas
tend to be built fairly close to growth cen-
tres where jobs and transport are not too
far away, and other public services are be-
ginning to appear. These pioneering settle-
ments in peripheral areas of the city also
become important sources of rental accom-
modation of various sorts, and as the city
grows over time, the access to public ser-
vices in these settlements — and their rental
units — will improve.
FACTOR 3: Access to basic
infrastructure
The demand for (and consequently the
value of) a rental housing unit can also be
measured by how easy it is for the tenants
to get access to utilities such as electricity,
water and sanitation. Self-contained apart-
ments, rooms and houses tend to have the
easiest access, whereas rooms with shared
access to services do not always do so well.
The popularity of rental housing dimin-
ishes considerably as access to utilities gets
farther away from the room or is not per-
manently available. Rental units in slums,
squatter settlements and illegally subdivided
tenement structures tend to have the great-
est problems of access to basic services.
This is often because accessing municipal
electricity and water supply is contingent
upon having some legal status or house
registration, which many rental units do not
have. In these cases, tenants are likely to be
forced to share utilities and utility areas such
as toilets, washing and cooking spaces with
others, or else pay higher rates for infor-
mal electricity and water connections from
nearby houses and businesses.
15
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
CONCEPTS
Upgrading programmes are themselves an excellent means by which to increase the supply of
rental housing in low-income settlements. The provision of water, electricity and schools, the im-
provement of transport links, and the integration of self-help settlements into the urban fabric
attract tenants and encourage the creation of more rental housing. Studies from many countries
have demonstrated that tenants wish to move into improved neighbourhoods and that own-
ers respond positively to the increased demand for housing. Not only does the upgrading of
informal settlements improve the quality of owners’ lives, it also increases their opportunities for
generating income from letting rooms.
Unfortunately, upgrading projects all too often ignore the effects both on the existing tenant
population and in terms of the opportunities for generating more rental accommodation. Those
who plan, implement, finance and study urban upgrading programmes frequently fail even to
mention tenants.
What seems essential in future is that managers of urban upgrading programmes be made
aware of the presence of tenants and of the potential for increasing rental accommodation.
They should take tenants into consideration in planning the programme because upgrading
can create tension between owners and tenants. Since tenants are generally less motivated to
join community projects than homeowners, community organizations must be encouraged to
include more members from among the tenants.6
UPGRADING OF INFORMAL SETTLEMENTS OFTEN BYPASSES RENTAL
ACCOMMODATION
FACTOR 4: Location and social
support systems
Uncertain and irregular employment, vary-
ing sources of income and unexpected ex-
penditures can all force poor tenants to rely
extensively on their families and on the infor-
mal support networks in their communities
when crises occur. At the same time, their
low incomes make it important to minimize
unnecessary expenses on utilities, services
or transport, which can also sometimes be
done by staying with or close to their rela-
tives. When all these needs and constraints
are added together, it is clear that the best
place for the poor to live is near their social
support networks. Since most of these rela-
tionships are settlement-based and formed
over time, location is important.
FACTOR 5: Responsiveness to
tenants’ mobility patterns
Besides temporary labourers, seasonal mi-
grants and short-term factory workers, a
lot of poor people who are working in the
city have good reasons to rent their hous-
ing and to avoid being tied down to hom-
eownership at a certain point in their lives,
either because the time is not right to invest
in housing, or because they may wish to
remain mobile, or because they have other
priorities.
Moving in and out of cities has become an
inherent part of life for many Africans – peo-
ple move constantly between the city and
the rural areas, or between different cities.
Whether they come for higher education,
to find a job, or to seek health care, most
people will need flexible accommodation in
the city which, most frequently, is provided
in the form of rental housing.
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
16
CONCEPTS
Fresh graduates and young people want-
ing to gain experience are always on the
lookout for new and better-paid jobs and
may find it advantageous to change jobs
frequently. Young tenants may base their
housing choices on the possibility of leav-
ing at short notice and with a minimum of
formalities. Single people may want to save
enough money to settle down elsewhere
later. Others may wish to settle down in the
city once they have found stable employ-
ment.
This mobility is a crucial part of many peo-
ple’s lives and an important part of the
country’s economic and human resource
development. As these people come into
cities they all require housing, and rental
housing at the right price and in the right
location is an important option for many.
FACTOR 6: A tenant’s income level
People’s motivation to rent is usually linked
explicitly to their long-term security, as it is
for people who seek homeownership. The
only difference is that because low-income
tenants lack long-term security of income,
they may opt to set aside whatever money
they can for investments other than hous-
ing, such as supporting an extended family
or saving to pay for education. The need to
rent can arise from different priorities, and
for this reason, the affordability of rental ac-
commodation is directly tied to the cost of
meeting these long-term priority needs. The
lower a tenant’s income level, the less he or
she will be able to allocate to rental, relative
to funds set aside for achieving other long-
term goals.
FACTOR 7: A tenant’s stage in the
life cycle
Rental and shared housing is often a feature
of the earlier stages of people’s lives. Ten-
ants tend to be younger than homeown-
ers and are often single — students, recent
migrants, wage-workers, factory workers
or professionals. Couples who rent tend to
have fewer children than owners. Sharers
are similar to renters, but they have friends,
17
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
CONCEPTS
fellow employees or relatives who are able
to provide them with accommodation,
whereas tenants may not have such options
to fall back on.
As improvements in medical care lead to
declining mortality rates and increasing life-
spans, households are now commonly span-
ning three or four generations. That means
there are more people to take care of, in-
creasing pressures on households. This may
result in households deciding to rent space
in their house to others, or it may mean that
younger household members move out to
rental accommodation. For young families,
rental housing is often their first step into
the housing market, with the eventual goal
of homeownership.
Declining birth rates, HIV and AIDS, and
growing rates of separation and divorce
amongst married couples also have an ef-
fect on household composition and cohe-
sion, and therefore on housing demand.
The increase in female-headed households,
for example, often means more low-income
households, which require flexible, afford-
able rental housing.
HOW DO LANDLORDS AND TENANTS
WORK OUT THEIR RENTAL
ARRANGEMENTS?
The rental amount a landlord charges will
depend on the quality of the accommoda-
tion itself, as well as the quality of the larger
environment, including the unit’s access to
basic infrastructure, public services, neigh-
bourhood amenities and jobs. In most rental
arrangements, the rental rate will be set at a
level which allows the landlord to profit from
the rental unit and to have a return on the in-
vestment, by earning more than the amount
invested in constructing the rental unit and
the maintenance costs. But in cases of subsi-
dized public sector housing, the rental rates
may be lower than what is required to re-
cover the original investment.
Landlords tend to argue that rents are too
low, whereas tenants, and their associa-
tions, argue that they are too high. Part of
the problem about rent levels relates to what
is meant by rents being “too high”. Some-
times, rents make up a very high proportion
of the tenant’s income but are nonetheless
still too low for landlords to make a profit or
even pay for maintenance of the property.
If a tenant household cannot pay the rent
being charged, the market would suggest
that either the rent must fall or the house-
hold must leave, voluntarily or through evic-
tion. If the rent falls, and landlords receive a
smaller income, the danger is that the quality
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
18
CONCEPTS
of the housing supply will decline. A further
problem is that when there is a substantial
difference between the level of rent that will
encourage landlords to rent out property and
the ability or willingness of rental households
to pay that level of rent, landlords will stop
investing in rental housing. Similarly, if land-
lords measure rent levels against what is re-
quired to match the returns from other kinds
of investment opportunity and poor tenants
measure the rents against what they are able
to pay, there will often be a mismatch.
How do tenants pay their rent?
Most rental agreements require the tenant
to pay a fixed sum of money to the landlord
on a monthly basis. In addition, the tenant
usually has to deposit “key money” with the
landlord on first taking occupation of the
accommodation – an amount equal to one,
two or more months’ rental, to be kept by
the landlord if the tenant defaults on pay-
ments, or damages the property. In some
countries tenants have to pay a very large ad-
vance on rental, to protect the landlord from
losses if they fail to make monthly or weekly
payments; in Ghana, for example, the tenant
may have to pay up to three years’ rental at
the outset, to secure the accommodation.
Low-income tenants face great difficulty in
accumulating the lump sums needed to pay
key money or a big advance. Policy makers,
savings collectives and private sector finance
institutions can help tenants to meet their
rental costs by developing financial tools to
protect landlords against loss of rental, while
helping tenants to save money for regu-
lar rental payments. (See Quick Guide 5 on
Housing Finance.)
HOW THE DURATION OF RENTAL
AGREEMENTS IS NEGOTIATED
Another important variable in rental hous-
ing arrangements is the duration of the
rental agreement. A rental contract can be
made for a specific period of time – such as
a month, a year, five years or even longer. In
some countries lease periods are limited by
specific laws, but can be renewed once the
contract period has expired. Rental housing
contracts may be made as verbal agreements
or involve some simple paper lease contract,
which both landlord and tenant sign. Some
types of longer-term rental agreements re-
quire a written contract, sometimes even
with some official registration of the con-
tract. For some landlords and some ten-
ants, a short-term rental agreement may be
the most suitable one.
Landlords may need to generate income
from a vacant room or house for a short
period, before selling the property. Tenants
may not want to commit themselves to stay-
ing in one settlement or city for a long time.
These short-term arrangements are one of
the reasons why rental housing is such a
useful part of the urban housing market.
But short-term agreements can also lead to
a lack of maintenance of the property, as
tenants may feel too insecure with a short-
tenure lease to invest time and money in
keeping the premises in good repair. Secure
long-term tenure, on the other hand, cre-
ates conditions in which tenants are more
willing to take responsibility for keeping
their rental accommodation in good condi-
tion.
19
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
CONCEPTS
LANDLORD-TENANT
RELATIONSHIPS
The relationship between the landlord and
the tenant is based on an agreement. While
their relationship is usually reasonable,
some common problems are experienced in
African cities:
s The landlords complain that their ten-
ants don’t take good care of the rental
housing, pay their rent late, misbehave
in general and don’t understand that
rising costs of utilities, maintenance and
repairs make it necessary to raise the
rent.
s The tenants complain that their land-
lords fail to maintain the housing prop-
erly, don’t repair things when they
break, charge unfairly high fees for utili-
ties, increase the rent without warning,
turn hostile when the rent is paid a little
late, threaten eviction or fail to return
security deposits when they move out.
Many rental agreements between landlords
and tenants are personal and informal in
nature, concluded outside of any govern-
ment regulatory framework or formal legal
system. This informality and lack of official
documentation makes going to court an
extremely impractical way of dealing with
landlord-tenant conflicts. In some cases,
landlords will try to avoid problems by only
accepting tenants who have been recom-
mended by people they know. But in other
cases, landlords use a different strategy and
actively seek to attract strangers and outsid-
ers, because they want to avoid being too
close to their tenants to maintain a more
business-like relationship, in the hopes that
the tenants will take care of their rental
unit, respect the rental conditions and leave
when they are asked to.
There can also be a “dark side” to the in-
formal agreements between tenants and
small-scale landlords, where a landlord takes
advantage of the lack of a written contract
to constantly raise the rent, squeeze more
and more tenants into limited space, let
the building deteriorate into slum condi-
tions, or in other ways disregard the needs
of tenants and the terms of their agree-
ment. Where there is a serious shortage of
low-income housing in a city, unscrupulous
landlords will know that tenants have little
option but to put up with exploitative and
often illegal rental conditions, because they
lack the resources to find better housing or
challenge the landlord’s actions using the
legal system.
Resident landlords
Relations are often better when landlords
live in the same building or on the same
land as their tenants. To prospective ten-
ants, it may be reassuring to have a resi-
dent landlord, who will be closer at hand
to ensure good services and help discover
the neighbourhood’s social infrastructure.
Rental housing with resident landlords also
has the reputation of being better serviced
and better maintained, which in turn makes
for fewer landlord-tenant tensions.
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
20
APPROACHES
WHEN TENANTS ARE THEIR
OWN LANDLORDS
For the poor, the collective support net-
works of the communities they live in are
an important survival mechanism, which
helps them to meet the needs and resolve
problems they cannot deal with individually.
Cooperative housing is one form of collec-
tive support that offers advantages because
it pools resources to lower individual hous-
ing costs, fosters collective action and self-
help, increases the creditworthiness of low-
income households, and limits or prevents
speculation.7 This experience has not been
widespread in Africa but in recent years
there has been some evidence of tenant co-
operatives emerging in some African cities.
A housing cooperative is an association that
collectively owns and/or rents and governs
their housing on a not-for-profit basis. Ide-
ally, it works on the basis of providing af-
fordable ownership of housing for its mem-
bers. Credit and reference checks are carried
out on all prospective members. They are
required to attend information and training
sessions before they can become members.
Their membership gives them a share in
the housing cooperative and they share the
costs of financing and managing it. They
have a right to live in housing owned by the
cooperative, and to sign a Use Agreement
with it. This makes them part-owners and
part-tenants of the cooperative.
Governments’ support for cooperatives var-
ies. At times it is limited to just financial sup-
port. In Egypt, until recently, the government
subsidized 40-year loans, at an interest rate
of 5–6%, to lower-income groups through
cooperatives. In Ethiopia, there have been
more substantial forms of support for co-
operative housing at different times in the
country’s post-revolution history. A new ur-
ban housing policy was introduced in 1986,
which included measures such as providing
standard house plans free of charge to co-
operatives, cutting the maximum plot size
from 500 m2 to 250 m2, creating a govern-
ment enterprise to provide building materi-
als to cooperatives at controlled prices, and
reducing bureaucratic delays to legalising
cooperative membership.8 This approach
was subsequently overtaken by the Condo-
minium Housing Programme which lead to
the unintended promotion of private rental
housing because the intended beneficiaries
could not service the debts associated with
it and then started to rent it out to higher
income groups.
21
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
APPROACHES
THE SUPPLY OF RENTAL
HOUSING
1. PUBLIC RENTAL HOUSING:
Large-scale government-built housing has
generally been negligible in African coun-
tries. In some African countries, for example
Kenya, Malawi and Tanzania, a good num-
ber of rental housing schemes were cre-
ated to provide subsidized accommodation
within local authority jurisdictions, mostly
through ‘national housing corporations’.
Elsewhere in Africa government rhetoric
greatly outweighed any achievement on the
ground; in Nigeria, for example, although
public housing was warmly embraced by of-
ficial rhetoric very few housing units were
produced even during the height of the oil
boom.
Where governments have attempted at one
time or another to provide housing for por-
tions of their population, one way of do-
ing this was to develop and provide rental
or rent-free housing units to the families
of public sector employees, including the
armed forces, police officers, civil servants
or employees of various government agen-
cies. Another way was to develop and deliv-
er public or subsidized housing, which pro-
vided rental units to vulnerable low-income
groups, including migrants, slum evictees or
fire victims. But since the investment cost of
these public housing initiatives was too high
for governments to construct enough units
to satisfy the real housing needs, there were
bound to be problems with allocating those
units that were built. In many cases, formal
selection criteria were not able to avoid in-
stances of nepotism, patronage, favourit-
ism based on party membership or outright
corruption, and as a result, the projects ex-
cluded the households most in need. And,
in spite of generous subsidies, the rents in
many of these public housing projects were
still too high for the poorest households
to afford. Many government agencies also
proved to be rather inefficient landlords,
and quickly ran into financial difficulties be-
cause rents were often set too low and sel-
dom rose as rapidly as prices. In the end, the
required investment, problems in allocation
and failure to carry out adequate mainte-
nance – resulting in buildings rapidly falling
into disrepair – often made governments
decide to sell off the units to households
outside the original target group.
The growing need for governments to be
“financially responsible” quickly discour-
aged further rental housing developments.
In most African countries, from the middle
1980s local authorities stopped investing
in rental housing and, during the 1990s,
almost all government and corporation
houses were sold. The debt crisis of 1982
and the subsequent need for economic re-
structuring meant that few governments in
Africa had money for housing programmes.
When some kind of recovery began in the
1990s, it was generally argued that govern-
ments should stay out of the housing arena
– if they wished to help poor people obtain
housing, the only suitable way was through
providing up-front capital subsidies for the
purchase of low-cost housing in the mar-
ket.9
2. PRIVATE RENTAL HOUSING:
As a result of the problems associated with
public housing production and delivery,
state involvement in housing has been de-
clining in most African countries. And the
private sector (both formal and informal)
has come to be the major producer of most
urban rental housing for upper, moderate
and low-income households, sometimes
supported by the state.
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
22
APPROACHES
Many countries in sub-Saharan Africa have large stocks of government-built houses, which for
various reasons are in poor physical condition or don’t conform to occupants’ expectations. In
many countries, occupants of such housing make unauthorized but quite considerable changes
and extensions to their dwellings for their own use and for renting out. These changes and ex-
tensions are generally known as ‘transformations’, and can offer useful models for future policy
concerning existing housing estates and new developments. A study completed of 398 houses
in Ghana and 335 in Zimbabwe showed how relatively low-income households are capable of
supplying new rooms and services both to improve their own housing conditions and to supply
rental rooms for family members living rent free. In addition, the new construction is often of a
quality at least as good as the original structures and sometimes envelops the original in a new
skin. Thus, transformation can be seen as a means of renewing the housing stock at the same
time as adding accommodation and services.
In both Ghana and Zimbabwe the estates were originally built as subsidized rental housing for
local workers, but dwellings had been sold to the sitting tenants. In Ghana, the main motive
for extending was the need to accommodate growing households, although many did include
rooms for rental. In contrast, about half of the Zimbabwe extensions were motivated by the
possibility of rental income.
One of the benefits of transformations is that they allow more people to live within the currently
built-up area of the city, and so reduce the demand for peripheral development. In this way they
make more efficient use of existing urban space, instead of adding to the inefficient sprawl.
There is a difference between the types of renting rooms built in the two countries. In Zimba-
bwe, renting rooms in the dwelling is a business venture for at least some profit. Seventy per
cent of transformed houses have tenants, and on average there are three households per house.
In Ghana, however, where rents are low and renting rooms to tenants is not normally a busi-
ness venture, only 27% of transformed houses have renters, while 33% of them have rent-free
(family) occupants.
In both instances, occupancy rates improve with transformation, and transformation can be
seen as a process in which households improve their own use of living space and that of other
residents in their houses. This is one of the best arguments in favour of transformations as a
positive way to develop and improve housing quality and supply, and this approach should be
encouraged in countries that have a great need for housing.10
TRANSFORMATIONS IN GHANA AND ZIMBABWE: RESIDENTS CREATE
NEW RENTAL UNITS
23
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
APPROACHES
MIGRANTS AND RENTAL
ACCOMMODATION
In many urban settings in Africa, complex
letting and subletting arrangements evolve
amongst people living permanently in the
city and migrants arriving from rural areas.
Sharing of rented rooms takes place in Khar-
toum, Lagos and many parts of West Africa.
Sleeping spaces may be rented in the store-
rooms of commercial enterprises or in guest
houses and hostels. In South Africa, hostels
were constructed during the apartheid era
by private companies and the state to ac-
commodate single black men or women for
the duration of their stay as labourers in ur-
ban areas – they were not allowed to bring
their families to settle in the cities. Several
hundred thousand people still live in these
hostels, often in appalling and overcrowded
conditions. It is quite common for up to 7
people to share a room of less than 10 m2
and for up to 16 families to share a toilet.
In Botswana, the failure of formal public
and private organizations to meet the de-
mand for homeownership throughout the
1990s, the progressive stripping away of
subsidies for homeownership, and the de-
cision to sell plots to urban residents has
escalated demand for, and pressure on, al-
ternative forms of tenure such as renting.
Many homeowners in the sites-and-service
areas have therefore built additional, unau-
thorized rooms in their backyards to rent
out. In the more affluent parts of Gabo-
rone where local authorities have provided
“servant’s quarters” for the high-income
estates, such quarters are increasingly being
sublet by tenants to people earning higher
incomes whose housing needs have not
adequately been met by the municipality.
Heightened demand for rentals has resulted
in rent levels rising, with rents in some parts
of the city consuming over 50% of average
income.
In these difficult conditions, tenants have
had to develop a range of strategies to
meet their housing needs, including sharing
with relatives. The shift from being tenants
to sharers has led to a decline in housing
standards, with many people now sleep-
ing in kitchens and sitting rooms with other
sharers and/or their hosts’ children. Another
strategy is to move to peripheral villages and
towns in search of more affordable rental
accommodation or cheaper land. This has
placed high pressures on peri-urban and
village land, and raised transport costs for
those who have to look further and further
afield. A final strategy of tenants is that of
land invasions, which have become com-
mon since the early 1990s.11
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
24
APPROACHES
HOW MUCH RENT TO
CHARGE?
For commercial landlords, the rents they
charge their tenants are critical in the de-
cision about whether to set up, expand or
discontinue a rental business. If the rent is
too low, it may affect the quality of the ac-
commodation by restricting the amount a
landlord can spend on maintenance, ameni-
ties and repairs. If rents are too high, units
may stay empty or tenants may seek cheap-
er housing elsewhere or have to be evicted
when they can’t pay.
Some commercial landlords are satisfied
with fairly low rents because they consider
rental property a long-term investment and
anticipate a value increase of the property.
Since rental payments are closely linked to a
tenant’s real income, landlords stand to lose
if a tenant’s income drops so low that he or
she can’t afford to keep paying the rent, and
the landlord is left with a difficult decision
to either evict the tenant (and forsake the
chance of any income at all) or keep the ten-
ant and hope he or she will be able to pay
the rent arrears later on.
Rental housing specialists suggest that a
reasonable level of monthly income from
a rental unit should be about 1% of the
market sale price of that unit. The fact that
rent levels are tied to property prices means
that rents can go up as land values rise or as
macro-economic forces influence property
prices. These market forces put formal rental
housing out of reach of most poor house-
holds. That’s why informal rental housing al-
ternatives in slums and squatter settlements
make up such a large portion of most Afri-
can cities’ rental housing stock. When hous-
ing is developed outside the formal system,
it may have all kinds of drawbacks, but the
main point is that it is more affordable.
Small-scale (household) landlords have a dif-
ferent set of factors to consider, when decid-
ing how much rent to charge their tenants.
While affluent property owners may rent
out a second house or a vacant piece of land
they own at the highest possible rental to
high-income tenants, most small-scale land-
lords are found in low-income settlements,
where they rent out part of their own home
to supplement their limited income. Their
tenants are unlikely to be able to pay rentals
at the same levels as higher-income tenants,
and the landlords may be willing to accept
a lower rental than this simply to meet their
own basic needs.
The 25% rule: Some housing specialists sug-
gest that rental housing is affordable if a
household spends no more than 25% of its
monthly income on rent. This rule of thumb
loses its meaning as you go down the eco-
nomic ladder, where the only rule is that the
poorer you are, the greater proportion of
your monthly income you are likely to pay
for housing and basic services.
In South Africa, almost 50% of township
landlords, especially those in informal settle-
ments, the income earned from renting to
tenants is their sole or main income, and
apart from owning property, these landlords
are among the most marginalised groups
in society: poor, aged women with minimal
sources of regular income. Rentals are most-
ly paid in cash, but can also take the form
of, for instance, the purchase of electricity
for the household, or payments in kind such
as undertaking regular chores or prepar-
ing meals. The majority of these landlords
include the service charges for water and
electricity in the rent rather than charging
for them separately.12
25
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
APPROACHES
RENT CONTROL: IS IT AN
OPTION?
Over the years, some African governments
have tried to achieve housing affordabil-
ity by forcing landlords to keep rents low.
The introduction of such controls some-
times represented a genuine effort to help
tenants, and some governments in newly
independent African countries introduced
rent controls as part of an ideological com-
mitment to socialism. Rent control was seen
to be an effective way of protecting poorer
groups from exploitation by the rich. At
times, governments used socialist rhetoric
and mechanisms such as rent control as part
of a strategy of winning elections.
Arguably, however, many governments
maintained those controls as a façade to hide
the lack of an effective housing programme.
Public housing construction programmes
were expensive, whereas rent controls cost
the state nothing, as they placed the finan-
cial burden of renting out housing units
at low profit or no profit on the landlords
who owned them. In addition, since tenants
greatly outnumbered landlords, it was not
always that easy to remove rent controls.
However, in recent years, rent controls have
been discredited, as some negative effects
that they have on the rental housing supply
in cities have become evident. Some of the
main problems with rent control are:
s Equity: Rent controls can operate in-
equitably in three ways. Firstly, they
favour some tenants at the expense of
others. In particular, they tend to favour
those who have lived in rental housing
for years against those who wish to be-
come tenants. When rent controls apply
only to sitting tenants, new tenants lose
out. Secondly, there is no guarantee that
those covered by rent controls are actu-
ally poor. For example, if the legislation
only covers sitting tenants and these are
more affluent than new tenants, the
result is to give a rental advantage to
those who need it least. Thirdly, tenants
clearly gain at the expense of landlords.
And in cases where tenants are more
affluent than the landlords, the effects
of rent control are the reverse of what
is intended. For example, artificially low
rents in Egypt have meant that tenants
are sitting on a significant asset and
the only way an owner can reclaim the
unit – besides waiting for the death of
the tenant and his or her children – is
to offer a sizeable cash incentive (some-
times approaching the market value of
the unit) for the tenant to renounce the
contract and leave.
s Efficiency: By distorting market values,
rent control often encourages the ineffi-
cient use of housing. For example, small
tenant households may occupy housing
that is much larger than they require,
and for which they would not be pre-
pared to pay the market price, limiting
the availability of accommodation to
larger households. More importantly, by
holding down profits, rent controls dis-
courage some landlords from investing
in rental property.
s Maintenance: Where rent control
makes rental housing unprofitable, a
regular complaint has been that land-
lords do not maintain the property.
Rent controlled buildings in cities often
deteriorate to slum conditions, for this
reason.13
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
26
APPROACHES
POLICIES WHICH REGULATE RENTAL
HOUSING IN AFRICAN CITIES
There are four major problems with rental
housing arrangements:
1. Housing policies are often biased in favour
of homeowners and fail to take the needs
of tenants into account. A lack of policies
that protect the rights of tenants can in-
crease the risk of them being exploited by
unscrupulous landlords.
2. When rental housing conditions are poor,
the problem is not usually with the rental
arrangement itself. Rather, it is related to
the state of a city’s overall housing condi-
tions and the complex factors which cause
poor living conditions and poverty in gen-
eral.
3. Because so much of rental housing is in-
formal and largely “invisible”, a lot of it
falls outside the control of government
rules and regulations. This has allowed
for a great diversity and flexibility in rental
housing markets, but at the same time has
made it more difficult to plan policy recom-
mendations and interventions to support
rental housing.
4. Housing policies that don’t include con-
ditions for acceptable rental agreements
lead to situations in which landlords and
tenants must struggle to claim their rights
when an agreement is breached. Absence
of enforceable written contracts and ef-
ficient arbitration systems means that the
cost of going to court to claim unpaid rent,
fight illegal evictions, or force landlords to
do necessary maintenance must be borne
by individual tenants and landlords, who
usually don’t have the resources to do so.
Using policies to promote rental
housing in a city
If national governments can acknowledge
the gaps in their existing housing policies,
and adjust their regulatory frameworks to
give more support to the aspects of ongoing
rental practices that work well, it will help a
lot to tap the enormous potential of both the
formal and informal rental housing markets.
Where there is political will to improve a
city’s housing policies and make them more
“renter-friendly” in the long term, a good
start would be to promote more competition
in housing markets in the short term. Greater
competition would mean more options and
greater flexibility in what kinds of rental units
are available. This could be done in a number
of ways.
On the supply side, policies could be devel-
oped which reduce obstacles to the produc-
tion of more rental housing so the supply and
variety increase. For example, if homeowners
were offered incentives to build one rental
unit on their property, this would lead to a
new supply of units emerging in all parts of
the city, suitable for tenants with different in-
come levels and rental needs. It is important
to make sure that rental supply exists to meet
the needs of middle-income tenants in the
city, so that this income group does not end
up taking over the available supply of hous-
ing designed to be affordable for low-income
households.
On the demand side, policies which can en-
able more households to rent might include
ones that encourage landlords to offer se-
cure long-term tenure to tenants. This would
make it possible for people to see renting
housing as a safe option, and tenants would
be likely to invest more care and resources
in the maintenance of their rental housing if
they knew they would be able to stay there
over the long term.
27
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
TOOLS AND GUIDELINES
SIX WAYS TO PROMOTE RENTAL
HOUSING THROUGH HOUSING
POLICIES
A strategic approach to developing a work-
able rental housing policy should first ac-
knowledge the rental arrangements which
already exist and find flexible, realistic ways
to regulate them. In most cities rental hous-
ing arrangements contribute enormously to
local livelihoods, and so measures to gov-
ern and promote their further development
should be formulated. Local dynamics and
housing market conditions are different in
every city, and there is no single formula for
how to do this. But the following six sug-
gestions will help policy makers and gov-
ernment agencies to make their cities more
rental housing-friendly — especially for the
poor.
1. Acknowledge and understand ex-
isting rental practices
Civil society organizations, NGOs and com-
munity organizations, as well as some civil
servants and politicians, are all aware of the
rental housing options in their cities. Their
combined understanding represents a valu-
able local resource which can be channelled
into making rental housing practices more
balanced, more inclusive and more effec-
tive. But before rental housing problems
can be solved, local groups need to work
together to create a common understand-
ing amongst different communities about
tenure issues in the city. One way to raise
interest is by making an inventory of the
local rental housing stock. This inventory
should include both formal and informal
arrangements and occupied and unoccu-
pied rental units. Local organizations can
establish this inventory jointly, exchange
perspectives on their local rental markets
and work together to identify and analyze
the problems. The results should be spread
around in the widest possible way, so as
to widen the local debate on housing ten-
ure options and concerns. To keep up the
momentum, data on rental housing should
be updated regularly, and changes in the
housing situation should be closely moni-
tored. This inventory can provide important
baseline information for better planning
and housing interventions.
2. Get rental housing on the larger ur-
ban policy agenda
Once local organizations have collectively
acknowledged the rental situation in their
cities, the next step is to open up the is-
sue to public discussion and to gather more
detailed information on the inner workings
of rental housing, including the larger eco-
nomic, political and social factors which af-
fect rental supply and demand. Identifying
bottlenecks as well as successes in achiev-
ing lasting rental arrangements should be
given special attention. The information
gained in this way could help to identify the
social and political influences that underlie
rental housing arrangements in a city, so
that these can be incorporated in the de-
bate and balanced where they are working
against a healthy rental housing situation.
At this point, urban policy makers will be
in a better position to estimate how impor-
tant rental housing is in the local context.
While monitoring developments in the
overall housing market, they can put rental
housing on the policy agenda, either as an
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
28
TOOLS AND GUIDELINES
issue that merely needs to be regulated or
as a priority that needs to be actively pro-
moted.
Supporting and improving on what is al-
ready there: Some of the best policies are
those that support and improve the systems
of rental housing delivery that are in place
and already working well. Policies which
seek to introduce something new often end
up destroying or hindering these already
functioning systems, or forcing them to go
underground.
3. Work out practical, flexible rental
housing policies and regulations
In the policy-making process, it is essential
for decision makers to maintain a constant
and meaningful dialogue with a broad
spectrum of local community organizations,
NGOs and civil society organizations and
other development stakeholders, to ensure
that the rental housing policy framework
they develop matches the specific realities
and needs of the local context. Existing and
potential landlords often feel threatened
by government policies and regulations
that either give tenants the right to claim
a house that has been rented to them il-
legally, or don’t sufficiently protect them
when tenants fail to pay rent. The adop-
tion of rental policies and regulations that
protect the rights of both tenants and
landlords will go some way in encouraging
landlords to invest more in rental housing.
The framework should include means and
incentives that encourage the production,
exchange and consumption of a variety of
rental housing options. It should also in-
clude a system of checks and penalties to
curb mismanagement or abusive practices
within a city’s rental housing market, and
to prevent the deterioration of its rental
housing stock through lack of maintenance
or repairs.
The policy should also address the need
to inform both tenants and landlords of
their legal rights and obligations relating
to the rental contract, and to provide sup-
port where either party needs to take legal
action to assert their rights. Information,
advice and proactive campaigns to increase
awareness of these rental tenure rights
should form part of the ongoing work of
the municipality in relation to urban hous-
ing administration.
It is important that this regulatory frame-
work is simple, practical and easy to apply.
If a specialized administrative unit has to
be set up to implement the rental housing
policy, it probably means the policy is too
complicated to be practical. A better option
would be to integrate the policy into a city’s
existing administrative procedures, such as
issuing building permits and house registra-
tions, measuring water and electricity con-
sumption or collecting rental income taxes.
It is also important that the policy frame-
work is flexible in these three ways:
a. The implementation of measures and
incentives in the policy framework
should be flexible enough to cover a
wide range of tenant target groups (of
all incomes) and rental housing types.
b. The standards that are outlined in the
policy framework can be adjusted as
needed, in order to allow as wide a
range of actors to take part in the city’s
rental housing market, to produce as
wide a variety of rental options, as
possible.
c. The process of approving these adjust-
ments should be kept as simple and
straightforward as possible and should
29
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
TOOLS AND GUIDELINES
require a minimum of procedures.
d. Ensure that rental housing arrange-
ments are sustainable, especially for
vulnerable groups and women
To ensure that the regulatory framework
encourages a variety of rental housing to
be produced and rented out (especially for
lower-income tenants, vulnerable groups
and women-headed households), the pol-
icy and regulations should:
s Set minimum standards for the manage-
ment and maintenance of rental prop-
erties. These standards need to take
into account existing rental practices
and rental rates, and forecasts of future
housing needs and future increases in
property values. Incorporating rental
housing into upgrading programmes or
encouraging its development may re-
quire modifications to regulations and
infrastructure capacities. Involving com-
munity organizations in a settlement
in monitoring compliance with these
standards may be necessary, in places
where corruption could lead to housing
inspectors and landlords colluding to
evade regulations.
s Combine efforts to improve the quality
of rental housing, as well as the qual-
ity of basic infrastructural services in
the areas where rental housing exists.
Critical here is to build rental incentives
into upgrading programmes. In order to
support already-existing systems which
provide affordable rental housing in
many cities, the cost and effort of up-
grading should involve the key stake-
holders — community organizations,
community-based savings groups,
NGOs and landlords. To minimize sud-
den rent increases, this settlement up-
grading could be combined with tem-
porary rent control in targeted areas.
s Provide follow-up measures in these up-
graded informal settlements. This could
include introducing a simple rental con-
tract system which stipulates rights and
obligations of both landlords and ten-
ants. In addition, these measures could
establish a housing consumer forum to
settle disputes between landlords and
tenants.
s Enable established communities to take
over the responsibility for upkeep and
repairs, whenever landlords or tenants
fail to fulfil their contractual obligations.
The Rental Housing Act implemented in South Africa in 1999 defines the responsibilities of
government in respect of the rental housing market. It sets out the duties and responsibilities of
both landlords and tenants, and provides for the establishment of rental tribunals, which have
power to make rulings in line with those of a magistrate’s court, thus allowing for a speedy
and cost-effective resolution of disputes between landlords and tenants. However, a negative
consequence of the new legislation is that it has become extremely difficult for landlords to evict
tenants who fail to comply with the rental agreement, or when the landlord wants to regain
use of the property for other purposes, and this may discourage some property owners from
becoming landlords.14
USING LEGISLATION TO PROTECT LANDLORDS AND TENANTS IN SOUTH AFRICA
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
30
TOOLS AND GUIDELINES
In situations where it is hard for land-
lords and tenants to jointly maintain the
rental housing, an important alterna-
tive to consider is the establishment of
community-based tenant cooperatives.
Landlords could also subcontract build-
ing management and rent collection to
community-based savings groups or to
community committees of renters, or
to larger city-wide networks or federa-
tions of shack-dwellers.
Gender, poverty, rental and
access
The fact that many of the poorest house-
holds in African cities are those headed by
women, means that rental housing is espe-
cially significant for women-headed house-
holds. In many countries, women also face
considerable discrimination in terms of their
access to formal housing finance markets,
and thus rental housing is the only option
available to them. Some women prefer to
rent in central-city tenements which may
offer greater physical security, a wider
range of support networks and community
acceptance of single mothers.
And the pressure on women to perform
domestic and community roles may reduce
the attraction of ownership in poorly ser-
viced peri-urban settlements.15 Policies
and regulations related to rental housing
therefore should pay special attention to
the availability of rental units in locations
and on terms that allow women to provide
safe, stable, affordable accommodation for
their households, with access to the neces-
sary infrastructure and services.
5. Mobilize finance to improve and ex-
pand rental housing
To be effective, rental housing policies need
to support easy access to financial mecha-
nisms, to encourage landlords and tenants
to maintain, repair and improve the qual-
ity of the rental housing that already exists,
and to increase the city’s stock of rental
housing.
The nature of these financial mechanisms
depends on the kind of financial resources
local authorities have at their disposal, or
can get through central government agen-
cies. Interventions could include:
s Providing subsidies to poor owners, or
poor private landlords, who create living
space for others such as the household
rental grant programme used in South
Africa. This scheme supports the expan-
sion of small-scale rental units in poor
settlements by providing capital grants
to landowning households to build or
renovate housing rental units of a cer-
tain minimum standard on their land.
s Providing microcredit for small-scale
landlords. Governments can also en-
courage banks to move into the low-
income sector and to lend to landlords
wishing to enlarge or improve their
rental properties.
s Mobilizing finances from locally based
sources and through cross-subsidy poli-
cies. Tapping into these different sourc-
es of income to provide new rental
housing is especially important where
social housing interventions are linked
to urban regeneration/renewal, which
often tends to displace and squeeze
the poor out of well located areas. (See
Quick Guide 5 on Housing Finance.)
31
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
TOOLS AND GUIDELINES
What to do when cities don’t
have funds for grants and
subsidy programmes
When the local authorities don’t have large
funds available (which is often the case)
they could achieve similar ends by offering
tax incentives to owners to make it worth
their while to develop affordable rental
housing units on their land. These tax in-
centives could take several forms:
s boffering reduced tax rates on income
from rental housing;
s giving tax rebates to low-income land-
lords who invest in improvements to the
quality of their rental housing units;
s granting tax deductions to housing de-
velopers who produce or renew rental
housing which specifically targets low-
income groups.
Such tax incentives, however, will only have
relevance for those landlords operating in
the formal housing market who already
pay land, property and/or income taxes.
The local authorities therefore need to con-
sider ways to recognize and regularize the
status of informal landlords, and to offer
them incentives to participate in the for-
mal housing systems of the city. Landlords
will be more likely to accept the payment
of taxes on their property if they see that
the authorities are using their tax money
to upgrade the area and provide adequate
services to the settlement where the prop-
erty is located.
6. Encourage large-scale and small-
scale investment in rental housing
Local authorities must look into strate-
gies and incentives that make large-scale
and small-scale investment in low-income
rental housing more attractive and more
sustainable to investors. Besides offering
tax incentives to investors who produce
new rental housing, these measures might
include ways to increase tenants’ “owner-
ship” of a project.
s Diversify rental housing options for the
poor in and across the formal-informal
and the public-private sector divides:
Formal housing projects (in the pub-
lic and private sphere) do not have to
stick to the standard concept of self-
contained rental housing units. Besides
being costly, severely under-utilizing
a scarce commodity (urban land) and
often very badly designed (so-called
sleep cities), such units can enforce
social isolation and cut poor people
off from economic activities and social
support systems they rely on to sur-
vive. One option would be to develop
transitional communal housing (tran-
sitional because this is aimed at entry-
level rentals): houses with single rooms
and shared facilities and communal ar-
eas. Other options could target tenant
groups (rather than individuals) willing
to commit to long-term collective leases
on housing. Or tenure arrangements
could allow tenants to shift from one
type of rental agreement to another
during their rental contract period – for
example they could start as monthly
renters, but decide later to purchase
their unit with a mortgage when they
are ready for this step.
s Promote alternative, participatory forms
of rental housing management: While
the ownership of a large rental housing
block or settlement might still remain
with the public, private, or public-pri-
vate owner, the housing itself can be
leased by a tenant cooperative which
then rents out the individual units to its
members. It is also possible that a rent-
al housing block or group of separate
units could be built originally, or bought
later, by a similar tenant cooperative —
which then becomes an owner cooper-
ative. In all these arrangements, the ad-
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
32
TOOLS AND GUIDELINES
vantage of cooperative management of
rental housing is that the tenants who
occupy that housing participate central-
ly in maintaining and making decisions
about their housing — collectively. This
approach is not yet widespread but an
important avenue for policy makers to
explore for its relevance and sustainabil-
ity in specific contexts.
s Get NGOs and CBOs to help: NGOs and
community-based organizations (CBOs)
can help with awareness-raising, train-
ing and organizational support to com-
munities of low-income tenants. NGOs
should advocate for the housing rights
of poor tenants, but they can also sup-
port low-income tenants to develop
their own tools and knowledge to take
greater responsibility in managing, up-
grading and maintaining their rental
housing — individually or as tenant col-
lectives or CBOs. NGOs can also help
poor tenants to form collective organi-
zations (like consumer forums or tenant
cooperatives) and help start selective
savings and loan groups among groups
of poor tenants in the same area or rent-
ing from the same landlord. All these
measures can expand people’s tenure
options, while they integrate rental
needs into people’s more comprehen-
sive process of self-development.
33
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
RESOURCES
REFERENCES
1. UN-HABITAT (2003) Rental Housing, an Essential Option for the Urban Poor in Developing Coun-
tries. Nairobi: UN-HABITAT
2. UN-HABITAT (2003) Rental Housing, an Essential Option for the Urban Poor in Developing Coun-
tries. Nairobi: UN-HABITAT
3. UN-HABITAT (2003) Rental Housing, an Essential Option for the Urban Poor in Developing Coun-
tries. Nairobi: UN-HABITAT. See also Amole B, Korboe D & Tipple G (1993) The family house in
West Africa. Third World Planning Review 15: 355–372; Tipple AG (1987) The development of
housing policy in Kumasi, Ghana, 1901 to 1981. University of Newcastle-upon-Tyne, Centre for
Architectural Research and Development; Tipple AG & Willis KG (1991) Tenure choice in a West
African city. Third World Planning Review 13: 27–46.
4. Adapted from UN-HABITAT (2003) Rental Housing, an Essential Option for the Urban Poor in
Developing Countries. Nairobi: UN-HABITAT.
5. UN-HABITAT (2003) Rental Housing, an Essential Option for the Urban Poor in Developing Coun-
tries. Nairobi: UN-HABITAT
6. UN-HABITAT (2003) Rental Housing, an Essential Option for the Urban Poor in Developing Coun-
tries. Nairobi: UN-HABITAT
7. UN-HABITAT (2001) Cities in a Globalizing World: Global Report on Human Settlements 2001.
Nairobi: UN-HABITAT
8. UN-HABITAT (1989) Cooperative housing: experiences of mutual self-help. Electronic version
published in 2006.
9. UN-HABITAT (2003) Rental Housing, an Essential Option for the Urban Poor in Developing Coun-
tries. Nairobi: UN-HABITAT
10. Tipple AG, Owusu SE & Pritchard C (2004) User-initiated extensions in government-built estates in
Ghana and Zimbabwe: Unconventional but effective housing supply. Africa Today 51(2): 79–105
11. Khan F (2009) Background paper on rental housing in Africa. Prepared for UN-HABITAT, Nairobi
12. Shisaka Development Management Services & CSIR Built Environment (2006) Resource Report
6: Research into Landlords in Townships. Report produced as part of the Housing Entrepreneurs
Research Project funded by the Finmark Trust, the Social Housing Foundation, Nedbank, and the
National Department of Housing, South Africa
13. UN-HABITAT (2003) Rental Housing, an Essential Option for the Urban Poor in Developing Coun-
tries. Nairobi: UN-HABITAT
14. Social Housing Foundation (2008) Supply and Demand of Rental Accommodation in South Africa.
Johannesburg: Social Housing Foundation
15. Khan F (2009) Background paper on rental housing in Africa. Prepared for UN-HABITAT, Nairobi
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
34
RESOURCES
SUGGESTED FURTHER READING
Andrew CL (1987) The Role of Rental Housing in Developing Countries: A Need for Balance. Washing-
ton DC: World Bank, Report No. UDD-104
Anzorena E (1996) Housing the Poor: The Asian Experience. Cebu, Philippines: Pagtambayayong
Foundation
Gilbert A (2008) Slums, tenants and home-ownership: on blindness to the obvious. International
Development Planning Review 30(2): i–x
Gilbert A, Mabin A, McCarthy M & Watson V (1997) Low-income rental housing: are South African
cities different? Environment and Urbanization 9(1): 133–147
Gilbert A & Varley A (1990) Landlord and Tenant: Housing the Poor in Urban Mexico. London: Rout-
ledge
Kumar S (2001) Social Relations, Rental Housing Markets and the Poor in Urban India. London: London
School of Economics and Political Sciences
Mondel P (2001) Unlocking the Opportunity for a National Rental Housing Strategy. Presentation to
the Federal, Provincial and Territorial Ministers of Housing, 2001 Housing Ministers’ Conference,
Quebec City, Quebec
Precht R (2005) Potentials of upgrading projects in Dar es Salaam (Tanzania) and Voi, Kenya. Les
Cahiers De L’ifra 27: 3–8
Rakodi C (1995) Rental tenure in the cities of developing countries. Urban Studies 32(4–5): 1–25
(internet version)
Tonkin A (2008) Sustainable medium-density housing: A resource handbook. Cape Town: Develop-
ment Action Group
UN-HABITAT (1996) An urbanizing world: global report on human settlements 1996. Nairobi: UN-
HABITAT
UN-HABITAT (1999) Strategies for Low-Income Shelter and Services Development: The Rental Housing
Option. Nairobi: UN-HABITAT
UN-HABITAT (2006) Enabling Shelter Strategies. Review of Experience from Two Decades of Implemen-
tation. Nairobi: UN-HABITAT
UN-HABITAT (2008) The State of African Cities 2008: A framework for addressing urban challenges in
Africa. Nairobi: UN-HABITAT
Watson V (1996) Rental housing experiences in developing countries. Issues in Development 12: 1–17.
Johannesburg: Friedrich Ebert Stiftung
Watson V & McCarthy M (1998) Rental housing policy and the role of the housing rental sector: Evi-
dence from South Africa. Habitat International 22(1): 49–56
35
QUICK GUIDES FOR POLICY MAKERS 7 RENTAL HOUSING
RESOURCES
WEBSITES
International Union of Tenants (IUT). This organization’s website provides facts and figures as well as
an overview of conferences related to rental housing. The IUT’s quarterly magazine, Global Tenant, has
information about tenant issues, land and housing rental situations in cities around the world.
www.iut.nu
United Nations Human Settlements Programme, www.unhabitat.org
For an annotated list of websites that offer more information about the key issues discussed in this
Quick Guides series, please visit the Housing the Urban Poor website www.housing-the-urban-poor.net
and follow the links to ‘Organizations database’.
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Article
Full-text available
Up to one billion tenants may be living in cities across the globe, but most governments continue to ignore them. Insofar as they recognise that tenants exist, the policy is to turn them into home-owners. Even in the UK and US, where this strategy has been underway for some years, it has not managed to reduce the numbers of tenants during the last decade. With the sub-prime crisis, the proportion of tenants is likely to rise. In the rest of the world, few governments recognise that renting is an essential shelter option. This viewpoint demonstrates why tenants and landlords are not likely to disappear, and explains why, for many, renting is a vital housing option. Fundamentally, it is a plea for a tenure-neutral shelter policy.
Article
Full-text available
: A significant proportion of the black urban popula-tion in South Africa rent accommodation. Surveys conducted in two low-income settlements in Cape Town and Johannesburg show that the rental housing scene is in many ways similar to that found in other Third World cities. Landlords are older than their tenants, many are female, their families are larger, their homes have more space and better services. Few landlords make any money and landlord-tenant relationships are not generally conflictive. At the same time, rental conditions in the survey set-tlements appear to be very different from those found in most other poor cities. Most significant is that few South African land-lords build accommodation; the majority merely offer space to tenants who build their own shacks. The poor quality of accom-modation helps keep rents low which in turn accentuates the feeling that is it not worth investing in rental accommodation. Few landlords actively seek out tenants, most grant space in the backyard only out of compassion. Further research is investi-gating whether more typical forms of rental housing exist in Cape Town and Johannesburg. The project also seeks to persuade the South African government that it should develop some kind of rental housing policy.
Article
This review attempts to provide an overview of the rental housing literature as a springboard for future research into urban housing markets which is less biased towards ownership. Research into rental tenure can be grouped into those investigations which attempt to describe and explain the nature of rental housing and those which attempt to evaluate the impact of government policy on the supply of rental dwellings. Following a collation of information on the significance of rented housing in the total urban stock, some characteristics of the tenure are explored: forms of rental housing, landlords, tenants, and the relationships between them. The third section of the paper examines aspects of policy related to rental housing. -from Author
Article
Many countries in Sub-Saharan Africa have large stocks of government-built housing, which, for various reasons, is in poor physical condition and/or does not conform to occupants' expectations. In many countries, occupants of such housing make unauthorized but quite considerable changes and extensions to their dwellings for their own use and for renting out. These changes and extensions are generally known as "transformations," and may contain useful models for future policy concerning existing housing estates and policy on new developments. This paper examines user-initiated transformations to government-built housing in Ghana and Zimbabwe.1 Both cases were surveyed in a DFID-sponsored research program. The 733 dwellings (398 in Ghana and 335 in Zimbabwe) surveyed show how relatively low-income households are capable of supplying new rooms and services both to improve their own housing conditions and to supply rental rooms or accommodation for family members living rent-free. In addition, the new construction is often of a quality at least as good as the original structures and sometimes envelops the original in a new skin. Thus, transformation can be seen to be a means of renewing the housing stock at the same time as adding accommodation and services. The research demonstrates that conventional views of housing design should be rethought with long-term users' involvement allowed for and encouraged. It also demonstrates that extensions tend to turn "modern" bungalows into traditional compounds. Through workshops, it has had some success in changing official attitudes in Ghana and Zimbabwe. Suggested policies to encourage transformations include the provision of loan finance and the planned colonization of open space next to the dwellings where plots are not provided. For new housing, transformations demonstrate that designs should take account of the likely increase in housing on site over decades. This, in turn, indicates larger plots, rather than smaller ones, and wider ones, rather than narrower.
Article
A growing body of research on rental housing in developing countries has pointed to the fact that while government and commercial investor provision of low income rentals is at an all time low, the numbers of people in rental accommodation has increased steadily. In some cities this is now the dominant form of tenure. The bulk of this rental accommodation is in fact provided by the “household sector” which tends to be unrecognized in policy terms. This paper examines attempts by both the past and current South African government to address housing problems and indicates how authorities have followed international trends in terms of attitudes to the provision of rental housing. The paper draws on a small-scale survey of households in South Africa to highlight the crucial role being played by the household rental sector, and argues for its incorporation into current housing policy.
Rental Housing, an Essential Option for the Urban Poor in Developing Coun-tries Nairobi: The family house in West Africa The development of housing policy in Kumasi, Ghana, 1901 to 1981 University of Newcastle-upon-Tyne Tenure choice in a West African city
  • Un-Habitat Un-Habitat See
  • B Amole
  • Korboe
  • Tipple
UN-HABITAT (2003) Rental Housing, an Essential Option for the Urban Poor in Developing Coun-tries. Nairobi: UN-HABITAT. See also Amole B, Korboe D & Tipple G (1993) The family house in West Africa. Third World Planning Review 15: 355–372; Tipple AG (1987) The development of housing policy in Kumasi, Ghana, 1901 to 1981. University of Newcastle-upon-Tyne, Centre for Architectural Research and Development; Tipple AG & Willis KG (1991) Tenure choice in a West African city. Third World Planning Review 13: 27–46
Rental Housing, an Essential Option for the Urban Poor in Developing Countries The family house in West Africa The development of housing policy in Kumasi, Ghana, 1901 to 1981. University of Newcastle-upon-Tyne, Centre for Architectural Research and Development Tenure choice in a West African city
UN-HABITAT (2003) Rental Housing, an Essential Option for the Urban Poor in Developing Countries. Nairobi: UN-HABITAT. See also Amole B, Korboe D & Tipple G (1993) The family house in West Africa. Third World Planning Review 15: 355–372; Tipple AG (1987) The development of housing policy in Kumasi, Ghana, 1901 to 1981. University of Newcastle-upon-Tyne, Centre for Architectural Research and Development; Tipple AG & Willis KG (1991) Tenure choice in a West African city. Third World Planning Review 13: 27–46.
Social Relations, Rental Housing Markets and the Poor in Urban India
  • S Kumar
Kumar S (2001) Social Relations, Rental Housing Markets and the Poor in Urban India. London: London School of Economics and Political Sciences