ArticlePDF Available

Placing the power of real options analysis into the hands of natural resource managers - Taking the next step

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

This paper explores heuristic methods with potential to place the analytical power of real options analysis into the hands of natural resource managers. The complexity of real options analysis has led to patchy or ephemeral adoption even by corporate managers familiar with the financial-market origins of valuation methods. Intuitively accessible methods for estimating the value of real options have begun to evolve, but their evaluation has mostly been limited to researcher-driven applications. In this paper we work closely with Bush Heritage Australia to evaluate the potential of real options analysis to support the intuitive judgement of conservation estate managers in covenanting land with uncertain future conservation value due to climate change. The results show that modified decision trees have potential to estimate the option value of covenanting individual properties while time and ongoing research resolves their future conservation value. Complementing this, Luehrman's option space has potential to assist managers with limited budgets to increase the portfolio value of multiple properties with different conservation attributes.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Placing the power of real options analysis into the hands of natural resource
managers eTaking the next step
Rohan Nelson
a
,
*
, Mark Howden
a
, Peter Hayman
b
a
CSIRO Climate Adaptation Flagship, GPO Box 284, Canberra, ACT 2601, Australia
b
South Australian Research and Development Institute, GPO Box 397, Adelaide, SA 5001, Australia
article info
Article history:
Received 4 March 2012
Received in revised form
31 October 2012
Accepted 15 March 2013
Keywords:
Real options
Climate change
Covenants
Decision support
Natural resource management
abstract
This paper explores heuristic methods with potential to place the analytical power of real options analysis
into the hands of natural resource managers. The complexity of real options analysis has led to patchy or
ephemeral adoption even by corporate managers familiar with the nancial-market origins of valuation
methods. Intuitively accessible methods for estimating the value of real options have begun to evolve, but
their evaluation has mostly been limited to researcher-driven applications. In this paper we work closely
with Bush Heritage Australia to evaluate the potential of real options analysis to support the intuitive
judgement of conservation estate managers in covenanting land with uncertain future conservation value
due to climate change. The results show that modied decision trees have potential to estimate the option
value of covenanting individual properties while time and ongoing research resolves their future con-
servation value. Complementing this, Luehrmans option space has potential to assist managers with limited
budgets to increase the portfolio value of multiple properties with different conservation attributes.
Ó2013 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
1. Introduction
In this paper we explore the potential of real options analysis to
assist natural resource managers to manage the uncertainty that
climate change introduces to the future conservation value of land.
Real options analysis has evolved to overcome the limitations of
discounted cash ow analysis for valuing the exibility to adapt
corporate investment strategies as new information resolves un-
certainty. It does so by refocusing risk management away from
minimising adverse outcomes within an existing set of activities,
towards exploiting the valuable opportunities inherent in future
uncertainty. The challenge we confront in this paper is whether the
complexity of real options analysis can be distilled into intuitive
rules of thumb (heuristics) and analytical tools to assist natural
resource managers to adapt to climate uncertainty. We then
explore whether these heuristics have potential to support the
intuitive judgement of conservation estate managers in covenant-
ing land in response to the uncertainty posed by climate change.
We begin by briey reviewing the origins and nature of real
options analysis. A supporting appendix reviews the evolution of
heuristic approaches with potential to distil the analytical power of
real options analysis into forms intuitively accessible to decision
makers. We then report on a collaborative evaluation of two of the
most promising approaches emodied decision trees and Luehr-
mans option space ewith conservation estate managers in Bush
Heritage Australia (BHA). Through this collaboration, we investi-
gate the potential for these two approaches to support the design of
appropriate conservation covenants and management actions.
2. Real options analysis
2.1. Why use real options analysis?
Real options analysishas evolved in the worldof corporate nance
to overcome the limitations in valuing uncertain investments that
arise when discounted cash ow analysis is simplistically applied
(Copeland and Antikarov, 2003;Dixit and Pindyck, 1994). If a single
linear pathway of project development and investment is assumed,
discounted cash ow analyses incorporate the probability of failure
into expected monetary values regardless of whether these can later
be avoided via adaptive management. Simplistic application of dis-
counted cashow analysis candirect the focus of riskmanagement to
reducing downside risk by reducing the variability of all future out-
comes eboth positive and negative.
The problem is that reducing the variability of future outcomes
can also reduce the upside potential of strategies that create new
opportunities with uncertain but potentially highly valuable
*Corresponding author. Present address: Tasmanian Institute of Agriculture,
University of Tasmania, Private Bag 98, Hobart, TAS 7001, Australia.
E-mail address: rohan.nelson@utas.edu.au (R. Nelson).
Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect
Journal of Environmental Management
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jenvman
0301-4797/$ esee front matter Ó2013 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2013.03.031
Journal of Environmental Management 124 (2013) 128e136
outcomes. The capacity to defer irreversible decisions until new in-
formation begins to resolve future uncertainty gradually truncates
the downsidefrom the probability distribution of expected outcomes
over time (Copeland and Antikarov, 2003;Dixit and Pindyck, 1994).
This refocuses risk management on actively creating upside uncer-
tainty by investing in the development of new and potentially high
value investment opportunities (de Neufville, 2003;Triantis, 2005).
2.2. What is a realoption?
An option in this sense is a right, but not an obligation, to make
an investment decision. The two most basic types of nancial op-
tion are call and put options. A call/put option is the right but not
obligation to purchase/sell shares at an agreed price at a future date
known as the exercise date. The value of nancial options derives
from volatility in the price of the underlying shares on which they
are written. The value of call/put options starts to be realised as
share prices rise/fall above/below the amount paid for the option.
Financial options with a predened exercise date are known as
European options, whereas those with a exible exercise date are
known as American options.
The term real option is used to describe the option value of in-
vestments in physical rather than nancial assets, and has been
attributed to Myers (1977) by Borison (2003) and Triantis (2005).
Real options can involve the right to defer,expand,contract,abandon
or extend the life of a physical investment (Copeland and Antikarov,
2003). Investments that can be deferred or later expanded, for
example, have similar characteristics to call options. Examples
include mining leases, manufacturing plants and pharmaceutical
research, all of which represent a right, but not an obligation to
commercialise production depending on uctuations in market
prices. In contrast, options to contract or abandon investments have
characteristics similar to put options. Insurance, for example, is the
right, but not obligation, to sell a damaged asset at a predened
price if an uncertain adverse event occurs (de Neufville, 2003). The
ability to halt production until market prices improve is a common
example of a put real option in manufacturing industries.
The characteristics of real versus nancial options have been
comprehensively reviewed by Copeland and Antikarov (2003) and
Mun (2006). Financial options are relatively easy to value because
they are well dened and because historical share price informa-
tion is readily available. The only source of risk is the future price of
the underlying security which is set in well established and publicly
accessible markets. Because the value of the underlying nancial
security is beyond the immediate and direct inuence of manage-
ment in the normal course of business, it can be modelled as a well
dened stochastic process. Financial options are relatively easy and
costless to exercise.
In contrast, real options can be difcult to value. The future value
of a real option is determined by an interaction of technical, mana-
gerial and market factors, many of which can be inuenced by
managers. Real options are much less liquid than nancial options,
being less divisible and often maturing over longer periods (Woolley
and Cannizzo, 2005). Many are not traded at all, and their value is
intrinsically conned to, and inuenced by, the investment decisions
of a specic business and its immediate competitors. It can therefore
be unclear what asset the holder of a real option has a right to, or
what criteria should beused to determinewhen to exercisean option.
Exercising a real option may not be a single instantaneous market
transaction, and may incur signicant transaction costs (Boer, 2002).
3. The utility of real options analysis to decision makers
Numerous analytical techniques for valuing real options have
evolved from the techniques used to value nancial options. These
are comprehensively reviewed in Appendix A. We argue in this
paper that the choice of appropriate analytical techniques for
valuing real options depends both on the mathematically validity of
each method, and whether the results can be intuitively under-
stood and applied effectively by decision makers. The literature
review in Appendix A reveals two analytical approaches with po-
tential to meet both of these criteria: modied decision trees
(Copeland and Antikarov, 2003;Borison, 2003;Hertzler, 2007) and
Luehrmans options space (Luehrman, 1998a,b).
3.1. Capacity and preferences of decision makers
There is mounting evidence that the complexity of real options
analysis has led to patchy or ephemeral adoption even by corporate
managers. Amram and Kulatilaka (2000) attributed interest in the
1990s to the novel valuation methods developed by Dixit and
Pindyck (1994). Since then, adoption has waned. A survey by
Busby and Pitts (1997) suggested that although investment
rescaling options were frequently assessed by 44 senior nance
ofcers in the United Kingdom, few of them had heard the term real
options. A later survey of 392 chief nancial ofcers by Graham and
Harvey (2001) found that nearly 27% of them always or almost al-
ways incorporate the real options of a project when evaluating it (pg
199). However, an unpublished survey by Bain & Company (cited by
Copeland and Tufano, 2004: pg 1) of 451 senior executives that had
trialled real options analysis showed that one third of them had
abandoned the approach within the same year. Similarly, a survey
of 205 Fortune 1000 chief nancial ofcers by Ryan and Ryan
(2002) found that only 10e15 per cent were using real option
techniques always or often.
There have been ongoing challenges to the intuitive accessi-
bility and hence adoptability of the most commonly promoted
forms of real options analysis (Lander and Pinches, 1998;Borison,
2003). The title of a paper by Borison (20 05) encapsulates this
sentiment eReal options analysis: where are the emperors
clothes? The most commonly cited reason for the limited adop-
tion of real options analysis by corporate managers is the
complexity of its analytical techniques (Copeland and Tufano,
2004;Copeland and Antikarov, 2003;Cortazar, 2004;Lander
and Pinches, 1998). A key point of contention has been the
extent to which the concept of risk neutral probabilities used in
binomial lattices is intuitively accessible to decision makers
(Lander and Pinches, 1998). Throughout this debate, even those
committed to promoting real options analysis have lamented a
lack of heuristics for communicating its analytical power to de-
cision makers (Triantis, 2005).
The issue of complex analytical techniques is a relative one,
and depends on the context and preferences of potential users.
Scepticism has been reported amongst corporate managers as to
whether the intuition and creativity of managerial decision
making can be reduced to an analytical decision tool (Copeland
and Tufano, 2004;Lander and Pinches, 1998). This scepticism
has been echoed by researchers evaluating the adoption of deci-
sion support systems in agriculture (such as Hayman, 2004;
Matthews et al., 2008). Complexity has tended to conne the
application of real options analysis to extractive natural resource
industries such as minerals, oil and forestry, where price uncer-
tainty can be analysed in well-developed markets (Triantis and
Borison, 2001;Saphores, 2001;Rocha et al., 2001). Complexity
has also tended to conne application of real options analysis to
companies where sophisticated analytical tools are common,
particularly those populated by engineers (Triantis and Borison,
2001). Contrary to its origins, the banking and nance industries
have expressed little interest in real options analysis (Triantis and
Borison, 2001).
R. Nelson et al. / Journal of Environmental Management 124 (2013) 128e136 129
3.2. Application to conservation and natural resource management
Early applications of real options analysis to natural resource
management included those exploring the phased development of
extractive (mining and oil) industries (Cortazar, 1999;Cortazar and
Casassus, 2000). Real options analysis has subsequently been
applied to a number of forest-related applications. Saphores (2001)
used real options analysis to explore harvesting decisions for nat-
ural forests where uncertain growth limited effective evaluation by
traditional methods. Rocha et al. (2001) found that the estimated
value of Amazon forest concessions to be consistently higher using
real options analysis than estimates derived using costebenet
analysis. Saphores et al. (2002) used real options analysis to show
that ignoring unexpected price changes can lead to sub-optimal
decisions to harvest old growth timber. In contrast, real options
analysis has been found to add little to existing valuation methods
for plantation forest investment decisions (Manley and Niquidet,
2010;Hildebrandt and Knoke, 2011).
Irrigation and dam investment have also been the focus of real
options analysis, often contrasted with net present value ap-
proaches. In some cases, real options analysis ranks projects as
more protable than indicated by discounted cash ow analysis
because of economic shocks and design uncertainties (Michailidis
and Mattas, 2007). In other cases, real options analysis has indi-
cated that projects are less protable than suggested by discounted
cash ow analyses (Michailidis et al., 2009). Real options analysis
has informed public policy on water conservation in irrigated
agriculture, focussing attention on upgrading irrigation systems
rather than structural adjustment (Seo et al., 2008). It has also been
used to show that policies that reduce uncertainty in water prices
can encourage adoption of more water-efcient irrigation systems
(Carey and Zilberman, 2002).
In agriculture, Tozer (2009) applied real options analysis to
determine whether or not to invest in precision agriculture relative
to conventional farming. He found that standard costebenet
analysis consistently overvalued precision farming relative to
conventional agriculture because it does not adequately account for
uncertainty or irreversibility. Mithoefer et al. (2004) used real op-
tions analysis to explore decisions by farmers in southern Africa to
conserve indigenous fruit trees when clearing woodland for agri-
culture. Similarly, Schatzki (2003) showed that agricultural land-
owners in the United States value the ability to keep their land
conversion opportunities open when making land use conversion
decisions. This helps to explain why land is often not converted
even though cost-benet analysis suggests specic land conversion
opportunities are protable.
Real options analysis has also been applied to wildlife conser-
vation decisions and in the valuation of biodiversity. Arrow and
Fisher (1974) explored the amount of wilderness to conserve
assuming that development was irreversible and the future value of
wilderness was uncertain. They found that the inclusion of a quasie
option value led to the allocation of more land to wilderness than
would have been the case if only expected benets and costs were
assessed. Kassar and Lasserre (2004) explored the value of
conserving biodiversity using real options analysis, in cases where
more than one species provide similar ecological functions. They
demonstrated that the availability of substitute species has
inherent option value, and that this option value increases as cor-
relation in conservation value between species decreases. Bakshi
and Saphores (2004) used real options analysis to come up with
intuitive rules for managing the reintroduction of wolves into re-
gions of North America.
There has been some preliminary investigation of the potential
for real options analysis to support decisions to adapt to the un-
certainty introduced by climate change. Dobes (2008) has argued
that using real option thinking should underpin adaptation policy.
Whitten et al. (2012) found that real option analysis is a potential
pathway for applying resilience thinking to the management of
environmental risks, including adaptation to climate change. In
agriculture, Hertzler (2007) used modied decision trees to show
that real options analysis can provide insights into how to manage
climate change uncertainty in cropping and grazing systems.
Our focus in this paper is supporting the management of land as
a natural resource for the purpose of maintaining or enhancing
biodiversity. The evolving literature shows that the potential of real
options analysis to improve decision making in conservation and
related natural resource management has been known for some
time. However, few applications of real options analysis attempt
to frame the decision problem from the perspective of decision
makers. They are either researcher-invented stylised examples, or
complex researcher interpretations of real world investment sce-
narios. Either way, the lack of adoption and use suggests that
neither approach has been particularly helpful to decision makers.
We take the next logical step in closing this gap between
research and decision support. We worked with conservation
reserve managers to build intuitively accessible models enabling
them to explore the potential for real options analysis to inform
decisions to purchase or covenant land with uncertain future
conservation value due to climate change. Our intention is to
identify heuristic approaches with potential to be extended more
widely to the managers of conservation estates for designing land
covenants.
4. Case study, Bush Heritage Australia
4.1. BHA and real options analysis
Bush Heritage Australia (BHA) is an independent non-prot
organisation committed to preserving Australias biodiversity.
1
At
the time that this research was conducted in 2008, BHA owned and
managed 34 reserves throughout Australia covering close to 1
million hectares. The implications of climate change for BHAs land
acquisition policy were investigated via interviews with conserva-
tion estate managers. BHA recognised that climate change is likely
to have signicant implications for the conservation of permanent
reserves. This is because climate change alters ecological niches and
processes throughout the landscape, altering the survival prospects
of many rare and threatened species. Climate change can mean that
a conservation estate established to protect a specic set of biodi-
versity values may end up protecting an entirely different set in the
future. BHA is tackling this problem through its Beyond the
Boundaries program that aims to maintain the biodiversity value of
land surrounding the properties that it purchases.
BHAs strategies for maintaining conservation values on sur-
rounding properties include the use of covenants. Covenants are
agreements with landowners to conserve a range of ecological
values on areas of land that could later be brought into a reserve
system, even though this option may never be exercised. Covenants
have the properties of a real option ea small initial investment to
create the right to later purchase land at an agreed price. Climate
change, management and market factors make these future land
and ecological values highly uncertain.
Estimating the future value of land, including multiple non-
market conservation values, and weighing this against the nan-
cial cost of purchasing it pose a signicant valuation challenge for
BHA. A rigorous process of research and expert judgement is
currently used to make these tradeoffs. Various tiers of assessment
1
http://www.bushheritage.org.au/.
R. Nelson et al. / Journal of Environmental Management 124 (2013) 128e136130
have been created to efciently balance the effort expended in the
assessment process against the value of each property within BHAs
overall portfolio of land investments.
Discussion with BHAs staff identied several stages of the
assessment process in which real options analysis has potential to
support intuitive expert judgement. At the earliest stages of
assessment, for example, decision trees may provide BHAseld
ecologists with a relative sense of whether the option value of a
specic property with climate sensitive conservation values is high
or low. At later stages of assessment, Luehrmans option space may
provide more precise estimates of option value across a portfolio of
diverse properties. Both approaches can also be used to design
appropriate covenanting arrangements for individual properties.
For example, agreeing with land owners to manage weeds and
pests could signicantly increase the future conservation value of
land. These applications were evaluated using intuitive models that
broadly simulate some of the more important characteristics of
these investment decisions.
The following applications of modied decision trees and
Luehrmans option space were developed in iterative consultation
and participatory workshops with conservation estate managers.
Models of conservation investment scenarios were developed until
conservation estate managers found them realistic enough to
explore the consequences of alternative management and invest-
ment strategies. Each property characterised in the model has the
essential characteristics of properties under consideration for in-
vestment at the time that this research was conducted in 2008.
Each model can be easily rescaled to reect the actual size of real
investment opportunities.
4.2. Decision trees and the option value of a single property
The literature reviewed in Appendix A suggests that the chal-
lenging problem of risk neutral probabilities raises doubts as to
whether modieddecision trees can provide preciseestimates of real
option value. Despite this, the method has intuitive appeal for
communicating the presence or absence of option value, and the
relativemagnitude of this option value sothat alternative investment
options can be ranked. The intuitive appeal of this approach from a
research perspective has been explored in agriculture by Hertzler
(2007). The case study presented in this paper conrmed this intu-
itive appeal through participatoryevaluation from the perspective of
conservation reserve managers in BHA.
Fig. 1 provides a simple example of how modied decision trees
can be used to estimate the relative value of delaying irreversible
investments in properties with uncertain future conservation value
due to climate change. In this example, the decision problem is
whether to purchase a property located on a mountain (Mnt in
Fig. 1) or one on a plain.
The plain in this example represents a large property relatively
insensitive to climate change. This may be because its ecology is
mostly dened by non-climatic attributes such as soils, or because
it is large and well connected spatially to other ecosystems. Pur-
chasing the property on the plain results in an estimated
Expected valu e of Expected value Prob ability Result
delaying or not of decision
$ per ha
Change these numbers
severe 0.33 2000
Decision Buy Mnt moderate 0.33 1750 Buy Plain
Decision Buy Plain 1485
Delay mild 0.33 750
Buy Plain 1500
1500
severe 0.70 1900 100
Act now
1500 Decision Buy Mnt moderate 0.15 1650 Buy Mnt
Buy Mnt 1675
1675 mild 0.15 650
Heading to severe Buy Plain 1400
0.33 1400
Delay for 10 years severe 0.15 1900
1522
Heading to moderate Decision Buy Mnt moderate 0.70 1650 Buy Mnt
0.33 Buy Mnt 1538
mild 0.15 650
1538
Buy Plain 1400
1400
Heading to mild severe 0.15 1900
22$ ha 0.33
Decision Buy Mnt moderate 0.15 1650 Buy Plain
Buy Plain 988
1400 mild 0.70 650
Buy Plain 1400
1400
Optimum decision
Pe nalt y for wai tng
Value of w aiting
Fig. 1. Modied decision tree showing the value of delaying irreversible investments in conservation properties with a changing climate.
R. Nelson et al. / Journal of Environmental Management 124 (2013) 128e136 131
conservation value of $1500 per hectare, regardless of whether
climate change is mild, moderate or severe.
In contrast,the property on the mountain is small and particularly
sensitive to climate change. It has high conservation value ($2000 or
$1750 per ha) as a biodiversity refuge if climate change is severe or
moderate, but lowconservationvalue ($750) if climate changeis mild.
The analysis can be thought of as abstracting from the use of dis-
counting, or alternatively as being expressed in present value terms.
The properties can be purchased now, or in 10 years time when
more information on the regional impacts of climate change are
known. This is consistent with investment scenarios that conser-
vation estate managers often face when working with farmers. In
this example, the regional climate is expected to change, but little is
currently known about the relative severity of this change. This lack
of knowledge about the future severity of regional climate change
in say 2050 is represented by an equal objective probability of mild,
moderate or severe impacts (33%).
Over time, downscaled climate projections are likely to become
available to rene these probabilities. This model assumes that
more information about the regional severity of climate change will
be known in 10 years when the option for purchase the land ma-
tures. This is represented by three possible scenarios in which an
additional 10 years of climate data and scientic advance may alter
the subjective probability of mild, moderate or severe impacts to
70% respectively in each case. Which of these three future scenarios
will occur is currently unknown, and hence they have an equal
objective probability of occurring at the time when the decision to
defer the purchase of the land needs to be made.
Regardless of which scenario eventuates, delaying the decision to
purchase land is expected to incur a penalty in terms of lost con-
servation value. If purchase is delayed by 10 years, management for
other values such as agricultural production is expected to reduce
the conservation benets of both properties by $100 per hectare.
It is important that in both the act nowbranch and the delay
for 10 yearsbranches of the decision tree, the objective probabil-
ities of mild, moderate or severe climate impacts in 2050 are
exactly the same. Subjective opinion regarding trends in climate
change over the next 10 years does not change the objective
probability of mild, moderate or severe impacts actually occurring
in the future. If there is specic scientic knowledge of the relative
probability of climate change impacts in 2050, this information
must be added to both the act nowbranch of the tree as well as the
delay for 10 yearsbranch. This would mean altering the equal
likelihood of each level of climate change impact in Fig. 1 (33%)
towards the most likely outcome.
The value of delaying the purchase in this case is positive, but
small ($22 per ha). The value of waiting is strongly contingent on
improved future knowledge of climate change, as well as reducing
any potential future degradation of the land. For example, if the
knowledge accumulated over the next 10 years provided only a 64%
probability of mild, moderate or severe impacts, there would be no
value in delaying the purchase. Similarly, an increase in the penalty
for waiting to $122 per hectare is also enough to make delaying the
purchase unattractive. This provides conservation estate managers
with a rough tool for exploring the relative option value of a
covenant designed to maintain the conservation value of a property
for 10 years (up to $122 per hectare).
Correctly specifying this problem as a decision tree requires
considerable expertise, and the nal product appears deceptively
simple. This expertise is unlikely to rest at least initially with end-
users, and expert assistance is likely to be required until users ac-
quire this capability. Once structured correctly, the spreadsheet
model is easy to use, and can be rapidly recongured to explore the
sensitivity of relative option value to changes in various input pa-
rameters. With current settings, the decision tree legitimises
choices to delay land purchase while waiting to see if some of the
uncertainty in local climate change impacts can be resolved by new
knowledge over the next 10 years.
4.3. Luehrmans option space and the option value of a conservation
portfolio
The relative option value of a single property with climate
sensitive conservation value is only part of the investment problem
faced by BHA. BHAs overall objective is to construct a portfolio of
conservation properties, all with greatly divergent characteristics,
that together maximise the biodiversity values conserved with the
funds available. Properties can differ in their size, the rate at which
their conservation value changes over time, and the mechanisms
via which they can be brought under management. Purchasing a
property provides BHA with the strongest inuence over manage-
ment, but it is also the most expensive and least reversible alter-
native. Covenants and management agreements are more exible,
but conservation values may be at risk for as long as the property is
being managed for other uses such as grazing.
Decision trees are efcient tools for exploring the option value of
paired investment alternatives and the interaction of choice with
time, but quickly become messy when generalised to a greater
number of alternatives. For property portfolio decisions, Luehr-
mans option space has potential to provide clearer insights to
support investment decisions. As described in more detail in
Appendix A, Leuhrmans option space is dened by NPV
q
, which is
the ratio of the future value of the asset (S) over its cost (the present
value of its exercise price, X). This metric is compared to the
volatility of the annual returns from the asset,
s
ffiffi
t
p, estimated using
Monte Carlo simulation, historical data and/or expert opinion. Us-
ing these metrics, the value of each option can be estimated via look
up tables. Luehrman uses option space to emphasise the role that
active management plays in enhancing option value. Options tend
to move upward in option space (see Figure A1) as time to their
expiry lapses and uncertainty is resolved (Figure A1,Appendix A).
Active management can shift investments to the right and down-
wards in option space as innovation creates positive forms of
uncertainty.
A portfolio of properties with simplied but realistic conserva-
tion characteristics was developed based on conversations with
BHA estate managers (Table 1). Using Luehrmans real options
terminology (Appendix A), the exercise price (X) is the price that
land can be purchased for, whether now or at its present value at
some pre-agreed point in the future under a covenant. It is current
practice for conservation estate managers to use expert judgement
to value each property (S
0
) including conservation value. Real op-
tions analysis provides no additional insight into the difcult
problem of estimating conservation values in monetary terms. The
properties can be purchased immediately, or put under a man-
agement agreement for Tyears. At the end of this management
period, the future value of the properties is uncertain (S
T
), and this
uncertainty can be characterised as a probability distribution by
estate managers. A triangular distribution was used because the
parameters of this type of distribution are intuitive and easy for
estate managers to manipulate to reect their future expectations.
This probability distribution can be readily generalised to any other
form.
A spreadsheet was built so that these parameters could be
altered readily in conversation with estate managers to broadly
capture the characteristics of alternative properties. Properties A
and B in Table 1, for example, could be medium to large properties
with low current conservation value relative to their current pur-
chase price, but with potential to be of high conservation value in
the future. Their future conservation value could be expected to
R. Nelson et al. / Journal of Environmental Management 124 (2013) 128e136132
increase due to climate change or the increasing scarcity of these
ecotypes in the landscape. An important difference between op-
tions A and B is the length of time that purchase can be delayed
(T¼5, 10). Property C, in contrast, could represent a small property
of high current and future conservation value. Property D could
represent an iconic large landholding with high and relatively
certain conservation values over a long period. Property E is a small
to medium property of some conservation value that is at risk,
perhaps due to detrimental management (such as overstocking).
The management issues surrounding property E are so problematic
that its purchase under current management could incur consid-
erable future rehabilitation costs (future conservation value S
T
is
negative).
A decision to purchase one or more of these properties imme-
diately creates some difcult trade-offs, particularly with limited
budgets. For example, if the conservation estate manager has only
$14 million to spend on the properties in Table 1 then one imme-
diate implication is that the iconic property D cannot be purchased.
Properties A, B, C and E can be purchased individually, or properties
A and C, A and E, or C and E can be purchased together. However,
this poses a dilemma because only properties C and D have suf-
cient immediate conservation value to yield a positive net present
value. Purchasing properties A and C, A and E, or C and E together
result in a net present value of zero. The only option that ts within
the budget and generates a positive net present value is the pur-
chase of property C, the smallest property, but this option may have
a low impact on regional conservation outcomes. What should the
conservation estate manager do?
As discussed in Section 4.1, BHA is using property covenants to
inuence conservation values beyond the reach of the properties
that it directly owns. The option characteristics of each property in
Table 1 can be mapped in the option space designed by Luehrman
(1998a,b) (Fig. 2), and their option value estimated using lookup
tables (Brealy and Myers, 1991)(Table 1). The options values in
Table 1 suggest that all of the properties other than property E have
a positive option value. Both options A and B require proactive
management intervention to realise their potential future conser-
vation value. However, the short time available (5 years) to manage
property B towards higher conservation outcomes places a signif-
icant constraint on its potential option value. Overall, the total
amount worth paying to retain options on properties AeD is less
than $14 million, creating potential to inuence their management
until more is known about their future conservation value. This
includes the larger property D, the high option value of which
derives more from its iconic nature than uncertainty in its future
conservation value.
Note that even if the budget were less than $14 million, the
estimates of real option value provide some useful quantitative
information that could assist conservation estate managers to make
difcult trade offs. For example, the analysis of future conservation
value suggests that there may be little risk to the future conser-
vation value of the large iconic property D, even if the conservation
estate manager does not get involved in its management. Proper-
ties A and C have similar option value, but completely different
ecological characteristics. The choice between the two may come
down to a discussion of the specic threats inuencing the value of
property C, and the ability through management to alter the future
conservation value of property A. The analysis of option value re-
directs the conversation from a discussion of unknowns, to a dis-
cussion of how to positively inuence future uncertainty from a
range of sources including climate change.
-0.20
-0.18
-0.16
-0.14
-0.12
-0.10
-0.08
-0.06
-0.04
-0.02
0.00
0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0 4.5
Value to cost ratio (NPV
q
)
Worthwhile now
Management
likely to refine
Management
may fail
Management
likely to improve
Management
may rescue
Volatility
D
C
A
B
E
Fig. 2. A hypothetical (but realistic) portfolio of conservation properties in Luehrmans
option space.
Table 1
The option characteristics of a hypothetical portfolio of conservation properties.
Property X(input) S
0
(input) NPV ¼(S
0
X)S
T
etriangular distribution (input) T(input) Option value (look up tables)
$ million $ million $ million $ million years $ million % of S
T
Low Med High
A862 4 8 16 10 2.96 32.9
B13103 3 10 15 5 0.14 1.50
C 3 5 2 3 7 9 12 2.14 32.9
D 20 25 5 22 25 28 15 8.23 32.9
E6422 2 4 3 0.00 0.00
Total 0 13.5
X¼the purchase price of the property.
S
0
¼estimated current value of the property, including conservation value.
S
T
¼uncertain future value of the property, including conservation value.
T¼period over which a covenant or management agreement can be negotiated before a decision needs to be made to purchase the property.
AeMedium-sized property currently rundown (S
0
<X). Assessed as likely to have improved conservation potential under a 10 year covenant (S
Tmed & high
>S
0
), but some
downside risk of deteriorating conservation value (S
Tlow
<S
0
).
BeLarge property, similar to A in that it is currently rundown. Assessed as likely to have improved conservation value under a 5 year covenant, but with a risk of deteriorated
conservation value. Unlike property A, the median future conservation value is less than the purchase price (S
Tmed
<X).
CeSmall property with a high current conservation value (S
0
>X). Over a 12 year covenant the conservation value is assessed to improve or stay the same. Even in the worst
case, the conservation value remains the same as the purchase price (S
0
>S
Tlow
¼X).
DeIconic large property with a high current conservation value. Over a 15 year covenant this is assessed as likely to improve. In the worst case, the conservation value remains
greater than the purchase price (S
0
>S
Tlow
>X).
EeA small to medium property with low current conservation value and an assessment that under a 3 year covenant, the conservation value will not improve and remain less
than the purchase price (S
0
¼S
Thigh
<X).
R. Nelson et al. / Journal of Environmental Management 124 (2013) 128e136 13 3
4.4. Luehrmans option space and the design of appropriate
covenants and management actions
Evaluation of Luehrmans option space with BHA revealed
another application useful to conservation estate managers ethe
design of appropriate covenants. Current assessment methods tend
to suggest that a property is likely to have signicant option value,
but it can be difcult to place even an approximate estimate on the
nancial value of this option. Conservation estate managers may be
able to roughly assess their potential to inuence the management
of a property, and how this could enhance its future conservation
values, but it can be difcult to assess how much this would alter its
current option value. How much should the conservation estate
manager pay for an option? What conditions such as expiry date
and potential management outcomes should the conservation es-
tate manager negotiate?
Luehrmans option space can help conservation estate managers
design the appropriate attributes of covenants, and work through
important trade-offs. This can be demonstrated by revisiting the
example of property E, which is reproduced in Table 2 and Fig. 3.In
the previous example (Table 1,Fig. 2), the option value of property E
was constrained by the detrimental impacts of current management
on conservation values (future conservation value was negative),
and the limited time available to inuence its management (3 years).
However, if it were possible to negotiate a longer period (say 10
years) over which management could be positively inuenced, the
value of a covenant could be much higher. This is true even if there
remains some risk of negative future conservation outcomes(S
T
can
still fall as low as $2 million), providing the longer period has
greater upside potential (say the upper limits of the distribution are
now S
T
¼$8 and $10 million). The result in this example is a sub-
stantially positive option value. Real options analysis has enabled
the manager to explore the consequences of different covenant
conditions and proactive management on option value.
5. Discussion
5.1. Real options and strategy
Part of the value of real options analysis derives from reframing
and guiding strategic decision making (Triantis and Borison, 2001)
as demonstrated in the biodiversity examples in Section 4. Real
options analysis makes more explicit some of the key principles
intrinsic to innovative risk management, and provides some
quantitative tools for supporting their application. From this
perspective, real options analysis is a logical and much needed
enhancement of traditional valuation methods, rather than a rev-
olution in the way decisions are made. This inductive dimension
means that the principles of real options analysis have long been
applied at a more intuitive level without the relatively recent jar-
gon or analytical techniques. According to Copeland and Antikarov
(2003), for example, the rst recorded application of real options
analysis was revealed in the story of Thales, recorded by Aristotle,
who bought exclusive rights to all the olive presses on the island of
Milos at the standard rent prior to the harvest season. When an
outstanding season eventuated, Thales reportedly made a fortune,
presumably without rst completing a sophisticated real option
analysis.
A number of authors have questioned the need for complex
analytical techniques to precisely estimate the value of real options
(van Putten and MacMillan, 2004;Lander and Pinches, 1998;de
Neufville, 2003;Eapen, 2003). These authors suggest that deci-
sion making strategies can often be enhanced effectively using less
precise methods to rank alternatives. According to de Neufville
(2003), for example, managers dont need high degrees of preci-
sion because they make choices between competing alternatives
rather than detailed judgements of individual options. This is
consistent with the foundational decision making theory of Herbert
Simon (see Simon, 1983). A focus on improved outcomes from
decision making helps to the bridge the gap between theory and
practice, refocusing real options analysis on its value to decision
makers (Luehrman, 1998b), rather than its mathematical elegance
and appeal to analysts. This has led to the development of the
intuitive approaches for approximating the value of real options
that have been evaluated in Section 4.
There is broad agreement that the main benet to most users of
real options analysis lies in refocusing risk management away from
the standard approach of avoiding negative outcomes towards
proactively nuturing and exploiting positive sources of uncertainty
(de Neufville, 2003). This is clearly evident in the biodiversity ex-
amples explored in Section 4which focus attention on manage-
ment actions that increase future conservation value. Proponents of
adaptive management and adaptive governance have described
how positivism (see Lacey, 2005) has created unrealistic expecta-
tions of the degree to which reductionism can resolve the uncer-
tainty inherent in natural resource management (Holling, 1978;
Brunner and Steelman, 2005). This has led to narrowly bureau-
cratic denitions of risk management that focus on procedures to
Table 2
Alternative options characteristics of a conservation property.
Property X(input) S
0
(input) NPV ¼(S
0
X)S
T
etriangular distribution (input) T(input) Option value (look up tables)
$ million $ million $ million $ million years $ million % of S
T
Low Med High
E original 6 4 22 2 4 3 0.00 0.00
E modied 6 4 22 8 10 10 1.99 33.1
E - original
E - modified
-0.25
-0.2
-0.15
-0.1
-0.05
0
0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0
Management
may rescue
Volatility
Management
likely to improve
Value to cost ratio (NPV
q
)
Fig. 3. Using Luehrmans option space to evaluate alternative covenants.
R. Nelson et al. / Journal of Environmental Management 124 (2013) 128e136134
maintain current activities. For example, citing the joint Australian/
New Zealand Standard on Risk Management, Hardaker et al. (2004)
dene risk management as the systematic application of manage-
ment policies, procedures and practices to the tasks of identifying,
analysing, assessing, treating and monitoring risk (pg 13). As a
result, the conventional approach to managing risk is to attempt to
minimise the incidence of risky events, and negate their impact.
In contrast, more holistic approaches to risk management can
uncover additional and previously unknown opportunities through
careful analysis of the risks involved in taking a certain course of
action before the event occurs. Real options analysis refocuses risk
management on proactively seeking out and exploiting the new
opportunities embedded in future uncertainty. This is consistent
with pursuing diversication as a pathway to desired outcomes, to
enable increased substitution between activities and assets in
household livelihood strategies (Ellis, 2000). According to de
Neufville (2003), the real option approach offers a fundamentally
eperhaps even cataclysmically edifferentapproach to risk man-
agement compared to todays standard engineering approach (pg
30). Proactively seeking sources of uncertainty to create new op-
portunities can be a difcult concept for conventional risk man-
agers to accept. However, it is neither new nor untested, as the
example of Thales demonstrates.
6. Conclusions
This paper has demonstrated that real options analysis can be
distilled into intuitively accessible heuristics with potential toplace
its analytical power into the hands of natural resource managers.
The evaluation with conservation estate managers shows that the
value of real options analysis derives from enabling managers to
explore options for proactively managing the uncertainty arising
from climate change and other sources. However, this value can
only be realised if the analytical power of real options analysis is
made intuitively accessible to decision makers. Real options anal-
ysis builds on the intrinsic intuitive appeal of avoiding irreversible
decisions and creating future opportunities. This paper adds to
growing evidence that this intuition can be supported with
analytical methods that rank alternatives, without necessarily
having to provide complex and precise valuations of individual
options. In doing so this paper has demonstrated the potential to
take the next step with real options analysis beyond researcher-
driven applications, to real applications that support practitioners
in the eld.
Acknowledgements
This research was funded by the Managing Climate Variability
Program of Land & Water Australia. The authors acknowledge the
generous collaboration of Bush Heritage Australia, and are grateful
for the signicant contributions made by Stuart Cowell, Annette
Stewart and Mel Sheppard. The authors acknowledge the valuable
technical assistance of Mike Dunlop and Phil Kokic, and Greg Hert-
zler for contributions to the theory of real options in agriculture.
Appendix A. Supplementary data
Supplementary data related to this article can be found at http://
dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2013.03.031.
References
Amram, M., Kulatilaka, N., 2000. Strategy and shareholder value creation: the real
option frontier. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 13, 8e21.
Arrow, K.J., Fisher, A.C., 1974. Environmental preservation, uncertainty, and irre-
versibility. Quarterly Journal of Economics 88, 312e319.
Bakshi, B., Saphores, J., 2004. Grandma or the wolf? A real options framework for
managing human-wildlife conicts. http://www.realoptions.org/papers2004/
SaphoresHA.pdf.
Boer, P., 2002. The Real Options Solution eFinding Total Value in a High-risk World.
John Wiley & Sons, New York.
Borison, A., 2005. Real options analysis: where are the emperors clothes? Journal of
Applied Corporate Finance 17, 17e31.
Borison, A., 2003. Real Options Analysis: Where Are the Emperors Clothes?. Pre-
sented at Real Options Conference, Washington DC, July. www.realoptions.org/
abstracts/abstracts03.html.
Brealy, R., Myers, S., 1991. Principles of Corporate Finance, fourth ed. McGraw-Hill,
New York.
Brunner, R., Steelman, T., 2005. Beyond scientic management. In: Brunner, R.,
Steelman, T., Coe-Juell, L., Cromley, C., Edwards, C., Tucker, D. (Eds.), Adaptive
Governance: Integrating Science, Policy and Decision Making. Columbia Uni-
versity Press, New York.
Busby, J., Pitts, C., 1997. Real options in practice: an exploratory survey of how
nance ofcers deal with exibility in capital appraisal. Management Ac-
counting Review 8, 169e186.
Carey, J., Zilberman, D., 2002. A model of investment under uncertainty: modern
irrigation technology and emerging markets in water. American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 84, 171e183.
Copeland, T., Antikarov, V., 2003. Real Options ea Practitioners Guide. Texere, New
York.
Copeland, T., Tufano, P., 2004. A real-world way to manage real options. Harvard
Business Review, March, 1e12.
Cortazar, G., 2004. Simulation and numerical methods in real options valuation. In:
Schwartz, E., Trigeorgis, L. (Eds.), Real Options and Investment Under Uncer-
tainty: Classical Readings and Recent Contributions. The MIT Press, Cambridge.
Cortazar, G., 1999. The valuation of natural resources. In: Trigeorgis, L. (Ed.), Real
Options and Business Strategy: Applications to Decision Making. Risk Books,
London, pp. 263e278.
Cortazar, G., Casassus, J., 2000. A compound option model for evaluating multi-stage
natural resource investments. In: Brennan, M.J., Trigeorgis, L. (Eds.), Project
Flexibility, Agency, and Competition: New Developments in the Theory and
Application of Real Options. Oxford University Press, New York, pp. 205e223.
de Neufville, R., 2003. Real options: dealing with uncertainty in systems planning
and design. Integrated Assessment 4, 26e34.
Dixit, A., Pindyck, R., 1994. Investment Under Uncertainty. Princeton University
Press, Princeton.
Dobes, L., 2008. Getting real about adapting to climate change: using real options
to address the uncertainties. Agenda 15, 55e69.
Eapen, G., 2003. The accidental real options practitioner. Journal of Applied
Corporate Finance 15, 102e107.
Ellis, F., 2000. Rural Livelihoods and Diversity in Developing Countries. Oxford
University Press, Oxford.
Graham, J., Harvey, C., 2001. The theory and practice of corporate nance: evidence
from the eld. Journal of Financial Economics 60, 187e243.
Hardaker, J., Huirne, R., Anderson, J., Lien, G., 2004. Coping with Risk in Agriculture,
second ed. CABI Publishing, Wallingford.
Hayman, P.T., 2004. Decision support systems in Australian dryland farming: a
promising past, a disappointing present and uncertain future. In: Fischer, R.A.,
Turner, N.C., Angus, J.F., McIntyre, L., Robertson, M., Borrell, A., Lloyd, D. (Eds.),
4th International Crop Science Congress. Brisbane. www.cropscience.org.au/
icsc2004/symposia/4/1/1778_haymanp.htm.
Hertzler, G., 2007. Adapting to climate change and managing climate risks by using
real options. Australian Journal of Agricultural Research 58 (10), 985e992.
Hildebrandt, P., Knoke, T., 2011. Investment decisions under uncertaintyda
methodological review on forest science studies. Forest Policy and Economics 13,
1e15.
Holling, C. (Ed.), 1978. Adaptive Environmental Assessment and Management. The
Blackburn Press, Caldwell.
Kassar,I., Lasserre, P., 2004. Species preservation and biodiversity value: a real options
approach. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 48, 857e879.
Lacey, A., 2005. Positivism. In: Honderich, T. (Ed.), The Oxford Companion to Phi-
losophy, second ed. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Lander, D., Pinches, G., 1998. Challenges to the practical implementation of
modelling and valuing real options. The Quarterly Review of Economics and
Finance 38, 537e567.
Luehrman, T., 1998a. Investment opportunities as real options: getting started on
the numbers. Harvard Business Review, JulyeAug, 3e15.
Luehrman, T., 1998b. Strategy as a portfolio of real options. Harvard Business Re-
view, SepteOct, 89e99.
Manley, B., Niquidet, K., 2010. What is the relevance of option pricing for forest
valuation in New Zealand? Forest Policy and Economics 12, 299e307.
Matthews, K.B., Schwarz, G., Buchan, K., Rivington, M., Miller, D., 2008. Wither
agricultural DSS? Computers and Electronics in Agriculture 61, 149e159.
Michailidis, A., Mattas, K., 2007. Using real options theory to irrigation dam in-
vestment analysis: an application of binomial option pricing model. Water
Resource Management 21, 1717e1733.
Michailidis, A., Mattas, K., Karamouzis, D., 2009. Assessment of irrigation dam using
real options and discounted cash ow approaches: a case study in Greece.
Water Policy 11, 481e488.
R. Nelson et al. / Journal of Environmental Management 124 (2013) 128e136 13 5
Mithoefer, D., Wesseler, J., Waibel, H., 2004. Private Investment in Biodiversity
Conservation ea Real Options Approach. Paper Presented to the 8th Annual
International Conference on Real Options. Montréal Canada, June 17e19. www.
realoptions.org.
Mun, J., 2006. Real Options Analysis eTools and Techniques for Valuing Strategic
Investments and Decisions, second ed. John Wiley & Sons, New York.
Myers, S., 1977. Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Eco-
nomics 5, 147e175.
Rocha, K., Moreira, A., Carvalho, L., Reis, E., 2001. The Option Value of Forest Con-
cessions in Amazon Reserves. Paper Presented to Real Options eTheory Meets
Practice. 5th Annual Real Options Conference. Anderson School of Management,
UCLA, Los Angeles.
Ryan, P., Ryan, G., 2002. Capital budgeting practices of the fortune 1000: how have
things changed? Journal of Business and Management 8, 355e365.
Saphores, J., 2001. The Option Value of Harvesting a Renewable Resource. School of
Social Ecology and Economics, University of California, Irvine.
Saphores, J., Khalaf, L., Pelletier, D., 2002. On jumps and arch effects in natural
resource prices ean application to Pacic Northwest stumpage prices. Amer-
ican Journal of Agricultural Economics 84, 387e400.
Schatzki, T., 2003. Options, uncertainty and sunk costs: an empirical analysis of land
use change. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 46, 86e105.
Seo, S., Segarra, E., Mitchell, P., Leatham, D., 2008. Irrigation technology adoption
and its implication for water conservation in the Texas high plains: a real op-
tions approach. Agricultural Economics 38, 47e55.
Simon, H., 1983. Reason in Human Affairs. Stanford University Press, Stanford.
Tozer, P., 2009. Uncertainty and investment in precision agriculture eis it worth the
money? Agricultural Systems 100, 80e87.
Triantis, A., 2005. Realising the potential of real options: does theory meet practice?
Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 17, 8e16.
Triantis, A., Borison, A., 2001. Real options: state of practice. Journal of Applied
Corporate Finance 14, 8e24.
van Putten, A., MacMillan, I., 2004. Making real options really work. Harvard
Business Review, December, 1e8.
Whitten, S., Hertzler, G., Strunz, S., 2012. How real options and ecological resilience
thinking can assist in environmental risk management. Journal of Risk Research
15, 331e346.
Woolley, S., Cannizzo, F., 2005. Taking real options beyond the black box. Journal of
Applied Corporate Finance 17, 94e98.
R. Nelson et al. / Journal of Environmental Management 124 (2013) 128e136136
... CBA does not properly account for flexibility and uncertainty, while ROA can deal with them recognizing that 'flexibility in decision making has value when new information affecting the investment or policy alternative arrives either periodically or at random intervals in the future' (Ando and Shah 2016, 337). ROA has been previously applied to decisions regarding public services (Deng et al. 2013) or land use management (Nelson, Howden, and Hayman 2013;Regan et al. 2015), but not to the specific analysis of management decisions related to the tourism use of PAs. A combination of CBA and ROA, under an adaptive management framework of PAs to foster a sustainable tourism entrepreneurship, could help reinforce the positive contribution of PAs to regional development. ...
... The reliance on command-and-control measures and in traditional CBA, disregarding uncertainty and flexibility, could lead to suboptimal sustainability outcomes (Watson et al. 2014;Weaver and Lawton 2017). Similar to previous studies that have demonstrated the power of ROA to capture the additional value derived from uncertainty and flexibility when assessing a project or decision (Deng et al. 2013;Nelson, Howden, and Hayman 2013;Regan et al. 2015), the application of ROA to the Ons Island case has proved that the options to expand or reduce visitors' quotas have intrinsic value, and justify the infrastructure investments needed to guarantee a sustainable tourism development of the island. Thus, a CBA-ROA combined model can be a useful tool for both park managers and government. ...
... Paulrud and Laitila (2013) critique that CBA is not usually applied to support management decisions. Similar to Nelson, Howden, and Hayman (2013), this study wants to place the analytical power of real options in the hands of PA managers. Managers are asked to translate their management objectives and the necessary constraints imposed by the socio-economic and biophysical environment into benefits and cost figures, including not only all relevant information but also the consideration of uncertainty and flexibility in their decision-making processes. ...
Article
Tourism entrepreneurship has not received sufficient attention in the context of protected areas (PAs). It needs careful management to avoid conflicts with conservation objectives and positively contribute to regional development. Traditional management approaches based on the strict application of the carrying capacity principle are suboptimal. An adaptive management framework has been demanded, but it has been scarcely adopted in practice or explored in previous research. Moreover, appropriate decision-making tools are lacking. This study proposes a combination of cost-benefit analysis (CBA) and real options analysis (ROA) to support the sustainable tourism entrepreneurship development in PAs under an adaptive management framework. Costs are related to the conservation and restoration activities, and benefits to the use and non-use value placed by visitors on it, measured through visitors’ willingness to pay (WTP) for sustainable tourism. The proposed model also embraces uncertainty and flexibility, considering visitors’ WTP and tourism demand as the primary sources of uncertainty. Through the analysis of the sustainable tourism management of Ons Island, part of the Marine-Terrestrial National Park of the Atlantic Islands of Galicia, we exemplify the power of a combined CBA-ROA approach and derive implications for policymakers, PA managers, tourism entrepreneurs, and researchers.
... Much has been written about the need for the scientific community to embrace uncertainty (e.g. Popper et al., 2005;Lempert et al., 2004;Nelson et al., 2013;Bammer and Smithson, 2008). We argue that this in itself will not suffice, and that there is also a need to embrace ambiguity in certain situations. ...
... Thus, we suggest climate adaptation researchers in particular could try a different approach: embracing ambiguity (along the lines of the successes achieved by embracing complexity and uncertainty, e.g. Popper et al., 2005;Nelson et al., 2013;Bammer and Smithson, 2008). This could allow a more practical focus toward facilitating cooperation and action. ...
... Achieving impact through integration and multiplication of ideas rather than impositions of particular ideas (and the values embedded in them) over others. This work would be a useful complement to the progress of climate adaptation literature which examines complexity, contested values, and successfully acting despite uncertainty (Adger et al., 2009;Farbotko and Lazarus, 2012;Hulme, 2009;Popper et al., 2005;Nelson et al., 2013). ...
Article
Diversity, interdisciplinarity and transdisciplinarity are now recognized as vital to tackling wicked problems such as those presented by a changing climate (Nature editorial 2015, Ledford 2015; Dick et al., 2016). Including diverse disciplines in science projects enables a range of different views which often facilitate the creation of innovative solutions. Supporting multiple views and options requires a different way of worldng beyond traditional reductionist approaches to science, communication and decision-making. To embrace diversity in scientific project teams in order to tackle complex, integrated and urgent issues but to expect singular and linear pathways forward is paradoxical. Much has been written about the need for the scientific community to embrace uncertainty (e.g. Popper, Lempert & Bankes 2005; Lempert et al., 2004; Nelson, Howden & Hayman 2013; Bammer & Smithson 2008). We argue that this in itself will not suffice, and that there is also a need to embrace ambiguity in certain. situations. Thus, in this article we explore: (1) what ambiguity is, including the benefits it can offer to climate adaptation in particular, using existing approaches to ambiguity in the arts and humanities as examples (2), we discuss practical meanings of ambiguity in relation to climate change, (3) we propose possible next steps for bringing ambiguity into interdisciplinary practice, and (4) we identify some challenges and necessary preconditions to successfully and appropriately embracing ambiguity.
... Much has been written about the need for the scientific community to embrace uncertainty (e.g. Popper et al., 2005;Lempert et al., 2004;Nelson et al., 2013;Bammer and Smithson, 2008). We argue that this in itself will not suffice, and that there is also a need to embrace ambiguity in certain situations. ...
... Thus, we suggest climate adaptation researchers in particular could try a different approach: embracing ambiguity (along the lines of the successes achieved by embracing complexity and uncertainty, e.g. Popper et al., 2005;Nelson et al., 2013;Bammer and Smithson, 2008). This could allow a more practical focus toward facilitating cooperation and action. ...
... Achieving impact through integration and multiplication of ideas rather than impositions of particular ideas (and the values embedded in them) over others. This work would be a useful complement to the progress of climate adaptation literature which examines complexity, contested values, and successfully acting despite uncertainty (Adger et al., 2009;Farbotko and Lazarus, 2012;Hulme, 2009;Popper et al., 2005;Nelson et al., 2013). ...
... Included in the switch options, agricultural conversion arises as an alternative for land uses showing the high value that this option can incorporate. In this context, ROT has been applied to organic farming [43][44][45], adoption of precision agriculture [45,46], expansion of agricultural enterprises [46][47][48], the adoption of genetically modified crops [49] and adaptation to climate change [50][51][52]. Most of above mentioned works use a continuoustime stochastic price models in their application of ROT. ...
Article
Full-text available
In the valuation of forest resources, the alternative uses of the land is one of the central themes. In most cases it is made without taking into account the uncertainty and the possible flexibility of the alternative use. Within these alternatives, the strategy of shifting to a more profitable and sustainable crop is a well-studied topic in forest research. Although the transformation opportunity could add great value to the project, the valuation of this flexibility is obviated by traditional discounted cash flow criteria (NPV). The application of real options theory (ROT) makes it possible to assess this flexibility based on the uncertainty that the transformation entails. However, the hypotheses that are made about the future evolution of the underlying asset, in this case the value of the new crop, may condition the precision of the result. Usually some researchers model these conversions under the hypothesis of Geometric Brownian Motion (GBM), hypotheses that are not plausible when the new crop has a strong seasonal component. In this work, it is proposed an adapted model framework to evaluate forest transformation opportunity into another crop when land use has both high agronomic potential and high seasonal component, context in which classic real options framework is not applicable. As a work based on a theoretical model, after methodological motivation, it is chosen a the strawberry crop as alternative due to its seasonal component. Using private data for this crop, we model through the Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process, with mean-reversion (MR) to a seasonal component, and then we use of Longstaff and Schwartz's Algorithm to calculate the option value. The results show that when considering flexibility into option valuation it leds to an increase on the return of more than 4%. Furthermore, robustness analysis evidence that option value is very sensitive to seasonal component, reinforcing previous evidence that suggests that MR process offers a more accurate and appropriate valuation over the traditional GBM in the arena of agronomic potential valuation. Specifically, the result of valuing this transformation through the MR process is between 1.5 and 1.7 times the value of the NPV, which results in approximately 13% annual return. If GBM had been used, the valuation would have been a 72% annual return, an unrealistic result in this context, due to the non-consideration of the seasonal mean-reverting prices process. .
... Armstrong et al. [23] address the treatment of uncertainty in the development of oil exploitation through the study of the option of obtaining more information, due to the irreversible nature of the decision to invest in oil exploitation. Nelson, Howden, and Hayman [24] perform an application of RO through decision trees on the conservation of natural properties taking into account climate change as uncertainty. Wang and Du [25] perform a development of the binomial method through RO to evaluate investment decisions in carbon capture and storage in coal-fired power plants in China. ...
Article
Full-text available
Aquaculture is an increasingly relevant sector in the exploitation of natural resources; therefore, it is appropriate to propose various models that include the fundamental variables for its economic-financial valuation from a business point of view. The objective of this paper is to analyze different models for the valuation of investment projects in a company in the aquaculture sector in order to conclude whether there is a model that represents a better valuation. Therefore, in this study, four valuation models have been applied, three classical models (net present value, internal rate of return, and payback) and a more recent model, real options (RO) for a company producing and marketing seaweed in Galicia (region located in the northwest of Spain). The results obtained, RO (€5,527,144.04) and net present value (€5,479,659.19), conclude that the RO model estimates a higher added value by taking into account in its calculations the flexibility given by the expansion option. Future lines of research include the application of valuation models that have been applied to companies belonging to the same sector in order to compare whether the results found are similar.
... There are many approaches to analyze cost-intensive investments under the conditions of uncertainty (Cristóbal et al., 2013). One of the methods gaining popularity is real options as it is being applied in different fields (Insley, 2002;Nelson et al., 2013;Regan et al., 2015;Schatzki, 2003;Slade, 2001). Real options are a right, not an obligation, to undertake business initiatives connected with tangible assets (Kodukula and Papudesu, 2006;Wang and Neufville, 2005). ...
Article
The re-processing of mine tailings to obtain critical raw materials (CRMs) could reduce the mining of new deposits as well as ensure the profitable use of the waste materials. Though, it requires large scale industrial installations and the development of specialized technologies to obtain CRMs. New investment in mining activities is an operation, engaging for considerable financial resources involved. The scale of such an endeavor makes a new mining activity a high-risk operation due to several uncertainties present. Therefore, there is an acute need to use new tools to assess the risk associated with the planning and development of new mining activities. This study introduces a framework to evaluate the economic risk related to the re-processing of mine tailings to obtain CRMs. The framework, based on real options analysis (ROA), and sensitivity and uncertainty analysis, was applied to analyze the profitability of using mine tailings as a source of CRMs in the Chilean mining industry. The novelty of this approach consists in enabling the investment decision making including the uncertainties related to a novel investment mining project. Results show that tailing storage facilities in Chile have some stocks of CRMs, like scandium, whose extraction could be profitable. For the data used, the results of uncertainty and sensitivity analyses show that capital expenditure has a more significant influence than the other variables. Therefore, for the case of mine tailings re-processing, it is essential to develop processes and technologies that enable lower capital expenses.
... In this conference paper, we present a discussion support framework (Nelson et al. 2013) that extends the use of the concept of cross-over points to a group setting, aimed at guiding water user discussion about investments in irrigation water sources. To test applicability of the framework, we describe the set-up for a case study in the Coal River Valley in Tasmania, Australia, where multiple water sources are available. ...
... In this conference paper, we present a discussion support framework (Nelson et al. 2013) that extends the use of the concept of cross-over points to a group setting, aimed at guiding water user discussion about investments in irrigation water sources. To test applicability of the framework, we describe the set-up for a case study in the Coal River Valley in Tasmania, Australia, where multiple water sources are available. ...
Article
Full-text available
Regional long-term water management plans increasingly depend on investments by local water users such as farmers. However, local circumstances and individual situations vary and investment decisions are made under uncertainty. Therefore, the perceived values of costs and benefits may also vary considerably among water users, leading to non-uniform investment decisions. This variation can be explored by examining cross-over points, that is, points of equal preference when comparing alternatives. In a participatory context, cross-over analysis has the potential to structure and strengthen discussions among actors and enhance social learning. This paper presents a framework to use cross-over points in a group setting to support discussions among farmers about strategic investments in irrigation water. The framework is tested in a case study in the Coal River Valley in Tasmania, Australia, where various water sources are available. A discussion workshop is designed to learn from each other's perspectives and investment rationales. Instead of focusing on " what is best " , participants engage in a dialogue about when and why a particular water resource is preferable over others for increasing on-farm water availability. These insights can provide valuable background information for investment decisions by other water users, irrigation scheme designers and water managers.
Preprint
Full-text available
Carbon credits are a key component of most national and organizational climate strategies. However, financing and delivering carbon credits from forest-related activities face multiple risks at both the project and asset levels. Financial mechanisms are employed to mitigate risks for investors and project developers, complemented by non-financial measures such as environmental and social safeguards. Despite these efforts, academic research highlights that safeguards and climate risk mitigation measures are not efficiently implemented in some carbon projects and that specification of environmental safeguards remains underdeveloped. Further, environmental and social risk mitigation capacities may not be integrated into financial mechanisms. This text examines how ecosystem capacities can be leveraged and valued for mitigation of physical risks by complementing carbon credits with biodiversity insurance and resilience value.
Article
Full-text available
Scientists predict that some climate change is already inevitable, even if greenhouse emissions are stabilised. Adaptation strategies will be of comparable importance to reducing emissions. However, the specific effects of climate change are currently unknowable, especially at the local level. Given this uncertainty, deterministic adaptation strategies are inappropriate. Rather than building 'worst-case scenario' sea walls, for example, strong foundations can be laid — so that walls can be built (or not built) in future to match actual climatic conditions without incurring unnecessary upfront expense. Other examples of such 'real options' are provided to illustrate the feasibility of the approach.
Book
Full-text available
The purpose of the first edition of the book, published in 1997, was to contribute to improved agricultural decision making by explaining what can be done in risk analysis and management. Since 1997 progress has been made in risk analysis in agriculture. The material covered in this second edition has been restructured and most of the 1997 text has been revised. Topics that are more thoroughly dealt with in this edition include: assessing and quantifying the degree of risk aversion of a decision maker; judging how important risk aversion is likely to be in particular circumstances; an improved approach for partially ordering risky stochastic distributions when the decision maker's attitude to risk is not fully known; stochastic simulation and its combination with optimization for the analysis of risky choice; and risk considerations in agricultural policy making. The book is written for advanced undergraduate and postgraduate students of agricultural economics and farm management, as well as advisers to farmers and agricultural research workers. It has 13 chapters and a subject index.
Article
Full-text available
Adapting to climate change and managing climate risks are new challenges for farmers, community leaders, and catchment management authorities. To meet this challenge, a new method of making decisions under risk may help. This method is called real options. It begins with common sense and adds rigour. It helps us decide when to keep our options open and when to foreclose options and create new ones. In this paper, real options are explained and applied to several examples by developing a new type of decision diagram. The diagrams are a language for thinking about complex decisions under risk. Farmers, community leaders, and catchment management authorities can develop similar diagrams and use them to communicate with other decision makers and with researchers. Finally, the decision diagrams are related to new mathematical tools to help find optimal decisions for managing climate risks.
Article
This article extends the evaluation techniques of an irrigation dam in northern Greece, called "Petrenia", by comparing the real options approach along with, a traditional one, the discount cash flow. By introducing first a Monte Carlo simulation, the various uncertainty factors can be simulated and alternative value options can be computed, feeding them later in the real options model. Results from the case study in Greece clearly demonstrate that the irrigation dam can be classified as a profitable investment, by applying traditional discount cash flow analysis, while by applying the real options approach the project cannot be classified as profitable. Taking into consideration the uncertainty factors, the real options approach reveals that the investment could be postponed and decision makers can keep the option of investing open. Sequentially, discount cash flow analysis accompanied by the real options approach facilitates decision making and improves the investment assessment analysis. In this particular project assessment, two uncertainty factors, variation in dam capacity and water price, restrict the profitability of the irrigation dam, according to the results of the real options approach.
Article
Several parametric and non-parametric approaches have been developed to value financial assets. Yet, financial valuation techniques have only slowly percolated into disciplines concerned with the management of ecosystems. Particularly in forest management, decision-makers often find themselves confronted with extremely long time horizons and severely uncertain information. This requires careful valuation approaches, which are often underrepresented or even completely lacking in forest management. This paper gives a comprehensive overview on techniques for financial decision-making under uncertainty and develops future research needs. First, we analyse different approaches from the expected utility framework as well as option pricing models and robust optimisation techniques as possible approaches to make decisions on forest investments and giving a short review regarding forestry-related applications. Afterwards we discuss the suitability of the presented approaches to support decisions in forestry and conclude that robust optimisation techniques should be developed further, especially since erroneous financial data is likely to occur, as well as deviations from the assumption of normality. Currently, the maximization of financial robustness is probably the most adequate approach for many long-term decisions in forestry, such as selecting the optimum tree species composition. Further development of this approach appears possible and necessary. Finally, we come to the conclusion that even though it is intuitively clear that many long-term decisions should consider uncertainty, adequate financial valuation is not sufficiently developed within forest science. In the case of Central Europe, this may be an effect of ecological research dominating in forest science. Consequently, an intensification of the analysis of uncertainty in forest decision-making is necessary.
Article
In a real-option model of land conversion incorporating return uncertainty and sunk costs, optimal conversion thresholds are significantly higher than those from expected net present value models not accounting for these factors. Empirical tests of conversion from agriculture to forest suggest that landowners value the option to convert when making conversion decisions. Higher uncertainty in returns to all potential uses and lower correlation between shocks to agricultural and forest returns decreases the likelihood of conversion. Estimates indicate a significant impact on conversion decisions, with approximations of option values ranging from 7% to 81% of the expected value of the land asset.
Article
This article develops a natural resource investment evaluation model that considers multi-stage production decisions as compound options. The model allows for multiple stages with finite resource and finite capacity output levels at each stage. Numerical solutions for the two-stage case are presented, showing that the lower the remaining resources and the higher the intermediate inventory, the higher the critical production prices. The optimal operating policy is dependent on the natural resource life-cycle, inducing more first-stage production and inventory accumulation during the early years, and more second- stage production and inventory depletion as reserves decline.
Article
The analogy between financial options and corporate investments that create future opportunities is both intuitively appealing and increasingly well accepted. Executives readily see that today's investment in R&D, or in a new marketing program, or even in a multiphased capital expenditure can generate the possibility of new products or markets tomorrow. But for many, the leap from the puts and calls of financial options to actual investment decisions has been difficult and deeply frustrating. The calculations required to value real options have been dauntingly complex, and practical how-to advice on the subject has been scarce and mostly aimed at specialists, preferably with Ph.D.'s in finance. The framework presented here bridges the gap between the practicalities of real-world capital projects and the higher mathematics associated with formal option-pricing theory. Timothy Luehrman's step-by-step approach can be mastered by anyone who knows how to work with basic discounted cash flows. It is based on a simple mapping between the characteristics of a capital project and the five variables that determine the value of a simple call option on a share of stock. Luehrman's methodology is designed to be used by general managers, not technical specialists. It deliberately sacrifices absolute precision in order to generate a number "good enough" to provide executives with valuable insight into their most important and complex investment decisions - insight that standard discounted-cash-flow analysis typically obscures.