ArticlePDF Available

Lumpy Investments, Factor Adjustments, and Labour Productivity

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

This paper describes firms’ output and factor demands before, during, and after episodes of lumpy investment. By using a rich employer–employee panel data set for two manufacturing industries and one service industry, we focus on simultaneous variations in output, capital, materials, man hours, labour productivity, and the skill composition and hourly cost of labour. Investment spikes are followed by roughly proportional changes in sales, labour, and materials, and significant increases in capital intensity. The changes in labour productivity that are associated with the investment spikes are small, which indicates that productivity improvements are not related to instantaneous technological change through investment spikes. Focusing on sectoral differences, capital adjustments are found to be smoother in the service industry than in the two manufacturing industries which may be related to differences in labour intensities between the industries.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Lumpy Investments, Factor Adjustments and Productivity
Øivind A. Nilsen
(Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration, IZA, and Statistics Norway)
Arvid Raknerud
(Statistics Norway)
Marina Rybalka
(Statistics Norway)
Terje Skjerpen
(Statistics Norway)
February 2006
This paper has benefited from comments and suggestions from Erik Biørn and Ådne Cappelen. We
acknowledge financial support from The Norwegian Research Council (Grant no. 154710/510).
* Corresponding author: Address; Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration, Helleveien 30,
NO-5045 Bergen, Norway. Phone; +47 55 959 281, Fax; +47 55 959 543, E-mail: oivind.nilsen@nhh.no.
1
Abstract
This paper describes firms’ output and factor demands before, during and after episodes of
lumpy investment. By using a rich employer–employee panel data set for two manufacturing
industries and one service industry, we focus on simultaneous variations in output, capital,
materials and man hours, as well as the skill composition and hourly cost of labour.
Investment spikes are followed by roughly proportional changes in sales, labour and
materials, and significant increases in capital intensity. Capital adjustments are found to be
smoother in the service industry than in the two manufacturing industries. This result may be
related to differences in labour intensity between the industries. The changes in productivity
that are associated with the investment spikes are small, which indicates that productivity
improvements are not related to instantaneous technological change through investment
spikes.
Keywords: Lumpy investments, Adjustment costs, Productivity, Panel data
JEL classification: C13, C33, D21, D24
2
1. Introduction
Several studies have pointed out that firms adjust input factors (e.g., capital and labour) in a
lumpy fashion, which generates investment spikes, and with little or no investment activity
between the spikes.1 Such a pattern suggests that the smooth adjustment of capital and labour
is precluded by fixed costs, (partial) irreversibilities or indivisibilities. The motivation for
investment in new capital may be to increase either capacity or productivity, since new capital
embodies the latest technology. The latter effect is a driving force behind productivity growth
at the industry level.2 However, Power (1998), Huggett and Opsina (2001) and Sakellaris
(2004) find that the immediate impact of large investments on productivity is small, or even
negative. This may reflect adjustment costs due to the disruption of production.
The focus of our analysis is on the dynamics of, and interrelationships between, input
and output variables in the periods before and after an investment spike. Specifically, we
investigate how new technology is adapted by the firm and how it affects the firm’s
productivity (relative to the industry average). Moreover, we investigate whether new capital
affects the skill composition of the labour force. Following Sakellaris (2004), Letterie, Pfann
and Polder (2004) and others, we adopt an explorative econometric approach. Using a non-
structural approach has several advantages. First, a structural model that embeds theories of
non-convexities in the adjustments of several input factors is difficult to implement because it
involves dynamic optimization with multiple decision variables.3 Second, even if we were
1 For capital adjustment, see Doms and Dunne (1998), Caballero and Engel (1999), Cooper, Haltiwanger and
Power (1999) and Abel and Eberly (2002) for the US. See Nilsen and Schiantarelli (2003) for Norway, and see
Letterie and Pfann (2005) for the Netherlands. For labour adjustment, see the seminal contribution by
Hamermesh (1989), and the more recent ones of Rota (1995), Abowd and Kramarz (2003) and Nilsen,
Salvanes and Schiantarelli (2003).
2 See, for instance, Jensen, McGuckin and Stiroh (2001).
3 Most of the empirical literature investigates the adjustment of capital and labour separately. However, as
pointed out by several authors, lumpiness in one factor may be caused by non-convexities in the adjustment of
that factor or by lumpiness in other input factors. For interrelationship in input factors, see for instance Nadiri
and Rosen (1969), and more recently Abel and Eberly (1998), and Letterie, Pfann and Polder (2004).
3
able to obtain estimable equations from such a model, it is not clear that this would be the best
way of determining the relevant relationships between output, inputs and productivity. The
model would necessarily build on restrictive, simplifying assumptions to which the resulting
inferences would be sensitive. Our analysis is instead based on a reduced form random effects
model, in which the endogenous variables are sales, materials, capital, hourly wage costs,
total man hours and the share of total man hours worked by high-skilled workers. All
variables are treated as being simultaneously determined. Efficient estimators are obtained by
using the method of maximum likelihood.
This paper is based on a new and unique matched employer–employee data set from
Norway, covering the period 1995–2003. While the existing literature has focused mainly on
the manufacturing sector, a novelty of our study is that we describe the link between
investment spikes, factor adjustments and productivity for services as well as manufacturing.
Another advantage of our data set is that it includes all joint stock (i.e., limited dependent)
companies in the industries under study. Our sample is more representative than those used in
most other studies, as it represents roughly 70 per cent of all man hours in these industries and
includes both large and small firms. However, since indivisibilities and fixed costs play a
more important role for small firms than for large firms, some challenges also arise, which
need to be addressed.
In the literature, a lumpy investment is defined as one that causes the investment-to-
capital ratio to exceed a certain threshold, typically 20 per cent; see Cooper, Haltiwanger and
Power (1999). However, investment-to-capital ratios that exceed 20 per cent are quite
common in our sample. Moreover, since the volatility of these ratios decreases with the
capital stock (before the investment), spikes are much more common for small firms than for
large firms. To address this problem, we propose a modified threshold, which takes this
particular form of heteroscedasticity into account.
4
Our results confirm that investments are lumpy, which indicates that firms concentrate
their investments in short periods of time. This is consistent with non-convexities in the
adjustment cost function for capital. These non-convexities may be due to fixed adjustment
costs or indivisibilities.4 Evidence suggests that adjustments of capital are smoother in the
service industry than in the two manufacturing industries. In all the industries, an investment
spike leads to approximately proportional changes in sales, man hours and materials after two
to three years, while capital intensity increases significantly. We also find that the changes in
productivity associated with investment spikes are small. This suggests that productivity
improvements may have more to do with learning-by-doing than with instantaneous
technological change through investment spikes.
The paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2, we describe the data, define the variables
and report some descriptive statistics. In Section 3, we describe the empirical specification
used. In Section 4, we discuss the empirical results. Section 5 concludes the paper.
2. Data description
2.1 The data sources
We have constructed panels of annual firm-level data for Norwegian firms in three industries,
covering the period 1995–2003. The three industries are the Manufacture of machinery and
equipment (NACE 29), the Manufacture of electrical and optical equipment (NACE 30–33)
and Retail trade and repairs of personal and household goods (NACE 52). The first industry is
a traditional manufacturing industry, the second is a high-tech industry and the last one is a
service industry. Henceforth, we refer to the three industries as Machinery, Electrical
equipment and Retail trade, respectively. The two manufacturing industries accounted for
4 See Hamermesh and Pfann (1996) for a critical review of adjustment-cost functions.
5
about 17 per cent of man hours worked in the manufacturing sector in the period 1995–2003.
Relative to total man hours in Norway, the share of Retail trade was about 6 per cent, while
the sum of the shares of the two manufacturing industries was 3 per cent. The empirical
analysis is carried out at the firm level, at which accounting information is available, and is
undertaken for each industry separately. Focusing on narrowly defined industries has the
advantage of reducing the heterogeneity in the sample that is due to systematic differences in
technology, factor prices and demand conditions between the different types of industrial
activities. We account for industry-wide effects in our empirical model by using period-
specific intercepts.
Five different sources of Norwegian micro data are used. Two of them are firm-level
data sets. One is based on the accounts statistics of joint stock companies, and the other
comprises structural statistics for different industrial activities.5 The three remaining data sets
contain individual-level data. These are the Register of Employers and Employees (REE), the
Pay Statements Register (PSR), and the National Education Database (NED). These
individual-level data were integrated into a common data base and then aggregated to the firm
level. After aggregation, we had unbalanced panel data sets for the following: 1,743 firms in
Machinery, with approximately 900 observations per year; 1,177 firms in Electrical
equipment, with approximately 600 observations per year; and 22,806 firms in Retail trade,
with approximately 11,500 observations per year. The model used in the paper contains one
lag and one lead. Only firms with at least three years of contiguous data and no missing
variables were included. As shown in Table 1, the final samples used for estimation are
considerably smaller than the original samples. Nevertheless, these samples represent
5 The term ‘structural statistics’ is a general term for different industrial activities statistics, such as
manufacturing statistics, building and construction statistics, wholesale and retail trade statistics, and so on.
They all have the same structure and all include information about production, input factors and investments.
A more detailed description of this and other data sources is in Data Appendix A.
6
approximately 75, 67 and 68 per cent of total man hours in Machinery, Electrical equipment,
and Retail trade, respectively.6
(Table 1 ‘Number of firms in the final sample’ about here)
2.2 Variable construction
Both the accounts statistics and the structural statistics distinguish between several groups of
physical assets. To obtain consistent definitions of asset categories for the two sources over
the sample period, all assets have been divided into two types: equipments, denoted by e,
which includes machinery, vehicles, tools, furniture, and transport equipments; and buildings
and land, denoted by b. The expected lifetimes of the physical assets in group e (of about 3–
10 years) are considerably lower than those of the assets in group b (about 40–60 years). Total
capital, it
K, is an aggregate of equipment capital, e
it
K, and building capital, b
it
K, for firm i in
period t. When aggregating the two capital types, we use a Törnqvist volume index with time-
varying weights that are common across firms in the same industry (see OECD, 2001). Thus,
we follow the practice applied by most official statistical agencies, e.g., the Bureau of Labor
Statistics. The Törnqvist index can be interpreted as a constant-returns-to-scale Cobb–
Douglas aggregation function in which the elasticity of each type of capital is estimated from
their shares of the total (annualized) cost of capital.7 An important property of the Törnqvist
volume index of capital is that it can be equivalently formulated in terms of the rental cost of
6 The corresponding numbers based on sales are 71, 65 and 66 per cent.
7 The aggregate capital stock is calculated as
(
)
(
)
1vv
tt
it be
it it
KKK
=, where /( )
bbe
ii
tititit
vRRR=+
∑∑ and, for
{,}jeb, ()
j
j
it j it
Rr K
δ
=+ . Thus,
j
it
R is the annualized cost of capital. The median depreciation rates, j
δ
, are
about 0.2 for equipment and 0.05 for buildings. These are obtained from the accounts statistics: see Raknerud,
Rønningen and Skjerpen (2003). The real rate of return, r, which we calculated from the average real return on
10-year government bonds for the period 1996–2002, is 4.2 per cent.
7
capital.8 Thus, it is straightforward to aggregate capital owned by the firm and capital
obtained through operational leasing.9 Since operational leasing contributes substantially to
firms’ capital inputs (see Data Appendix B for details), both owned and leased capital are
included in j
it
K, for
{}
bej ,. Table 2 presents an overview of the data sources used to
construct our capital measures together with the definitions and sources of the other variables
used in our study.
(Table 2 ‘Overview of variables and data sources’ about here)
Investments in the two types of capital are denoted by e
it
I
and b
it
I
. We define an
investment as any purchase of a fixed capital good that is capitalized, i.e., taken into the
firm’s balance sheet, and depreciated over its expected lifetime.10 Note that this definition of
an investment implies that sales of fixed capital goods are not subtracted. Our justification of
this is that gross purchases, rather than purchases net of sales, is the most adequate measure of
embodied technological change. In line with accounting rules, we consider repairs as
operating costs, unless they improve the quality of the asset (in which case, the value of the
asset increases relative to its ex ante expected value). In this case, the additional value is
considered an investment (see McGrattan and Schmitz, 1999 for a discussion). Financial
leasing is also considered to be investment: Under financial leasing, most of the risks and
rewards are transferred to the firm that leases, and capitalizes, the asset (see Hawkins, 1986).
The main focus of the paper is to estimate the effects of investment spikes, it
S, on some
key variables. In accordance with the literature, we define investment spikes only for
8 That is, ln ln (1 )ln constant.
be
it t it t it
KvR vR+=+ Cf. the previous footnote.
9 With an operational leasing agreement, the firm that leases an asset does not capitalize it in its balance sheet but
pays leasing costs, such as rents on buildings.
10 See Raknerud, Rønningen and Skjerpen (2003) for details of this definition.
8
equipments. One justification for this is that equipments account for the largest share of total
capital expenditure. Another argument is that equipment capital reflects the type of
investment that is often assumed to embody technological progress.11
Traditionally, the concept of a spike has been applied in two main ways. If the ratio of
equipment-investment to equipment capital, ,1
ee
it i t
IK
(hereafter, the investment ratio),
exceeds 0.2, there is an absolute spike (see Cooper, Haltiwanger and Power, 1999).
Alternatively, if ,1
ee
it i t
IK
exceeds the median investment ratio by a factor of
, which is
typically set between 1.5 and 3 (see Power, 1998), there is a relative spike, which is expressed
by:
()
,1 ,1
/median/
ee ee
it i t s is i s
IK IK
ρ
−−
>,
where the median is calculated for each firm, i, based on all the observations for that firm.
An investment spike is meant to represent a sudden and unusual burst in the firm’s
investment activity. A priori, an investment spike should fulfil the following three criteria.
First, the investment must be large, both relative to the investment history of the individual
firm and relative to the (cross-sectional) dispersion of investment ratios within the industry.
Second, the investment must constitute a rare event. Third, the spikes must account for a
disproportionate share of total industry investments. However, if we apply either the concept
of a relative spike, or the concept of an absolute spike, the identified investment spikes in our
data set are neither unusual, nor do they account for a disproportionate share of total
investment. Hence, we propose the following modified definition of an investment spike, it
S:
11 This is not to deny that spikes in building capital may be interesting for some purposes, e.g., in productivity
analysis. For example, in Retail trade, the capacities and location of shops and inventories may affect both
sales and variable factor costs (e.g., transportation costs) and thus productivity.
9
(
)
,1 ,1
1if / max ,0.20
0else
ee e
it it it
it
IK K
S
ασ
−−
⎡⎤
>
⎣⎦
=
,
where
() ( )
()
,1 ,1
|/ |
eee
it it it
KEIK
σ
ξ
−−
≡−
is the expected absolute deviation from the mean investment ratio,
()
,1
/
ee
it i t
EI K
ξ
,
considered as a function of ,1
e
it
K. The first argument in the max operator takes into account
that fluctuations in investment ratios increase as the denominator decreases; i.e.,
()
,1
e
it
K
σ
is
decreasing in ,1
e
it
K.12 For a fixed value of
α
, there is a threshold value, *
,1
e
it
K, such that for
*
,1 ,1
ee
it it
KK
−−
>, the second argument of the function,
(
)
*
,1
max ,0.20
e
it
K
ασ
, is binding.
Thus, for firms with sufficiently large equipment capital stocks, the criterion coincides with
that of a 20 per cent investment ratio.
A comparison of our combined rule,
(
)
*
,1 ,1
/max ,0.20
ee e
it it it
IK K
ασ
−−
>
, applied to our
data, and Power’s relative rule applied to US data, for different values of α and
, is
presented in Table 3. Our rule generates surprisingly similar results to those obtained by
Power (1998). However, the absolute spike criterion, which corresponds to 0
α
=, does not
12 We model
(
)
,1
e
it
K
σ
as a generalized Box–Cox transformation of equipment capital, i.e.,
() ( )
(
)
,1 0 ,1 1/
ee
it it
KK
λ
σ
γγ η λ
−1
=+ + − . When estimating this regression function for each industry, we use the
method of non-linear least squares with ,1 ˆ
|/ |
ee
it i t
IK
ξ
as the left-hand side variable, where ˆ
ξ
is the global
empirical mean of the investment ratio. We find a clear pattern: the estimate of 1
γ
is negative and highly
significant in all industries. Thus, there is a strong negative relationship between the absolute deviation of the
investment ratio of the firm and its capital stock (at the beginning of the year). That is, the fluctuations in the
investment ratios of small firms are much larger than those of large firms. Furthermore, we find that the
estimates of
λ
and
η
are close to zero, which implies a log-linear model in ,1
e
it
K
.
10
produce credible results. When 1.75
α
=, our combined rule for identifying investment spikes
classifies about 10 per cent of the observations as spikes; these observations account for one-
third of all investments. The 20 per cent threshold was binding for 4–6 per cent of the
investment observations. Our results are robust to variations in
α
within the range of 1.75 to
3.25 (cf. Table 3).
(Table 3 ‘Comparing different rules for identifying investment spikes’ about here)
Turning to the other variables (cf. Table 2), the logarithm of sales, s, is defined as the
logarithm of operating revenues. The variable m is the logarithm of materials, which are
operating expenses minus payroll expenses, depreciation, write-downs and operational
leasing. The logarithm of man hours, mh, is the logarithm of the sum of all individual man
hours worked by employees in the given firm according to the contract. The logarithm of
hourly labour costs, w, is the logarithm of all recorded labour costs in the firm, including
wages, bonuses and commissions, payroll taxes, and so on, minus the logarithm of man hours,
mh. For each industry, we distinguish between two educational groups, high-skilled and low-
skilled. High-skilled workers are those who have post-secondary education, i.e., persons who
have studied for at least 13 years. (For a description of the educational levels, see Table A1.)
The man hours worked by high-skilled persons were aggregated to the firm level and divided
by the total number of man hours worked in the given firm; this defines ssk. That is, ssk is the
share of man hours worked by high-skilled workers.
2.3 Descriptive statistics
Panel (a) of Figure 1 reports investment ratios for equipment capital at the industry level. In
each of the three industries, the firms invested more intensively at the beginning of the period
than at the end. This pattern could be influenced by the ending of the recession around 1993–
11
1994, when firms had low capital stocks following years of low investment activety. When
capital stocks increased at the firm level, investment ratios fell. Nevertheless, average
investment ratios remained high throughout the period. Panel (b) of Figure 1 shows the shares
of investment observations classified as investment spikes according to our criterion, with
1.75
α
=. We see the same declining pattern as for the investment ratios in panel (a): 8–13 per
cent of the observations are classified as investment spikes in 1996, compared with 5–7 per
cent doing so in 2002.13
(Figure 1 ‘Investment ratios and relative frequencies of spikes’ about here)
To assess the degree of lumpiness of investments, panels (a) and (b) in Figure 2
present the distributions of investment ratios classified as spikes and non-spikes, respectively,
based on our combined rule with 75.1=
α
. In addition, panel (c) shows the distributions of all
the investment ratios, 1,
/tiit KI , in our data. These distributions are similar for the three
industries. In general, investment spikes are large. Less than 10 per cent of the spikes
correspond to investment ratios smaller than 0.5. The distributions are also skewed to the
right, with a median value of about 0.8. The distributions of all the investment ratios (see
panel (c)) are asymmetric and have a tail similar to that of the exponential distribution.
Investments of zero occur quite often: about 22 per cent of the investment observations in
each of the two manufacturing industries and 26 per cent of those in Retail trade are zeros.
(Figure 2 ‘Distribution of investment ratios’ about here)
The panels of Figure 3 show the means of some key variables in the different
industries. Note that the two manufacturing industries consist, on average, of larger firms (in
13 Up to 33, 29 and 24 per cent of the firms in Machinery, Electrical equipment and Retail trade, respectively,
experienced at least one spike during the period 1996–2002.
12
terms of man hours) than does Retail trade.14 The average hourly wage in manufacturing is
higher than that in Retail trade, while the growth rates of average hourly wage are similar
between the three industries (see panels (a) and (b)). Electrical equipment can be
characterised as a high-tech industry, in which human capital is important. This is confirmed
by panel (c) of Figure 3, which shows that the share of man hours worked by high-skilled
workers in Electrical equipment is more than twice as high as the shares in the two other
industries. The share of man hours worked by high-skilled workers increased slowly between
1996 and 2002 in Electrical equipment, but was quite stable over time in the other two
industries.
(Figure 3 ‘The means of variables in different industries over time’ about here).
Labour productivity, measured as sales per man hour, exhibited an upward trend
during 1996–2002 (see panel (d)). Labour productivity is much higher in Retail trade than in
the two manufacturing industries. This reflects greater materials intensity in Retail trade (see
panel (e)) and does not mean that the efficiency of the workers is highest in Retail trade. It is
not appropriate to compare labour productivity across industries with different materials
intensities. Note also that the two manufacturing industries are more equipment capital
intensive than is Retail trade (see panel (f)). However, the growth rates of average capital
intensity in the three industries are similar.
3. Methodology
We are interested in studying how the performance of firms, measured by a vector of response
variables, it
X
, evolves over time, before, during and after the occurrence of an investment
14 Similar differences are found when we measure firm size with regard to capital.
13
spike. We first define a vector of covariates, it
Z, which identifies the position of the firm in a
‘window’ of observations around the spike. Let
s
tart
i
T and end
i
T denote the first and last years
in which firm i is included in the sample. We define it
Z as follows:
()
()
()
1
2
31
412
1
11
≤≤
−≤
⎡⎤
⎡⎤
⎢⎥
⎢⎥
⎢⎥
⎢⎥
==
⎢⎥
⎢⎥
⎢⎥
⎢⎥ −−
⎢⎥
⎢⎥
⎣⎦
⎣⎦
start end
ii
is
TsT
i
,it it
it ,it it i,t
,it it i ,t s t is
max S
Z
ZS
ZZSS
ZSSmaxS
The first component of it
Z
, 1i
Z
, is an indicator of whether the firm experiences at least
one investment spike during the period ,
s
tart end
ii
TT
. The second component, 2,it
Z
, is an
indicator of a spike in year t, while the third component, 3,it
Z
, is an indicator of a spike in
year 1t but not in year t. Finally, 4,it
Z
is an indicator of whether there was an investment
spike during the period ,2
start
i
Tt
⎡⎤
⎣⎦
but not in year t or year 1t
. This last covariate is used
to identify possible shifts in the average level of it
X
after the spike, relative to its normal
level before the spike. Note that if there is a multi-year spike, i.e., if 1
,2 =itit SZ for a
consecutive sequence of years, 0
,3
=
it
Z until one year after the last year in this sequence,
while 0
,4 =
it
Z until two years after the last year in this sequence.
The response variables in the vector it
X
are as follows:
()
,,, ,, '
it it it it it it it
X
smwsskkmh=.
We investigate the co-movements of the elements of it
X
as functions of the covariates, it
Z
.
For this purpose, we specify the following simple random effects model:
14
4
11 ,
2, , 1,...,
μβ β
=
=++ + + = +
s
tart start end
it i t i k k it it i i i
k
X
uZZetTTT,
where i
u is a 6×1 vector of random effects, with a mean of zero and an unrestricted
covariance matrix, t
μ
is a vector of fixed time-specific intercepts common to all firms in the
industry, 14
,..,
β
β
are four 6×1 vectors of regression parameters that describe the relationships
between it
X
and 1i
Z
, 2,it
Z
, 3,it
Z
and 4,it
Z
, and it
e is a vector of idiosyncratic error terms with
an unrestricted covariance matrix.
For the group of firms that experience no spikes, the pattern of it
X
over time has a
simple two-way structure, fluctuating randomly around it
u
μ
+
, where the common movement
is given by t
μ
. By contrast, firms that experience spikes, i.e., firms with 1
1=
i
Z, may differ
systematically from other firms, both before, during and after the spike. By assumption, the
random effect, i
u, is independent of the dummy variables ititi ZZZ ,3,21 ,, and it
Z,4 . Note that
1
β
is the (common) vector of fixed effects for firms with at least one spike, relative to firms
that experienced no spikes during the observation period (i.e., the reference category).
Because the spikes should account for a disproportionately large share of aggregate
investment, one would expect that large firms are overrepresented among firms with spikes.
That is, the components of 1
β
corresponding to kms ,, and mh should be positive. If a spike
occurs in year t, this is accompanied by a shift in it
X
equal to 2
β
, relative to the years before
the spike. In the year just after a spike, there is a shift equal to 3
β
. The impact of a spike in a
subsequent year is 4
β
. Thus, 4
β
can be interpreted as the ‘long-run’ effect on it
X
of the
spike, relative to the normal level of it
X
before the spike.
15
Although our model is similar to that of Sakellaris (2004), there are differences. First,
our approach allows investment spikes to have persistent effects. This is because 4
β
is not
constrained to zero. By contrast, Sakellaris (2004) forces the effects of lumpy investments (in
year t) to vanish by year 2t+. Furthermore, we estimate the equations simultaneously within
a Seemingly Unrelated Regression Equations (SURE) system; i.e., we do not estimate an
equation for each of the components of it
X
separately. This makes estimation more efficient
by exploiting the fact that firms’ gross error terms, iit
ue
+
, are correlated over time because of
the firm-specific random variable, i
u (cf. Avery (1977) and Baltagi (1980), who address this
issue within a feasible GLS framework in the context of a balanced panel). The model is
estimated separately for each of the three industries by using the method of maximum
likelihood.15
4. Empirical results
Table 4 reports the estimated values of the parameter vectors, k
β
, for Machinery, Electrical
equipment and Retail trade for the model described in the previous section. We use the
notation ,kj
β
, in which the second subscript denotes an element in the vector X; e.g., ,ks
β
denotes the sales component, ,km
β
denotes the materials component, and so on (see Table 4,
column 1). Furthermore, ˆk
β
denotes the maximum likelihood estimate of k
β
. For the
components of it
X that are measured on the log scale, the corresponding k
β
components can
be interpreted as relative changes.
(Table 4 ‘Estimates of the parameter vectors k
β
’ about here)
15 The computer algorithm is written in GAUSS.
16
Figures 4, 5 and 6 illustrate the results of Table 4 by showing the development of a
representative firm’s response values before, during and after the occurrence of an investment
spike. The vertical axis measures the average difference between firms without spikes and
firms with spikes over a sequence of four periods. On the horizontal axis, 1]t<− represents
all years before the spike, t represents the year in which the spike occurred, 1t+ is the year
following the spike, and [2t+> corresponds to two or more years after the spike. The graphs
show the average levels of it
X in these four periods; i.e., 1
β
, 12
β
β
+
, 13
β
β
+ and 14
β
β
+
,
respectively.
(Figure 4 ‘Firms’ responses to investment spikes – Machinery’ about here)
(Figure 5 ‘Firms’ responses to investment spikes – Electrical equipment’ about here)
(Figure 6 ‘Firms’ responses to investment spikes – Retail trade’ about here)
According to 1
ˆ
β
, in all three industries, firms that experience one or more spikes have,
on average, significantly higher levels of (log) sales, (log) materials, (log) man hours and
(log) stock of capital than do firms without spikes. This could be because our definition of a
spike implies that the spike threshold declines with the level of the equipment capital stock.16
The immediate effect of an investment spike is revealed by the estimates of 2
β
. The
estimated coefficient of capital, k,2
β
, implies that, for Machinery, the estimated relative
growth in capital from t – 1 to t is 0.53. For Electrical equipment and Retail trade, the
corresponding estimates are 0.40 and 0.33, respectively. Recall from Table 3 that spikes
16 Nilsen and Schiantarelli (2003) found significant differences in the investment patterns of small and large
firms and plants, with more frequent episodes of inactivity and lumpier investment for smaller units.
17
account for 35 per cent of all investment recorded in the sample. Lumpy investment implies
that firms concentrate their investments in short periods of time. This is consistent with the
existence of non-convex adjustment costs for capital caused by either fixed adjustment costs
or indivisibilities. The estimated components of 2
β
corresponding to s, m, k and mh are lower
for Retail trade than for the two manufacturing industries. This indicates that non-convexities
in adjustment costs are less important in Retail trade. The effect of an investment spike in the
year after the spike is represented by 3
β
. In Machinery, the estimated change in the capital
stock between t and t + 1 is negative; i.e., 3, 2,
ˆˆ
kk
β
β
<, although the decrease is moderate. In
the other industries, the effect of the spike is virtually the same in t and t + 1. This result is
consistent with the findings of Sakellaris (2004); i.e., that lumpy capital adjustments are
followed by smooth adjustments. The estimates of k,3
β
are slightly lower then the estimates
of k,2
β
in all the three industries: k,3
ˆ
β
is smaller in Retail trade (0.29) than in Machinery and
Electrical equipment (0.46 and 0.38, respectively).
The estimates of 4,k
β
imply that the relative changes in the capital stock from year
1t (just before the spike) to [ 2t+> (two or more years after the spike) are positive and
highly significant for all three industries. This means that the capital stock remains at the new
higher level after the investment spike. Moreover, the estimated effects are similar in the three
industries, although the estimate in Retail trade (0.24) is below those in the two
manufacturing industries (0.30 and 0.34). The development of the log of capital intensity
(capital per man hour) is depicted in Figures 4–6 (in the upper panels). The growth rates of
capital intensity from t – 1 to [2t+>
are 0.18, 0.17 and 0.15 in Machinery, Electrical
equipment and Retail trade, respectively. Thus, investment spikes are accompanied by similar
‘long-run’ increases in capital intensity in all three industries.
18
Turning to sales, we find that the increase in log sales from period t – 1 to t is 0.17,
0.22 and 0.08 in Machinery, Electrical equipment and Retail trade, respectively. The
estimates of 4,
s
β
in Table 4 show that, two or more years after the spike, the relative increase
in sales is about 10 per cent in Machinery and Retail trade, and about 20 per cent in Electrical
equipment. Thus, the capital stock grows at a higher rate than do sales.
The growth patterns for materials and man hours are similar to that of sales. That is,
the changes in sales, man hours and materials are almost proportional, although the growth
rate of about 20 per cent two years after the spike for Electrical equipment exceeds that for the
other industries (about 10 per cent). Adjusting labour seems as costless as adjusting materials
and easier than adjusting the capital stock. The observed pattern of factor adjustments is not
consistent with the traditional assumptions of homothetic production technology and (strictly)
convex adjustment costs, with technological change driven by Hicks-neutral innovations. Our
findings indicate instead that firms face non-convex capital-adjustment costs.
In Figures 4–6 (lower panels), we present our results for labour productivity, skill
composition and wages. Note that the skill composition, measured as the share of man hours
worked by high-skilled employees, is fairly constant.17 This may be because investments
classified as spikes stem from technological shocks only to a limited degree. It has been found
that such technological changes, particularly computerization, affect the organization of work
and the composition of the work force.18 That there is no evidence in our study that
investment spikes are associated with changes in the composition of the workforce at the
micro level may indicate that technological change accompanies steady investment over time
17 The findings of Sakellaris (2004) are similar.
18 See, for instance, Autor, Levy and Murnane (2003), and Berman, Bound and Machin (1998). See also Machin
(2003) for a review of the literature on changes in skill composition as a response to technological change.
19
rather than investment spikes. The lack of change in the composition of the work force is also
reflected in average wages being unaffected by investment spikes in all three industries.
General technological upgrading and increased productivity is accounted for by the
fixed time-specific effects. Thus, our estimates measure the effects of investment spikes
around these time trends and do not contradict the finding of increased productivity over time
illustrated in Figure 4. We find evidence that labour productivity changes during an
investment spike. Power (1998) finds that productivity growth decreases as the number of
years since the last investment spike increases.19 However, as she points out “the quantitative
magnitudes are small, and most of the growth rate coefficients are not statistically significant”
(p. 307). Huggett and Ospina (2001) find that a fall in productivity growth is associated with
large equipment investments.
In summary, our findings of small and insignificant changes in productivity associated
with investment spikes are consistent with several international studies based on the
estimation of econometric models using firm- or plant-level data. These studies also find
evidence of unchanged skill compositions and wages. This indicates that productivity
improvements are related more to learning-by-doing than to instantaneous technological
changes through investment spikes. A similar conclusion is reached by Bessen (2000), who
finds that productivity at new plants improves as a result of learning-by-doing, which, unlike
an investment spike, takes place smoothly.
Finally, we investigate whether our results attach too much weight to small firms,
given that firms are not weighted by their relative contributions to total industry output when
estimating the empirical model. They may do if small and large firms respond differently to
investment spikes. In that case, it would also be difficult to compare our results with those of
19 See Sakellaris (2004) for related findings using US manufacturing data.
20
the existing literature, which deals almost exclusively with large firms. To examine this
question empirically, we re-estimated our model by excluding firms with less than 50,000
man hours (about 25 full-time employees). While this substantially reduced our sample of
firms, the estimates of the parameter vectors, 23
,
β
β
and 4
β
not statistically different from
those obtained using the full sample. We conclude that our results are not artefacts of certain
‘small business’ anomalies. On the contrary, small and large firms seem to respond similarly
to investment spikes.
5. Conclusions
In this paper, we used a new and rich matched employer–employee data set from Norway for
two manufacturing industries and one service industry to describe changes in the demand for
capital and labour, changes in labour productivity and changes in the skill composition of the
labour before, during, and after an investment spike. Traditional definitions of an investment
spike capture neither sudden nor unusual bursts in investment activity when applied to a
representative sample of firms. Hence, we proposed a modified definition of an investment
spike, which is more suitable for samples comprising small and large firms. Under the
modified definition, the threshold value for an investment spike increases with the volatility
of the investment ratio as a function of the capital stock (immediately before the investment).
The threshold is negatively related to the size of the firm.
By applying our definition of an investment spike, we obtained a number of important
findings. First, spikes account for a large share of aggregate industry investment. Second,
investment spikes are accompanied by almost proportional increases in sales, materials and
man hours. Third, two or more years after the spike, there is substantial capital deepening, but
labour productivity is relatively unaffected. Fourth, the growth patterns of materials and man
hours are similar and much smoother than are those for capital. In addition, the observed
21
patterns of factor adjustment are not consistent with the assumptions of homothetic
production technology and (strictly) convex adjustment costs; rather, they indicate the
presence of non-convexities in capital-adjustment costs.
The changes in labour productivity associated with investment spikes are small. This
may be because investment spikes temporarily disrupt production. The small changes in
productivity may indicate that general technological upgrading and increased productivity at
the industry level are explained by trend factors, rather than by lumpy investment behaviour.
We also found that the skill composition is not affected by investment spikes. This suggests
that productivity improvements are related more to learning-by-doing than to instantaneous
technological changes through investment spikes. This finding is consistent with results often
obtained in related empirical studies.
We found interesting differences between the two manufacturing industries and the
service industry. Capital adjustments are smoother in the service industry than in the two
manufacturing industries. This suggests that the structure of capital-adjustment costs differs
between the capital-intensive manufacturing industries and the relatively labour-intensive
Retail industry. The responses of sales and input factors (other than capital) to lumpy
investments indicate that non-convex adjustment costs are less important in Retail trade than
in the manufacturing industries.
22
References
Abel, A.B. and J.C. Eberly (1998): The Mix and Scale of Factors with Irreversibility and
Fixed Costs of Investment. Carnegie Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 48,
101–135.
Abel, A.B. and J.C. Eberly (2002): Investment and q with Fixed Costs: An Empirical
Analysis, mimeo. The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, April.
Abowd, J.M. and F. Kramarz (2003): The Cost of Hiring and Separations. Labour Economics,
10(5), 499–530.
Autor, D.H., F. Levy and R.J. Murnane (2003): The Skill Content of Recent Technological
Change: An Empirical Exploration. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4), 1279–
1333.
Avery, R.B. (1977): Error Components and Seemingly Unrelated Regressions. Econometrica,
45(1), 199–209.
Baltagi, B.H. (1980): On Seemingly Unrelated Regressions with Error Components.
Econometrica, 48(6), 1547–1551.
Berman, E., J. Bound and S. Machin (1998): Implications of Skill-Biased Technological
Change: International Evidence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(4), 1245–1279.
Bessen, J. (2000): Productivity Adjustments and Learning-by-Doing as Human Capital.
Working paper. Research on Innovation.
Caballero, R.J. and E.M.R.A. Engel (1999): Explaining Investment Dynamics in U.S.
Manufacturing: A Generalized (S, s) Approach. Econometrica, 67(4), 783–826.
Carlsson, M. and S. Laséen (2005): Capital Adjustment Patterns in Swedish Manufacturing
Firms: What Model do They Suggest? Economic Journal, 115, 969–986.
Cooper, R., J. Haltiwanger and L. Power (1999): Machine Replacement and the Business
Cycle: Lumps and Bumps. American Economic Review, 89(4), 921–946.
Doms, M. and T. Dunne (1998): Capital Adjustment Patterns in Manufacturing Plants, Review
of Economic Dynamics, 1(2), 409–429.
Hamermesh, D.S. (1989): Labor Demand and the Structure of Adjustment Costs. American
Economic Review, 79(4), 674–689.
Hamermesh, D.S. and G.A. Pfann (1996): Adjustment Costs in Factor Demand. Journal of
Economic Literature, 34(3), 1264–1292.
Hawkins, D.F. (1986): Corporate financial reporting and analysis. Text and cases. The
Robert. N. Anthony/Willard J. Graham Series in Accounting, Homewood: Irwin.
Huggett, M. and S. Ospina (2001): Does Productivity Growth Fall after the Adoption of New
Technology? Journal of Monetary Economics, 48(1), 173–195.
23
Jensen, J.B, R.H. McGuckin and K.J. Stiroh (2001): The Impact of Vintage and Survival on
Productivity: Evidence from Cohorts of U.S. Manufacturing Plants. Review of
Economics and Statistics, 83(2), 323–332.
Letterie, W. and G.A. Pfann (2005): Non-linearities in the Expansion of Capital Stock.
Mimeo, BIRC, Faculty of Economics and Business Administration, Maastricht
University.
Letterie, W., G.A. Pfann and J.M. Polder (2004): Factor Adjustment Spikes and Interrelation:
An Empirical Investigation. Economics Letters, 85(2), 145–150.
Machin, S. (2003): Skill-Biased Technical Change in the New Economy. In D. Jones (Ed.):
New Economy Handbook. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
McGrattan, E.R. and J.A. Schmitz Jr. (1999): Maintenance and Repair: Too Big to Ignore.
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 23(4), 2–13.
Nadiri, M.I. and S. Rosen (1969): Interrelated Factor Demand Functions. American Economic
Review, 59(4), 457–471.
Nilsen, Ø.A., K.G. Salvanes and F. Schiantarelli (2003): Employment Adjustment, the
Structure of Adjustment Costs, and Plant Size. Discussion Paper No. 920, IZA–Bonn.
Nilsen, Ø. A. and F. Schiantarelli (2003): Zeros and Lumps in Investment: Empirical
Evidence on Irreversibilities and Nonconvexities. Review of Economics and Statistics,
85(4), 1021–1037.
OECD (2001): Measurement of capital stocks, consumption of fixed capital and capital
services. OECD manual 131 (Paris and Washington).
Power, L. (1998): The Missing Link: Technology, Investment, and Productivity. Review of
Economics and Statistics, 80(2), 300–313.
Raknerud, A., D. Rønningen and T. Skjerpen (2003): A Method for Improved Capital
Measurement by Combining Accounts and Firm Investment. Discussion paper 365,
Oslo: Statistics Norway.
Rota, P. (1995): Dynamic Labour Demand with Lumpy and Kinked Adjustment Costs.
Mimeo. London: University College.
Sakellaris, P. (2004): Patterns of Plant Adjustment. Journal of Monetary Economics, 51(2),
425–450.
Statistics Norway (1989): Norwegian Standard Classification of Education. Revised version.
Oslo/Kongsvinger.
Statistics Norway (2001): Accounts statistics. Official Statistics of Norway D 297.
Oslo/Kongsvinger.
24
Data Appendix
A. Detailed data description
As mentioned above, the empirical analysis is carried out at the firm level. In the accounts
statistics, a firm is defined as “the smallest legal unit comprising all economic activities
engaged in by one and the same owner” and corresponds in general to the concept of a
company (Statistics Norway, 2001). A firm can consist of one or more establishments. The
establishment is the geographically local unit conducting economic activity within an industry
class. Another unit is the consolidated group, which consists of a parent company and one or
more subsidiaries. Both the parent company and the subsidiaries are firms as defined here.
All joint-stock companies in Norway are obliged to publish company accounts every
year. The accounts statistics contain information obtained from the income statements and
balance sheets of joint-stock companies, in particular, the information about the book values
of a firm’s tangible fixed assets at the end of a year, their depreciation and write-downs.
However, they do not contain data on purchases of tangible fixed assets, since data on
investments do not have a specific standard in the annual report. Instead, these are provided in
the notes on the annual report and are hence not included in the statistics. The accounts
statistics in their present version are available from 1993. Currently, the most recent data are
for 2003.
The structural statistics are organized according to the NACE standard.20 They are
based on General Trading Statements, which are given in an appendix to the tax return. The
EU’s structural regulations require statistics at the firm level. However, out of consideration
to Norwegian users, local kind-of-activity units statistics have been compiled for
20 The Standard Industrial Classification (SN2002) in Statistics Norway is based on the EU standard NACE Rev.
1.1.
25
employment, turnover, the compensation of employees and gross investments. Since the
manufacturing statistics are available at the firm level only from 1996, data at the plant level
aggregated to the firm level were used for earlier years. In addition to the variables that are
also included in the accounts statistics, the structural statistics contain data about purchases of
tangible fixed assets and operational leasing. These data were matched with the data from the
accounts statistics. For the firm identification number, we use the registration number given to
the firm in the Register of Enterprises, one of the Brønnøysund registers,21 which is operative
from 1995.
The Register of Employers and Employees (REE) contains information obtained from
employers. All employers are obliged to send information to the REE about each individual
employee’s contract start and end, working hours, overtime and occupation. An exception is
made only if a person works less than four hours per week in a given establishment and/or is
employed for less than six days. In addition, this register contains identification numbers for
the firm, the establishment and the employee. These data are available for the period 1995–
2004.
The Pay Statements Register (PSR) contains annual data obtained from the Norwegian
Internal Revenue Service. This register provides information on wages, bonuses and
commissions, variable additional allowances and deductions, received by wage earners in
each establishment. Moreover, this data set includes some demographic information, for
example, regarding age. Merging these data with the REE by using personal identification
numbers yields information about the occupations and earnings of wage earners in different
establishments from 1995 to 2004. This can easily be aggregated to the firm level.
21 See www.brreg.no.
26
The National Education Database (NED) gathers all individually based statistics on
education from primary to tertiary education and has been provided by Statistics Norway
since 1970. We use this data set to identify the duration of education. For this purpose, we
utilize the first digit of the NUS variable. This variable is constructed on the basis of the
Norwegian standard classification of education and is a six-digit number, the leading digit of
which is the code of the educational level of the person. According to the Norwegian standard
classification of education (NUS89),22 there are nine educational levels in addition to the
major group for “unspecified length of education”. The educational levels are given in Table
A1.
(Table A1 ‘Educational levels’ about here)
B. Operational leasing
Figure B1 shows operational leasing costs as a share of total (annualized) costs of capital. In
the two manufacturing industries, operational leasing costs constituted around 40 per cent of
the total costs of building capital in 1996, and 60–70 per cent in 2002. In Retail trade, this
share is over 90 per cent for the whole period. For equipment capital, operational leasing costs
represent a substantial share of the total costs of capital. For example, in 1996, this share was
around 40 per cent in both manufacturing industries and was about 30 per cent in Retail trade.
Figure B1 shows why leasing should be included in the capital input measure, regardless of
whether the focus is on equipment capital or aggregate, total capital. In particular, leasing
considerably smooths capital adjustments. This is confirmed by the distribution of firm-level
annual growth rates of capital (not shown), which is much less skewed to the right than if
22 A new version of the Norwegian standard classification of education has been available since 2000
(NUS2000). We used the definitions of educational levels from the old version (Statistics Norway, 1989, p.
20), because the individuals incorporated in our data completed their education under the old educational
system.
27
(operational) leasing had been excluded from the capital measure, as in, e.g., Carlsson and
Laséen (2005).
(Figure B1 ‘Operational leasing’ about here)
28
Table 1. Number of firms in the final sample
Year Machinery Electrical equipment Retail trade
1996 500 300 6,958
1997 531 336 7,618
1998 538 347 7,893
1999 544 344 8,039
2000 548 353 8,026
2001 567 367 8,122
2002 560 378 8,108
Total number 883 577 12,661
29
Table 2. Overview of variables and data sources
Variable Interpretation Data source(s)
j
K capital stock a,b of type j, {,}jeb
accounts statistics, structural
statistics
j
I purchases of capital a of type j, {,}jeb
structural statistics
s log of sales a accounts statistics
m log of materials a accounts statistics
mh log of man hours c REE
w log of hourly labour costs a,c REE, PSR, accounts statistics
ssk share of man hours worked by high-skilled
persons c REE, PSR, NED
Derived variables:
k log of total capital, K
lp log of labour productivity:
s
mh
ki log of capital intensity: kmh
mi log of materials intensity: mmh
S Investment spike indicator
a The variable is deflated by the consumer price index. The units of measurement are 1000
NOK in 1995 prices.
b Capital stock at the end of the year
c Man hours according to labour contracts
30
Table 3. Comparing different rules for identifying investment spikes
Power’s relative rule. US data Our combined rule. Norwegian data
ρ
Share of #
observations Share of
total
investment
α
Share of #
observations Share of
total
investment
0 22 39
1.75 14 46 1.75 9 35
2.50 8 31 2.50 5 30
3.25 5 26 3.25 4 27
31
Table 4. Estimates of the parameter vectors
β
k
Parameter estimates (standard errors)
1
β
2
β
3
β
4
β
Machinery
s 0.90 (0.10) 0.17 (0.02) 0.13 (0.03) 0.12 (0.03)
m 0.89 (0.11) 0.16 (0.03) 0.10 (0.03) 0.10 (0.03)
w 0.04 (0.02) 0.03 (0.01) 0.01 (0.02) 0.00 (0.02)
ssk 0.00 (0.01) –0.01 (0.00) –0.01 (0.01) –0.01 (0.01)
k 0.90 (0.10) 0.53 (0.04) 0.46 (0.04) 0.30 (0.05)
mh 0.87 (0.10) 0.11 (0.02) 0.15 (0.02) 0.12 (0.02)
Electrical equipment
s 0.67 (0.14) 0.22 (0.03) 0.24 (0.03) 0.21 (0.03)
m 0.70 (0.15) 0.23 (0.03) 0.27 (0.04) 0.23 (0.04)
w 0.04 (0.03) 0.04 (0.02) 0.02 (0.02) 0.02 (0.02)
ssk 0.02 (0.02) 0.01 (0.01) 0.00 (0.01) 0.01 (0.01)
k 0.56 (0.14) 0.40 (0.05) 0.38 (0.05) 0.34 (0.06)
mh 0.58 (0.12) 0.12 (0.02) 0.19 (0.03) 0.17 (0.03)
Retail trade
s 0.73 (0.07) 0.08 (0.01) 0.11 (0.02) 0.10 (0.02)
m 0.74 (0.07) 0.09 (0.01) 0.10 (0.02) 0.09 (0.02)
w 0.12 (0.02) 0.02 (0.02) 0.01 (0.01) 0.01 (0.02)
ssk 0.01 (0.01) 0.00 (0.01) 0.00 (0.01) 0.00 (0.01)
k 0.64 (0.07) 0.33 (0.03) 0.29 (0.03) 0.24 (0.03)
mh 0.53 (0.06) 0.07 (0.02) 0.11 (0.02) 0.10 (0.02)
32
Figure 1. Investment ratios and relative frequencies of spikes
(b) Share of observations classified as investment spikes
0 %
4 %
8 %
12 %
16 %
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
Machinery Electrical equipment Retail trade
(a) Investment ratio for equipment capital
0 %
15 %
30 %
45 %
60 %
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
33
Figure 2. Distribution of investment ratios
(a) Observations defined as spikes
0
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
0.25
0.3
0.35
0 0.05 0.15 0.25 0.35 0.45 0.55 0.65 0.75 0.85 0.95 1.05 1.15 1.25 1.35 1.45 1.55 1.65 1.75 1.85 1.95
Mac hinery
El. equipment
Retail trade
(b) Observations defined as non-spikes
0
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
0.25
0.3
0.35
0 0.05 0.15 0.25 0.35 0.45 0.55 0.65 0.75 0.85 0.95 1.05 1.15 1.25 1.35 1.45 1.55 1.65 1.75 1.85 1.95
Mac hinery
El. equipment
Retail trade
(c) All observations
0
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
0.25
0.3
0.35
0 0.05 0.15 0.25 0.35 0.45 0.55 0.65 0.75 0.85 0.95 1.05 1.15 1.25 1.35 1.45 1.55 1.65 1.75 1.85 1.95
Mac hiner y
El. equipment
Retail trade
34
Figure 3. The means of variables in different industries over time
(c) Mean share of man hours worked by high-
skilled workers
0 %
10 %
20 %
30 %
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
(b) Mean log hourly wage
–3.0
–2.5
–2.0
–1.5
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
(a) Mean log man hours
8.5
9.0
9.5
10.0
10.5
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
(d) Mean log labour productivity
–1.25
–1.00
–0.75
–0.50
–0.25
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
(e) Mean log materials intensity
–2.0
–1.5
–1.0
–0.5
0.0
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
(f) Mean log equipment capital intensity
–6.0
–5.5
–5.0
–4.5
–4.0
–3.5
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
Machinery Electrical equipment Retail trade
35
Figure 4: Machinery. Firm characteristics before, during and after an investment spike.
Measured as deviations from firms without spikes
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
1.2
1.4
1.6
<t-1] t t+1 [t+2>
log sales log materials log capital log hours w orked log capital intensity
-0.1
-0.05
0
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
0.25
0.3
<t-1] t t+1 [t+2>
log wage share high-s killed log labour productivity log materials intensity
36
Figure 5: Electrical equipment. Firm characteristics before, during and after an
investment spike. Measured as deviations from firms without spikes
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
1.2
1.4
1.6
<t-1] t t+1 [t+2>
log sales log materials log capital log hours w orked log capital intensity
-0.1
-0.05
0
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
0.25
0.3
<t-1] t t+1 [t+2>
log wage share high-skilled log labour productivity log materials intensity
37
Figure 6: Retail trade. Firm characteristics before, during and after an investment
spike. Measured as deviations from firms without spikes
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
1.2
1.4
1.6
<t-1] t t+1 [t+2>
log sales log materials log capital log hours w orked log capital intensity
-0.1
-0.05
0
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
0.25
0.3
<t-1] t t+1 [t+2>
log w age shar e high-skilled log labour productivity log materials intensity
38
Table A1. Educational levels in the NUS89
Tripartition of levels Level Class level
0 Under school age
Primary education 1 1st – 6th
2 7th – 9th
3 10th
Secondary education 4 11th – 12th
5 13th – 14th
6 15th – 16th
7 17th – 18th
Post-secondary education
8 19th+
9 Unspecified
39
Figure B1. The share of operational leasing costs for different types of capital
0%
25%
50%
75%
100%
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
Type e, Machinery Type e, Electrical eq. Type e, Retail trade
Type b, Machinery Type b, Electrical eq. Type b, Retail trade
... Some literature exists that studies the relationship between the increase of the firms' wealth based on investment and their business performance as revealed by productivity and growth rate [15][16][17][18][19], by employment growth [20], by sales growth [21], or by other production factors [18,22]. ...
... Some literature exists that studies the relationship between the increase of the firms' wealth based on investment and their business performance as revealed by productivity and growth rate [15][16][17][18][19], by employment growth [20], by sales growth [21], or by other production factors [18,22]. ...
Chapter
Full-text available
This paper, which is derived from comprehensive research based on the microeconomic theory of investment and the theoretical approach to measuring the financial performance of firms, presents a conceptual model to define, assess, and measure the impact of corporate investment on business performance. In terms of investment, the focus falls only on tangible fixed assets, whereas business performance is defined solely as performance measured by the relevant financial indicators. Several research hypotheses are tested on an extensive sample of Slovenian firms. A statistically significant correlation between investment and financial performance indicators is found for the period 2000–2017. This correlation is particularly strong with net sales revenues, added value, and operating cash flow (EBITDA). Since the global financial crisis occurring at the break of the last decade is also included in the designated period, the creditless growth of investment together with the simultaneous deleveraging that took place after the financial crisis is explored and compared with the growth of selected financial performance indicators.
... Adapting to the French context the empirical approach developed in Acemoglu and Restrepo (2021), we identify relevant investment episodes in AI and automation through purchases of selected categories of imported capital goods. As shown in Domini et al. (2021), acquisitions of such goods display the typical spiky nature that characterizes investment in capital goods (Nilsen et al., 2009;Grazzi et al., 2016). ...
... More restrictive spike definition We also test the robustness of our findings to setting a size threshold for identifying an automation/AI spike, following the investment spike literature (Nilsen et al., 2009;Grazzi et al., 2016). In our main analysis, we define a spike as the main episode of imports of such technologies, without any restrictions. ...
Preprint
Full-text available
This paper investigates the impact of investment in automation-and AI-related goods on within-firm wage inequality in the French economy during the period 2002-2017. We document that most of wage inequality in France is accounted for by differences among workers belonging to the same firm, rather than by differences between sectors, firms, and occupations. Using an event-study approach on a sample of firms importing automation and AI-related goods, we find that spike events related to the adoption of automation-or AI-related capital goods are not followed by an increase in within-firm wage nor in gender inequality. Instead, wages increase by 1% three years after the events at different percentiles of the distribution. Our findings are not linked to a rent-sharing behavior of firms obtaining productivity gains from automation or AI adoption. Instead, if the wage gains do not differ across workers along the wage distribution, worker heterogeneity is still present. Indeed, aligned with the framework in Abowd et al. (1999b), most of the overall wage increase is due to the hiring of new employees. This adds to previous findings showing picture of a 'labor friendly' effect of the latest wave of new technologies within adopting firms.
... Adapting to the French context the empirical approach developed in Acemoglu and Restrepo (2021), we identify relevant investment episodes in AI and automation through purchases of selected categories of imported capital goods. As shown in Domini et al. (2021), acquisitions of such goods display the typical spiky nature that characterizes investment in capital goods (Nilsen et al., 2009;Grazzi et al., 2016). ...
... More restrictive spike definition We also test the robustness of our findings to setting a size threshold for identifying an automation/AI spike, following the investment spike literature (Nilsen et al., 2009;Grazzi et al., 2016). In our main analysis, we define a spike as the main episode of imports of such technologies, without any restrictions. ...
... Tout d'abord, l'article de Eberly et al. (2012) (Nilsen et Schiantarelli, 2003). Ces deux régimes peuvent être identifiés soit par une méthode qui isole les pics (Cooper et al., 1999 ;Nilsen et Schiantarelli, 2003 ;Nilsen et al., 2009) soit en estimant un modèle avec changement de régime (Letterie et Pfann, 2007) 3 . Il est inté ressant de noter que les deux épisodes d'investissement les plus impor tants dans la série temporelle d'un établissement sont souvent observés lors de deux années consécutives (Abel et Eberly, 1996 ;Doms et Dunne, 1998). ...
... Plus précisément, la première approche s'effectue soit en tenant compte de l'impor tance de l'épisode relativement à la série temporelle de l'investissement de chaque entreprise ou établissement productif, soit par le fait que le taux d'investissement (c'estàdire normalisé par le capital) dépasse un seuil prédéterminé. La première méthodologie a été présentée parDoms et Dunne (1998) alors que plusieurs versions de la deuxième approche ont été introduites parPower (1998),Cooper et al. (1999),Nilsen et al. (2009) et Grazzi et al. (2013. ...
Article
Full-text available
Cette étude questionne le processus d’investissement des entreprises du secteur manufacturier en France entre 1996 et 2007. Nous confirmons la présence de pics d’investissements mais identifions aussi une certaine continuité des taux d’investissement dans le temps, indiquée par un coefficient d’autocorrélation relativement faible mais très persistant. En effet, le taux d’investissement est significativement et positivement corrélé avec ses valeurs passées jusqu’à dix ans d’écart. De plus, une estimation du coefficient d’autorégression montre que le taux d’investissement est partiellement expliqué par sa valeur passée. Ces résultats s’expliquent notamment par l’indivisibilité du capital, qui requiert plusieurs épisodes d’investissement pour être totalement intégré dans le fonctionnement de l’entreprise.
... He employs the model based on a Generalised Leontief (GL) cost function, which proposes that the most promising cost function is a measure used to relate capital investment and capacity utilisation to price change and labour productivity in an integral framework. Øivind A. Nilsen et al. (2009) find that the labour productivity changes that are associated with the investment spikes are small; in turn, this indicates that productivity improvements are not related to instantaneous technological changes through investment spikes. Matilde Bini, Leopoldo Nascia, and Alessandro Zeli (2014) employ a multilevel regression model to detect the relation between firms' current level of labour productivity and a set of indicators, including tangible and intangible investments. ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper analyses the link between the tangible investment rate and apparent labour productivity in the European manufacturing industry. The research results show a negative and opposite relation between apparent labour productivity and investment rate, that is, changes in apparent labour productivity cause changes in investment in tangible assets but not vice versa. The findings do not show any significant differences among European countries when the relation between apparent labour productivity and investment rate is analysed. However, when analysing the gross investment in tangible goods, as well as in machinery and equipment, period effects are observed. A crisis and economic slowdown reduce investment in tangible capital. Meanwhile, the growth of the economy spurs more investment. The negative correlation between apparent labour productivity and investment rate indicates that investment in tangible assets is ineffective. An analysis on individual countries is required in order to reach more nuanced conclusions.
Article
The stagnation of investments and its causes have attracted great attention in the recent economic debate. In this paper, we show that during the Great Recession, the flattening of the capital formation rate at the firm level is not due to lower average propensity to invest. Rather, it is the result of growing heterogeneity of choices among firms. While a subset of firms is oriented towards increasing investments, another group substantially divest. The result is a polarization of conducts that tend to cancel each other out, resulting in a flattening of aggregate investment. We argue that this asymmetry in firm’s decisions depends on two main factors. The first one is the diversity of corporate strategies, which firms have developed in the past. The second driver is managerial discretion, that plays an important role in the adoption of specific investment/divestment trajectories when faced with a recession. The results of our empirical analysis provide strong support for our hypotheses: after controlling for contextual and firm-specific structural, financial and demographic variables, corporate strategies and managerial discretion in the allocation of liquid assets explain large part of the heterogeneity in investment decisions during the recession. Policy implications are discussed.
Article
The literature has found that interaction effects exist between capital and labour in the adjustment cost function of firms, but there is no consensus on whether these costs are positive or negative. Using a dynamic firm structural model where capital is broken up into buildings and machinery & equipment, this paper finds that part of this ambiguity can be directly tied to capital heterogeneity. Firms are found to enjoy negative costs between labour and machinery & equipment and between labour and buildings, while they suffer from positive costs between buildings and machinery & equipment. When compared to a model with only capital and labour, the interaction cost is found to be positive, highlighting how neglecting capital heterogeneity can lead to a spurious result on its sign. I evaluate the importance of these interactions by simulating three shocks: an increase in uncertainty, an increase in the interest rate, and an increase in the wage rate. I uncover large differences in the steady state dynamics of each input that are directly attributable to the interaction effects in the adjustment cost function.
Article
This paper investigates the impact of investment in automation- and AI-related goods on within-firm wage inequality in the French economy during the 2002–2017 period. We document that most wage inequality in France is accounted for by differences among workers belonging to the same firm rather than by differences between sectors, firms, and occupations. Using an event-study approach on a sample of firms importing automation- and AI-related goods, we find that spike events related to the adoption of automation- and AI-related capital goods are not followed by an increase in within-firm wage inequality or in gender wage inequality. Instead, wages increase by 1% three years after the events at different percentiles of the distribution. Our findings are not linked to the rent-sharing behavior of firms obtaining productivity gains from automation and AI adoption. Instead, if wage gains do not differ across workers along the wage distribution, worker heterogeneity will still be present. Indeed, in agreement with the framework in Abowd et al. (1999b), most of the overall wage increase is due to the hiring of new employees. This adds to previous findings presenting a picture of a ‘labor friendly’ effect of the latest wave of new technologies within adopting firms.
Chapter
We study firm-level expansionary investment activities in both equipment and buildings—the so-called investment spikes. Our identification strategy decomposes firm investment spikes into three streams: a spike in equipment only, buildings only, or a simultaneous spike. Empirically, we find that the timing and size of investment in equipment and buildings are not independent. Firms conducting a simultaneous spike enhance firm scale more than in the case of a spike in equipment or buildings alone. Employment growth occurs when a firm builds structures. Investment in equipment affects the optimal input mix and high productivity in equipment and buildings provides investment timing signals. In low-tech sectors firm production growth depends on investment in buildings. In contrast, a necessary condition for firms in high-tech sectors to grow their production is investment in equipment.
Article
Full-text available
This paper provides a description of the dynamic choices of manufacturing plants when they undertake rapid adjustment in output. The focus is on episodes that involve lumpy adjustment in capital or employment. I examine the behavior of variables such as capital utilization, hours per worker, overtime use, capacity utilization, materials and energy use. Finally I describe the observed patterns of productivity during those adjustment episodes and propose some hypotheses that seem to fit them. The costs associated with output adjustment seem to arise from building and destroying a particular organization of the structure of production and associated worker experience. As such they are related to learning-by-doing and investment in specific training.
Article
Full-text available
Optimal investment depends both on expected returns and the costs of acquiring and installing capital. Empirical work using q-theory has emphasized the measurement of expected returns using Tobin's q, while more recent theoretical work focuses on investment costs, particularly fixed costs and irreversibility. This paper uses panel data to estimate a model of optimal investment and disinvestment using q to measure expected returns and allowing for a general "augmented adjustment cost function "-- incorporating fixed, linear, and convex adjustment costs. The results indicate both statistically and economically important nonlinearities, potentially arising from fixed costs, in the relationship between investment/disinvestment and its determinants. These nonlinearities imply that the cross-sectional distribution of q affects aggregate investment, so that the nonlinear model predicts aggregate investment substantially more successfully than does the linear model, particularly during large cyclical fluctuations.
Article
Demand for less-skilled workers plummeted in developed countries in the 1980s. In open economies, pervasive skill-biased technological change (SBTC) can explain this decline. SBTC tends to increase the domestic supply of unskill-intensive goods by releasing less-skilled labor. The more countries experiencing a SBTC, the greater its potential to decrease the relative wages of less-skilled labor by increasing the world supply of unskill-intensive goods. We find strong evidence for pervasive SBTC in developed countries. Most industries increased the proportion of skilled workers despite generally rising or stable relative wages. Moreover, the same manufacturing industries simultaneously increased demand for skills in different countries. Many developing countries also show increased skill premiums, a pattern consistent with SBTC.
Article
We analyze the dynamics of firms' employment decisions which underlie lumpy and kinked adjustment costs. We consider a dynamic structural model in which, in each period, firms face a choice of whether to vary the labor input or to postpone the adjustment to the future. By exploiting the first order condition for optimality, we derive a semi-reduced form in which firms' intertemporal employment are defined by a standard static marginal productivity condition augmented by a forward-looking term. In this way we obtain a marginal productivity equilibrium relation which takes into account the future alternatives of adjustment or non-adjustment that firms face as the result of the presence of fixed and linear adjustment costs. Linear costs amount to 35% of average labor costs, and fixed costs are estimated to be about 3.65 times average unit labor costs.
Article
In this article, we use the structure of French labor law and the data from three linked sources to estimate the costs of hiring, separation and retirement of employees for a representative sample of French establishments matched with a representative sample of their employees. The estimates are computed using data from the Wage Structure Survey (ESS), the Workforce Movement Questionnaire (DMMO), and the Occupational Structure Survey (ESE). We show that the estimated separation costs are increasing and mildly concave functions of the number of exits and include a very large fixed component. Estimated hiring costs are much lower and those associated with short-term contracts are effectively zero. Profit maximizing French firms should adjust employment primarily through hiring changes.
Article
This paper provides a description of the dynamic choices of manufacturing plants when they undertake rapid adjustment in output. The focus is on episodes that involve lumpy adjustment in capital or employment. There is evidence that these episodes involve also smooth changes in employment or capital. I examine the behavior of variables such as capital utilization, hours per worker, capacity utilization, materials and energy use. Plants use these margins of adjustment actively and in an economically meaningful way. Additionally, I describe the observed patterns of productivity during these adjustment episodes and propose some hypotheses that seem to fit them. The level of Total Factor Productivity (TFP) drops after spikes in investment or bursts in job destruction and recovers slowly afterward. These productivity costs seem to arise from the adoption of new technologies and the ensuing learning of how to use them as well as from building and destroying a particular organization of production. Bursts of job creation are not accompanied by significant movements in TFP.
Article
A number of theoretical models of technology adoption have been proposed that imply that measured productivity growth may initially fall and then later rise after the adoption of a new technology. This paper investigates whether or not this implication is a feature of plant-level data from the Colombian manufacturing sector. We focus on technology adoption embodied in new equipment. We find evidence that the effect of a large equipment purchase is initially to reduce plant-level total factor productivity growth.
Article
When factors of production can be adjusted costlessly, the mix of factors can be considered separately from their scale. We examine factor choice and utilization when investment is irreversible and subject to a fixed cost, so that the capital stock is a quasi-fixed factor that is adjusted infrequently and by discrete amounts. We derive and analyze analytic approximations for optimal investment behavior, and show how the quasi-fixity of capital eliminates the dichotomy between factor mix and scale. We show that the quasi-fixity of capital can give rise to labor hoarding, even when labor is a purely flexible factor.