ArticlePDF Available

Do Transnational Corporations Care About Labor Standards?

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

This paper explores the relationship between foreign direct investment, or the activities of transnational corporations, and core labour standards. It discusses the channels through which labour standards may influence foreign direct investment and presents the results of an empirical test of that linkage. The results show that, contrary to the conventional wisdom that transnational corporations engage predominately in countries with low standards, higher labour standards are positively associated with foreign direct investment inflows. Concerns about "social dumping" or "a race to the bottom" on such standards appear to be mistaken. This result even holds for poor developing countries. Die Beziehung zwischen ausländischen Direktinvestitionen, das heißt die Aktivitäten internationaler Konzerne, und grundlegenden Sozialstandards werden in dem vorliegenden Beitrag untersucht. Im Mittelpunkt dabei steht zum einen eine Diskussion möglicher Wirkungskanäle zwischen Sozialstandards und ausländischen Direktinvestitionen; zum anderen eine empirische Überprüfung dieser Zusammenhänge. Die Ergebnisse zeigen, dass internationale Konzerne überwiegend in Ländern investieren, die überdurchschnittlich hohe Sozialstandards aufweisen. Befürchtungen über "soziales Dumping" oder eine wettbewerbsbedingte Verschlechterung der Standards nach unten sind demnach nicht zu erwarten. Dies gilt auch für relativ arme Entwicklungsländer.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Journal of Developing Areas, Vol. 36 (2003), No. 2, pp. 39-58
Matthias Busse
Do Transnational Corporations Care About Labor Standards?
Abstract
The paper empirically explores the relationship between foreign direct investment, or
the activities of transnational corporations, and core labor standards. The results show
that, contrary to the conventional wisdom that transnational corporations engage
predominately in countries with low standards, higher labor standards are positively
associated with foreign direct investment inflows. Concerns about “social dumping” or
“a race to the bottom” on such standards appear to be mistaken. This result even holds
for poor developing countries. In view of the empirical evidence, the paper concludes
with a discussion of some policy implications for international institutions.
JEL Classification: F23, O19
Key Words: Transnational Corporations, Foreign Direct Investment, Labor Standards,
Cross-Country Regression Framework
2
1. Introduction
The rapid expansion of foreign direct investment (FDI), or the rise of transnational
corporations’ activities across countries, is maybe the clearest sign of the globalization
of the world economy over the past 15 years. The average annual growth rate of FDI
was 26 per cent between 1986 and 2000, much faster than other economic aggregates
like world production (7 per cent) or trade (9 per cent) (UNCTAD, 2001). Most
international investments take place within the Triad - Japan, the European Union and
the United States. In the period 1995-2000, they accounted for three-quarters of global
FDI inflows and 85 per cent of outflows.
Accordingly, absolute levels of FDI flows to developing countries are relatively small.
In the period 1995-2000, the 49 least-developed countries
1
attracted less than 1 per cent
of FDI inflows, which amounted to an annual average of only US$ 3.3 billion. Yet a
different picture emerges if shares of FDI flows of host country gross domestic product
(GDP) are considered. Whereas the ratio of FDI inflows to GDP in the least-developed
countries was as low as 0.2 per cent in the period 1980-1985, it increased to 2.2 per cent
in the period 1995-2000 (world average: 1.9 per cent), suggesting an increase in the
relevance of FDI to these countries (UNCTAD, 2001).
Though some political activists from non-governmental organizations doubt the
evidence, increasing FDI inflows and activities of transnational corporations, in
particular in developing countries, will benefit their host economies: FDI is likely to, for
the most part, introduce new technologies, augment the capital stock of the host
country, increase competition within key sectors of the economy, and benefit local
workers through more and better paid jobs.
2
Whereas FDI itself appears to have
favorable effects, a growing global competition among governments trying to attract
FDI might have less beneficial consequences. More specifically, worries have been
1
At present, 49 countries are on the United Nations (UN) list of least-developed countries (UNCTAD,
2001). They have in common a GDP per capita of less than US$ 900 in 1999 and low levels of capital,
human, and technological development.
2
See Klein et al. (2001) for a detailed survey of studies on the effects of FDI in developing and emerging-
market countries.
3
raised that there will be a lowering of workers’ rights, or, in other words, “social
dumping” or a “race to the bottom” on labor standards (Bhagwati, 1996; Drenovsky,
1992).
These issues have attracted interest not only from trade unions and governments, but
also from a large public audience, including humanitarian organizations, partly due to
concerns about the effects of the increasing globalization of the world economy. In
particular, non-governmental organizations have raised their voices. Amnesty
International (2002), for instance, stated in a recent report on the activities of
transnational corporations in developing countries:
“Many transnational corporations operate in countries with repressive
administrations where the rule of law is weak, where the independence
of the judiciary is questionable, and where arbitrary arrest, detention,
torture and extra-judicial executions occur. The government may ban
free trade union activity and deny its citizens freedom of association.
Factory workers in plants from which companies source their products
may be subject to inhuman and degrading working conditions.”
This paper seeks to address these concerns and elucidates the relationship between labor
standards and decisions of transnational corporations on where to invest abroad. It
focuses on the question of whether countries could gain a competitive advantage from
low labor standards, and thereby affect FDI flows. A second question, partly related to
the first one, is whether transnational corporations have an influence on labor standards
in the country of operation or whether they can improve respect for these standards.
This reversed link, however, is beyond the scope of this paper and hence not addressed.
Against this background, this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 gives a brief
introduction to different concepts of labor standards. Section 3 reviews previous
empirical work on the linkage between labor standards and FDI flows. The results of
empirical tests with respect to that relationship are reported in Section 4. Finally, some
4
policy implications are discussed in Section 5, and the paper concludes with a summary
of the major results and some concluding remarks in Section 6.
2. Definition and Scope of Labor Standards
Obviously, the extent of labor standards differs across countries, depending on political,
cultural, and social preferences and conditions, as well as income levels (Brown et al.,
1998; Bhagwati, 1996). There is, however, a lack of agreement on a definition or a
common list of labor standards. It is necessary to outline carefully the set of labor
standards used, since the choice of labor standards will definitely influence empirical
results. For the intention of analyzing the effects on FDI flows, and for more clarity, the
distinction between “core” and other labor standards is crucial. Core (or fundamental)
labor standards focus on important human and workers’ rights and include (ILO,
2002b):
Freedom from forced labor, in the form of compulsory labor and slavery;
The abolition of exploitative forms of child labor that put the safety and health of
children at significant risk;
Equal opportunity in employment, that is, the right to equal treatment for all workers;
Fundamental union rights like freedom of association and collective bargaining, i.e.
rights of workers to organize themselves and to negotiate freely their working
conditions with their employers.
Apart from these core standards, other standards, such as health and safety standards in
the workplace, annual leave with pay or minimum wages, are related to actual working
and labor market conditions. These other labor standards are extremely controversial,
whereas core labor standards receive overwhelmingly acceptance. For instance, the
5
three United Nations acts on core labor standards have been ratified by more than 130
countries (UN, 2002).
3
Separately from the three United Nations acts, the conventions of the International
Labor Organization (ILO) on core labor standards have come next to a set of standards
most countries can reach agreement on. Initially, the ILO was created in 1919 primarily
for the purpose of adopting international standards to cope with problems of labor
conditions, such as "injustice, hardship and privation" (ILO, 2002a; Sengenberger,
1994). Later on in 1944, the ILO standard setting mandate was broadened to include
more general, but closely related, human and civil rights and social policy matters. Core
labor standards, however, have remained one of the most important issues of the ILO.
Within the ILO framework, international labor standards are in effect expressions of
international tripartite agreement. The tripartite representatives consist of governments
as well as workers’ and employers’ organizations. Since its foundation, the ILO has
adopted more than 180 conventions and more than 190 recommendations (ILO, 2002a).
ILO conventions are international treaties subject to ratification by ILO member states,
whereas recommendations are purely advisory and non-binding instruments. The ILO
relies basically on voluntary compliance and monitors the carrying out of the ratified
conventions, since it does not have any enforcement power.
Starting with the Forced Labor Convention in 1930, so far the ILO has adopted eight
conventions on core labor standards, two each on union rights, forced labor, child labor,
and discrimination (see Table 1). Apart from the two on child labor, the total number of
ratifications by member states is in the range of 140 to 160.
4
Though most countries
agree on the principles of these conventions, only 80 countries have ratified all eight (as
of 1 September 2002). In some circumstances, the precise wording or the interpretation
of these conventions contradicts national laws or regulations (OECD, 1996). Ratifying a
3
The three United Nations acts are (1) the Convention on the Rights of the Child, (2) the Covenant on
Economic, Social and Cultural Rights, and (3) the Covenant on Civil and Political Rights; see UN (2002)
for details.
4
Since the Worst Forms of Child Labour Convention (No. 182) was only agreed on as recently as 1999,
member countries are still in the process of ratifying this convention.
6
particular convention, on the other hand, does not automatically entail enforcement.
Albania, for example, has ratified all eight conventions, and the United States only two,
but few would argue that Albania has higher labor standards.
Table 1: Ratification of ILO Fundamental Labor Standards (as of 1 September 2002)
ILO Convention
Number of countries
having ratified the
convention
Union Rights
(1) Freedom of Association and Protection of the Right to Organize Convention,
1948 (No. 87)
141
(2) Right to Organize and Collective Bargaining Convention, 1949 (No. 98)
152
Forced Labor
(3) Forced Labor Convention, 1930 (No. 29)
161
(4) Abolition of Forced Labor Convention, 1957 (No. 105)
158
Child Labor
(5) Minimum Age Convention, 1973 (No. 138)
117
(6) Worst Forms of Child Labor Convention, 1999 (No. 182)
129
Discrimination
(7) Equal Remuneration Convention, 1951 (No. 100)
159
(8) Discrimination (Employment and Occupation) Convention, 1958 (No. 111) 156
Source: ILO (2002b).
3. Previous Studies of Foreign Direct Investment and Labor Standards
Taking into account the extensive international discussion about the relationship
between labor standards and FDI, it is rather astonishing that only a few studies have
addressed that link empirically. Those studies available in the literature have focused
more on the consequences of labor costs and social and political stability on FDI flows.
5
So far, four studies have looked at the linkage between labor standards and FDI (see
Table 2 for an overview of the results).
In a first attempt, the OECD (1996) analyzed the linkage between a fundamental union
right, the freedom of association, and FDI flows. Based on ILO studies and reports from
5
See Brown (2000) for a comprehensive survey.
7
international trade union organizations, the OECD rated 76 countries on a scale from
1 (union rights almost non-existent) to 4 (union rights guaranteed in law and practice).
In the examination of the data, the authors of that study first relied on a simple chart in
relating freedom of association and FDI flows and, in an update (OECD, 2000), also
computed a partial correlation. Both the chart and the correlation coefficient (0.20)
indicate a positive but rather weak link between freedom of association and FDI flows.
Rodrik (1996) regressed several indicators for labor standards on the FDI by majority-
owned United States affiliates abroad as a share of the stock of such investment. In the
benchmark regression, he used control variables like the black-market premium for
foreign currency as a substitute for government policy distortions, population, and
income growth in the host country. Afterwards he added several indicators for core and
other labor standards. Only the indicators for child labor and democracy were
statistically significant, and the coefficients imply that countries with weaker
democratic rights and more child labor attract less United States capital than
democracies that protect child workers.
Alternatively, Cooke and Noble (1998) focused on the linkage between the total number
of ratified ILO conventions by each country and United States FDI abroad. This implies
that they did not incorporate any indicator which measures the de facto compliance with
rather than the de jure ratification of ILO conventions. Yet they discovered a positive
and statistically significant relationship between the two variables, which implies that
United States firms prefer countries with a stronger record of ratifications of ILO
conventions as a site for investment.
8
Table 2. Previous Studies of Foreign Direct Investment and Labor Standards
Author(s) and
Sample Period
Countries Dependent Variable Independent Variables Statistically Sign.
Variables
OECD (1996,
2000)
1995-98
76 OECD
and non-
OECD
countries
FDI inflows Freedom of association (Weak) pos.
Correlation
Rodrik (1996)
1982-89
40
countries
FDI by US firms
abroad / stock of FDI
Black-market premium for
foreign currency
Neg. correlation
Population Neg. correlation
GDP growth Pos. correlation
Total ILO conventions ratified
CLS* ILO conventions ratified
Democracy indicator Pos. correlation
Incidence of child labor Neg. correlation
Cooke and
Noble (1998)
33
countries
FDI by US firms
abroad
Total ILO conventions ratified Pos. correlation
1993
Raynauld and
Vidal (1998)
91
countries
Change in inward-FDI
shares
Indicator for labor standards Pos. correlation
1980-90
Note: * Core Labor Standards.
Finally, Raynauld and Vidal (1998) used the Human Development Index (HDI) of the
United Nations as an indicator of the extent of labor standards in each country. The HDI
comprises life expectancy, educational attainment, standard of living, and so on.
6
Assuming that the HDI is closely associated with the level of labor standards, they
found a positive and statistically significant relationship between the HDI and its
dependent variables, the percentage change in inward-FDI as a share of total FDI flows.
This implies that countries with a higher human development level attract more FDI
than countries with lower development levels. To sum up, the empirical evidence in the
literature is not very comprehensive, but the results indicate that low-standard countries
are likely to receive less FDI than nations with higher standards.
4. Data and Empirical Results
6
See UNDP (2002) for more information.
9
An appropriate basis for the empirical investigation of the relevance of labor standards
to investment decisions by transnational corporations would be to use a standard
theoretical model, incorporate labor standards and then analyze them. Unfortunately, we
do not have such a model.
7
Instead, for the empirical analysis we have to rely on the
results of other studies that have address the underlying reasons why transnational
corporations realize investment abroad.
According to the empirical studies, the two most important determinants of FDI flows
are the size and growth of a market (Chakrabarti, 2001). Thus, for the benchmark
ordinary least squares regression of the FDI model, only market size (the variable is
labeled GDP), quantified by GDP per capita in current US dollars, and market growth
(GROWTH), measured as real GDP per capita growth, are included as independent
variables. Since FDI flows, as the dependent variable, can vary significantly from year
to year for a single country, a period of six years from 1995-2000 has been chosen.
8
The
data used are average annual net FDI inflows per capita in the reporting economy for
that period in current US dollars (FDI).
9
For the quantification of labor standards, five indicators are used. First, there is GDI for
the extent of discrimination against women, representing the gender-related
development index of discrimination against women in education and working life,
computed by the UNDP (2002). The index quantifies gender inequalities in literacy
rates, the combined gross primary, secondary, and tertiary enrolment ratio, life
expectancy, and income. It varies from 0 (very high discrimination) to
1 (no discrimination).
Second, CHILD is used for the occurrence of child labor, defined as the share of
children of ages 10-14 who are not working. With this definition, CHILD measures thus
7
See Graham (1995) and Chakrabarti (2001) for overviews of the literature on FDI flows.
8
GDP and GROWTH are also averages for the period 1995-2000. Data sources of all variables are
reported in Appendix A.
9
The subsequent results do not change fundamentally if FDI stocks are used instead of flows. Given that
FDI stocks represent FDI flows over a longer period and the indicators used for labour standards are
relatively recent, the focus is on flows rather than stocks.
10
the non-prevalence of child labor. To ensure a straightforward interpretation of the
subsequent regression results, a higher number of CHILD, like the four other indicators,
implies a higher labor standard. Third, UNION is taken to represent basic union rights,
such as collective bargaining and freedom of association. This variable is the OECD
(1996, 2000) indicator for union rights (see Section 3).
10
Fourth, CONVEN stands for
the number of ratified ILO conventions on core labor standards.
And, finally, FORCED is the indicator for the prevalence of forced labor. Starting point
for this indicator is a comprehensive ILO (2001) report on forced labor. With the help of
this report, each country has been assessed as to whether there are insufficiencies either
in legislation or enforcement. Shortcomings in legislation are linked to the absence of
forced labor regulations or to specifications in national laws that are incompatible with
ILO conventions on forced labor. Inadequacies in enforcement, on the other hand, relate
to a lack of government ability or willingness to use existing legislation. In the analysis,
three numbers have been applied for FORCED: 1 if problems have been reported with
both enforcement and legislation, 2 if there are shortcomings with one of them, and 3 if
there are no insufficiencies at all.
11
Incorporated in the benchmark OLS regression were all 134 countries reporting FDI,
GDP, and GDP growth data for the considered period 1995-2000. Like most empirical
studies on the determinants of FDI, a semilog model has been applied, that is, the
logarithm for both FDI and GDP has been taken. As GDP growth rates can be negative,
GROWTH has been added without taking the logarithm to ensure the highest number of
countries included in the regressions. Then, the basic regression specification is
(1) Log (FDI) = α
0
+ α
1
LOG (GDP) + α
2
GROWTH + e,
10
Yet again, to ensure an easier interpretation of the regression results, the range from 1 to 4 has been
defined exactly opposite to that of the OECD.
11
See Appendix B for the assigned numbers for each country.
11
where e is an error term and α
i
are parameters. The results, reported in the first column
of Table 3, show that both explanatory variables have the expected signs and are
statistically significant at the 1 per cent level. To see whether labor standards also have
an impact on FDI flows (and to reduce the problem of multicollinearity), each indicator
is added one by one to the benchmark regression, without taking the logarithm:
(2) Log (FDI) = α
0
+ α
1
LOG (GDP) + α
2
GROWTH +
α
3
Indicator for Labor Standards + e.
The coefficients for the five indicators explained above are reported in the remaining
columns of Table 3. All four indicators that quantify the de facto compliance with the
ratification of the ILO conventions have positive signs and are statistically significant at
the 1, 5, or 10 per cent level. The results show that less discrimination against females, a
lower extent of child and forced labor, and improved basic union rights are associated
with higher FDI inflows. In other words, countries with higher core labor standards
received more FDI per capita in the period 1995-2000 than would have been forecasted
on the basis of the other country characteristics.
12
Table 3: Core Labor Standards and Foreign Direct Investment, All Countries
Independent
Variables
Dependent Variable: LOG (FDI)
Constant -3.737***
(0.507)
-3.511***
(0.551)
-4.448***
(0.674)
-4.231***
(0.528)
-3.516***
(0.684)
-3.741***
(0.566)
LOG (GDP) 1.117***
(0.068)
0.827***
(0.167)
0.979***
(0.097)
1.013***
(0.077)
1.030***
(0.113)
1.116***
(0.070)
GROWTH 0.149***
(0.046)
0.134***
(0.049)
0.155***
(0.047)
0.160***
(0.045)
0.001
(0.069)
0.149***
(0.047)
GDI 2.835**
(1.417)
CHILD 1.915*
(1.063)
FORCED 0.475***
(0.176)
UNION 0.720*
(0.413)
CONVEN 0.001
(0.063)
Adj. R
2
0.70 0.72 0.70 0.71 0.76 0.70
N 134 122 130 134 68 134
Notes: See Appendix A for data sources; standard errors, which have been checked for heteroskedasticity,
are reported in parentheses; multicollinearity has been tested by the creation of variance inflation factors
(VIF); *** significant at 1% level; ** significant at 5% level; * significant at 10% level.
Conversely, CONVEN, which stands for the de jure ratification of the ILO conventions,
seems not to significantly affect FDI flows. CONVEN is just above zero and not
statistically significant. In addition, the number of ratifications appears to be a rather
poor quality measure of the de facto compliance. To compare ratification and
compliance for each of the four core labor standards, the number of ratifications for
each of the four core labor standards is first computed. The variables are labeled
CONDISC for equal opportunity in employment (no discrimination) and the number of
ratifications of Conventions No. 100 and No. 111, CONCHILD for the abolition of
exploitative forms of child labor (No. 138 and No. 182), CONFORCE for freedom of
forced labor (No. 29 and No. 105) and CONUNION for fundamental union rights
(No. 87 and No. 98). Then the partial correlations between these four variables and the
equivalent indicators for compliance with labor standards are computed.
The results, shown in Table 4, indicate that the maximum partial correlation is 0.22 (for
union rights), which implies a weak positive correlation. The partial correlations for the
discrimination against females and forced labor are even negative, which indicates that
– on average – countries that ratify more conventions on these two core labor standards
13
are less likely to ensure their enforcement in practice. As has been pointed out in
Section 2, the interpretation of these results should not go too far, since some countries
do not ratify the conventions due to legal issues but nevertheless ensure the compliance
in their countries.
Table 4: Ratifications of Fundamental ILO Conventions
and Level of Labor Standards
Variables Partial Correlation
GDI / CONDISC -0.02
CHILD / CONCHILD 0.09
FORCED / CONFORCE -0.15
UNION / CONUNION 0.22
Note: See Appendix A for data sources.
By and large, similar to the outcome of previous empirical work on this subject, the
results clearly indicate that the level of core labor standards is positively associated with
FDI inflows. In fact, one probable reason for this finding is that most FDI for the
countries included in the data set (in absolute numbers) is horizontal rather than vertical.
Vertical FDI occurs when transnational corporations divide the production process
internationally by locating each stage of production in the place or country where it can
be done at lowest cost (Bjorvatn et al., 2001). Foreign affiliates of TNCs in developing
or emerging-market countries typically produce labor-intensive intermediate products
that are transported back to high-wage countries. This kind of investment is called
“efficiency seeking” FDI, since the main motive for the investment is to improve the
cost effectiveness of the firm’s production.
Horizontal FDI, on the other hand, takes place when transnational corporations produce
the same or a very similar commodity in various plants and service local markets
through affiliate production rather than through exports from their home base (Bjorvatn
et al., 2001). This type of FDI, sometimes called “market seeking” FDI, is to a very
large extent directed towards high-income countries, since market size or potential are
the most relevant determinants. There is strong evidence that horizontal FDI dominates
vertical investment flows. For example, according to Brainard (1997), only 13 per cent
14
of the overseas production of United States-owned foreign affiliates is shipped back to
the United States, and that only two per cent of the output produced by foreign affiliates
located in the United States is shipped to their parents.
Clearly, these findings are overwhelmingly influenced by the dominance of FDI flows
between high-income countries and regions like the United States, Japan, and the
European Union (see figures in Section 1), where horizontal is by far larger than vertical
FDI. To see whether the inclusion of high-income countries has a decisive role, high
and upper middle-income countries have been left out in a second set of regressions.
Based on a definition by the World Bank (2002), only developing countries with a low
or lower-middle income with a GDP per capita in 1999 of US$ 2,995 or less were
included in the regressions. Together, 87 developing countries have been identified with
combined FDI inflows of US$ 76 billion or 8.6 per cent of world FDI inflows in 2000
(UNCTAD, 2001).
Table 5 shows the results for the new set of regressions. Overall, they are much like
those of the first set. Whereas the overall fit of the benchmark and the other regressions
for the labor standards worsens, signs as well as statistical significance of all variables
are similar. The only exception is UNION, which implies that fundamental union rights
are less likely to be positively associated with FDI inflows in developing countries.
Unfortunately, there is evidence of multicollinearity between GDP, GDI and CHILD.
Given that the extent of child labor and the degree of discrimination against women are
likely to be substitutes for income levels in developing countries, GDP in these two
regressions has been omitted. Partly as a consequence, GDI and CHILD are highly
significant at the 1 per cent level. To sum up, there is not only a positive linkage
between labor standards and FDI flows if all countries are considered, but also in
developing countries with a low and lower-middle income.
12
12
Neither the statistical significance nor the signs change much if additional developing countries or
emerging-market economies with, for instance GDP per capita between US$ 2,995 and US$ 9,265, which
are middle- and upper-middle-income countries, are incorporated in the regressions. To save space, these
results are not reported.
15
Table 5: Core Labor Standards and Foreign Direct Investment, Developing Countries
Independent
Variables
Dependent Variable: LOG (FDI)
Constant -4.517***
(1.079)
-5.584***
(0.388)
-1.819*
(0.933)
-4.630***
(1.052)
-5.277**
(2.104)
-4.518***
(1.145)
LOG (GDP) 1.230***
(0.164)
1.056***
(0.176)
1.212***
(0.269)
1.230***
(0.166)
GROWTH 0.167***
(0.058)
0.131**
(0.066)
0.187***
(0.065)
0.184***
(0.057)
0.001
(0.120)
0.167***
(0.059)
GDI 3.568***
(0.975)
CHILD 6.249***
(1.080)
FORCED 0.501**
(0.212)
UNION 0.466
(0.367)
CONVEN 0.001
(0.083)
Adj. R
2
0.43 0.38 0.33 0.46 0.39 0.43
N 87 78 84 87 31 87
Note: According to a definition by the World Bank (2002), developing countries can be classified as low
and lower middle-income countries with a GDP per capita in 1999 of US$ 2,995 or less; see Table 3 for
further notes.
5. Policy Implications and the Role of International Institutions
Considering this empirical evidence, recent reflections
13
on whether labor standards
should be incorporated into a framework of an international institution, such as the
World Trade Organization (WTO), to enforce the rules at a global level seem to be
misguided. Yet in particular the European Union is still in favor of linking investment
(and trade) and core labor standards and brought the issue to the negotiating table at the
WTO conference in Doha in November 2001. However, this attempt was discarded by a
vast majority of developing countries and the issue of labor standards has not be
included in the new Doha Round of multilateral trade talks.
Though the empirical results are clear-cut, it is obvious that core labor standards may
influence investment decisions in some cases. To illustrate this, violations of workers’
13
For instance, see not only calls for binding labour standards by non-governmental organisations like
Amnesty International (2002), but also Morris (2001) for an economic analysis and an overview of the
literature.
16
rights have been reported in particular in export-processing zones in Asian and Central
American countries (OECD, 2000). Poor working conditions and low standards in these
zones may attract a few transnational corporations that use predominately unskilled
labor. Likewise, some governments in Asia, such as Bangladesh or Pakistan, have
exempted export-processing zones from national labor and industrial relations
legislation, thereby restricting workers’ rights, to help attract inward FDI (ICFTU,
2002).
Furthermore, there simply is no excuse on humanitarian grounds for repellent working
conditions to prevail anywhere in the world. Thus, the remaining question is how to
deal with these reported cases. In general, there are two approaches: binding rules
within international institutions or dealing with single firms that violate fundamental
labor standards. At the international level, an attempt was made with the Multilateral
Agreement on Investment (MAI), which had been negotiated by OECD countries from
1995 to 1998 (Hoekman and Saggi, 2000).
While global rules do exist to regulate trade in commodities, it was recognized by
OECD governments that there are none to regulate foreign investment. Apart from rules
for investment protection or dispute settlement, negotiators also discussed the issue of
standards related to working practices (Graham, 2000). More specifically, a provision
had been added that aimed at not lowering health, safety, or labor standards. It obligated
governments not to relax core labor standards as a means of encouraging investment
inflows. Also, it had been discussed whether the provision might be enforceable in the
sense that it could be the basis for bringing a dispute to the agreement’s dispute
settlement procedures.
But the MAI negotiations failed in late 1998 and that provision never went into force
(Graham, 2000). Indeed, the MAI had been in trouble from the beginning, partly
because the investment negotiations were taken on by the OECD and not the WTO.
This was an unfortunate idea on several counts. As a start, the OECD has only 30
members, most of them comparatively open to FDI; the talks excluded such countries as
Indonesia and India, where foreign investment is regulated to a large extent. Also, the
17
OECD, whose primary job is economic research, has no experience running such a
complicated negotiation. And third, while the WTO has a legal apparatus in place to
deal with nations that violate their commitments to open trade, the OECD does not. The
lack of possible enforcement power thus further weakened the negotiations and the MAI
talks failed.
Apart from the breakdown of these talks, imposing (trade or economic) sanctions on
countries where appalling working conditions exist by means of multilateral
agreements, whether within the WTO, OECD or ILO, does not seem to be the best way
forward. It clearly makes no sense to use sanctions against a whole nation if only one or
two firms violate labor standards. Punishing the innocent along with the guilty is rarely
a sound policy. Moreover, sanctions may result in negative economic consequences, as
measures to enforce fundamental workers’ rights are likely to be exploited by high-
income countries to protect their markets against alleged “unfair” imports from lower-
income developing countries with poorer standards (Graham, 1997). This would in turn
be harmful to GDP growth rates (and, thus, FDI inflows) in developing countries,
because their cost competitiveness and economic welfare would somewhat erode.
A more promising and effective approach is likely to sanction individual firms that
violate fundamental labor standards by using, for example, product labeling. This
method, argued at length by Freeman (1994) and Rodrik (1996), is also appealing to
economists, since the market mechanism can be applied. If imported commodities can
be appropriately labeled, consumers in high-income countries who might be willing to
pay a premium for high standards in all countries will be able to do so. Also, this could
reduce concerns about low standards by trade unions in the United States and Europe
and would generate the incentive for producers in the exporting nations to upgrade their
standards voluntarily.
For a number of reasons, the voluntary participation of all parties involved is the most
appealing argument for labeling (Rodrik, 1996): (1) It allows the willingness-to-pay rule
to determine the level of harmonization in labor standards; (2) developing-country
exporters are compensated for the costs of raising their labor standards by an increase in
18
prices; (3) import-competing workers in the high-income countries get certain
protection through the higher prices; (4) labeling avoids internationally binding trade
restrictions, as it does not involve any actions by governments apart from perhaps
setting some standards on labeling through associations, under which firms agree to
adhere to voluntary codes of labor standards; and (5) it reduces the chances that labor
standards are abused by protectionist groups.
First examples of product labeling are Levi Strauss and Wal-Mart in the early and mid-
1990s, following some critical publicity surrounding their use of underpaid workers in
appalling conditions.
14
More specifically, both introduced new rules for their foreign
subsidiaries/subcontractors and excluded suppliers who use child labor. Another
example is the Swedish furniture store IKEA, which announced in 1995 that it would
not put up carpets for sale that it could not certify as having been made without child
labor.
On the other hand, using labeling to identify and punish firms that violate core labor
standards may also involve some problems. First, it produces incentive problems for
private firms. In particular, consumers cannot check the claims made on the product
labels, as information about production circumstances cannot be obtained for free
(Freeman, 1994). Companies, in turn, have the incentive to overstate the standards by
which they abide. This problem could be controlled by close governmental monitoring,
but this raises the problem of bureaucratic interference and protectionism anew. Second,
since labor standards are multifaceted, that is, they consist of core and other standards,
simple labeling could not address all likely sources of concern. Consider core labor
standards: Even if labeling could truthfully deal with child labor, what about non-
discrimination, basic union rights or the complex issue of forced labor?
A role for international institutions might arise in this context, in particular for the ILO.
Since information on abuses of core labor standards is available to some extent, the ILO
can determine which countries and/or firms do not meet the provisions in their
conventions and recommendations. Also, the ILO could create corps of inspectors
14
See Rodrik (1996) and Freeman (1994) for details and more examples.
19
within its organization whose mission it would be to go to production facilities around
the world to decide whether core standards are being violated or not (Varley, 1998).
Finally, supporting the fundamental ILO operations by providing financial and technical
assistance to the countries involved, as well as more transparency, would show far
higher effects on the improvement of fundamental workers’ rights than binding
international regulations within the WTO framework.
6. Concluding Remarks
The main argument of this paper has been that, contrary to the conventional wisdom
that transnational corporations favor low-standard countries, higher labor standards are
positively associated with FDI inflows. The main line of attack from non-governmental
organizations is the conviction that due to the increasing integration of the world,
countries will engage in fierce competition to attract FDI, leading, among other things,
to “a race to the bottom” on labor standards; this assumption seems unable to be
justified. Employing aggregate FDI data for 134 countries, the regression results clearly
indicate that low standards are not an attraction for transnational corporations. This
result holds for all four core labor standards, that is, non-discrimination in employment,
abolition of child labor, basic union rights, and elimination of forced labor. Also,
separate regressions for relatively poor developing countries show that the results do not
depend on income levels.
Obviously, there are abuses of fundamental workers’ rights in a number of countries.
The number of reported cases, however, do not lead to the conclusion that workers’
rights in general are suffering from severe violations or that any of the empirical results
of the present study have to be looked at again. Weak core labor standards are not
considered a major factor in assessing investment opportunities by transnational
corporations in a potential host country. As has been shown, the empirical results point
rather to the opposite outcome: On average, transnational corporations prefer to invest
in countries where basic human and workers’ rights are higher.
20
Yet to address humanitarian concerns about the appellant mistreatment of workers’
rights in individual cases, two differing approaches have been discussed: binding rules
within international institutions and product labeling. Whereas the former is likely to be
unfair towards innocent workers and firms and less efficient in terms of economic
welfare, the latter seems to be more promising, as it allows for voluntary commitments
and monitoring for labor standards. Since numerous non-governmental organizations,
trade unions, and some governments of high-income (and high-standard) countries are
still interested in raising labor standards to a certain level in all countries,
15
the issue is
highly likely to arrive on the scene of future trade and investment talks again. Yet this
paper has indicated that human rights activists may be fighting the wrong enemy, as
labor standards and FDI are positively associated.
15
See Palley et al. (1999) for the trade unions viewpoint on labour standards and their demands.
21
References
Amnesty International (2002), Business and Human Rights: A Geography of Risk,
Internet posting: http://www.amnesty.org.uk.
Bhagwati, Jagdish (1996), The Demands to Reduce Domestic Diversity Among Trading
Nations, in Jagdish Bhagwati and Robert Hudec (eds.), Fair Trade and
Harmonization, Cambridge (MA), MIT Press, pp. 9-40.
Bjorvatn, Kjetil; Kind, Hans Jarle and Nordaas, Hildegunn Kyvik (2001), The Role of
FDI in Economic Development, Discussion Paper No. 31/2001, Norwegian
School of Economics and Business Administration (forthcoming in Nordic
Journal of Political Economy).
Brainard, Lael (1997), An Empirical Assessment of the Proximity-Concentration Trade-
off Between Multinational Sales and Trade, American Economic Review, Vol. 87,
No. 4, pp. 520-544.
Brown, Drusilla (2000), International Trade and Core Labour Standards: A Survey of
the Literature, OECD Labour Market and Social Policy – Occasional Papers
No. 43, Paris: OECD.
Brown, Drusilla; Deardorff, Alan and Stern, Robert (1998), Trade and Labor Standards,
Open Economies Review, Vol. 9, No. 2, pp. 171-94.
Chakrabarti, Avik (2001), The Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment: Sensitivity
Analyses of Cross-Country Regressions, Kyklos, Vol. 54, No. 1, pp. 89-113.
Cooke, William and Noble, Deborah (1998), Industrial Relation Systems and US
Foreign Direct Investment Abroad, British Journal of Industrial Relations,
Vol. 36, No. 4, pp. 581-609.
Drenovsky, Cynthia (1992), Child Labor Force Participation in the World System.
Journal of Comparative Family Studies, Vol. 23, No. 2, pp. 183-195.
Freeman, Richard (1994), A Hard-headed Look at Labour Standards, in Werner
Sengenberger and Duncan Campbell (eds.), International Labour Standards and
Economic Interdependence, Geneva: ILO, pp. 117-157.
Graham, Edward (1995), Foreign Direct Investment in the World Economy, IMF
Working Paper WP 95/59, Washington, DC: IMF.
Graham, Edward (1997), Should There Be Multilateral Rules on Foreign Direct
Investment? in John Dunning (ed.), Governments, Globalization, and
International Business, New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 481-505.
Graham, Edward (2000), Fighting the Wrong Enemy: Antiglobal Activists and
Multilateral Enterprises, Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.
Hoekman, Bernard and Saggi, Kamal (2000), Assessing the Case for Extending WTO
Disciplines on Investment-related Policies, Journal of Economic Integration,
Vol. 15, No. 4, pp. 629-653.
ICFTU (2002), Annual Survey of Violations of Trade Union Rights (various issues),
International Confederation of Free Trade Unions, Internet posting:
http:/www.ifctu.org.
ILO (2001), Stopping Forced Labour. International Labour Conference 89
th
Session
2001, Report I (B), Geneva: International Labor Office.
22
ILO (2002a), About the International Labor Organization, Internet posting:
http://www.ilo.org.
ILO (2002b), Ratifications of the ILO Fundamental Conventions, Internet posting:
http://webfusion.ilo.org/public/db/standards/normes/appl/appl-
ratif8conv.cfm?Lang=EN.
Klein, Michael; Aaron, Carl and Hadjimichael, Bita (2001), Foreign Direct Investment
and Poverty Reduction, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2613,
Washington, DC: World Bank.
Morris, David (2001), Free Trade: The Great Destroyer, in Jerry Mander and Edward
Goldsmith (eds.), The Case Against the Global Economy, London: Earthscan,
pp. 115-124.
OECD (1996), Trade, Employment and Labour Standards: A Study of Core Workers’
Rights and International Trade, Paris: OECD.
OECD (2000), International Trade and Core Labour Standards. Paris: OECD.
Palley, Thomas; Drake, Elizabeth and Lee, Thea (1999), The Case for Core Labor
Standards in the International Economy: Theory, Evidence, and a Blueprint for
Implementation, Economic Policy Paper E041, Public Policy Department,
Washington, DC: AFL-CIO.
Raynauld, Andre and Vidal, Jean-Pierre (1998), Labour Standards and International
Competitiveness: A Comparative Analysis of Developing and Industrialized
Countries, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Rodrik, Dani (1996), Labor Standards in International Trade: Do They Matter and What
Do We Do About Them? in Robert Lawrence, Dani Rodrik and John Whalley
(eds.), Emerging Agenda For Global Trade: High States for Developing
Countries, Washington Overseas Development Council Essay No. 20, Baltimore:
Johns Hopkins University Press, pp. 35-79.
Sengenberger, Werner (1994), International Labour Standards in a Globalized
Economy: The Issues, in Werner Sengenberger and Duncan Campbell (eds.),
International Labour Standards and Economic Interdependence, Geneva:
International Institute of Labor Studies, pp. 3-16.
UN (2002), Treaty Bodies Database, United Nations High Commissioner for Human
Rights, Internet posting: http://www.unhchr.ch/tbs/doc.nsf.
UNCTAD (2001), World Investment Report 2001, New York and Geneva: United
Nations.
UNDP (2002), Human Development Report 2002 (and earlier issues), Geneva: United
Nations Development Programme.
Varley, Pamela (1998), The Sweatshop Quandary: Corporate Responsibility on the
Global Frontier, Washington, DC: Investor Responsibility Research Center.
World Bank (2002), World Development Indicators, Data on CD-ROM, Washington,
DC: World Bank.
23
Appendix A: Definition of Variables and Data Sources
Variable Definition Source
FDI Foreign direct investment, net inflows in current US dollars,
annual average for the period 1995-2000
World Bank (2002)
GDP GDP per capita in current US dollars, annual average for the
period 1995-2000
World Bank (2002)
GROWTH Growth of GDP per capita, annual average for the period
1995-2000
World Bank (2002)
GDI Gender-related development index, index 0-1, annual average
for the period 1995-2000
UNDP (2002)
CHILD Percentage of children ages 10-14 who are not working, annual
average for the period 1995-2000
World Bank (2002)
FORCED Indicator for forced labor, scale from 1-3, 1999 ILO (2001) and
own calculations
UNION Basic union rights, scale from 1-4, 1999 OECD (1996,
2000)
CONVEN Number of ratifications of the eight fundamental ILO
conventions, Dec. 1999
ILO (2002b)
CONDISC Number of ratifications of the two fundamental ILO
conventions on discrimination No. 100 and No. 111, 1999
ILO (2002b)
CONCHILD Number of ratifications of the two fundamental ILO
conventions on child labor No. 138 and No. 182, 1999
ILO (2002b)
CONFORCE Number of ratifications of the two fundamental ILO
conventions on forced labor No. 29 and No. 105, 1999
ILO (2002b)
CONUNION Number of ratifications of the two fundamental ILO
conventions on basic union rights No. 87 and No. 98, 1999
ILO (2002b)
24
Appendix B: Indicator for Forced Labor
Group 1
Bangladesh, Cambodia, China, Congo (Democratic Republic), Congo (Republic), Haiti, India,
Madagascar, Nepal, Sierra Leone, Sudan, Vietnam
Group 2
Benin, Bolivia, Brazil, Burkina Faso, Central African Republic, Costa Rica, Cote d'Ivoire,
Dominican Republic, Ethiopia, Ghana, Guatemala, Honduras, Kenya, Mali, Mauritania,
Mexico, Niger, Pakistan, Paraguay, Peru, Philippines, Senegal, Sri Lanka, Swaziland, Tanzania,
Thailand, Togo, Zimbabwe
Group 3
Albania, Algeria, Angola, Argentina, Armenia, Australia, Austria, Azerbaijan, Bahamas,
Barbados, Belarus, Belize, Botswana, Bulgaria, Burundi, Chad, Chile, Colombia, Croatia,
Cyprus, Czech Republic, Denmark, Djibouti, Ecuador, Egypt, El Salvador, Estonia, Fiji,
Finland, France, Gabon, Gambia, Germany, Greece, Guinea, Guyana, Hungary, Iceland,
Indonesia, Iran, Israel, Italy, Jamaica, Jordan, Kazakhstan, South Korea, Kyrgyzstan, Latvia,
Lebanon, Lesotho, Cameroon, Canada, Cape Verde, Lithuania, Macedonia, Malawi, Malaysia,
Maldives, Malta, Mauritius, Moldavia, Mongolia, Morocco, Mozambique, New Zealand,
Nicaragua, Nigeria, Norway, Panama, Papua New Guinea, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Russia,
Samoa, Seychelles, Slovakia, Slovenia, South Africa, Spain, Switzerland, Syria, Trinidad and
Tobago, Tunisia, Turkey, Uganda, Ukraine, United Kingdom, United States, Uruguay,
Uzbekistan, Venezuela, Zambia
Source: ILO (2001) and own calculations; see text for explanations.
... Over a couple of decades of research on the role of labour standards in determining the IFDI has suggested that contrary to received wisdom, global "race to the bottom" exemplified by growing economies competing to attract FDI by exercising low labour standards (Bhagwati, 1996;Davies and Vadlamannati, 2013) has become less obvious. Today, neither does a country maintain a weak regulatory environment to attract FDI (Carstensen and Toubal, 2003;Kucera, 2001;Busse, 2003; Labour unrest and labour quality in Taiwan Dean et al., 2005) nor "low-standard countries are (anymore) a haven for investors" (see Rodrik, 1996, p. 57). Evidence supporting countries with low labour protection having advantages in attracting FDI has faded away (Duanmu, 2014;Kucera, 1992). ...
... Studies on whether foreign investors invest in a regulated over a non-regulated labour market have earned their due place in academic commentaries [1]. However, most studies have used labour protection (see Busse, 2003) loosely to explain investors' motives given that low labour cost, which is crucial for attracting FDI, is largely attributed to system denying workers' minimum protection as per labour laws (see Kucera, 2001Kucera, , 2002Sarna, 2005). However, there are other outcomes of enforcement of regulatory standards that can also predict IFDI. ...
Article
Full-text available
In this paper, we examined the changes in labour unrest and labour quality brought by high labour standards over a considerable period in Taiwan. Then we studied the role of these changes in predicting the inflow of foreign direct investment (FDI) in the country. To test the role, we measured the differences in effects of the two changes on wages, working hours, and employment opportunities of skilled female and skilled male workers in FDI-intensive and non-intensive industries. Using a model built on pooled cross-sectional time-series data from 1999–2012, we measured the effect of changes in labour unrest and the presence of skilled workers on the net inflow of FDI. Using data from the Manpower Utilization Survey, we applied Differences–in–Differences–in–Differences (DDD) and Differences–in–Differences–in–Differences–in–Differences (DDDD) estimation methods to test the effect of changes in labour unrest and labour quality on three labour market outcomes viz., wages, working hours and job opportunities of skilled workforce. Increasing labour unrest affected the employment opportunities of almost every unemployed person seeking skilled jobs in Taiwan. When we compared the adverse effect of high labour standards on employment opportunities and working hours, we found women looking for skilled jobs in foreign-owned firms to be the worst affected. Besides, foreign firms paid different wages to skilled educated men than what their domestic counterparts paid to skilled educated men employed in Taiwanese firms. An in-depth analysis of changes in labour unrest and presence of skilled workers because of high labour standards and the extent to which such changes helped the nation to attract FDI should be useful to policymakers interested in understanding the impact of legislative measures and policy reforms on labour market outcomes across industry types, which matter to foreign investors. If changes in labour unrest and labour quality influenced the inflow of FDI more to firms in one set of industries than the others, the same should have a bearing on revamping of future enactment and enforcement in Taiwan. Current study findings would not only provide broad lessons to policymakers in Taiwan but findings of our country case study should be able to guide growing economies who are equally careful while raising the labour standards as most fear that high labour standards can deter inflow of FDI because of increasing labour cost.
... These studies indicate that labor standards are not a major factor when MNCs investment assessment. Other studies suggest that FDI is positively associated with labor standards (Busse, 2003;Mosley and Uno 2007;Mosley 2011). In particular, Mosley and Uno (2007) and Mosley (2011) focus on the improvement of collective labor rights which are positively associated with other labor standards and working conditions. ...
Article
Full-text available
How does the influx of foreign direct investment (FDI) affect labor protests in China? Building on the framework of fragmented authoritarianism, I argue that the regional competition to attract foreign investment causes labor protests in China due to its deregulatory effects on labor regulation. Each actor, including the central and local governments, foreign investors, and workers, has different cost–benefit considerations, which provide an explanation for the link between foreign investment and labor protests. By theorizing each actor's preferences, this article explains how FDI induces labor deregulation and workers’ protests in China. Analyzing China's prefecture-level city data from 2012 to 2018, I find that the influx of FDI is positively associated with labor protests. The result remains robust to alternative model specifications and instrumental variable estimation. I also provide empirical evidence for the deregulatory effect of FDI on labor standards with an analysis at the firm level using the World Bank Enterprise Survey. These findings deepen our understanding of how FDI shapes labor regulation and induces workers’ protests in the context of China.
... Optimistic accounts of the presence of MNCs, however, suggest a "çlimb-to-the-top," with positive labor market outcomes in the host economy in the form of higher wages (Myint et al., 2015), better compensation packages, and higher job security than comparable domestic firms. Foreign direct investors are said to bring best practices for workers' rights to host countries (Aggarwal, 1995;Busse, 2003;Finnemore, 1996;Garcia-Johnson, 2000;Kucera, 2002;Mosley & Uno, 2017; Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development [OECD], 2000[OECD], , 2002. FDI inflows are also considered to be greater in countries with stronger workers' rights, as MNCs with their strong corporate culture strive to avoid bad publicity and product boycotts by investing in countries with low labor standards. ...
Article
This article identifies the dilution of key aspects of labor standards and establishes their systematic links with the global integration of the Malaysian economy through capital and labor inflows. The approach taken in this article is that investors and migrants, may, serve as channels of (lower) labor rights. For this purpose, the study consolidates information through interviews conducted with trade unions, activist groups and non-governmental organizations. The findings suggest that migrants have influenced and lowered the labor rights for the unskilled group. Since migrants have little information about their rights, they are directed into the secondary labor market with insecure and exploitative jobs. They have therefore become a preferred source of employment, “naturally” relegating the unskilled locals into contractual jobs with minimal to no work entitlements.
... Indeed, with respect to FACB rights he finds that countries with stronger rights receive more rather than less FDI inflows. Busse (2003) also finds no evidence that a higher incidence of violations of core labor standards attracts FDI. If anything, the opposite seems to hold since 'on average, transnational corporations prefer to invest in countries where basic human and workers' rights are higher' (p. ...
Article
У статті проаналізовано наукові джерела та актуальні дослідження, присвячені вивченню суспільного впливу прямих іноземних інвестицій (ПІІ). Для усунення виявлених обмежень зазначених підходів запропоновано новий концептуальний погляд на сутність суспільного впливу ПІІ, який полягає у зміні рівня задоволення людських потреб. Застосування гіпотези про рекурсивний зв'язок між потребами членів суспільства та іноземних інвесторів, а також концепції ієрархії потреб людини дало змогу сформулювати структурно-функціональну модель суспільного впливу ПІІ. Також представлено математичну інтерпретацію взаємозв'язку між зазначеними категоріями, кількісними й якісними характеристиками ПІІ. Виходячи з цієї моделі та її математичної інтерпретації, висунуті гіпотези щодо специфічних аспектів взаємозалежності суспільного ефекту ПІІ, властивостей іноземного капіталу, рівня економічного розвитку держави та її галузевої структури. Їх подальше дослідження на основі запропонованої моделі дасть змогу глибше зрозуміти, як різні параметри інвестицій та розвитку економіки впливають на формування соціального впливу ПІІ, виявити ключові чинники, що визначають цю взаємозалежність у різних умовах.
Chapter
On the basis of the normative theory of sustainability just laid out, effective implementation measures can be identified. In a first step, a number of promising starting points can be identified for individual and entrepreneurial action as well as for educational measures. Education, voluntary corporate social responsibility (CSR) and consumer engagement can play a role, but they cannot eliminate the need to contain capitalist economic activity and daily life through effective policy instruments, especially with regard to sustainability. Knowledge and intrinsic (self-interested or value-driven) motivation alone cannot trigger the necessary transformation. At the level of the individual person or company, it is also not possible prescribe sufficiently precise what each of the actors has to achieve individually. In addition, there are some general governance problems with regard to addressing single actions (such as shifting effects and rebound effects: see below). At the political level, there has been an impressive collection of sustainability programmes and declarations on an international, EU and national level to date, although this collection is conflicting with the still large ecological footprint per capita. This also applies to the much-discussed stipulations in the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC), in the Kyoto Protocol and now in the Paris Agreement, which sets a very ambitious temperature limit, but falls far short in all details of establishing instruments of implementation. The previous sustainability governance in terms of command-and-control law, information law, subsidy law, and procurement law offers a diverse picture which, overall, is not very effective measured against the ambitious (!) objectives (and only this way the effectiveness of instruments can be analysed). Keywords for severe governance problems especially with regard to sustainability include direct and indirect rebound effects (which also include wealth effects), resource-related, sectoral, and spatial shifting effects, lack of rigour, enforcement problems and problems of depicting. These governance problems can only be solved if sustainability issues are consistently understood as (mostly) quantity problems and which require ambitious quantity limits. Thus, those need to be established as core instrument of sustainability policy. The most promising approach of quantity governance in terms of sustainability would be a cap (and trade) approach or a similarly structured levies on central noxious agents. Given this is construed in a substantially and geographically broad way and with a clear orientation towards ambitious goals, the above-mentioned governance problems can be solved. Furthermore, the diagnosed motivational situations of citizens, companies and politicians (self-interest, conceptions or normality, etc.) can be adequately addressed—in a freedom- and democracy-friendly manner. Questions such as “certificate markets or levies”, “overall market or submarkets” or “costefficiency” are mostly overestimated, as is the question of which instruments should be labelled as economic or regulatory. The idea that the controlling effect of prices is only limited (allegedly due to price elasticity of demand) is based on several false assumptions. The existing EU emissions trading system (ETS) in the climate sector, however, solves almost none of the problems just listed, and neither do various tax approaches. The key instrument for climate protection as well as for other environmental problems would be a strict cap on fossil fuels in line with the temperature limit in Article 2 para. 1 Paris Agreement. This could be achieved by means of a completely revised emissions trading scheme that integrates all fossil fuels (instead of merely some industrial sectors) and commits to strict caps and closed loopholes. This could be started by the EU and other willing states and thus gradually removing fossil fuels from the market by 2030 or 2035. For individual citizens and businesses, this would result in increasing and soon relatively massive price incentives in favour of more efficiency, more renewable resources and, as is mostly neglected, frugality (whose necessity due to the very ambitious target is typically ignored in the economic discourse). The approach could gradually be extended to a global scale. The revenues of the system would essentially contribute to financing mitigation and adaptation in the participating countries of the Global South. An important complementary instrument are border adjustments towards non-willing states for imports and exports. Shifting effects for emissions or resource consumption (and competitive disadvantages) are thus avoided, and pressure is exerted on other states to participate in the system. At the same time, the economic viability of an effective sustainability policy can be demonstrated, ultimately paving the way for later global agreements. A quantity-controlling approach can be even advantageous from the point of view of social distribution, especially on a global scale, but also with regard to social inequalities within industrialised countries. It addresses both the long-term fatal social impacts of climate change and resource depletion as well as poverty reduction in developing countries. In addition, the model favours the establishment of administrative, educational and welfare institutions in developing countries, which will probably lead to slower population growth (which, like demographic change in general, is overinflated as a cause of problems and too little recognised as their consequence). Furthermore, in the North and South, permanently available and affordable energy is secured, a global race to the bottom in terms of eco-social standards is avoided, and positive effects on the labour market are also likely. In addition, compensation on a global scale and to a lesser extent also for the socially weaker in the industrialised countries is conceivable from the revenues of a quantity governance system. Global concepts for resource and sink problems can thus be linked to combatting poverty. If an integrated solution is to be sought for various environmental problems (climate, biodiversity, nitrogen, phosphorus, soils, water), a rapid phasing-out of fossil fuels is key. But a cap for livestock farming is similarly important. In connection with capping fossil fuels, this would trigger far-reaching changes also in agriculture, e.g. in the direction of organic farming, pasture farming and significantly lower consumption of animal food, which would in total greatly relieve biodiversity, soils, water, nitrogen (and phosphorus) cycles and public health. Other pricing instruments are also conceivable. In addition, in order to avoid hot spot problems and path dependencies, a number of supplementary command-and-control rules and subsidies (public money only for public goods and phasing-out of harmful subsidies) remain important in the area of sustainability, for example as additional tool for peatlands, forests and biodiversity protection. This would, however, be more selective and, moreover, would involve stricter and more stringent regulatory law in terms of content and enforcement than is currently the case. The same applies to informational and planning instruments. In contrast, direct pricing of control variables that are difficult to grasp, such as biodiversity, is not very effective. A sustainability policy that is pursued by a group of willing states has to assert itself against a global, borderless world economy. Cross-border free trade in particular has typical social and ecological defects and calls for regulatory containment of capitalist economic activity. This is true not only in terms of sustainability (in order to avoid shifting effects) but also in terms of democracy which is put under pressure by globalisation minimising the decisive power of domestic parliaments (legally and factually). The current state of establishing global liberal-democratic institutions is ethically and legally only partially compatible with the justification of a universal, global and intertemporal liberal-democratic law and ethics. At least, a sustainability pioneering role of some states is not prohibited under international trade law, including border adjustments for imports and exports. All in all, a categorical rejection of free market systems remains unconvincing even considering the concept of free trade. But whether open societies—and world peace—will survive the current (and very often fossil-fuel-based) challenges by autocracies, remains an open question.
Chapter
Non-sustainable societies can therefore be explained descriptively, but can sustainability be justified as a normative goal? The factual influence of values on our behaviour is limited. But when we ask what is normatively right, talking about values is the crucial level. Sustainability, in the sense of intertemporally and globally tenable ways of life and production, is a normative requirement. In order to justify this ethically and legally, a new foundation of universal justice is necessary. Common ethical approaches, which are intended to show the possibility of objective normative statements, prove to be not very convincing on closer inspection. The present theory of universal justice explores the limits of normative rationality and demonstrates that there is considerable scope for balancing without rendering normative questions purely subjective. Furthermore, the area of good living proves to be rationally intangible. The variant of universal justice developed here as the basis of ethics and law and thus also the concretisation of sustainability is a heterodox discourse ethics. It is designed as the basis of a revised ethical and right-interpretive conception of liberal democracy with human rights and separation of powers at the national, European and international level. In particular, the argument that there is no alternative and an elenctic argument justify (a) the possibility of reason in questions of about what is supposed to be and (b) human dignity, i.e. the respect for the autonomy of the individual, and impartiality as (the only) universal principles of justice that logically cannot be denied without self-contradiction. This proves right not only in discourse, but also in practice and also vis-à-vis merely hypothetical discourse partners, i.e. vis-à-vis all human beings. These principles provide the basis for a comprehensive universal right to liberty, which is not limited to certain areas of life, to a democracy with separation of powers, and to a duty to guarantee all this legally. This entire approach, centred around the liberal-democratic basic principles of reason, dignity, impartiality and freedom (and democracy with separation of powers), which in their (still unclear) connection appear for the first time with Kant, can be read as crucial modification of classical discourse ethics. In contrast, contextualistic, metaphysical and skeptic (including empiricist, e.g. utilitarian and cost-benefit-analytical) approaches which compete with a liberal-democratic universalism of discourse-ethical character prove to be unconvincing. This also applies to other versions of liberal-democratic theory such as those of Rawls or Sen. In order to determine concrete sustainability contents, an interpretation of the concept of sustainability itself or of topoi such as a legal “state objective for environmental protection” is not very promising, because it remains too vague. Rather, a new ethical and legal interpretation of human rights in the sense of overcoming a primarily economy-oriented understanding of freedom makes sense. This provides an ethically and legally stable basis for sustainability while at the same time overcoming the incompleteness of liberal-democratic philosophies. All statements on justice are statements on the social level. Ethical obligations of the individual that go beyond the obligation to bring about a just—including sustainable—social order are difficult to imagine inter alia due to a lack of concreteness under the auspices of sustainability problems as quantity problems. This is one of the reasons why human rights are always conveyed through public authority, even if their origin lies in the relationship between individuals. In general, human rights prove to be rights to freedom and to the elementary preconditions of freedom. A distinction of negative and positive freedom does not work. The ethical and legal interpretation that human rights only protect selected, supposedly particularly valuable freedom activities, is equally unconvincing. The humandignity principle (understood as the required respect for the autonomy of the individual, i.e. the principle of self-determination) and the impartiality principle understood as the required independence from specific perspectives) are not fundamental rights, nor are they intended to say anything at all about a concrete ethical or legal individual case. Rather, they are the basis for justifying and interpreting freedom and thus also for a sustainability-oriented reinterpretation of freedom, of the rules of balancing, and of democratic institutions. All this and more applies to liberal-democratic nation states, to the EU and also to international institutions and organisations—also based on a further developed figure of general principles of international law. Ethically and legally (also on a transnational level), as normative essence of sustainability, there is a right to the elementary preconditions of freedom. This means conditions such as life, health, subsistence level in the form of food, water, security, climate stability, elementary education, absence of war and civil war, etc. The protection of other freedom-promoting conditions, on the other hand, has no ethical or legal human-rights status, but nevertheless deserves recognition, albeit not the duty of the public authorities to act. This is where sustainability concerns are located if they are not elementary to freedom.—The possible alternative to the existing concept of freedom, which would be an ethics of capabilities or need, is rejected due to a number of logical and legal issues, problems of application, and illiberal tendencies. The freedom outlined in this way, including its elementary preconditions, deserves legal and ethical protection also intertemporally and globally, and thus leads to a human-rights-based theory of sustainability. In particular, arguments for this intertemporal and global extension can be formulated under aspects of potentiality and freedom protection where freedom is endangered. Counterarguments against an intertemporal-global protection of fundamental rights such as the future-individual paradox or the reference to unknown preferences of future generations are ultimately not convincing. The precautionary principle can be classified as a sub-aspect of human rights; it reflects their protection even in uncertain, long-term and multi-causal risk situations. Furthermore, freedom also contains protection by the state, not only defense against the state. These insights are not rendered irrelevant by certain widespread objections to such a multipolar understanding of freedom (e.g. in relation to democracy and the separation of powers). The classical distinctions of action and omission and also deontology versus consequentialism thus latently lose their object. Only in view of all of these steps it is possible to interpret human rights in a manner which includes the protection against climate change, dwindling resources, etc. and thus concrete normative sustainability criteria become conceivable. Environmental-ethical pathocentrism or eco-centrism can make no additional contribution to the normative theory of sustainability issues, since these approaches prove to be untenable at closer inspection. Nevertheless, environmental protection has a comprehensive ethical and legal justification. In general, freedom is limited only by freedom and the preconditions of freedom of other people, not by any form of common good or the like, which should rather be rejected as a concept. Questions of the good life elude regulation, which is why the ethical and legal justification of sustainability measures does not refer to the subsequent possibly greater happiness of those whose freedom is restricted. Discourses on frugality and nudging, for example, are often based on false assumptions in this respect. Main issues of the welfare state can be identified as sustainability phenomena, taking the threat of climate change into account, although the possibility of objectively answering distributional questions is often overestimated. Ethical and legal decisions can only be understood as a balancing situation (between various freedoms, elementary preconditions of freedom, further freedom promoting conditions and everything that can be derived from all of the above). Any sustainability decision is thus marked by normative and factual uncertainties (which is usually overlooked). Concrete problems such as “strong versus weak sustainability” or the relevance of a specific argument can only be meaningfully resolved within this theoretical framework. The ethical and legal theory of sustainability is also developed as a transformed theory of democracy and of balance of powers. The main victims of today’s unsustainability are not voters of today’s parliaments and governments, but future generations and people in other countries. Sustainability is thus in conflict with democracy, to which it—on the other hand—has an affinity because of the necessity of discourses and learning processes (which also rules out any kind of ecodictatorship). Institutional innovations compared to the existence of democracies based on separation of powers are only indicated to a limited extent in the context of sustainability. The most important point is to establish liberal-democratic institutions on an international level in addition to the national sphere. The right balancing rules, which are the very basis for normative sustainability statements, can be obtained through a legal and ethical balancing theory, which goes beyond traditional legal and ethical approaches and sociological risk theory. These balancing rules outline the scope normatively rational statements which are possible to make e.g. on sustainability and which are based on liberal-democratic principles. Rules of procedure and fact-finding rules can also be derived, as can a new human-rights understanding of the precautionary principle in law and ethics. There are also rules for taking new findings in valuations and facts into account. In the interplay of the powers (nationally and transnationally), the violation of balancing rules leads to an obligation to make a new decision in compliance with the previously violated rule—and thus ultimately to an obligation to (significantly) more sustainability. Violated rules in terms of sustainability concern e.g. the factual basis of climate policy to date and the polluter pays principle. The most important rule for the context of sustainability is the prohibition to ruin the basis of balancing as such by depriving its physical foundations. In spite of all remaining leeway, this already carries a human rights obligation similar to the extent of the 1.5-degree temperature limit in Article 2 para. 1 Paris Agreement. A partly similar statement can be made for other resource and sink challenges, but not for all of them. If using further balancing rules such as the polluter pays principle and economic capacity, it is also possible to give some indications as to how the efforts and costs of mitigation and adaptation should be distributed globally. All this is also meant as an alternative to the economic cost-benefit analysis, which ultimately represents an empiricist ethics in disguise. It is not only based on a (hidden) untenable normative basic theory and has unsolvable application problems. It also finds itself in insoluble conflicts with a liberal-democratic legal system that does not allocate rights according to solvency and does not primarily organise votes as plebiscitary snapshots.
Chapter
On the basis of the normative theory of sustainability just laid out, effective implementation measures can be identified. In a first step, a number of promising starting points can be identified for individual and entrepreneurial action as well as for educational measures. Education, voluntary corporate social responsibility (CSR) and consumer engagement can play a role, but they cannot eliminate the need to contain capitalist economic activity and daily life through effective policy instruments, especially with regard to sustainability. Knowledge and intrinsic (self-interested or value-driven) motivation alone cannot trigger the necessary transformation. At the level of the individual person or company, it is also not possible prescribe sufficiently precise what each of the actors has to achieve individually. In addition, there are some general governance problems with regard to addressing single actions (such as shifting effects and rebound effects: see below).
Chapter
Non-sustainable societies can therefore be explained descriptively, but can sustainability be justified as a normative goal? The factual influence of values on our behaviour is limited. But when we ask what is normatively right, talking about values is the crucial level. Sustainability, in the sense of intertemporally and globally tenable ways of life and production, is a normative requirement. In order to justify this ethically and legally, a new foundation of universal justice is necessary. Common ethical approaches, which are intended to show the possibility of objective normative statements, prove to be not very convincing on closer inspection. The present theory of universal justice explores the limits of normative rationality and demonstrates that there is considerable scope for balancing without rendering normative questions purely subjective. Furthermore, the area of good living proves to be rationally intangible.
Article
Full-text available
In this paper we evaluate the potential benefits of international disciplines on policies towards foreign direct investment, paying particular attention to developing countries. We conclude that, at present, the case for initiating negotiations on investment policies is weak. Negotiations that center on improving market access on a nondiscriminatory basis, especially in services, are likely to be more fruitful: although imperfect, existing multilateral instruments such as the General Agreement on Trade in Services, are far from fully exploited and provide significant opportunities for governments to improve market access.
Article
Full-text available
Les normes de travail définies par l’OIT en 1998 sont universelles mais très différemment appliquées dans les pays. Elles sont d’autant mieux respectées que les pays disposent d’un revenu élevé. Néanmoins la causalité entre les normes de travail et la croissance reste une question controversée. Les stratégies de croissance par les exportations peuvent inciter les pays en développement à contenir la progression des normes de travail d’une part pour accroître leur dotation en travail non qualifié et ainsi renforcer leur avantage comparatif relativement aux pays qui les respectent, d’autre part à mener des stratégies de « dumping social » qui visent à accroître plus directement la compétitivité. Nous utilisons un modèle de gravité en coupe pour évaluer l’impact du niveau de respect des normes de travail sur le commerce en distinguant d’une part les effets bilatéraux sur la spécialisation géographique et, d’autre part, les effets sur l’ouverture aux exportations et aux importations. Nous montrons que, toutes choses égales par ailleurs, les pays qui respectent les normes de travail tendent à échanger davantage avec les pays qui ne respectent pas les normes de travail qu’entre eux, alors que les pays qui ne les respectent pas tendent à échanger davantage entre eux. Ces effets jouent surtout sur le travail des enfants et la liberté d’association. De même, toutes choses égales par ailleurs, les pays qui respectent les normes de travail, tendent à être moins ouverts que les pays qui ne les respectent pas mais de manière différente selon les normes avec une relation non-linéaire pour certaines d’entre elles (travail des enfants, travail forcé). Labour standards defined by the ILO in 1998 are universal but applied very differently in countries. They are much better respected in high income countries. However, the causality between labour standards and growth remains a controversial issue. The strategies of export-led growth might encourage developing countries to contain the rising process of standards, first to increase their unskilled labour endowments for strengthening their comparative advantage relative to complying countries, and then to pursue strategies of "social dumping", which aim more directly at increasing competitiveness. We use a gravity model to assess the trade impact of pushing back the level of compliance with labour standards in distinguishing one hand the effects on bilateral trade (geographical specialization) and, secondly, the effects on the export and import openness. We show that, other things being equal, countries that meet the standards of work tend to trade more with no-complying countries, while countries that do not respect standards tend to trade more each other. These effects are mainly identified on child labour and freedom of association. Similarly, all other things being equal, countries that meet labour standards, tend to be less open than countries that do not comply but in different ways according to the standards with a non-linear relationship for some of them (child labour, forced labour). oui
Chapter
It is a cliché to say that we live in a globalized world in which investment flows. Communications, and the operations of multinationals from all parts of the world have changed the character of the international business environment. But they say the concept of globalization poses as many questions as it answers, and it is the purpose of this book to address these challenges. In Governments, Globalization, and International Business a prestigious group of international scholars describe and analyse the deepening globalization of the world economy and its implication for governments, firms, and different regions of the world. In doing so, they also consider the increasing mobility of knowledge and information, the role of multinational entrepreneurs, and the sovereignty of nation states in an emerging borderless world. After the introduction by the editor, the book is arranged in three parts: The analytical framework (5 chapters), Country case studies (10 chapters), and The implications for national and supra‐national governments (2 chapters).
Article
In developing countries today children play significant economic roles. Field studies show that children in many developing countries are economically active in both rural and urban settings. This cross-national study investigates the economic roles of children in contemporary developing and developed countries. Dependency theory guides hypotheses that a less developed country’s dependence on the more developed core countries (measured by multinational corporation penetration and commodity concentration) serves to create a labor market within the less developed country where children are economically active. Additional hypotheses regarding the influence of female labor force participation on increased child labor and urban growth on increased child labor are also tested. Regression analyses, based on demographic data from 70 developed and developing countries, reveal that dependency variables (multi-national corporation penetration and commodity concentration) are not positively related to children’s labor force participation. Urban growth and female labor force participation however, are positively related to children’s labor force participation. These results suggest an important link between women’s roles and the roles of children and the influence of urbanization on children. The utility of dependency theory to the understanding of children’s labor force activity is also challenged.
Article
Five readily distinguishable industrial relations systems are identified based on differences in education levels, hourly compensation costs and various government and collective bargaining constraints placed on management’s freedom to set the terms and conditions of employment. A model of foreign direct investment (FDI) that incorporates these key industrial relations variables is then specified and tested against US FDI across a sample of nine industries and 33 industrialized and developing countries. The industrial relations system variables significantly influence US FDI abroad. In particular, education is negatively related to FDI across low skill–low wage countries but is positively related to FDI across high skill–high wage countries. Higher hourly compensation costs (apparently capturing higher productivity) are associated with greater FDI. Whereas government restrictions on layoffs, union penetration and centralized negotiation structures are negatively related to US FDI, the ratification of ILO standards and works council policies are positively related to US FDI. Based on these findings, the FDI attractiveness of industrial relations systems are compared and policy implications discussed.
Book
Antiglobalist forces have been gaining greater momentum in recent years in their efforts to reverse what they view as the negative effects of an integrating global economy. Their influence wasfelt earlier when efforts to create a Multilateral Agreement on Investment (MAI) ended in failure in 1998 after France left the bargaining table at the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, effectively killing the initiative. * In this book, through an evaluation of the MAI itself and the issues raised by its opponents, Edward M. Graham takes a fresh look atthe growing backlash against globalization. He first explores whether the MAI negotiations failed due to political maneuvering by antiglobalist nongovernmental organizations (supported by US organized labor) or because of irreconcilable differences among the negotiating parties over the substance of the issue of foreign direct investment. He then objectively and thoroughly assesses antiglobalist assertions that the activities of multinational firms have had negative effects on workers both in the home (investor) and host (recipient) nations, with a special focus on developing nations. An important finding is that multinational firms tend to pay workers in developing nations wages that are significantly above prevailing wages. Graham then examines the issue of globalized economic activity and the environment, finding that economic growth in developing nations can lead to increased environmental stress but also finding that foreign direct investment can lead to reductions in this stress. He finds that the worry of many environmentalists of a "race to the bottom" is not borne out by the evidence. * The final chapters assess whether or not a negotiation to create a comprehensive agreement on investment should be included in a multilateral negotiating round at the World Trade Organization in the near future. The interests of developing nations in this agenda are given special attention. Graham indicates that, while many developing nations would accept such rules, it might nonetheless be premature to press for a comprehensive agreement at this time. Rather, a limited investment agenda might be both more feasible and more productive.
Article
World Development Indicators, the World Bank's respected statistical publication presents the most current and accurate information on global development on both a national level and aggregated globally. This information allows readers to monitor the progress made toward meeting the goals endorsed by the United Nations and its member countries, the World Bank, and a host of partner organizations in September 2001 in their Millennium Development Goals. The print edition of World Development Indicators 2005 allows you to consult over 80 tables and over 800 indicators for 152 economies and 14 country groups, as well as basic indicators for a further 55 economies. There are key indicators for the latest year available, important regional data, and income group analysis. The report contains six thematic presentations of analytical commentary covering: World View, People, Environment, Economy, States and Markets, and Global Links.