ArticlePDF Available

Organic Farming Policies and the Growth of the Organic Sector in Denmark and the UK: A Comparative Analysis

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

There has been little systematic analysis of the extent to which organic farming policies have influenced growth in the organic sector. Analyses of organic farming policy instruments, for the most part, provide extensive and detailed reviews of instruments applied either in a single country or across countries. Hence, there is a great need to examine systematically whether there is a relationship between the introduction of organic farming policies and the growth of the organic food sector, and whether particular designs of organic farming policies are more effective than others. In this paper, we take the first step in the endeavour of analysing the effects of organic farming by undertaking an econometric analysis of the relationship between organic farming policies in Denmark and the UK and their effects on the number of farmers and growers converting to organic production.
Content may be subject to copyright.
ORGANIC FARMING POLICIES AND THE GROWTH OF
THE ORGANIC SECTOR IN DENMARK AND THE UK:
A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS
Carsten Daugbjerg (corresponding author)1, Richard Tranter2 and Garth Holloway3
1 Department of Political Science, University of Aarhus, Universitetsparken,
DK-8000 Aarhus C, Denmark, E-mail: cd[a]ps.au.dk
2 School of Agriculture, Policy and Development, University of Reading, P O Box 237,
Earley Gate, Reading RG6 6AR, United Kingdom, E-mail: r.b.tranter[a]reading.ac.uk
E-Mail: garth.holloway[a]reading.ac.uk
AbstractThere has been little systematic analysis of
the extent to which organic farming policies have influ-
enced growth in the organic sector. Analyses of organic
farming policy instruments, for the most part, provide
extensive and detailed reviews of instruments applied ei-
ther in a single country or across countries. Hence, there
is a great need to examine systematically whether there
is a relationship between the introduction of organic
farming policies and the growth of the organic food sec-
tor, and whether particular designs of organic farming
policies are more effective than others. In this paper, we
take the first step in the endeavour of analysing the ef-
fects of organic farming by undertaking an econometric
analysis of the relationship between organic farming
policies in Denmark and the UK and their effects on the
number of farmers and growers converting to organic
production.
Topics: (1) sustainability, (2) institutions, (3) environment
and resources
Key words: organic farming, policy
Archived at http://orgprints.org/13954
I. INTRODUCTION
There has been little systematic analysis of the extent
to which organic farming policies have influenced
growth in the organic sector. Analyses of organic
farming policy instruments tend to provide extensive
and detailed reviews of instruments applied either in a
single country or across countries, but offer no theo-
retically informed considerations on what mix of pol-
icy instruments contribute most to the growth of the
organic sector. For instance, Lampkin et al. (1999
p.vii) list the forms of state ‘support’ to organic sec-
tors under four categories: payments to producers;
marketing and regional development; legal definition
of organic; and information provision. Other, but not
dissimilar, studies have analysed the extent to which
organic farming policies have motivated farmers to
convert into organic production (e.g. Michelsen 2002)
or affected the economic viability of such farms (Col-
man 2000, Häring 2003, Tranter et al. 2007). Häring et
al. (2004, 25) observe that the development stage of
organic farming varies significantly across European
countries and argue that ‘different design of subsidies
for organic farming greatly influences the actual effect
on organic farming development’. However, it is less
clear precisely how these policy instruments bring
about growth in the organic sector.
So, there is a great need to examine systematically
whether there is a relationship between the introduc-
tion of organic farming policies and the growth of the
organic sector, and whether particular designs of or-
ganic farming policies are more effective than others.
Here, we take the first step in the endeavour of analys-
ing the effects of organic farming policies in Denmark
and the UK. We attempt to establish whether state or-
ganic farming policies affected farmers’ willingness to
convert to organic farming and which measures had a
significant impact.
II. COMPARISON OF DANISH AND UK OR-
GANIC FARMING POLICIES
In this section, we provide an overview over organic
farming policies in Denmark and the UK, distinguish-
ing between four types of policy instruments: direct
supply-side policy instruments, indirect supply-side
policy instruments, direct demand-side policy instru-
ments and indirect demand-side policy instruments.
A. Direct supply-side policy instruments
In both countries, direct supply side policy instruments
have been pivotal in the development of organic farm-
ing policy.
Denmark: Denmark was the first country to enact a
distinct law on organic farming (1987). It introduced
subsidies to ease conversion from conventional to or-
ganic farming for the first three years of the conver-
sion period. In 1989, additional conversion payments
for organic livestock were introduced.
As a consequence of implementation of EC Regula-
tion 2078/93, permanent subsidies for organic farming
were introduced in 1994 (see Table 1). This scheme
provided conversion subsidies, based on area, for two
years and permanent organic subsidies. To be eligible,
farmers had to farm organically for at least five years.
Table 1. Danish organic area payments, 1994-1997 (DKK
per hectare)
Year 1994 1995 1996
Conversion payment 300 275 200
Permanent organic payments 750 600 450
Payment for reduced fertiliser use 650 525 400
Supplement for environmentally sensitive
areas
215 215 215
Source : Bekendtgørelse no. 250, 1994.
To increase the supply of organic arable products and
pig meat, the subsidy was altered in 1996 (Table 2).
Additional support was provided to organic farms
without milk quotas and a special subsidy to pig pro-
ducers was also introduced (Strukturdirektoratet 1999,
136). In 2000, it was decided that support schemes di-
rected at selective commodity groups had to be abol-
ished. The market was perceived as a better means to
determine the level and type of organic production. In
the support scheme which came into effect in 2004,
permanent organic subsidies were abolished and farm-
ers were paid an environmental subsidy with organic
farming being given first priority for this. The only
remaining organic subsidy was the general conversion
payment to which only non-dairy farmers were eligi-
ble. Up to 2007 there was no wish to increase organic
milk production so dairy farmers were not eligible for
conversion subsidies. However, in 2006 forecasts en-
visaged future under-supply of organic milk so dairy
farmers again became eligible for conversion subsi-
dies.
3
Table 2. Danish organic area payments 1997-2003 (DKK
per hectare)
Year of five year obliga-
tion period
1 2 3 4 5
Permanent organic pay-
ments4,6
600 600 600 600 600
Conversion payment5,7 450 450
Supplement for envi-
ronmentally sensitive ar-
eas
500 500 500 500 500
Payment for farms with-
out dairy quota
2000 2000 12001,3 5001,3 5001,3
Payment for pig produc-
tion2
2000 2000 2000
Maximum area payment 5000 5000 4000 3500 3500
Maximum payment for
pig farms
5000 5000 5000 5000 5000
Source: Bekendtgørelse 226 1997; 881 1998; 883 2002; 700 2007,
Direktoratet for FødevareErhverv 2002, Økologisk Jordbrugsproduktion:
Vejledning om arealtilskud 2003.
1 Not paid to pig farmers.
2 This payment expired on 2 November 2002.
3 This payment was introduced in December 1998. It was not paid for the
five-year period that followed.
4 850 DKK until December 1998.
5 200 DKK until December 1998.
6 Before 1 January 1998 this payment was not paid to permanent grass
fields.
7 Not paid to permanent grass fields.
UK: Before 1993, Tranter et al. (2008) argued that
‘development of the European (and UK) organic sec-
tor was predominantly supply driven’ growing from
two broad strands - an ideological method of food
production and the encouragement by scientists inter-
ested in the link between soil and health. However,
since then the growth of organic farming has been
largely demand led to satisfy increasingly affluent
consumers (Willer, 2006); the UK government has en-
couraged farmers to meet this demand and, to help
them through the difficult conversion years, has pro-
vided financial assistance. The Organic Aid Scheme
(OAS) was the first such measure introduced in 1994
following EC Council Regulation 2078/92 allowing
Member States to provide financial support for con-
version under the agri-environment regulation (EC,
1992).
However, rates of payment under the OAS were
relatively low compared with other countries and up-
take was poor. Therefore, a new scheme was designed
to encourage further conversion - the Organic Farming
Scheme (OFS) which replaced the OAS in April 1999
- a move concurrent with the amendment of EC Regu-
lation 2092/91 to include livestock. The OFS was
seen as more helpful than the OAS: a one-off lump
sum payment was made of €750 per holding, spread
over three years for purchase of consultancy advice;
and (Table 3) payment rates were much higher than
under the OAS.
Table 3. Organic Farming Support Payments for England
1994-2007 (€ ha-1)1
OAS2
1994-
9
OFS3 from 1999
OAP4
2003-
Total Y1 Y2 Y3 Y4 Y5 Total Y1-5
AAPS5 eli-
gible land
and land in
permanent
crops
409 368 220 82 33 33 736 49
Other im-
proved land
82 286 172 65 25 25 573 38
Unimproved
land6
60 41 17 8 8 8 82 8
Source: Adapted from Tranter et al. (2007).
1 The exchange rate for 1 April 2002 of £1 = €1.04 has been used.
2 Organic Aid Scheme
3 Organic Farming Scheme
4 Organic Action Plan amendment to OFS, ongoing support once conver-
sion completed
5 Arable Area Payments Scheme
6 Such as moorland, rough grazing land and heath
The OFS was immediately successful leading to an in-
crease of some 150,000 ha in the area of organically
managed land in nine months. Indeed, the scheme was
forced to close after six months when the budget allo-
cated for the first two years was spent up (Lobley et
al., 2005). It reopened in January 2001.
In June 2003, on-going support after conversion
was introduced for a period of five years (Table 3). It
is likely that this on-going support was the cause of
numbers of producers and growers rising despite the
organic area falling since mid-2003.
The OFS closed to new entrants in March 2005 and
replaced by Organic Entry Level Stewardship, part of
the new Environmental Stewardship Scheme. The ra-
tionale for this was that organic farming provides
greater environmental benefits than conventional
farming. Hence, organic farmers receive €98 per ha
per year (twice the conventional rate) and have to farm
in a prescribed manner for five years. Payments are
also available for conversion with different rates for
different types of land and planned land uses (Defra,
2007e).
4
B. Indirect supply-side policy instruments
Denmark: In 1984 the National Association for Or-
ganic Farming agreed with the Smallholders’ Union
on the provision of an organic advisory service. Once
an organic extension service had been integrated into
the established advisory service, the Smallholders’
Union utilised its parliamentary contacts to have state
financial support for employing organic farming advi-
sors.
In 1996, funding was provided for additional advice
to farmers who were considering converting to organic
farming and, in 1997, a scheme was introduced in
which the state provided for 90% of the cost of con-
version advice 12 months before and after conversion.
In the mid-1990s, the state also provided funding for
teaching and information activities for organic farming
and the publication of organic farming manuals. Fur-
thermore, compulsory courses were introduced at
farming colleges (Strukturdirektoratet 1999, annex 1,
6-10).
An important component of Danish organic farming
policies has been state-funded research. In 1992, 50
million DKK for an organic research programme for
1993-1997 was allocated (Strukturdirektoratet 1999).
In 1996 the Danish Research Centre for Organic
Farming was established to coordinate research. The
most recent programme had a budget of 200 million
DKK for 2005 to 2011
(http://www.foejo.dk/forskning/index.html).
The Product Development Scheme provided in-
creased funding for organic product innovation pro-
jects in relation to production and processing. Innova-
tion projects for processing organic produce were also
eligible for increased support under the Food Technol-
ogy Research Programme (Strukturdirektoratet 1995,
154-55).
UK: Some financial, technical and marketing advice
was belatedly made available in the UK from June
1996. As a result of the poor uptake of the OAS, the
Government introduced the Organic Conversion In-
formation Service (OCIS) which supplied free, on-
farm, technical advice and information on conversion.
By 2001, 6,500 farmers had received a half-day visit
under OCIS and 2,400 farmers also made use of the
follow-up full day consultancy (Defra, 2002b). The
OFS, introduced in April 1999 gave a one-off lump
sum of €750 per holding, spread over three years, for
the purchase of consultancy advice.
Due to budgetary constraints, Defra closed the
OCIS on 31 December 2006. However, they said they
intended to re-open it in the future (Defra, 2006). Fi-
nally, a further measure introduced by Government to
aid organic farming was the publication of the ‘Action
plan to develop organic food and farming in England’
(Defra, 2002b) to identify what was needed to ensure
stable and strategic growth for the organic sector.
The Government has funded research on organic
production since 1991 when their spend was some
£500,000; in the 10 years after this it rose five times to
around £2.5 million a year (Costigan, 2002). In an in-
vestigation for Defra, the Elm Farm Research Centre
et al. (2005) found that: ‘total funding in UK organic
food and farming R&D between January 2000 and
March 2005 was in the region of £45 million with the
majority coming from the public purse (90%)’. Most
of this was experimental with crops research being the
most heavily funded area.
C. Direct demand-side policy instruments
Neither Denmark nor the UK apply direct demand-
side policy instruments. However, in Denmark, it has
been suggested that state, regional and local govern-
ment canteens should only use organic produce. So
far, government has refused to introduce such regula-
tions.
In the UK, Defra (2004) reviewed their original
‘Action plan’ to check on progress two years on. They
put forward ideas on how there should be an increase
in public procurement of organic food and measures
for the whole UK increasing the level of indigenous
sourcing of organic produce to 70% of the total by
2010. The major UK certification body announced
their expertise and availability for the provision of ad-
vice on public procurement of organic food matters
(Soil Association 2006b).
D. Indirect demand-side policy instruments
Denmark: The Law on Organic Farming of 1987 set
up state certification and labelling for organic farming.
The state label is the sole national organic label and
can only be applied by enterprises producing, process-
ing, packaging or labelling organic produce in Den-
mark. The introduction of the state label meant that
only state-certified farms would be allowed to sell or-
ganically labelled products and receive state support.
This caused some aggravation within the National Or-
ganic Farming Association (Nielsen 2005, 76-78) but,
as the state label became a success, the Association’s
dissatisfaction vanished. In 2002 and 2004, state
funding was provided to information campaigns about
the national state label and the EU label. Farmers do
5
not pay for certification and inspection; the costs of
operating the system are part of the involved agencies’
annual budget.
In addition to providing conversion subsidies, the
1987 Law on Organic Farming also granted financial
support for development initiatives related to process-
ing, marketing and distribution of organic food. From
1996-99, the state spent 100 million DKK subsidising
market research, product development and marketing
of organic produce. After 1999, the state continued
providing such support but funds allocated for these
activities declined from a peak of 97 million DKK in
2000 to 10 in 2005, but were increased again in 2007
to 40 million DKK. Between 1997 and 2000, the state
allocated 20 million DKK for training and other con-
version activities in state, regional and local govern-
ment canteens which wanted to use organic produce
(Strukturdirektoratet, 1999, 28). After 2000, this pro-
gramme was retained as part of the Innovation Act
(Bekendtgørelse no. 318, 2001 and Bekendtgørelse no.
865, 2006). The School of Organic Sales received
support to provide advice to these institutions and,
since 1998, the Veterinary and Food Safety Agency
has launched information campaigns on organic food
directed towards consumers, retailers and processors
(ibid., 26, see www.dffe.dk)
UK: In 1987, the Ministry of Agriculture, Fisheries
and Food founded the UK Register of Organic Food
Standards (UKROFS) to set baseline organic standards
and to approve and monitor the work of certification
bodies (Defra, 2002a). UKROFS standards were the
minimum standards which applied in the UK and were
based on EC regulation 2092/91 (EC, 1991). UK-
ROFS was succeeded in July 2003 by the Advisory
Committee of Organic Standards which provides gov-
ernment departments with advice on key areas relating
to organic production (Defra, 2007a). The Soil Asso-
ciation is by far the most important certification body
in the UK certifying over 80% of all organic food be-
ing sold in the UK. They inspect and license over
4,400 organic producers and manufacturers (Soil As-
sociation 2006a).
E. Comparison of organic policy instruments between
Denmark and the UK
Table 4 compares Danish and UK organic farming
policy instruments. It shows that such policy measures
were introduced 7 years earlier in Denmark than in the
UK and that the Danish government applies a greater
variety of policy instruments. Indirect supply-side pol-
icy instruments play a much greater role in Denmark
than in Britain, and did so early on in the rise in the
organic sector. Also, with the exception of state ac-
creditation of certification and labelling, the Danish
state is significantly more involved in creating demand
for organic produce through the introduction of a vari-
ety of indirect demand-side policy measures. The im-
portance given to demand-side and indirect supply-
side policy measures becomes clear when comparing
the funding for conversion and permanent organic
subsidies provided to farmers with those granted to
development projects. From 1988-94, 58% of the out-
lays under the Law on Organic Farming were spent on
such measures and only 42% on conversion and per-
manent subsidies for farmers. Within the first two
years after the introduction of subsidies for organic
Table 4. A comparison of organic farming policy typology between Denmark and the UK
Supply-side policy instruments (push) Demand-side policy instruments (pull)
Direct Indirect Direct Indirect
Denmark:
• Conversion subsidies introduced
in 1987. Additional conversion sub-
sidies for arable and pig farmers in-
troduced in 1996.
• Permanent organic subsidies in-
troduced in 1994.
UK:
• Conversion subsidies introduced
in 1994; increased in 1999.
• On-going organic subsidies intro-
duced in 2003
Denmark:
• Subsidies for organic extension in-
troduced in 1984.
• Support for education of organic
farmers introduced in 1995.
• Grants for organic research intro-
duced in 1992 .
UK:
• Limited subsidies for technical as-
sistance introduced in 1996.
• Free conversion advice introduced
in 1996.
• Further subsidy of technical advice
in 1999.
Denmark:
• None
UK:
• None
Denmark:
• State certification and labelling intro-
duced in 1987; fully operational in 1989.
• State sponsored market research and
marketing campaigns from 1988.
UK:
• State accreditation of certification
schemes and labels in 1987.
• Limited subsidies for marketing advice
introduced in 1996.
farming, approximately 50% of the outlays went to
development projects (Strukturdirektoratet 1995, 162).
However, as a result of the conversion waves of the
mid- and late 1990s, farm subsidies consumed most of
the budget for organic policy from 1997 onwards.
III. ASSESSING THE IMPACTS OF ORGANIC
POLICY MILESTONES EMPIRICALLY
Organic policy measures, or milestones, have been
considerable both in terms of complexity and in terms
of their intentions in both countries. And, while no
clear thematic developments emerge about their gen-
eral direction, their coverage and their precise influ-
ence on decisions by producers to switch from con-
ventional to organic production, the availability of
data concerning the timing of events and the numbers
of producers in the organic and non-organic subsec-
tors, raises considerable scope for nuanced empirical
enquiry.
Table 5 presents the data we used where it can be
seen that, in both study countries, the number of or-
ganic producers and growers grew by at least 20 times
in around 20 years. Thus, there does appear to be
some relationship between the ever-increasing num-
bers of organic producers in both the Danish and Brit-
ish agricultural sectors and the cumulative impacts of
the separate policy measures or milestones as we eye-
ball the series in Table 5. Whether these trends are
part of any systematic factors in either sector, or col-
lectively, is the matter we now take up in detail.
IV. METHODOLOGY
We interpret the data in three ways, where each is
linked with an over-arching common theme - that the
possibility exists that the separate policy milestones
have incrementally contributed to the growth of the
organic farming sectors in the UK and Denmark. In
order to assess this conjecture, we incorporate the data
using three alternative estimation vehicles. The first is
a simple linear regression with a binary variable indi-
cating the range of time over which each milestone
was enacted or in operation. Several of the policy
milestones continue in coverage throughout the end-
point of the range of the time series in question, which
is the period of monthly observations from 1989:1 to
2007:1 (217 in total); others existed for shorter peri-
ods. At interest, then, is the set of stepped response
functions that we manufacture for the purpose of
measuring a linear response in the regression relation-
ship with numbers of organic producers as the right-
hand side response.
A concern in this context is the fact that only 18 re-
sponse points exist for the various months. As de-
tailed in the methodological appendix, we treat the
missing values as latent data in the linear regressions.
On the right-hand side marketing-sales assistance for
organic producers is missing at one point, so we use
the average of the preceding and following periods.
Table 5. Area of organically managed land, number of organic producers and organic policy milestones, Den-
mark and UK, 1989-2007
Year
Organic land area
(’000 ha)
Organic producers
and growers Organic policy milestones
United Kingdom
Oct 89 18.3 557
Apr 93 30.4 655 EC Reg 2092/91 became effective 23 Jul 92
Feb 94 30.7 715 Organic Aid Scheme (OAS) introduced 1 Aug 94
Apr 95 45.2 828
Apr 96 48.2 865 Organic Conversion Information Service (OCIS) introduced 1 Jul 96
Apr 97 50.8 828
Apr 98 81.9 1064
Apr 99 276.0 1568 OAS closed & Organic Farming Scheme (OFS) introduced 1 Apr 99. OFS closed 1 Oct 99.
EC Reg 2092/91 amd to include livestock 1 Jul 99
Jan 00 425.9
Dec 00 527.3 2865
Dec 01 679.6 3691 OFS reopened 1 Jan 01
Jun 02 699.9 3865
Dec 02 724.5
Mar 03 741.2 4104 Ongoing support under Organic Action Plan introduced 1 Jun 03
Jan 04 695.0 4072
Jan 05 674.5 4321 Organic Entry Level Scheme introduced 1 Apr 05 & OFS closed 31 Mar 05
Jan 06 619.9 4285 OCIS closed 31 Dec 06
Jan 07 619.8 4639
Denmark
15 Jan 88: organic area conversion subsidies are introduced
1989 9.6 401 15 Jan 89: livestock subsidies introduced
1990 11.6 523
1991 18.0 672
1992 18.6 675
1993 20.0 640 1 Jan 93: extension & advisory service introduced
1994 21.1 676 16 Apr 94: permanent organic subsidies introduced; livestock subsidies abolished
1995 40.9 1050
1996 46.2 1166
1997 64.3 1617 27 Mar 97: special conversion subsidy for pig producers introduced; and for farms with-
out dairy quota introduced
1998 99.2 2228
1999 146.7 3099
2000 165.3 3466
2001 173.5 3525
2002 178.4 3714 2 Nov 02: special conversion subsidy for pig producers abolished
2003 168.0 3510 1 Nov 03: special conversion payment for farms without dairy abolished; a basic scheme
for permanent and conversion subsidies retained; dairy farmers no longer eligible to con-
version subsidies
2004 160.2 3166
2005 150.8 3036
2006 144.3 2794
Table 6. Empirical results
Coefficients OLS-UK OLS-Denmark Seemingly Unrelated Regressions
1 -0.12 0.03 0.19 0.23 0.26 0.29
2 -0.17 0.01 0.20 -0.03 0.01 0.05
3 -0.11 0.04 0.18 -0.03 0.01 0.05
4 -0.04 0.08 0.20 -0.01 0.03 0.07
5 0.19 0.32 0.45 -0.03 0.02 0.07
6 0.31 0.51 0.70 -0.06 -0.01 0.05
7 -0.17 -0.04 0.09 -0.00 0.04 0.09
8 0.06 0.28 0.50 0.01 0.08 0.15
9 -0.19 -0.00 0.19 -0.07 0.12 0.32
10 -0.07 0.11 0.29 -0.04 0.15 0.34
11 -0.20 -0.02 0.16 -0.03 0.04 0.10
12 -0.00 0.24 0.49 -0.03 0.17 0.37
13 -0.15 0.03 0.22 -0.11 -0.03 0.05
14 0.10 0.34 0.59 -0.02 0.07 0.17
15 0.33 0.46 0.61 0.05 0.11 0.17
16 -0.02 0.28 0.58 -0.13 -0.04 0.06
17 0.06 0.18 0.30 -0.04 0.01 0.06
18 0.06 0.09 0.14 0.00 0.01 0.01
19 0.06 0.09 0.14 0.01 0.01 0.02
20 -0.00 -0.00 0.00
'1. UK constant
'2. EC Reg 2092/91 became effective 23 Jul 92',...
'3. Organic Aid Scheme introduced 1 Aug 94',...
'4. (OCIS) introduced 1 Jul 96',...
'5. Organic Farming Scheme introduced 1 Apr 99',...
'6. EC Reg 2092/91 amd to include livestock 1 Jul 99',...
'7. Ongoing support under Organic Action Plan introduced 1 Jun 03',...
'8. Organic Entry Level Scheme introduced 1 Apr 05',...
'9. Denmark constant
'10. Jan 89: livestock subsidies introduced',...
'11. Jan 93: extension & advisory service introduced',...
'12. Apr 94: permanent organic subsidies introduced',...
'13. Mar 97: special conversion subsidy for pig producers',...
'14. Mar 97: special conversion subsidy for farms without dairy quota',...
'15. Mar 97 basic scheme for permanent and conversion subsidies retained',...
'16. marketing costs and expenditures',...
'17. marketing dummy for period 2001-2004')
'18. the variance parameter in the UK model.
'19. the variance parameter in the DK model.
'20. the cross-country correlation between UK and DK errors in the regressions.
V. RESULTS AND CONCLUSIONS
In the first model, we estimate separate regressions for
the Danish and UK time series obtaining the results
reported in Table 6. In this Table, column 1 indexes
the policy milestones explained at the foot of the table;
columns 2-4 report results for the OLS regression for
the UK; columns 5-7 report OLS results for Denmark;
and columns 8-10 report the results of estimation of a
system of seemingly-unrelated regressions for the
combined UK and Danish data. Within each estima-
tion the centre column reports posterior means of the
regression coefficients and the left- and right-side en-
tries report the 90% highest posterior density (hpd) in-
tervals. In this context, it is important to note that
90% hpd intervals that do not cross zero assert with
90% probability that the policy milestone in question
has the same sign as the posterior mean. The relevant
milestones in this context are emboldened. In the ini-
tial UK regression policy milestones 5, 6 and 8 are
significant; and in the initial Danish regression policy
milestones 14, 15 and 17 are significant. In the
pooled-data regression, only milestones 1 and 8 are
significant for the UK and only milestone 16 is sig-
nificant fort Denmark. The other observation that is
noteworthy is that the introduction of cross-country
equation error affects many of the locations and scales
of the relevant posterior density measures. Viewed
collectively, indications are available that some of the
policy milestones had their desired intentions, whereas
others have not, at least with the evidence available to
us at this present time. In particular, we observe rather
large increments in organic entry attributable to the
Organic Farming Scheme introduced (April, 1999),
the amendment to EC Reg 2092/91 to include live-
stock (July, 1999) and the Organic Entry Level
Scheme (April, 2005); and in Denmark, we observe
sizable entry increments attributable to the special
conversion subsidy for farms without dairy quota and
the basic scheme for permanent conversion subsidies
retention (March, 1997) and, importantly, the appear-
ance of assistance for organic producers (2001-2004).
Whether these conclusions remain robust to nuanced
empirical enquiry remains to be seen. Presently, the
statistical responsiveness of organic entry to some of
the various milestones suggests that additional work is
certainly warranted.
Appendix
The basic situation being considered is as follows. We
observe a response zi conditioned by the step functions
in the linear regression: zi = xiβ + i, i = 1, 2, .., N;
where zi (zi, zi2, .., zN) denotes an N-vector of latent
responses; xi (xi1, xi2, .., xiK) denotes the K-vector of
‘steps;’ and i denotes a random disturbance assumed
to be normally distributed with zero mean and vari-
ance given by σ2. Stacking over respondents leads to
the system: z = x β + , where z (z1, z2, ..,
zN); x (x1, x2, .., xN) denotes the N×K matrix of the
step covariates; and (1,2,M) denotes the N×1
vector of random disturbances. Given the missing
data assume position on the left-hand side of (2), a
procedure for implementing the model follows direc-
tions outlined in Gelman, Carlin & Rubin (1992). In
the case where the errors in the separate equations cor-
responding to DK and UK agriculture are assumed to
be correlated, the system in (2) can be implemented in
Zellner’s (1962) seemingly unrelated regression
framework.
References
Colman, D. R. (2000) Comparative economics of
farming systems. In: Shades of Green. A Review of
UK Farming Systems. (P. B. Tinker, ed.), pp 42-58.
RASE; Stoneleigh, UK.
Costigan, P. (2002) UK organic research funding –
scope and aims. In: UK Organic Research 2002:
Proceedings of the COR Conference, 26-28 March
2002, Aberystwyth. (J. Powell, ed), pp 1-5. Organic
Centre Wales, University of Wales, Aberystwyth;
Ceredigion, UK.
Defra (2002a) Agriculture in the United Kingdom
2001. London: The Stationery Office.
Defra (2002b) Action Plan to Develop Organic Food
and Farming in England. London: Defra.
Defra (2004) Action Plan to Develop Organic Food
and Farming in England. Two Years On. London:
Defra.
Defra (2006) Closure of the Organic Conversion In-
formation Service.
http://www.defra.gov.uk/farm/organic/convert/q&a-
070202.pdf
Defra (2007) Agriculture in the United Kingdom 2006.
London: The Stationery Office.
EC (1991) Council Regulation (EEC) No. 2092/91 of
24 June 1991 on organic production of agricultural
products and indications referring thereto on agri-
cultural products and foodstuffs. Official Journal of
the European Communities, L198, 1-15.
EC (1992) Council Regulation (EEC) No. 2078/92 of
30 June 1992 on agricultural production methods
10
compatible with the requirements of the protection
of the environment and maintenance of the country-
side. Official Journal of the European Communi-
ties, L215, 85-90.
Elm Farm Research Centre, SAC, Organic Centre
Wales and DARDNI (2005) What issues and aspi-
rations do stakeholders feel should be addressed by
publicly funded research into organic farming in
the UK. Final report of Project OFO350. Defra;
London, UK.
Gelman, A., J. B. Carlin, H. S. Stern & D. B. Rubin.
(1992) Bayesian Data Analysis. London: Chapman
& Hall.
Häring, A. M. (2003) An Interactive Approach to Pol-
icy Impact Assessment for Organic farms in Europe.
Organic Farming in Europe: Economics and Policy,
vol. 10. Stuttgart: University of Hohenheim.
Häring, A. M. et al. (2004) Organic Farming and
Measures of European Agricultural Policy. Organic
Farming in Europe: Economics and Policy, vol. 11.
Stuttgart: University of Hohenheim.
Koop, G. (2003) Bayesian Econometrics. Chichester,
United Kingdom: John Wiley.
Lampkin, N. et al. (1999) The Policy and Regulatory
Environment for Organic farming in Europe. Or-
ganic Farming in Europe: Economics and Policy vol
1. Stuttgart: University of Hohenheim.
Lobley, M., Reed, M. and Butler, A. (2005) The im-
pact of organic farming on the rural economy in
England. CRR Research Report No. 11. Exeter:
Centre for Rural Research, University of Exeter.
Michelsen, J. (2002) Organic Farming Development in
Europe: Impacts of Regulation and Institutional Di-
versity. In: Hall, D. C. and Moffitt, L. J. (eds.).
Economics of Pesticides, Sustainable Food Produc-
tion and Organic Food Markets, Vol. 4, Oxford: El-
sevier Science Ltd, pp 101-38.
Nielsen, A. L. (2005) Eco-labeling Policy in Britain
and Denmark - A Comparative Analysis. Unpub-
lished Masters dissertation, Dept. of Political
Science, Aarhus University.
Soil Association (2006a) Organic Market Report
2006. Bristol: Soil Association.
Soil Association (2006b) Soil Association Expertise in
Public Procurement.
http://www.soilassociation.org/web/sa/saweb.nsf/lib
rarytitles/IB506.HTM1
Strukturdirektoratet (1995) Aktionsplan for fremme af
den økologiske fødevareproduktion i Danmark, Co-
penhagen: Statens Information.
Strukturdirektoratet (1999) Aktionsplan II: Økologi i
udvikling, Copenhagen: Strukturdirektoratet.
Tranter, R.B., Holt, G.C. and Grey, P.T. (2007) Budg-
etary implications, and motives for, converting to
organic farming: case study farm business evidence
from Great Britain. Biological Agriculture and
Horticulture, 25. 133-151.
Tranter, R. B., Bennett, R. M., Costa, L., Cowan, C.,
Holt, G. C., Jones, P. J., Miele, M., Sottomayor, M.
and Vestergaard, J. (2008) Consumers’ willingness-
to-pay for organic conversion-grade food: evidence
from five EU countries. Food Policy. In press.
Willer, H. (2006) Organic farming in Europe: General
development – statistics – state support – research.
In: Willer, H. & Yussdi, M. The world of organic
agriculture: statistics and energy trends 2005.
Bonn: IFOAM.
Zellner, A. (1996) An Introduction To Bayesian Infe-
rence In Econometrics. New York: Wiley and Sons
1971 Wiley Classics Library Edition.
Zellner, A.(1962) An Efficient Method for Estimating
Seemingly Unrelated Regressions and tests for Ag-
gregation Bias. Journal of the American Statistical
Association 57, 348-68.
... It was the first country to enact a distinct organic farming law in 1987 and introduced subsidies for the conversion from conventional to organic farming, followed by permanent organic farming subsidies in 1994. However, in 2004, permanent organic subsidies ended, and farmers were paid an environmental subsidy, with organic farming given priority [61]. In the UK, the Organic Farming Scheme (OFS) included higher organic farming support payments. ...
... In June 2003, on-going support after conversion was introduced for a five-year period. The OFS closed to new entrants in March 2005 and was replaced by the Organic Entry Level Stewardship, with organic farmers receiving twice the conventional rate, along with conversion payments [61]. Thus, subsidies are an effective tool for conversion and maintaining alternative farming practices but may run into budget constraints and need to be modified along the way. ...
Article
Full-text available
The aim of this paper is to explore and assess various strategies for monitoring antimicrobial consumption (AMC) in animals, within the context of the One Health approach. Recent studies have shed light on the limited surveillance and data collection for AMC in animals. Using the United States Center for Disease Control and Prevention Policy Analytical Framework, we assess global, national, and farm-level surveillance strategies on public health impact and feasibility using evidence from primary, secondary, and grey literature. From this, we identify key policy mechanisms that support the adoption of surveillance while providing specific recommendations. We find that a global strategy, though valuable for benchmarking and policy guidance, faces participation and data visibility challenges. National-level surveillance offers direct inputs into national action plans but struggles with data uniformity and comparability. Farm-level surveillance, while resource-intensive, provides the most granular data for informing specific interventions. We advocate for a multi-faceted approach to AMC surveillance, emphasizing that legal mandates and financial incentives are crucial for encouraging surveillance participation, along with international cooperation for enhancing participation and data quality. Drawing parallels with public reporting challenges in other sectors can provide valuable lessons on how to address data collection, analysis, and reporting barriers.
... Las razones del aumento en superficie de las producciones ecológicas extensivas en Andalucía habría que buscarlas tanto en la facilidad de su reconversión como en la importancia de la ayuda agroambiental. Estas ayudas han jugado un papel clave en la conformación del sector ecológico en toda Europa y su efecto llamada ha sido reflejado en diversos estudios (Holt & Tranter, 2002;Daugbjerg et al, 2008;Guzmán & Alonso, 2009Offerman et al, 2009;Sanders et al, 2011;Tankam & Choumert, 2013). Sin embargo, algunos autores apuntan que la dependencia de los pagos a la superficie tendrá consecuencias en la sostenibilidad del sector ecológico (Offerman et al, 2009;Sanders et al, 2011;Nieberg et al, 2006;Guzmán y Alonso, 2010). ...
... Las razones del aumento en superficie de las producciones ecológicas extensivas en Andalucía habría que buscarlas tanto en la facilidad de su reconversión como en la importancia de la ayuda agroambiental. Estas ayudas han jugado un papel clave en la conformación del sector ecológico en toda Europa y su efecto llamada ha sido reflejado en diversos estudios (Holt & Tranter, 2002;Daugbjerg et al, 2008;Guzmán & Alonso, 2009Offerman et al, 2009;Sanders et al, 2011;Tankam & Choumert, 2013). Sin embargo, algunos autores apuntan que la dependencia de los pagos a la superficie tendrá consecuencias en la sostenibilidad del sector ecológico (Offerman et al, 2009;Sanders et al, 2011;Nieberg et al, 2006;Guzmán y Alonso, 2010). ...
... Daugbjerg (2010) highlights that the success of the Danish model lies in government's commercial approach from the onset, where it focused on developing and creating local demand, meeting the public's need for trustworthiness, credibility and product variety. This commercial focus has been maintained even as environmental benefits have been acknowledged and incorporated legislatively, underpinning the success of their organic sector (Daugbjerg, 2010;Daugbjerg et al., 2008). ...
Thesis
Organic farming is seen as a solution for responding to environmental, food safety and animal welfare concerns making it significant to policy makers. With current policy targets focused on increasing supply (i.e. area share), there is the expectation that supply will automatically be met with increased market share (i.e. demand). There is no understanding of the relationship between the area share and market share variables and whether area share targets will translate into increased market share, or vice versa, yet this is important for farmers in Ireland who face uncertainty in the market. Data from three consecutive years is analysed to test the relationship between the variables and generate lessons for the Irish organic sector from high market share countries. The results indicate that a significant positive linear relationship exists between area share and market. share. This provides useful information for target setting and provides strong evidence that market share targeting is warranted. Additionally the covariance analysis confirms that ‘market share’ and ‘country’ significantly influence the variation in area share. This provides the basis for a more comprehensive review and country comparison between high market share countries (Denmark and Germany) and low market share country (Ireland) as national country factors strongly impact area share and in turn market share growth. The author concludes that interventions focused on increasing either area share or market share will have a positive impact on the other, and interventions targeting both are warranted. The factors of ‘country’ and ‘market share’ explain a high proportion of variance in area share, and therefore country factors such as national policy, government support, national branding, market structures and socio-economic factors have a substantial role to play in influencing the area share-market share relationship. The outcome of the research is a number of recommendations for Ireland around stronger national policy, balanced policy targets and organic brand development supported through government intervention.
... It incorporated the members of the British Organic Standards Committee (BOSC) 2 in addition to the Ministry of Agriculture, Fisheries, and Food (MAFF), supermarkets, and consumers. Incrementally, more generous state support (mostly for conversion) has been forthcoming through the Organic Aid Scheme (1994), the Organic Farming Scheme (1999), and through measures associated with the 2002 Organic Action Plan (for details, see Daugbjerg et al., 2008). Lately, the state has funded scientific research into organic farming systems and an information and advisory service (the Organic Conversion Information Service or OCIS). ...
Article
Full-text available
Both interest-group and public-policy scholars accept that groups are important to policy formulation and implementation because they hold valuable capacities. However, the literature has not dealt with whether, and how, groups develop capacities. In this article, we examine the question of group capacity development by focusing on the adaption of specific groups to evolving policy contexts. Taking the example of organic farm policy we look at the impact that divergent policy strategies aimed at growing this infant industry sector have had on the way related industry groups have evolved in four countries. This comparative study supports our argument that policy strategy is one key force in shaping the capacities that groups develop over time.
Article
CONTEXT Regardless 30 years of similar regulations and a common internal market, the diffusion of organic farming strongly differs amongst European member states. While the share of organic farmland in 2018 in Denmark and Austria was respectively 9.8% and 24.7%, in the Netherlands it was only 2.3%. OBJECTIVE The aim of this paper was to analyze what factors may determine the very different diffusion of organic dairy farming in the Netherlands, compared to Denmark and Austria. METHODS We applied the Technological Innovation System (TIS) framework to the case of organic dairy farming in the Netherlands, for which a literature review and interviews with key actors within the dairy value chain were carried out. To identify potential leverage points for upscaling also interviews with key actors from Denmark and Austria were held. RESULTS AND CONCLUSIONS Various barriers in the fulfilment of the seven TIS functions of Dutch organic dairy farming could be identified. With regard to the system function market formation a diversification in certified dairy products are signaled as important factors for upscaling. The function entrepreneurial activities will benefit from an reinforcement of governmental subsidies, since farmers who convert to organic run financial risks. Regarding the function guidance of the search, more consistent and systemic governmental support is needed, since the conversion to organic encompass a regime shift rather that supporting newcomers entering the sector. SIGNIFICANCE By studying the blocking mechanisms that hinder diffusion of organic dairy, the paper provides several leverage points that may also be applicable to the arrested diffusion of organic farming in other countries as well as the larger sustainability transition in European agriculture.
Conference Paper
Full-text available
In Europe, many governments have already defined and implemented public policies for sustainable agricultures, at several scales and in different territories. Nowadays, decision-makers count on pre-defined and already tested evaluation methodologies for the policies they design. But indicators that are brought on the table for the evaluation tasks are mainly focused on one aspect of the sustainability. Many of those methodologies are mainly defined for a single objective, that usually is the environmental one. Thus, not all the tackled points are assessed, such as participation or socioeconomic issues. When it comes to define public policies and their evaluation systems from an holistic or multidisciplinary perspective, several main goals are to be tackled. Indeed, from an agroecological approach, policies must be engaged in environmental issues as well as on social and economical matters. Moreover, there is not yet a specific evaluation set for systemic public policies for sustainable agricultures. This article aims at identifying the current evaluation methodologies for public policies related to sustainable agricultures in Europe. Based on the review of several authors' publications, it presents an analysis of the existing and proposed methodologies so to highlight their potential and deficiencies for their translation into public policies defined from a multidimensional approach. This analysis, together with a reflexion on the nature of the indicators to be integrated on such methodologies will include participation, ex-ante or ex-post evaluations approach as well as whether the multidisciplinary sustainability evaluation are included. It pretends to propose a basis for defining evaluation methodologies well adapted to public policies related to sustainable agricultures that tackled simultaneously its three dimensions: social, economical and environmental.
Article
The question of the 'policy capacity' of interest groups is increasingly gaining prominence as a key variable in governing and transformative capacities. This raises the issue of whether group policy capacities can be developed. While group scholars have long talked of group capacity, this has largely amounted to compiling a 'shopping list' of possible capacities general to all groups. There has not been much attention to variations in capacity among groups, or with the development of capacity by a single group over time. This paper takes a tentative step towards filling this gap. In pursuing this general line of inquiry we argue that (i) initial 'selection' of group type shapes scope of capacity development, (ii) groups seek to adapt capacity to changing policy contexts, and (iii) adaptive efforts are shaped by the 'legacy' of the originating type – change is bounded unless the group engages in 'radical' organisational changes (e.g. redefinition of entire purpose). This general argument is fleshed out by comparing and contrasting the evolution of the key organic interest groups in both the UK and Denmark.
Article
The popularity of organic farming has grown along with the rise of green values in recent years. Organic cultivation is seen as one solution not only for the environmental problems in agriculture and for the question of the purity of foodstuffs, but also for the social problems in the countryside, such as the decrease in number of jobs and population. Most Western European countries are already subsidizing organic production. Also, the common agricultural policy of the European Union (CAP) has been aimed at steering farming in a more extensive direction not only on the basis of environmental aspects, but also because of overproduction. In Western Europe, the conversion to organic production has been the most intensive in the German-speaking countries and Scandinavia. In 1995, Austria had proportionally the greatest number of farms and the largest area of arable land under organic cultivation. Although organic production has grown steadily in the whole of Western Europe during the past years, the development in individual countries has often been rather unsteady. Organic production is, however, now seen as a sector of agriculture that has potential for growth, and most countries have set targets to increase its present proportion.
Article
In this paper a method of estimating the parameters of a set of regression equations is reported which involves application of Aitken's generalized least-squares [1] to the whole system of equations. Under conditions generally encountered in practice, it is found that the regression coefficient estimators so obtained are at least asymptotically more efficient than those obtained by an equation-by-equation application of least squares. This gain in efficiency can be quite large if “independent” variables in different equations are not highly correlated and if disturbance terms in different equations are highly correlated. Further, tests of the hypothesis that all regression equation coefficient vectors are equal, based on “micro” and “macro” data, are described. If this hypothesis is accepted, there will be no aggregation bias. Finally, the estimation procedure and the “micro-test” for aggregation bias are applied in the analysis of annual investment data, 1935–1954, for two firms.
Article
This paper explores the financial implications of converting to organic farming in Great Britain through a case study of farmers considering conversion in 2002. Most study farmers were motivated to convert for financial, not ideological or life-style reasons; organic meat production was the most common planned enterprise, although those choosing to produce milk, vegetables and cereals were also studied in depth. At the time of study, organic beef and sheep meat production was particularly profitable. It was found that, in these product sectors, a large improvement in Family Farm Income would result if organic production was introduced on the case study farms. With few exceptions, a fall in Family Farm Income during the conversion period would not be an obstacle to farmers changing to organic methods. Fixed cost changes would also not deter conversion but expensive investment in new livestock and appropriate buildings would be required by some of those businesses studied. These findings are, however, dependent upon the price premia assumptions used and, whilst these premia have dropped slightly since the time of study, this would lessen the financial shortfall during the conversion period. There is also the possibility that reversion to conventional agricultural production might occur, perhaps at a faster rate than the original conversion process that was taking place around the turn of the century.
Article
In this paper a method of estimating the parameters of a set of regression equations is reported which involves application of Aitken's generalized least-squares [1] to the whole system of equations. Under conditions generally encountered in practice, it is found that the regression coefficient estimators so obtained are at least asymptotically more efficient than those obtained by an equation-by-equation application of least squares. This gain in efficiency can be quite large if “independent” variables in different equations are not highly correlated and if disturbance terms in different equations are highly correlated. Further, tests of the hypothesis that all regression equation coefficient vectors are equal, based on “micro” and “macro” data, are described. If this hypothesis is accepted, there will be no aggregation bias. Finally, the estimation procedure and the “micro-test” for aggregation bias are applied in the analysis of annual investment data, 1935–1954, for two firms.
Article
In Europe the distribution of organic farming has increased along with growing political support during the 1990s - including a common EU definition of organic farming and financial support for organic farmers. Three qualitative analyses covering all EU member and three non-member states are summarised to analyse co-variation between policies and organic sector size. When comparing impacts of policy instruments, the results were unclear but mainly pointed towards positive effects from introducing uniform certification schemes. With regard to national policy processes no correlation appeared between conditions for policy oriented learning and the size of organic farming sector. Some explanatory power is, however, derived from distinguishing between three types of institutional interrelationships between organic farming and mainstream farming. Cooperation or creative conflict persists in countries with large organic farming sectors, while pure competition is found in countries with small ones.