ArticlePDF Available

Investing in Children: Changes in Parental Spending on Children, 1972–2007

Authors:

Abstract

Parental spending on children is often presumed to be one of the main ways that parents invest in children and a main reason why children from wealthier households are advantaged. Yet, although research has tracked changes in the other main form of parental investment-namely, time-there is little research on spending. We use data from the Consumer Expenditure Survey to examine how spending changed from the early 1970s to the late 2000s, focusing particularly on inequality in parental investment in children. Parental spending increased, as did inequality of investment. We also investigate shifts in the composition of spending and linkages to children's characteristics. Investment in male and female children changed substantially: households with only female children spent significantly less than parents in households with only male children in the early 1970s; but by the 1990s, spending had equalized; and by the late 2000s, girls appeared to enjoy an advantage. Finally, the shape of parental investment over the course of children's lives changed. Prior to the 1990s, parents spent most on children in their teen years. After the 1990s, however, spending was greatest when children were under the age of 6 and in their mid-20s.
Investing in Children: Changes in Parental Spending
on Children, 19722007
Sabino Kornrich &Frank Furstenberg
Published online: 18 September 2012
#Population Association of America 2012
Abstract Parental spending on children is often presumed to be one of the main
ways that parents invest in children and a main reason why children from wealthier
households are advantaged. Yet, although research has tracked changes in the other
main form of parental investmentnamely, timethere is little research on spend-
ing. We use data from the Consumer Expenditure Survey to examine how spending
changed from the early 1970s to the late 2000s, focusing particularly on inequality in
parental investment in children. Parental spending increased, as did inequality of
investment. We also investigate shifts in the composition of spending and linkages to
childrens characteristics. Investment in male and female children changed substan-
tially: households with only female children spent significantly less than parents in
households with only male children in the early 1970s; but by the 1990s, spending
had equalized; and by the late 2000s, girls appeared to enjoy an advantage. Finally,
the shape of parental investment over the course of childrens lives changed.
Prior to the 1990s, parents spent most on children in their teen years. After the
1990s, however, spending was greatest when children were under the age of 6
and in their mid-20s.
Keywords Children .Human capital .Inequality .Consumption
Introduction
Since roughly the late 1970s, income and wealth inequality increased steadily in the
United States, except for a short reprieve in the late 1990s (Danziger and Gottschalk
Demography (2013) 50:123
DOI 10.1007/s13524-012-0146-4
Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (doi:10.1007/s13524-012-0146-4)
contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.
S. Kornrich (*)
Center for Advanced Studies in the Social Sciences, Juan March Institute, Madrid, Spain
e-mail: skornrich@march.es
F. Furstenberg
Department of Sociology, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA, USA
1995; Gilbert 2008; Levy 1998). A key question surrounding increases in inequality
in the United States and elsewhere is the extent to which inequality will be re-
created: in other words, how much do increases in current inequality contribute
to persistent inequalities through the intergenerational transmission of disadvantage?
Scholars and policy makers worry about the widening gap between rich and
poor, and many researchers have begun to examine the nature of the gap
(Magnuson and Votruba-Drzal 2009). Recent research finds that the achievement
gap between rich and poor children has widened, and it appears that greater
inequality in earnings is associated with increased differences in childrensachieve-
ment (Reardon 2011).
A debate continues about why and how much resources and parental behaviors
contribute to childrens welfare, but broad consensus exists that children in families
with more resources enjoy considerable advantages in their development and long-
term prospects (e.g., Duncan and Magnuson 2005; Duncan et al. 2001; Mayer 1997).
Parents of all social strata today appear to have become more aware and mobilized to
invest in their offspring, choosing qualityover quantityas they have fewer
children, and mothers and fathers both spend more time caring for children (Becker
1975; Bianchi 2000; Bianchi et al. 2006; Gauthier et al. 2004; Sayer et al. 2004;
Yeung et al. 2001). As changes in the labor market provide a greater premium for
education and training, children require more investment in the form of time and
money than even in the recent past.
Yet, although there is ample evidence about time use and family size, there
is less evidence about the other major form of parental investment: spending
on children. This is true even though it is presumably differences in monetary
expenditure that make up a substantial portion of the advantage conferred by
parents with higher income: spending buys access to higher-quality child care
and education, and places children in environments that are more likely to
build human and cultural capital.
1
Changes in spending should be an important
component of changed investment in the face of increased social inequality. Some
research has documented increased inequality in spending on children over a
shorttimeperiod(Bianchietal.2004), but there is relatively little evidence
about how it has changed over the period of growth in income inequality or
about how changes are linked to household income, family structure, and
childrens and parentscharacteristics.
This article addresses the questions of whether and how spending on children has
changed over the period roughly coinciding with the beginning of the growth in
income inequality through the late 2000s and how investments in children vary with
parental income and education and by childrens gender and age. Despite the impor-
tance of spending as a measure of parental investment in children, there has been little
research examining this question using this type of data (but see Bianchi et al. 2004;
Lazear and Michael 1988; Lundberg and Rose 2004; Ziol-Guest et al. 2004). To track
1
Becker (1975:9) defined investment in human capital as any activities that influence future monetary and
psychic income by increasing the resources in people,whereas Bourdieu (1984) referred to cultural capital
as dispositions and cultural competences, particularly in areas of legitimate taste, which may play a role in
career and school advancement. For this article, we are agnostic about the differences but note that parents
likely are interested in some combination of these.
2 S. Kornrich, F. Furstenberg
1995; Gilbert 2008; Levy 1998). A key question surrounding increases in inequality
in the United States and elsewhere is the extent to which inequality will be re-
created: in other words, how much do increases in current inequality contribute
to persistent inequalities through the intergenerational transmission of disadvantage?
Scholars and policy makers worry about the widening gap between rich and
poor, and many researchers have begun to examine the nature of the gap
(Magnuson and Votruba-Drzal 2009). Recent research finds that the achievement
gap between rich and poor children has widened, and it appears that greater
inequality in earnings is associated with increased differences in childrensachieve-
ment (Reardon 2011).
A debate continues about why and how much resources and parental behaviors
contribute to childrens welfare, but broad consensus exists that children in families
with more resources enjoy considerable advantages in their development and long-
term prospects (e.g., Duncan and Magnuson 2005; Duncan et al. 2001; Mayer 1997).
Parents of all social strata today appear to have become more aware and mobilized to
invest in their offspring, choosing qualityover quantityas they have fewer
children, and mothers and fathers both spend more time caring for children (Becker
1975; Bianchi 2000; Bianchi et al. 2006; Gauthier et al. 2004; Sayer et al. 2004;
Yeung et al. 2001). As changes in the labor market provide a greater premium for
education and training, children require more investment in the form of time and
money than even in the recent past.
Yet, although there is ample evidence about time use and family size, there
is less evidence about the other major form of parental investment: spending
on children. This is true even though it is presumably differences in monetary
expenditure that make up a substantial portion of the advantage conferred by
parents with higher income: spending buys access to higher-quality child care
and education, and places children in environments that are more likely to
build human and cultural capital.
1
Changes in spending should be an important
component of changed investment in the face of increased social inequality. Some
research has documented increased inequality in spending on children over a
shorttimeperiod(Bianchietal.2004), but there is relatively little evidence
about how it has changed over the period of growth in income inequality or
about how changes are linked to household income, family structure, and
childrens and parentscharacteristics.
This article addresses the questions of whether and how spending on children has
changed over the period roughly coinciding with the beginning of the growth in
income inequality through the late 2000s and how investments in children vary with
parental income and education and by childrens gender and age. Despite the impor-
tance of spending as a measure of parental investment in children, there has been little
research examining this question using this type of data (but see Bianchi et al. 2004;
Lazear and Michael 1988; Lundberg and Rose 2004; Ziol-Guest et al. 2004). To track
1
Becker (1975:9) defined investment in human capital as any activities that influence future monetary and
psychic income by increasing the resources in people,whereas Bourdieu (1984) referred to cultural capital
as dispositions and cultural competences, particularly in areas of legitimate taste, which may play a role in
career and school advancement. For this article, we are agnostic about the differences but note that parents
likely are interested in some combination of these.
2 S. Kornrich, F. Furstenberg
parental investments over time, we use a resource rarely used by sociologists or
demographers: the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CES), which is a nationally
representative survey of consumer spending conducted by the U.S. Bureau of Labor
Statistics. We observe increases in inequality of spending over time, larger
shares of income spent on children, and parental expenditures over longer
periods of childrenslives.
Spending as Parental Investment in Children
Spending on children is one of the most direct ways that parents can invest in
children. Parental spending can buy children experiences that build human and
cultural capital: high-quality education, residence in better neighborhoods, and
potentially high-quality child care while children are young and parents are at
work. Although many of these experiences have long been available for parents
to purchase, their importance seems to have increased in recent years as
expectations for children have changed. Apprehensions about public schools
have grown over time, leading a growing percentage of parents to potentially
opt for private education, thus incurring larger expenditures. The growing
importance of higher education, often financed entirely or partly by parents,
has similarly added to the costs of raising a child and extended the period of
parental obligations.
Parental strategies designed to offer children appropriate learning experien-
ces at all stages of their life may also have driven up spending when children
are young. Hertz (1997:376) noted that couples speak a new language of
quasi-psychology that emphasizes developmentally appropriate educational
experiences for preschoolers who are introduced to the rudiments of a struc-
tured day, develop positive peer group experiences, and begin to develop a
positive relationship to learning,suggesting the importance even at early ages
of parental expenditures to provide learning environments. This expectation is
stronger among middle- and upper-class families. Indeed, Lareau (2003)exam-
ined class differences in child-rearing and found that middle- and upper-class
parents seek structured educational, social, and athletic activities for their children
in order to impart them with experiences necessary for a middle-class upbringing.
At early ages, then, spending opens up unique forms of investment that parents
seem to value more than in the past.
There have also been growing pressures on families to provide assistance for
older children in the form of postsecondary education. A growing body of
evidence suggests that parents at all income levels are increasingly willing to
provide assistance to their offspring in late adolescence and early adulthood.
Schoeni and Ross (2005) reported that one-fifth of all expenditures on children
living in the household are provided to those older than 18, and there are differences
in the level of transfers by parentsincome. Parents in all strata, according to this
study, provide about 10 % of their annual income to children older than the age of 18.
Thus, it appears parents are reconciled to the reality that it takes longer for their
children to reach economic maturity than it did a half-century ago (Danziger and
Rouse 2007; Furstenberg et al. 2004).
Changes in Parental Spending on Children, 19722007 3
Explaining Changes in Spending
Changes in aggregate spending may be understood in three ways. First, there are
changes in the level of spending, which capture the extent of parental investment.
Higher levels reflect more extensive, intense, and perhaps more valuable investments
in children. Of course, spending is not purely a measure of parentsdesire to invest
because the cost of goods plays a role. In this article, we adjust spending figures for
inflation, but the price of some goodsnotably higher educationhas increased
more rapidly than inflation. Although changes in prices have certainly occurred,
parents could respond to increased prices by contributing the same dollar amount
over time rather than increasing their investment as prices increase. Thus, a willing-
ness to pay for college or other goods that become more costly reflects a greater
commitment to investment in children.
2
The second important way to evaluate changes is to consider the composition of
spending: that is, what households buy with money they spend on their children. The
amount spent on each of the three categories that we examinenamely, education,
child care, and a range of consumer goodsshows whether households spend more
investing in education or in other areas.
The third set of changes is relationships between spending and household charac-
teristicsor, loosely, the determinantsof spending. Shifts linked to household
characteristics tell us how parents respond to changing social demands on the family
and whether this differs for different segments of the population. We examine both
childrens and parentscharacteristics.
Childrens Characteristics
We focus on childrens age and gender to gauge how norms of responsibility across
the course of childrens development and gender norms have changed over time.
First, in relation to the age of children, parents may allocate investment very
differently across the course of childrens lives. For example, parents could invest
heavily in children when they are young but relinquish responsibility at later ages, or
they could provide increased resources as children transition from the parental home
to help them establish independent lives, residences, and households. Given the
aforementioned qualitative evidence that parents today place great importance on
both early childhood development and postsecondary education, we ask whether
parents assume responsibility over a longer period of the life cycle of children
todaythaninthepast.
Childrens gender may also influence spending. The presence of sons instead of
daughters in the home influences a variety of marital outcomes, including stability,
fathersinvolvement, and gender traditionalism (Harris and Morgan 1991; Katzev et
al. 1994; Lundberg and Rose 2002). We expect that in the 1970s, when womens
2
An alternative explanation is that parental commitment to investment has driven up the price of college, as
demand has risen and supply has not kept pace. Whether this is the case or instead costs have gone up
independently and parents feel compelled to pay, we argue that payment reflects a commitment by parents
to invest in their college-age children.
4 S. Kornrich, F. Furstenberg
careers were more circumscribed and gender ideologies less oriented to egalitarianism,
parents would invest more in male children.
Although parents may have invested more in sons in the past, changes in gender
norms toward egalitarianism and steps toward gender inequality may mean that
contemporary parents make roughly equal investments in male and female children.
Indeed, evidence on third births suggests that parents today are indifferent about the
gender of their children, unlike parents of the past (Pollard and Morgan 2002).
Similarly, evidence in the early 1990s found few differences between the spending
of households with male children and households with female children, although
households with only male children spent slightly less on clothing and more on
personal care services (Lundberg and Rose 2004). We thus expect that expenditures
will be divided more equally between boys and girls in recent years than in the 1970s.
ParentsCharacteristics
We examine a range of parental characteristics, including income, wivesshare of
earnings and labor force participation, parentsage, and parental education. We focus
particularly on the role of income, given our interest in the extent to which inequality has
shifted investment. Herein, we discuss literature that drives expectations about spending.
From 1972 to 2007, inequality increased in the United States (Levy 1998). We thus
investigate inequality in spending across the income distribution as well as the overall
level of spending. The increase in inequality came from increased income at the top
of the income distribution and income stagnation for those at the bottom and middle
of the distribution, so there should be greater spending at the top of the income
distribution. However, it is less clear how spending changed near the bottom of the
income distribution as real incomes declined. Those with low incomes could cut
back, but they may also attempt to maintain levels of spending because households
can, to some extent, smoothconsumption by borrowing or using savings. If
households maintain spending despite declining incomes, spending as a portion of
income would be higher among those with low incomes, and this would increase over
time. We thus examine changes in expenditures in both dollar amounts and as a
portion of current income. We also examine income adjusted for household size
because household size may shape household budget constraints.
In addition to total income, the source of income within the family may matter.
Research suggests that women, more than men, use their income and general house-
hold resources on children. When control of a child benefit in the United Kingdom
shifted to the mother from the father, households spent more on childrens goods,
suggesting that when women controlincome, they use it on children (Lundberg et
al. 1997). Similarly, children are less likely to experience food insecurity when
parentspooled income is controlled by a mother or is jointly controlled than when
it is controlled by the father alone, again suggesting that when mothers rather than
fathers control income, they use it to invest in childrens well-being (Kenney 2008).
Although the CES does not contain measures of who controlshousehold income,
marital bargaining perspectives suggest that husbands and wives roughly control their
own individual incomes and use them for goods that they are more interested in (De
Ruijter et al. 2005). We thus expect that households in which the wifes share of
earned income is higher will invest more in children.
Changes in Parental Spending on Children, 19722007 5
Parentsage and education and the structure of the family may also influence
spending. Older parents will likely have longer labor force histories and higher
savings, leading to a greater willingness to spend. Educated parents, as discussed
earlier, are more likely to have tastes for structured child care experiences and likely
value education more highly, leading to higher spending. Given changes in family
structure over the time period that we examine, such as the greater likelihood that
children live in single-parent households, we include measures of family structure.
Spending: Cost and Investment
There has been little quantitative research charting changes in parental expenditures. One
reason for this absence may be the difficulty of identifying expenditures on children (cf.,
Folbre 2008; Lazear and Michael 1988). The best source of data on expenditures in
the United States, the CES, does not specify who incurred expenditures or the target
of expenditures, thus making it difficult to assign individual goods and services.
One method to construct estimates of the cost of raising a child to age 18, used by
the United States Department of Agriculture (USDA), is to use allocation rules to
assign household spending to children. The USDA allocates food, transportation, and
health care using rules generated from other surveys, goods with obvious child
recipients on a dollar basis, and other spending on a per capita basis (Lino and
Carlson 2009). This approach is useful in estimating the additional expendituresthe
costthat a family might incur to raise a child. However, changes in these estimates
are not necessarily linked to parental motivations to invest; instead, they are influ-
enced heavily by shifts in the cost of housing, food, and transportation, and on the
choice of rules determining what share of expenses should be allocated to children. In
the USDA method, nearly one-half of the cost of raising a child to age 18 results from
food and housing (Lino and Carlson 2009).
Because we are interested in spending on children that approximates investment, we
avoid a cost-based approach and instead focus on goods and services intended for
children, such as education, child care, and a range of consumer goods, including clothing
for boys, girls, and infants; and various toys and games. These three do not identically
capture parental investment in children: although education is clearly a form of parental
investment, the other two are perhaps less so. And although child care is not a pure
investment in children, given that it is a necessity for working parents without other care
options, parents try to choose high-quality child care environments for their children. In
addition, many middle- and upper-class parents now see exposure to these structured
environmentsasakeywaytohelpchildrendevelop.Finally,spendingonbooks,toys,
games, and clothing may be a way that parents expose their children to materials that grant
cultural capital and thus help develop class-appropriate tastes. Throughout the remainder
of the article, we use the terms spending on childrenand investmentinterchangeably.
Data
We use data fromthe CES, a nationally representative survey of Americans administered
by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics and generally considered the best source of
6 S. Kornrich, F. Furstenberg
nationally representative data on spending. Before 1979, CES data were gathered
only sporadically, with the most recent wave conducted in 19721973. After
1979, the survey has been conducted annually. We use two-year blocks of data
from more recent years to chart changes in the patterns and determinants of
spending over time. We use the most recent set of data available at the time of
writingfrom the 2006 and 2007 survey yearsand two sets of years roughly
equal in time from our endpoints: 19831984 and 19941995.
3
Our sample includes households with a child younger than age of 24 in the home.
This includes children who receive parental support but are away from home, such as
children attending college because parents are instructed to report these children in
the survey. To the extent that parents underreport children living away from home,
our estimates of expenditures may be downwardly biased. If parents today less often
report the presence of children who are in college because more children attend
college and receive some support, then results for change over time would be
downwardly biased, meaning that our estimate of increasing spending would under-
estimate a true increase.
Because the surveys are not identical over time, we harmonize them in several ways.
To construct comparable measures over time, we aggregate spending into three catego-
ries: child care, education, and all other specifically child-related expenses. Details on
these categories are listed in Online Resource 1. Differences in the data also require
harmonization. Surveys from all years are conducted over the course of four quarters.
However, data from 19721973 are reported only annually. For later years, responses
are reported quarterly. Because households are followed over four quarters, it is
possible to construct an annual estimate. However, substantial numbers of households
are not present in the survey for all quarters. Roughly 40 % of cases are missing, with
higher rates for subgroups such as those never married or divorced.
Existing research using the CES has used two approaches to deal with missing
data. Most research relies on the analysis of households that were present in all four
quarters of the survey and that fully reported income (e.g., De Ruijter et al. 2005;
Lundberg and Rose 2004; Ziol-Guest et al. 2004). Other research avoids dropping
cases by relying on data from only one quarter (e.g., Cohen 1998). This approach
avoids bias from the deletion of missing data, but it does mean relying on only a
portion of available data.
To create annualized estimates without dropping cases, we use data from all
quarters that a household is present in the survey and has resident children age 24
or younger in the home.
4
We average household characteristics for all quarters and
create annual measures. In addition to preserving cases, this has the benefit of not
overweighting households with more observations. The central drawback is that it
eliminates within-household variation in spending across quarters. Although explain-
ing both within- and between-household variation would strengthen an account of
spending on children, the goal of this analysis is to provide a comparison across
households over time. Additionally, most variables are stable over the course of four
quarters within households.
3
Additional analysis suggests that the choice of intermediate years does not substantially affect results.
4
A small portion of households reported the presence of children in some quarters but not others. In these
cases, we use data only when children are reported in the home.
Changes in Parental Spending on Children, 19722007 7
Although this strategy deals with missing quarters, missing data can still exist for
individual items. To address these missing values, we use multiple imputation, which
generates several estimates of values for missing data using the relationships between
variables for cases without missing data. These data sets are then analyzed separately,
and estimates are combined to produce overall estimates of coefficients and standard
errors. We use maximum likelihood estimation as implemented in the PROC MI
procedure in SAS. For general information on multiple imputation, see Allison
(2001) and Rubin (1987).
Our primary concern for imputation is missing values for household and individual
income. We impute data for those with no responses and those who are classified as
incomplete income reporters. Because individuals often report education, weeks
worked, and hours worked even when they do not report individual incomes, we
use these variables, husbandsand wivesages, and total household expenditures to
impute missing values for individual and household earnings, with separate imputa-
tions for households with only one parent. We then use imputed values to generate the
share of earnings from the wife. To do so, we replace imputed values of income less
than zero with zero. Rounding can lead to bias in parameter estimates (Allison 2001),
but it is necessary in this case because we use mens and womens income to generate
a measure of the share of earnings from wives, and negative values for income
produce additional uncertainty in parameter estimates when creating a ratio.
Measures
Spending Measures
Spending is measured by self-reports of expenditures over the past three months. To
increase the accuracy of responses, households are visited before their first interview
and asked to keep records to help them respond to the survey at later visits. The
relatively long reporting period of three months can downwardly bias estimates for
irregularly occurring and small purchases. However, for the items that we consider,
we expect that expenses will be large or regular enough to prevent substantial bias.
We examine three categories of spending: child care, education, and other miscel-
laneous goods and services for children. Child care includes both day care and
babysitting. Educational expenses include room and board at school; tuition, fees,
and books; private recreational lessons; and other educational expenses.
5
Finally, we
include a category of miscellaneous goods and services for those goods: clothes and
accessories for boys, girls, and infants; and toys, games, musical equipment, bicycles,
tricycles, and camping equipment; and services and repairs for these goods. One
weakness of this category is that the CES records spending on childrens clothing
only until age 15. After age 15, clothing intended for males is simply listed as male
adult clothing, and a similar change of definition occurs with clothing for women.
5
One important question about educational expenses is the extent to which children go to college versus
the extent to which parents are willing to pay college expenses. Our data show only whether expenditure
occurred, so we have no practical way of determining whether spending changes because of attendance or
because of parental support given attendance. We suspect that both play a role in changing expenditures,
but we are unable to differentiate the influence of each in this analysis.
8 S. Kornrich, F. Furstenberg
Thus, spending on this category declines near age 16. Details of the CES codes and
their components are included in Online Resource 1.
We use the Consumer Price Index Research Series (CPI-U-RS) to inflate expendi-
tures to 2008 dollars (Sahr 2009).
6
To compare households with different numbers of
children, we use a per-child measure because the goods and services we examine are
largely indivisible. Another option would be to use equivalence scales, which take
into account economies of scale that occur with goods such as housing, food, or
transportation. Economies of scale do not exist or are smaller for the items we
examine, so we measure spending per child.
Independent Variables
Income
The CES includes measures of earned and unearned income as well as income
before and after taxes. We use measures of final income before taxes after
1980, and the closest comparable measuretotal family incomefor 1972
1973 data. Because these measures are total income, they include welfare
benefits such as food stamps, which results in some equalization of income
levels. However, relying on after-tax income rather than pretax income would
likely result in greater equality because of progressivity in U.S. income taxes.
We choose the pretax measure of income because we expect that reporting on
this measure will be more reliable than after-tax income. As with spending
variables, we use the CPI-U-RS to inflate income to 2008 dollars.
One caveat about income is important. To ensure confidentiality, the CES
censored data near the top and bottom of the distribution for 19721973. Thus,
estimates of incomes for that year are not exact but are a rough average taking
censoring into account. However, only a small portion of households have
censored outcomes: roughly 10 % of those in either the top or bottom decile
in the 19721973 data have censored incomes. As we noted earlier, income is
one of the most frequently missing variables, particularly when incomplete
income reporters are treated as missing. However, because respondents often
report a range of correlated variables, including total expenditure, which is
highly correlated with income (with values of rnear .6), we are comfortable
using multiple imputation for missing income.
Wifes Share of Income
To gauge the effect of womens provision of income to the home, we measure
the proportion of reported earned income from the wife. For single-parent
households, we set the measure to 0 (zero) and introduce an additional set of
controls for family structure to differentiate these households from male bread-
winner households.
6
The CPI-U-RS is a new series incorporating methodological improvements, such as the use of rental
equivalence for homeowner costs and quality adjustments for prices (Stewart and Reed 1999).
Changes in Parental Spending on Children, 19722007 9
Family Structure
We use three dichotomous variables to examine family structure, using two-parent
households as the reference category: one for single-mother families, one for single-
father families, and a final category for all other families. The last category includes,
among others, households in which multiple generations reside in one household.
Wifes Work Status
Although wifes share of income partially controls for wifes employment, we
introduce two dichotomous variables to control for wifes time in addition to her
monetary contributions. These variables measure whether a wife is at work part-time
or full-time, with the reference category being a household in which the wife reports
no work.
Education
Because education may change parental incentives to spend on children, we also
control for parentseducational level. For the 19721973 data, the head of the
household is always listed as the husband; to maintain consistency, we use husbands
educational level in the later data. For single-parent households, we simply use the
education of the parent in the household. We include variables for completion of high
school, attending some college, and a college degree or higher. We do not differen-
tiate between the completion of college and advanced degrees because the latter
category does not exist in the 19721973 data.
Childrens Characteristics
We control for a number of characteristics of children. We include a measure of the age
of the youngest child in the home to examine the link between childrens age and
spending. We also include a squared term to capture nonlinearities in this relationship.
Because more children may mean resources that are stretched further, we include a
measure for the total number of children ages 0 to 24 in the home. In supplementary
analyses, described in Online Resource 2, we examine the effects of childrens gender.
Results: Changes in Spending
We begin by presenting descriptive results to establish whether and how this form of
parental investment has changed over the period we examine. Table 1shows average
household spending per child for all households with children ages 0 to 24 for each
year, and the share spent on each category, as well as total household spending on all
categories. Figure 1shows per capita spending among households by the age of the
youngest child in the household for three aggregate categories: child care; education;
and a category of miscellaneous goods, which includes childrens clothes, toys,
games, musical equipment, and other goods. As an example of interpretation,
Fig. 1shows that for the early 1970s, households in which the youngest child was
10 S. Kornrich, F. Furstenberg
age 12 spent on average $600 on education, a small amount on child care, and
roughly an additional $700 on miscellaneous goods for children. Because we include
households with more than one child, these results do not necessarily reflect spending
on a child of each given age. Indeed, many households have older children,
offering an explanation for educational expenditures among households with
very young children.
Figure 1and Table 1show two important patterns. First, spending increased
substantially from the early 1970s to the late 2000s, although much of the increase
occurred between the early 1970s and mid-1990s, with increases after the 1990s at a
slower rate. Not all components of spending increased at similar rates. Expenditures
on childrens toys, clothes, and games increased slightly from the early 1970s to the
early 1980s, but the share spent on these goods declined after this period. Although
some accounts of the commercialization of youth suggest that the advent of a
consumer culture targeted to children in the 1980s led households to spend exces-
sively on consumer goods (Schor 2004), our results do not support this perspective.
Rather than consumer goods, parents increased spending on child care and education,
presumably to attempt to invest in human capital. To place these figures in context,
Table 1 Average spending per child by year and percentage of expenditures in each area for all households
with children age 0 to 24
19721973 19831984 19941995 20062007
$% $% $% $%
Childrens Accessories 513 39 605 36 641 32 463 21
Education 621 47 743 44 937 46 1,189 54
Day Care 22 2 170 10 294 14 416 19
Babysitting 159 12 172 10 161 8 128 6
Child Care Total 179 14 343 20 455 22 544 25
Total Spending on Children 1,315 100 1,690 100 2,031 100 2,196 100
% Change From Previous Period 28.5 20.2 8.1
Household Spending, All Goods 42,704 49,629 52,875 60,559
% Change From Previous Period 16.2 6.5 14.5
n10,181 7,177 7,223 8,575
2,400
4,000
0
800
1,600
3,200
06
Age
1972–1973
612 18
e of youngest child
24 06
dAg
1983–1984 1994–1995
6
ge of youngest chil
Children's accessories
24 06
ld
Age
Child
6121812 18 12 18
e of youngest child
care Education
24 06
dAg
2006–2007
6
ge of youngest chil
24
ld
Fig. 1 Per child spending on education, child care, and childrens toys, games, and clothes by year and age
of youngest child in the household. Spending for all years is inflated to year 2008 dollars
Changes in Parental Spending on Children, 19722007 11
we also show shifts in household spending among families with children over this
time period. Household spending increased less rapidly than spending on children,
with the exception of the shift from the mid-1990s to the late 2000s, implying that
households were redirecting resources to children.
Second, the link between childrens age and spending changed over time. In
the early 1970s, concentrated spending occurred directly before age 16 and after
age 18, and spending was lowest in households with very young children or
those of college age. In the early 1980s, in contrast, spending was roughly
constant across childrens age, although spending declined after age 18. In the
1990s and 2000s, spending was highest for young children and for children
over age 18, and lower for children ages 612. More than in the past, parents
during the 1990s and 2000s spent earlier and extended their support for
children into the later ages. Later in the article, we investigate whether this
shift persists when we control for household characteristics.
Next, we ask how investment changed across the income distribution with increas-
ing income inequality. In Table 2, we present total spending on children, total income,
and the share of income spent on children for all households by income deciles.
Because these measures do not capture differences in the needs of households related
to household composition, we also present per-person and per-child equivalent
estimates of income and spending in Table 3. We equivalize income by dividing by
the square root of household size, an equivalence scale used in recent OECD research
(OECD 2009), and equivalize spending on children by dividing by the number of
children in a household because there are presumably few economies of scale for
spending on these goods. Figure 2illustrates results from both tables.
7
Spending on children grew more unequal over time as income inequality grew.
High-income households in the 2000s spent more relative to both those with high-
income in the past and the contemporary poor, and some of this growth can be traced
directly to increases in income, as incomes rose rapidly. However, the fact that the
proportion of income spent increased across the entire income distribution means that
increases did not result exclusively from increased income. Instead, increasing
proportions of income spent suggest that parents feel greater pressure to invest
regardless of their income, leading households in later periods to spend greater shares
of their income. Interestingly, there is a break from the overall trend of increasing
shares of income spent on children during the 2000s because for nearly all deciles, the
share of income spent was lower than in the 1990s. Part of this reduction is
attributable to increasing income. Yet, for the first time, some parents spent
less in real dollars than in the previous period. Parents in the bottom half of the
income distribution spent less in the late 2000s than in the mid-1990s. Thus,
the transition from the 1990s to the 2000s marked a distinct break with the
trend of increasing spending, although spending inequality continued increasing.
Whether this marks the formation of a new pattern of spending is unclear, but it is
worth pursuing in future research.
At the bottom of the income distribution, the share of income spent on children
was quite high and increased over time. Among households in the bottom decile, the
7
For figures using household equivalized income, decile cut points also use equivalized income.
12 S. Kornrich, F. Furstenberg
share of income spent on children more than doubled, although this is partially
attributable to changes in the treatment of income between the 19721973 data and
later data.
8
However, an increase in spending is also present in the second and third
Table 2 Total spending on children, income, and spending as a percentage of income, by income decile
Income
Decile 19721973 19831984 19941995 20062007
Total Spending on Children
1 1,126 1,522 1,429 1,318
2 1,495 1,378 1,558 1,516
3 1,763 1,623 2,010 1,813
4 1,953 2,021 2,277 1,878
5 2,230 2,524 2,527 2,217
6 2,468 2,481 2,851 3,081
7 3,001 2,870 3,192 3,355
8 3,337 3,452 3,991 4,585
9 4,115 4,007 5,139 5,857
10 6,246 6,276 8,389 11,013
Income (in 1,000s)
1 12.9 7.6 7.9 8.6
2 25.6 16.8 17.8 21.2
3 36.1 25.0 26.8 30.8
4 45.0 33.3 36.3 40.6
5 53.1 42.1 45.6 52.0
6 61.1 50.9 55.8 64.2
7 70.0 60.9 67.7 78.1
8 80.9 73.5 81.7 96.6
9 96.2 91.6 101.8 125.3
10 135.4 139.2 155.5 228.5
Spending as a % of Income
1 8.72 24.24 21.33 19.26
2 5.83 8.76 8.83 7.16
3 4.89 6.19 7.20 6.32
4 4.34 5.83 6.35 4.81
5 4.20 6.45 5.40 4.58
6 4.04 4.84 5.74 5.25
7 4.29 4.68 4.96 4.67
8 4.13 4.70 4.82 5.18
9 4.28 4.31 5.31 4.91
10 4.61 4.47 5.48 5.33
Note: Dollar figures adjusted to year 2008 dollars using the CPI-U-RS.
8
For the lowest income decile, some of the decline in income is due to the BLS practice of bottom-coding
income in the CES data in 19721973, which was abandoned at later time points. Roughly 5 % of cases had
their income recoded to protect confidentiality, inflating incomes slightly.
Changes in Parental Spending on Children, 19722007 13
deciles, suggesting a pattern not purely attributable to changes in data coding. For
those in the second decile of earners, spending increased by roughly 50 % from 5.8 %
of income to 8.8 % of income, although this declined to 7.2 % by the late 2000s; for
those in the third decile, spending similarly increased from 4.9 % to 7.2 %, with this
figure also declining by the mid-2000s.
Table 3 Spending per child, one-person equivalent household income, and spending as a percentage of
equivalized income, by equivalized income decile
Income Decile 19721973 19831984 19941995 20062007
Spending per Child
1 607 961 779 750
2 701 737 850 900
3 845 1,049 1,204 1,117
4 952 1,029 1,306 1,087
5 1,143 1,493 1,548 1,421
6 1,195 1,553 1,651 1,809
7 1,342 1,702 1,947 2,003
8 1,611 2,026 2,297 2,616
9 1,933 2,597 3,192 3,701
10 2,832 3,759 5,551 6,573
Income (in 1,000s)
1 7.7 4.1 4.3 4.6
2 14.1 8.8 9.4 11.0
3 19.3 13.1 14.2 16.1
4 23.5 17.4 19.0 21.4
5 27.4 21.8 23.9 27.1
6 31.3 26.4 29.1 33.3
7 35.7 31.4 35.0 40.3
8 41.6 37.8 42.3 49.6
9 49.7 47.0 52.7 64.4
10 69.3 71.7 80.5 117.4
Spending as a % of Income
1 7.9 23.4 18.1 16.3
2 5.0 8.3 9.0 8.2
3 4.4 8.0 8.5 6.9
4 4.1 5.9 6.9 5.1
5 4.2 6.8 6.5 5.2
6 3.8 5.9 5.7 5.4
7 3.8 5.4 5.6 5.0
8 3.9 5.4 5.4 5.3
9 3.9 5.5 6.1 5.8
10 4.1 5.2 6.9 5.6
Note: Dollar figures adjusted to year 2008 dollars using the CPI-U-RS.
14 S. Kornrich, F. Furstenberg
The apparent cause of this increase is declining income over time, perhaps because
of higher numbers of single-parent households.
9
Households spent similarly over
time, but investment composed a larger share of their income as income declined.
Parents at all points in the income distribution spent more, but households near the
bottom of the income distribution felt a greater burden as more of their income went
to children. These results become even stronger when we consider spending per child
as a share of one-person equivalized income. The presence of high shares of income
devoted to spending on children suggests a floorfor spending: parents do not lower
spending on children to devote income to other purchases, even under conditions of
relative hardship.
Parental Investment by Gender of Child
To capture the effect of childrens gender on spending, we compare households with
only male children to those with only female children. Table 4shows changes in the
influence of childrens gender on spending. In the early 1970s, parents in households
with only male children spent significantly more than parents in households with only
female children, with a gap of roughly $200 in spending. Nearly all additional
spending occurred because parents with only male children spent more on education.
In the 1980s and 1990s, overall spending equalized, although there were still differ-
ences in the target of parental expenditures. In the early 1980s, households with only
9
Average household income declined in these data after 19721973 and did not rebound even by the early
1990s. Although we are concerned that differences in coding and reporting of income lead to this result,
children experienced increases in poverty over the course of the 1980s and 1990s (Levy 1998), consistent
with declining incomes among households with children.
Total spending on children Spending per child
Total spending as share of household income Spending per child as share of 1-person equivalent income
0
2,000
4,000
6,000
8,000
10,000
12,000
12345678910
12345678910
12345678910
12345678910
Income Decile
1972–1973 1983–1984 1994–1995 2006–2007
0
1,000
2,000
3,000
4,000
5,000
6,000
7,000
Income Decile
1972–1973 1983–1984 1994–1995 2006–2007
0
5
10
15
20
25
Income Decile
1972–1973 1983–1984 1994–1995 2006–2007
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
Income Decile
1972–1973 1983–1984 1994–1995 2006–2007
Fig. 2 Total spending on children by income decile by year
Changes in Parental Spending on Children, 19722007 15
female children spent significantly more on childrens accessories; in the 1990s,
households with only female children spent significantly more on day care.
By the 2000s, however, these data show a reversal: households with only
female children spent more than households with only male children. Indeed,
there were significant differences in spending on goods, education, and baby-
sitting, and the overall difference was significant. To check whether differences
in spending were caused by differences on other characteristics related to
spending, such as household income or education, we used regression analyses
(presented in Online Resource 2), which confirm that other household character-
istics cannot account for these differences.
As we expected, our results show that parents spent more on male children in the
early 1970s. We also find equalization in the pattern of parental investment in the
1980s and 1990s. An unexpected result, however, is that in the 2000s, households
with only female children spent more than those with only male children. Whether
this pattern will persist remains uncertain, but it merits further investigation.
Multivariate Results
Finally, we use regression analysis to examine how shifts in overall spending are
linked to household and child characteristics. We present results using spending per
child, pooling the four years into a single analysis to enable tests for differences in
coefficients across years. Means and standard deviations for variables in the regres-
sion analysis are in Table 5, and coefficients are in Table 6. Coefficients and levels of
significance for 19721973 are for that year; for other years, coefficients and levels of
significance are for differences between those years and the earlier time period. We
also list within-period significances in the right-most columns.
Table 4 Comparison of spending in households with only female and only male children age 0 to 24
19721973 19831984 19941995 20062007
All
Male
Children
All
Female
Children
All
Male
Children
All
Female
Children
All
Male
Children
All
Female
Children
All
Male
Children
All
Female
Children
Childrens
Accessories
531.8 526.1 637.4 694.3* 691.6 704.0 458.5 540.8***
Day Care 30.2 22.9 210.4 208.5 317.9 395.5* 440 510.9
Babysitting 201.4 194.3 211.4 216.7 179.7 184.8 107.5 166.4*
Education 896.1 636.6*** 834.6 889.2 1,141.0 1,088.6 1,239.6 1,557.1*
Total 1,659.5 1,379.8*** 1,893.7 2,008.7 2,330.2 2,373.0 2,245.5 2,775.1***
n2,313 3,024 2,257 2,005 2,270 2,057 2,739 2,532
Notes: Totals may not equal sum of components due to rounding. All spending figures are in adjusted
(2000) dollars.
*p< .05; ***p< .001 (two-tailed ttests for differences in means, performed with assumption of unequal
variances)
16 S. Kornrich, F. Furstenberg
These regressions show stability in many determinants of spending over time.
There were gradual changes, however, and the late 2000s in particular departed from
earlier patterns. We begin by discussing childrens characteristics and then move to
parental and household characteristics. One shift occurs in the pattern of parental
spending by the age of the youngest child in the home. In the early 1970s, the positive
and significant coefficient for the age of the youngest child and the negative coeffi-
cient for age squared suggest that, controlling for other household characteristics,
spending was low when children were quite young and again when they were older,
with the highest spending when children were in their teenage years. This relationship
reversed over time, as shown by the negative coefficients for the age of youngest
child and the positive coefficients for age squared (significantly different in the 1990s
and 2000s). Thus, in recent times, spending grew over the course of a childs life,
including when they presumably left their parentshomes.
There is also variability in the intensity of parental investment by the number of
children present. Parents with fewer children invest substantially more per child
Table 5 Means and standard deviations of variables used in regression analysis
Variable
19721973 19831984 19941995 20062007
Mean SD Mean SD Mean SD Mean SD
Total Spending
per Child
1,315.12 2,072.68 1,690.35 2,634.79 2,031.82 3,504.94 2,196.74 4,838.34
Age of Youngest
Child
9.34 7.16 9.19 7.17 8.87 6.98 9.14 6.91
Household Income in
1,000s of Dollars
61.63 34.92 52.70 39.49 57.01 44.13 66.42 68.41
Proportion of
Earnings From
Wife
.13 .21 .31 .37 .37 .39 .40 .39
Wife Works
Part-Time
.31 .46 .29 .45 .26 .44 .23 .42
Wife Works
Full-Time
.14 .35 .11 .32 .17 .37 .18 .38
High School
Graduate
.35 .48 .34 .47 .35 .47 .27 .44
Some College .14 .35 .20 .40 .24 .42 .29 .45
College Degree .16 .37 .23 .42 .24 .42 .27 .44
Single Mother .12 .32 .12 .32 .14 .34 .13 .33
Single Father .01 .12 .01 .10 .02 .13 .02 .14
Other Families .01 .11 .15 .34 .18 .38 .19 .39
Only Girls .30 .46 .29 .45 .29 .45 .30 .46
Mixed Gender .49 .50 .40 .49 .40 .49 .39 .49
One Child .31 .46 .16 .37 .16 .36 .16 .37
Two Children .31 .46 .39 .49 .38 .49 .38 .49
Three Children .20 .40 .35 .48 .37 .48 .37 .48
Note: Numbers may not match others listed perfectly because of multiple imputation for missing data.
Changes in Parental Spending on Children, 19722007 17
relative to those with more children. In the early 1970s, parents with only one child
present spent roughly $1,000 more per child than did parents with four or more
Table 6 Regression results, pooled analysis using imputed data (R
2
0.19)
Variable
1972
1973
1983
1984
1994
1995
2006
2007
Period
Significance
83 94 06
Intercept 1,735.7*** 368.2 1,056.4 2,688.9*** *** *** *
Age of Youngest Child 67.5*** 43.2 88.2*** 145.9*** **
Age of Youngest Child, Squared 3.6*** 1.5 3.0** 6.2*** ** *
Household Income in 1,000s
of Dollars
25.1*** 1.1 12.2* 12.3* *** *** ***
Proportion of Earnings from Wife 407.9*** 40.1 177.8 222.8 *** *
Wife Works Part-Time 7.2 338.6** 190.7 519.8*** *** ***
Wife Works Full-Time 141.4 308.7 244.7 211.5 *** ** *
Parental Education (ref. = no high school diploma)
High school graduate 124.9** 162.4 145.8 85.0 *** *
Some college 307.0*** 356.9* 363.0* 388.4** *** *** ***
College degree 805.3*** 798.6*** 743.6*** 931.3*** *** *** ***
Family Structure (ref. = two-parent family)
Single mother 521.7*** 559.0** 481.3** 379.3*
Single father 240.0* 78.5 58.9 320.8
Other families 97.4 196.5 254.1 334.6 ** ** **
Gender of Children (ref. = boys only)
Only girls 120.1* 170.6 193.1 562.0*** ***
Mixed gender 51.3 47.3 193.9 272.0
Number of Children (ref. = four or more)
One 1,017.9*** 318.4 863.1*** 773.3*** *** *** ***
Two 498.4** 62.5 297.0 348.2* *** *** ***
Three 230.0 23.7 27.0 43.5
Earnings Decile (ref. = top decile)
1 1,013.6*** 839.3 1,212.4 1,873.8** *** *** *
2 942.1*** 536.5 991.1 2,461.6*** *** *** ***
3 838.4*** 347.7 809.9 2,457.5*** *** *** ***
4 715.1*** 368.2 769.1 2,286.3*** *** *** ***
5 616.9*** 603.6 475.2 2,563.5*** *** ** ***
6 438.8** 265.9 522.0 2,055.3*** ** ** ***
7 436.4** 172.3 153.3 2,173.3*** ** ***
8 295.9* 281.3 5.9 2,040.8*** ** ***
9 285.4** 101.8 86.1 1,637.4*** ***
Notes: Significance levels for 19721973 are for the hypothesis that the coefficient is equal to zero while
tests for other years are tests of whether the coefficient is significantly different than the coefficient for
19721973. Within-period significance levels are listed in the right 3 columns.
*p< .05; **p< .01; ***p< .001 (two-tailed ttests)
18 S. Kornrich, F. Furstenberg
children present in the home, a gap that grew greater over time. It is unlikely that
increasing gaps in spending between those with few children and those with more
children are driven by changes in economies of scale because the goods we examine
have few economies of scale. Thus, it is likely that this pattern is driven by an
increasingly sharp trade-off parents make between quantity and quality. Finally, these
results show that the shift in spending related to childrens gender remains even in a
multivariate framework. In the early 1970s, parents with only boys spent significantly
more than parents with only girls; this equalized throughout the 1980s and 1990s; and
in the late 2000s, parents with only girls spent significantly more than parents with
only boys.
Turning to family characteristics, the link between parental education and spend-
ing changed substantially. In the early 1970s, households in which parents had
attended some college or held a college degree spent significantly moreabout
$800 morethan households in which the parents had no high school diploma.
Additionally, the size of this difference increased significantly over time: in the early
1980s, households in which parents had a college degree are estimated to have spent
roughly $1,700 dollars more than households in which the parents had no high school
diploma (805.3 + 931.3 01,736.6). Parents with only some college also increased
spending over time. The links between family structure and spending are less
consistent. Both single-mother and single-father families reported higher expendi-
tures in the early 1970s than did two-parent families, but this difference disappeared
over time. However, within each time period, other familiesspent significantly less
than two-parent families.
The effects of wiveslabor force participation and earnings also vary over time. In
the earliest period, wivesearnings were associated with increased spending on
children. However, this coefficient becomes smaller over time, and is no longer
significant for the 2000s. This may reflect greater gender ambivalence among parents
as well, with both mothers and fathers spending their financial resources on children.
However, this interpretation is contradicted by the effect of wiveswork status
because wiveswork outside the home generally increases spending, albeit only in
later periods, as shown by significant within-period coefficients.
Finally, we turn to the link between income and spending. Because we are
interested in understanding changes in spending across the income distribution net
of income changes, we include a measure of householdsincome in constant dollars
and dummy variables capturing householdsincome decile, with the top decile as the
reference category. The effect of income on spending is positive and significant,
although it is somewhat higher in the 1990s and lower in the 2000s. The dichotomous
variables capturing a householdsposition in lower income deciles are significant and
positive in the early 1970s, indicating that households in these deciles spent more
than would be predicted on the basis of their other characteristics, compared with
those at the top of the income distribution. The fact that households near the bottom
spent more than their income would predict provides support for the idea of a floor
for spending below which parents will not spend. There are no significant differences
until the late 2000s, when coefficients are negative, significant, and substantively
large. Thus, spending among those in the lower earnings deciles is substantially
behind that among the rich, and this difference cannot be explained by income. In
other words, in the most recent time period, those at the top of the income distribution
Changes in Parental Spending on Children, 19722007 19
increased spending beyond what would be predicted from the relationship between
spending and income.
Conclusion
Using data from the CES, we examine changes in spending on children to capture
trends in parental investment from 1972 to 2007. Rather than considering the cost
of raising children, we focus on expenditures intended for children, which approxi-
mate parentsmonetary investment in their children and presumably account for some
substantial portion of the advantages that wealthier parents are able to confer on their
children. To our knowledge, this is the first long-term study tracking parents
monetary investments. Understanding changes in investments over this time period
is important because it may foreshadow persistent inequalities.
Our findings show, first and foremost, that parents are investing more heavily in
their children now than in the past. While scholars debate exactly which resources
matter most for childrens development (Duncan and Magnuson 2005; Duncan et al.
2001; Mayer 1997), parents are demonstrating a substantial willingness to spend in
order to better their childrens circumstances. These results mirror other shifts in
parental behavior: parents are having fewer children and, through a range of activities
like spending time with their children and choosing activities that impart cultural
capital, are investing more intensively in the children they do have.
Our findings also show that investment grew more unequal over the study
period: parents near the top of the income distribution spent more in real
dollars near the end of the 2000s than in the early 1970s, and the gap in
spending between rich and poor grew. Some growth in inequality is attributable
to higher incomes at the top of the income distribution. Still, both rich and
poor spent greater shares of their income on children over time, suggesting that
increasing investment and inequality of investment is not purely a result of
changes in available income. Instead, increased parental investment may reflect
growing pressures to invest in children. Ehrenreich (1989) suggested that worries
about fallingfrom the middle and upper classes have increased over time, as the
risks of falling have increased along with income inequality. Middle- and upper-class
parents may feel the most pressure to spend to ensure their childrens futures, and this
seems to be reflected in their expenditures.
Parents also shifted from heavier investment in boys to heavier investment in girls.
Parents in households with only female children spent less than parents in households
with only male children in the early 1970s, but spending in the 1980s and 1990s had
equalized. This pattern suggests weakened gender preferences of parents, with
parents valuing girls and boys equally. However, by the late 2000s, parents of girls
appeared to spend more than parents of boys. Although research shows gender
convergence in a variety of areas, relatively little research shows a preference for
girls. This difference may be driven by events outside the home, in that women now
out-enroll men in higher education, and parents assist with these payments. Still,
because parents spend more on other goods when they report having only girls in the
home, we are curious about the extent to which parental preferences have shifted and
whether parents invest more heavily in girls in other areas as well.
20 S. Kornrich, F. Furstenberg
These results match recent evidence about childhood achievement. Our finding
that the gap in parental investment between the top and bottom of the income
distribution matches recent findings (Reardon 2011) that the gap in test scores
between children of parents at the 90th percentile of the income distribution and
those at the 10th percentile has grown over time. Similarly, long-standing gaps
between boysand girlsperformances on standardized math tests have eroded to
parity over time (Hyde et al. 2008). Although there is no evidence to suggest that
spending alone can account for these shifts, monetary investment should be related to
achievement and, if nothing else, serves as a reflection of parentslevel of motivation
to invest in their children.
Finally, we find that the shape of parental investment over the course of
childrens lives has changed as well. Prior to the 1990s, parents appeared to
invest most in children in their teen years. In the late 1990s and the 2000s,
however, spending was greatest when children were quite young and when they
were in their mid-20s. These results provide an important characterization of
parentsmonetary investment to complement existing research documenting
parentstime with children.
Still, a number of unanswered questions deserve further scrutiny. First, in this
article, we rely on pretax income rather than after-tax income in expectation that it
was the most reliable measure and most consistent over time. Yet, taxes would lead to
some equalization of the income distribution and would mean that the reported share
of income spent on children would be higher among the rich than reported here. Local
taxes may also be an interesting and important source of variation; because many of
these taxes are dedicated to education, they can provide another measure of the extent
of investment in children.
A second area deserving further investigation is the shift that occurs in the most
recent time period. Unlike earlier periods, parental expenditures in at least some
portions of the income distribution declined for the first time between the 1990s and
the late 2000s. One possible explanation for this decline is simply that parents
reduced their investments because they perceived them, for whatever reason, to be
ineffective. However, another explanation could be that the years observed2006
and 2007were exceptional because they took place during a speculative boom in
housing, leading households to extend themselves to purchase housing. Observing
subsequent years might show whether these years were aberrations or represented a
shift in the trajectory of parental investment.
Parents invest in their childrens outcomes in many ways. This article tracks
one measure of parentscontributions to their childrennamely, their monetary
investmentsover time and finds that in the race to the top, higher-income
children are at an ever greater advantage because their parents can and do
spend more on child care, preschool, and the growing costs of postsecondary
education. The costs borne by the family impose a growing burden on low- and
moderate-income families, whose incomes have stagnated over the past several
decades. It seems evident that unless constraints on less-advantaged households
are reduced, the children of low- and moderate-income families will continue to
lose ground. Thus, contemporary increases in inequality may lead to even
greater increases in inequality in the future as advantage and disadvantage are
passed across the generations through investment.
Changes in Parental Spending on Children, 19722007 21
Acknowledgments The authors would like to thank Sheldon Danziger, Greg Duncan, Paula England,
Anne Gauthier, Luz Marina Arias, two anonymous reviewers, and participants in a seminar at the Juan
March Institute for their helpful comments and suggestions.
References
Allison, P. D. (2001). Missing data. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.
Becker, G. S. (1975). Human capital: A theoretical and empirical analysis, with special reference to
education (2nd ed.). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
Bianchi, S. M. (2000). Maternal employment and time with children: Dramatic change or surprising
continuity? Demography, 37, 401414.
Bianchi, S. M., Cohen, P. N., Raley, S., & Nomaguchi, K. (2004). Inequality in parental investment in
child-rearing: Expenditures, time, and health. In K. M. Neckerman (Ed.), Social inequality (pp. 189219).
New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Bianchi, S. M., Robinson, J. P., & Milkie, M. A. (2006). Changing rhythms of American family life. New
York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Bourdieu, P. (1984). Distinction: A social critique of the judgment of taste. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
Cohen, P. N. (1998). Replacing housework in the service economy: Gender, class, and race-ethnicity in
service spending. Gender & Society, 12, 219231.
Danziger, S., & Gottschalk, P. (1995). America unequal. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Danziger, S., & Rouse, C. (Eds.). (2007). The price of independence: The economics of early adulthood.
New York: Russell Sage.
De Ruijter, E., Treas, J. K., & Cohen, P. N. (2005). Outsourcing the gender factory: Living arrangements
and service expenditures on female and male tasks. Social Forces, 84, 305322.
Duncan, G. J., Boisjoly, J., & Harris, K. M. (2001). Sibling, peer, neighbor, and schoolmate correlations as
indicators of the importance of context for adolescent development. Demography, 38, 437447.
Duncan, G. J., & Magnuson, K. A. (2005). Can family socioeconomic resources account for racial and
ethnic test score gaps? Future of Children, 15(1), 3554.
Ehrenreich, B. (1989). Fear of falling: The inner life of the middle class. New York: Harper Collins.
Folbre, N. (2008). Valuing children: Rethinking the economics of the family. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
Furstenberg, F. F., Jr., Kennedy, S., McLoyd, V. C., Rumbaut, R. G., & Settersten, R. A., Jr. (2004).
Growing up is harder to do. Contexts, 3(3), 3341.
Gauthier, A. H., Smeeding, T. M., & Furstenberg, F. F., Jr. (2004). Are parents investing less time in
children? Trends in selected industrialized countries. Population and Development Review, 340, 647671.
Gilbert, G. (2008). Rich and poor in America: A reference handbook. Santa Barbara, CA: ABC-CLIO, Inc.
Harris, K. M., & Morgan, S. P. (1991). Fathers, sons, and daughters: Differential paternal involvement in
parenting. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 53, 531544.
Hertz, R. (1997). A typology of approaches to child care: The centerpiece of organizing family life for dual-earner
couples. Journal of Family Issues, 18, 355385.
Hyde, J. S., Lindberg, S. M., Linn, M. C., Ellis, A. B., & Williams, C. C. (2008). Gender similarities
characterize math performance. Science, 25, 494495.
Katzev, A. R., Warner, R. L., & Acock, A. C. (1994). Girls or boys? Relationship of child gender to marital
instability. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 56, 89100.
Kenney, C. T. (2008). Father doesnt know best? Parentscontrol of money and childrens food insecurity.
Journal of Marriage and Family, 70, 654669.
Lareau, A. (2003). Unequal childhoods: Class, race, and family life. Berkeley: University of California
Press.
Lazear, E. P., & Michael, R. T. (1988). Allocation of income within the household. Chicago, IL: University
of Chicago Press.
Levy, F. (1998). The new dollars and dreams: American incomes and economic change. New York: Russell
Sage Foundation.
Lino, M., & Carlson, A. (2009). Expenditures on children by families, 2008 (Miscellaneous Publication No.
1528-2008). Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Center for Nutrition Policy and
Promotion.
22 S. Kornrich, F. Furstenberg
Lundberg, S., Pollak, R., & Wales, T. (1997). Do husbands and wives pool resources? Evidence from the
U.K. child benefit. Journal of Human Resources, 33, 463480.
Lundberg, S., & Rose, E. (2002). The effects of sons and daughters on mens labor supply and wages.
Review of Economics and Statistics, 84, 251268.
Lundberg, S., & Rose, E. (2004). Investments in sons and daughters: Evidence from the Consumer
Expenditure Survey. In A. Kalil & T. DeLeire (Eds.), Family investments in childrens potential:
Resources and parenting behaviors that promote success (pp. 163180). Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence
Erlbaum Associates, Publishers.
Magnuson, K., & Votruba-Drzal, E. (2009). Enduring influences of childhood poverty. In M. Cancian & S.
Danziger (Eds.), Changing poverty, changing policies (pp. 153179). New York: Russell Sage
Foundation.
Mayer, S. E. (1997). What money cant buy: Family income and childrens life chances. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press.
OECD. (2009). What are equivalence scales? Retrieved from http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/61/52/
35411111.pdf
Pollard, M. S., & Morgan, S. P. (2002). Emerging parental gender indifference? Sex composition of
children and the third birth. American Sociological Review, 67, 600613.
Reardon, S. F. (2011). The widening achievement gap between the rich and the poor: New evidence and
possible explanations. In R. M. Murnane & G. Duncan (Eds.), Whither opportunity: Rising inequality,
schools, and childrens life chances (pp. 91116). New York: Russell Sage Foundation Press.
Rubin, D. B. (1987). Multiple imputation for nonresponse in surveys. New York: John Wiley & Sons.
Sahr, R. (2009). Consumer Price Index (CPI) conversion factors to convert to 2008 dollars using
the CPI-U-RS series, an experimental CPI measure. Retrieved from http://oregonstate.edu/cla/
polisci/faculty-research/sahr/cv2008rs.pdf
Sayer, L. C., Bianchi, S. M., & Robinson, J. P. (2004). Are parents investing less in children? Trends in
mothersand fatherstime with children. American Journal of Sociology, 110, 143.
Schoeni, R., & Ross, K. (2005). Material assistance received from families during the transition to
adulthood. In R. A Settersten, F. F. Furstenberg, & R. G. Rumbaut (Eds.), On the frontier of adulthood:
Theory, research, and public policy (pp. 396416). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
Schor, J. B. (2004). Born to buy: The commercialized child and the new consumer culture. New York:
Scribner.
Stewart, K. J., & Reed, S. B. (1999). Consumer price index research series using current methods, 197898.
Monthly Labor Review, 122(6), 2938.
Yeung, W. J., Sandberg, J. F., Davis-Kean, P. E., & Hofferth, S. L. (2001). Childrens time with fathers in
intact families. Journal of Marriage and Family, 63, 146154.
Ziol-Guest, K. M., Kalil, A., & DeLeire, T. (2004). Expenditure decisions in single-parent households. In
A. Kalil & T. DeLeire (Eds.), Family investments in childrens potential: Resources and parenting
behaviors that promote success (pp. 181208). Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates,
Publishers.
Changes in Parental Spending on Children, 19722007 23
... Indeed, the reduction in education expenses as a result of a higher health expenses shows the requirement for more public expenditure for health and education. This because spending on education is perceived as an investment in human capital of households [38] reflecting households' willingness to improve their labor productivity and enhance their wellbeing in the future. The reduction education expenditure with higher health expenses among households shows the urgency for substantial public expenditure for health and education and the urgency of social protection programs. ...
Article
Full-text available
Health shocks are common and have serious consequences for households in developing countries where health insurance is lacking. In this study, we examine whether out-of-pocket health expenditures crowd out household consumption of non-healthcare necessities, such as education items in Benin using a sample of 14,952 households from the global vulnerability and food security analysis survey. We estimated a system of conditional Engel curves with three stage least squared (3SLS) and seemingly unrelated regression (SURE) for seven categories of goods using the Quad-ratic Almost Ideal Demand System (QUAIDS) in the form of budget shares corresponding to proportions of total non-health expenditure. Findings show that out of pocket health expenditure leads households to spend more on health care that in fine crowd out expenditure in other necessity goods such as education item. These findings highlight the need for social protection programs to mitigate the impact of health shocks on vulnerable households in Benin.
... The upper-middle-class parents in our sample engaged in typical time-intensive forms of childrearing and 'investments' that have been well documented in the literature (e.g., Buchmann et al. 2010;Becker et al. 2018;Kornrich and Furstenberg 2013;Lareau 2002). This includes making major investments in schooling and extracurricular activities, and establishing close alignment between home and school environments (Table 1). ...
Article
Full-text available
Drawing on interviews with upper-middle-class parents in a large North-eastern city, we examine how “predictable stability” informs their assessment of downward mobility risks for their children. In contrast to anxiety and a ‘fear of falling,’ multigenerational achievement allows these parents to assume that their children will realize education and career success and a comfortable standard of living. This analysis extends contemporary theories of parenting and social stratification by illustrating variation among upper-middle-class dispositions and the micro-foundations that underlie quantitative research on the “stickiness” of intergenerational status mobility and the “glass floor” that protects upper-middle-class children from experiencing downward mobility.
... Household education expenditure means the total investment which parents spend on their children on educational use. Parental spending can provide children with experiences that help them develop human and cultural capital, such as high-quality schooling, living in better areas, and perhaps high-quality child care while their parents are at work [11]. So, there may have various factors in parents' background that would influence the expenditure. ...
... Children generate demand not only for basic goods but also durables and housing. Moreover, the influence of children on consumption varies as their needs evolve throughout the life course (Douthitt & Fedyk, 1988;Kornrich & Furstenberg, 2013). Some expenses are necessary immediately after childbirth (e.g., healthcare) while others are postponed (e.g., education). ...
Article
Full-text available
In this paper, we assess the scale of indebtedness of households with children and investigate the impact of having children on the likelihood of falling into excessive debt. Using the unique dataset on indebted households in Poland, we employ two indicators to identify over-indebtedness: debt service-to-income ratio (DSTI) and subjective debt burden (SB). Applying two different debt measures allows encompassing both the economic and psychological dimensions of debt burden. In addition, we divide households into two groups: young (with a reference person aged under 35) and middle-aged and older adults (aged 35+). We find that the number of children increases the monthly debt repayments and reduces the likelihood of over-indebtedness, both according to DSTI and SB, for middle-aged and older adult households. There is no evidence for the influence of children on the over-indebtedness of young families. Our results suggest that for this age group of households, the other variables related to their economic situation and debt structures may explain the likelihood of over-indebtedness better than the presence of children.
... First, future research should expand on this work and consider the underlying power dynamics that may determine decision-making regarding income pooling. Power dynamics, often gendered, are deeply tied to the ways money is handled and spent within households (Kornrich & Furstenberg, 2013;LeBaron et al., 2019;Vogler & Pahl, 1994). It is inarguable that income pooling requires trust, as combining finances may be a risky endeavor for many couples (Mahle, 2006;Smock, 2005), especially for young adults early in their careers or family building, or for cohabiting couples who lack the legal protections of their married counterparts. ...
Article
Full-text available
Recent studies have highlighted persistent differentials in income pooling (whether couples combine their earnings or keep their money separate) between married and cohabiting couples. The theories guiding research on income pooling suggest that couples pool their incomes for a variety of reasons, including increasing interdependence and growing commitment, but it is also likely that couples pool their incomes to pay for intra-household needs and avoid financial difficulties and material hardship. Using the Toledo Adolescent Relationships Study (TARS) (N = 517), we examined the associations between income pooling and measures of commitment and material hardship among married and cohabiting young adults (ages 22–29). Results show that increasing levels of commitment were associated with higher odds of completely income pooling, regardless of union status. Further, the odds of complete income pooling rose with increasing material hardship. However, the married-cohabiting gap in income pooling persisted after controlling for demographic factors, employment characteristics, and relationship characteristics: married young adults had significantly higher odds of income pooling than cohabiting young adults. Standardized estimates reveal that, although there are significant differences in commitment and material hardship between married and cohabiting young adults, these compositional differences do not drive the married-cohabiting income pooling gap. Instead, there are differences in role of commitment and material hardship for these young couples. Overall, results suggest that income pooling behavior is both an indicator of commitment and a strategy to manage economic hardship among married and cohabiting young adults in the U.S. These findings provide new insights into how young adults may navigate commitment and financial concerns within their intimate relationships.
... For example, using more recent U.S. data, Blau et al. (2020) revisited Dahl and Moretti (2008) but failed to find that having a female first child was associated with a higher probability of having additional children among natives, although a female first child was still more likely to be in the family without a father in particular among natives. A few studies find that parents treat girls and boys equally in plenty of dimensions, such as parental spending (Kornrich & Furstenberg, 2013), prenatal care (Lhila & Simon, 2008), and parental availability (Hofferth & Anderson, 2003). Even if parents treat boys differently from girls, it may not necessarily mean they have a gender bias (Baker & Milligan, 2016;Gugl & Welling, 2012). ...
Article
Full-text available
Using data drawn from 2010, 2012, and 2013 American Time Use Survey Well-Being Modules, this paper examines the existence of son preference among fathers in the U.S. by estimating the effect of child gender on the fathers’ subjective well-being. A wide range of subjective well-being measures, including happiness, pain, sadness, stress, tiredness, and meaningfulness, is analyzed, and fixed-effects models are adopted to control for unobserved individual heterogeneity. The results from the full sample show that fathers feel less sad and tired when interacting with both sons and daughters versus with daughters only. In families with only one child, fathers report no difference in subjective well-being when spending time with a son versus with a daughter. By further stratifying this sample of fathers by child’s age of three, we continue to find no difference in paternal subjective well-being between being with a son and with a daughter when the child is younger than three. However, when the child is three or older, we find that fathers feel less stressed and more meaningful being with a son versus with a daughter. The results from Asian fathers in the U.S., in contrast, show a tremendous reduction in stress in activities with sons only than with daughters only. These results indicate no evidence of son preference in the general U.S. population. If there is any, it only exists among Asian fathers in the U.S.
Article
Full-text available
This study investigates whether parents spend different amounts of time in housework, childcare, and employment across birth cohorts. We apply data from the American Time Use Survey (ATUS; 2003-2018) and age-cohort-period models to compare parents' time spent in these activities across three successive birth cohorts: Baby Boomers (1946-1965), Generation X (1966-1980) and Millennials (1981-2000). For housework time, we find no evidence of cohort change for mothers but for fathers, we observe an increase in housework time with each subsequent cohort. For time spent caring for children, we identify a period effect whereby mothers and fathers regardless of which cohort they belong to are spending more time in primary care of children over time. For work time, we find an increase in mothers' contributions across these birth cohorts. But, net of this overall trend, we find Generation X and Millennial mothers are spending less time in employment relative to Baby Boom mothers. Fathers' employment time, by contrast, has not changed across cohorts or over our measured period. Ultimately, we find gender gaps in childcare, housework and employment across cohorts remain suggesting cohort replacement and period effects are inadequate to close gender gaps in housework, childcare and paid employment time.
Article
This study examines how social context, in this case, income inequality, shapes the role of cultural capital in educational success. First, we revisit the associations between (objectified) cultural capital and academic achievement, and cultural capital's role in mediating the relationship between family SES and academic achievement. More importantly, we explore how national‐level income inequality moderates these two relationships. By analyzing a multilevel dataset of 32 OECD countries, a combination of PISA 2018 data and several national indexes, we find that: (1) cultural capital not only has a positive association with students' academic achievement but also acts as a significant mediator of the relationship between family SES and academic achievement in OECD countries; (2) both cultural capital's association with academic achievement and it's mediating role are stronger in more equal countries than in unequal ones. The findings shed new light on understanding how cultural capital shapes intergenerational education inequality across countries with different levels of inequality.
Article
Full-text available
What parents do for children "matters"-or so it is assumed. Much of the literature on social inequality at the individual or household level in the United States has focused on the role that families play in (re)producing inequality. For example, in the late 1960s and 1970s, the most studied topic in U.S. social stratification was intergenerational occupational mobility (Blau and Duncan 1967; Duncan, Featherman, and Duncan 1972; Jencks 1972). This tradition of research in sociology has had parallel streams within economics (see, for example, Robert Haveman and Barbara Wolfe's 1994 book Succeeding Generations). The continued focus on mechanisms through which parents monitor children's educational progress and risk-taking behavior and ensure their adult success is also manifest in the large and influential literature on the supposed harmful effects of growing up in a single-parent family. In the past decade many studies have tried to improve our understanding of what constitutes "successful parenting" and the costs that accrue when the conditions of parenting (for example, poverty or single-parenting or both) are less than optimal for producing salutary child outcomes; examples include Sara McLanahan and Gary Sandefur's widely cited 1994 book Growing up in a Single-Parent Family: What Hurts? What Helps? and Susan Mayer's 1997 book What Money Can't Buy: Family Income and Children's Life Chances. Beginning with the early work of James Coleman, an extensive literature developed on education that asked whether schools make a difference. The backdrop for these studies, however, was always implicitly family investment: Does the quality of schools add to the likelihood of later life success, or is variation in student performance largely determined within the family (either through genetic endowment or differential family investments or both in combination)? Recently, the importance of peer influences as determinants of child outcomes have captured the attention of researchers. Yet again, the backdrop remains the relative influence of these factors compared with genetic endowment, family factors, and parenting behaviors that help ensure children's well-being. The common theme in the large literature on the role of parents in determining children's success and well-being is that inequality in material and other investments that parents make in child-rearing may be one of the "keys" to predicting the inequality in the success of the next generation. Our subject in this chapter is the inequality in investment that occurs by socioeconomic level of the parents, focusing on the variation by college education. Several changes in U.S. society since the 1970s lead us to speculate that differentials in parents' ability to bestow resources on their children may be widening in recent years. First, as the wage gap between college-educated and less-educated workers widened in the 1980s and 1990s, income growth for children living in families with a college-educated parent outpaced that of children whose parent had less than a college degree. The family income distribution for children became more unequal after 1973. The Gini index for the income of children's families increased from 0.356 to 0.470 between 1973 and 1996 (Levy 1998, 164). Second, the growth in single-parent families shifted many children living only with their mother to the bottom of the income distribution (Cancian and Reed 1999; Chevan and Stokes 2000; Karoly and Burtless 1995; Levy 1998), and the prevalence of single-parenthood has been greater for less-than-college-educated men and women than for those with a college education. It is hypothesized that the decline in men's economic ability to support a family, combined with the availability of public assistance, has eroded the benefits of marriage among less-than-college-educated men and women (Becker 1981; Becker, Landes, and Michael 1977; Murray 1984; Oppenheimer 2000; Wilson 1987, 1996). Finally, there has been a dramatic increase in the employment of married mothers who responded to increased educational and labor force opportunities in recent decades, and that increase has been especially pronounced among more-educated women (Cohen and Bianchi 1999; Juhn, Murphy, and Pierce 1993). More and more children reside in two-parent families where both parents are employed. Wives' employment reached 80 percent for married-couple families in the top income quintile in 1996, up from 32 percent in 1949 (Levy 1998, table 2.4). Although families at all income levels experienced an increase in wives' employment, the increase is greater for highly educated women than for less-educated women. Moreover, high rates of marital homogamy by educational attainment have also been increasing (see Kalmijn 1991; Mare 1995). Thus, well-educated, dual-earner, two-parent families now typify families at the top of the family income distribution. Children with college-educated parents seem to be in a better position economically compared with children whose parents are not collegeeducated. As college-educated parents' family income rose relative to that of less-educated parents, the better-educated parents may have also become better able to make large financial investments in their children. In this chapter, we examine three major ways in which parents invest in their children. First, we focus on child-oriented expenditures. If, as Frank Levy (1998) argues, the family income of children's families by level of parents' education became more unequal, other things being equal, it would follow that expenditures targeted toward children should also have become more unequal. This implies that child-related purchases have increased or decreased at the same rate at which family income has increased or decreased. However, it may well be that parents protect monetary provisions for their children relative to other household expenditures. If this is the case, we would expect such expenditures to be inelastic relative to changes in income over time. By analyzing direct expenditures on children, we can ascertain whether increased income inequality has substantially increased the dispersion of material investments in children. Second, parents engage in an array of activities with their children that are aimed at promoting the health and well-being of their offspring. Mothers in higher-income households used to stay at home, at least when their children were young, and early time diary studies suggested that highly educated mothers did more enriching activities with their children than less-educated mothers (Leibowitz 1974; Hill and Stafford 1985). The increase in employment among college-educated mothers and the increase in family income for those with a college education suggest two countervailing possibilities in trends in the inequality in parental time investment in children. On the one hand, there may be growing similarity in maternal time investments in child-rearing across the income distribution as employment rates rise among highly educated, married mothers. Moreover, because of the increase in family income, highly educated parents may have encountered disincentives to use parental care for their children because the opportunity costs of time spent parenting, primarily mothers' time, have increased (Becker 1981). On the other hand, if parents wish to spend time with their children regardless of their level of education and family income, then it may be easier for well-educated parents than for less-educated parents to protect time for their children from the demands of paid work because they may have higher status, more flexible jobs, and a greater ability to purchase housekeeping services, prepared meals, and other services that reduce housework other than child care. How these countervailing tendencies have affected overall parental time with children is not immediately obvious, nor is it clear, without empirical investigation, whether these changes served to heighten socioeconomic differences in parental time with children, lessen them, or leave them unchanged. Finally, from the point of view of children, having healthy parents is an important advantage. Although the link between parental health behaviors and child outcomes is not as direct as that between the time and money spent on children and child outcomes, staying healthy and maintaining a healthy lifestyle is an indirect but important "investment" that parents can make in their children to enhance their children's life chances (see Zill 1999, 2000).
Article
BLS research indicates that the measured rate of inflation would have been lower since 1978 if methods currently used in calculating the Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers had been in place from that year to the present.
Article
The chapters in this volume document that it is taking young men longer to secure well-paying, stable employment that will allow them to support a family-the critical economic outcome in the transition to adulthood. In contrast, women are better able to support a family on their own than ever before, even though their economic status continues to lag that of men. Many commentators have argued that decreased employment prospects, lower wages, higher housing prices, and increased debt have made it more difficult for young people, especially men, to assume the responsibilities that have traditionally characterized adulthood. Taken together, the chapters in this volume suggest a limited role for such economic factors in explaining recent trends in other young adult outcomes. These new studies confirm that changes in the economy over the last several decades have affected individual decisions to establish an independent household, marry, have children, and complete education. However, the delay in these markers of the transition to adulthood that has occurred in the United States and in most industrialized countries over the past several decades does not appear to have been primarily driven by changing economic conditions. The delay is more likely to have been caused by changes in the social norms of young people, their parents, and society in general; changes in young adults' expectations regarding female labor force participation, marriage, and childbearing; and changes in opportunities for combining schooling with work or family roles. It is possible that some of the factors analyzed here will have a greater overall impact on the outcome of recent cohorts of young adults at later ages in the life course. Consider the growing prison population. The evidence suggests that former inmates are significantly less likely to find stable employment, to marry, and to reach the other markers of adulthood. Thus, as rates of incarceration continue to increase (particularly in some subpopulations), fewer young people may ever achieve all of the traditional markers of adulthood. If these future generations are less able to care for themselves and their children, this responsibility will increasingly fall on the rest of society. As such, there may well be an ever more important role for workforce development programs and basic education programs in prisons and for substance abuse and reentry programs for soon-to-be released prisoners. Further, while the current media attention regarding the debt of young adults appears to have neglected the distinction between debt to finance schooling and housing, which helps build long-run human capital and wealth, and debt to finance current consumption, the increasing availability of easy credit may become a problem for future generations. Finally, although earlier generations were more likely to stay with a single employer for periods lasting at least ten years, today's youth are likely to hold multiple "long" jobs. Whether this change will result in substantially less lifetime income and wealth and lower the ability of today's young adults to pay down their debts remains to be seen. There are many uncertainties regarding the long-term impact of the delayed attainment of the markers of adulthood. However, evidence from Europe suggests that as these changes become the norm, at a minimum the life satisfaction of young people will increase. As discussed by Newman and Aptekar (chapter 8), European youth who live with their parents have lower life satisfaction than youth who live independently, holding other factors constant. However, in countries where higher proportions of young adults live at home, this negative effect is attenuated. These data suggest that social anxiety declines when living with one's parents becomes widespread enough to be considered socially acceptable rather than an indicator of personal failure. Thus, while at the moment many express concern about the changing life course, ultimately it may become accepted as the norm. There are many questions that could not be addressed in a single volume. Our hope is that the new research presented here will stimulate a long and careful examination of the impact of economic conditions on the transition to adulthood.