ArticlePDF Available

From Financial Exploitation to Global Banking Instability: Two Overlooked Roots of the Subprime Crisis

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

The current meltdown in global banking and credit markets, which bears the unlikely name of the "sub-prime lending crisis," threatens to destroy asset values, financial markets, and national economies across the globe. The proximate cause of this situation was the end of the US housing bubble, which precipitated a rapid increase in mortgage delinquencies, especially among subprime mortgages issued in overheated markets. Since these mortgages were held in securitized form in portfolios around the world, these payments difficulties at the base of the financial food-chain led to seismic financial-market eruptions at the top. In the U.S., thousands of households have already lost their homes. The economy as a whole now resembles the submarine in the movie Das Boot: it has dived well below its tolerance level: oxygen is running low, and one valve after another is exploding under the pressure. It is too soon to know the ultimate impacts of this crisis, but not too soon to explore its causes. Some analysts have already identified the moving force of this episode: greed and overreach by globe-spanning financial firms.1 This diagnosis is correct. At the same time, it fingers a perenial feature of the Wall Street jungle. To point only to the long history of financial meltdowns, with the obligatory references to John Law and Kindleberger (1978), is to ignore unique characteristics of this crisis. This essay argues that two intertwined aspects of US banking behavior, largely overlooked until now in discussions of causes of the subprime crisis, are among its root causes: the strategic transformation of banking at the onset of the neoliberal era; and long-established patterns of racial exclusion in the US markets for housing credit. Here we use the "balance-sheet approach" advocated by Hyman Minsky to understand why the strategic transformation of banking in the neoliberal age led step-by-step to practices that now are revealed as eminently risky. Banks transformed their revenue-generation strategies due to macro- and micro-distress at the onset of the neoliberal age. These changes also transformed the structural relationships between loan- making and risk-taking, on one hand, and between banks' management and absorption of risks, on the other. That is, banks hit upon strategies that appeared to fundamentally reduce the risks associated with banking and financial intermediation activities. However, in adopting these strategies, banks ceased to perform some of their key roles in the economy as a whole. When banks generate default risks and liquidity risks through loan-making, and absorb those risks on their balance sheets, there are built-in breaks in tendencies toward speculative and overly-risk lending. For as default risks build up in the latter stages of an expansion, banks must consider both that default risk might worsen on marginal loans, at the same time that the liquidity risks of funding their entire asset portfolio are increasing. When
Content may be subject to copyright.
From Financial Exploitation to Global Banking Instability:
Two Overlooked Roots of the Subprime Crisis
Gary A. Dymski
December 11, 2007
1. Introduction
The current meltdown in global banking and credit markets, which bears the unlikely name of
the “sub-prime lending crisis,” threatens to destroy asset values, financial markets, and national
economies across the globe. The proximate cause of this situation was the end of the US housing
bubble, which precipitated a rapid increase in mortgage delinquencies, especially among
subprime mortgages issued in overheated markets. Since these mortgages were held in
securitized form in portfolios around the world, these payments difficulties at the base of the
financial food-chain led to seismic financial-market eruptions at the top.
In the U.S., thousands of households have already lost their homes. The economy as a whole
now resembles the submarine in the movie Das Boot: it has dived well below its tolerance level:
oxygen is running low, and one valve after another is exploding under the pressure. It is too soon
to know the ultimate impacts of this crisis, but not too soon to explore its causes. Some analysts
have already identified the moving force of this episode: greed and overreach by globe-spanning
financial firms.1 This diagnosis is correct. At the same time, it fingers a perenial feature of the
Wall Street jungle. To point only to the long history of financial meltdowns, with the obligatory
references to John Law and Kindleberger (1978), is to ignore unique characteristics of this crisis.
This essay argues that two intertwined aspects of US banking behavior, largely overlooked until
now in discussions of causes of the subprime crisis, are among its root causes: the strategic
transformation of banking at the onset of the neoliberal era; and long-established patterns of
racial exclusion in the US markets for housing credit. Here we use the “balance-sheet approach”
advocated by Hyman Minsky to understand why the strategic transformation of banking in the
neoliberal age led step-by-step to practices that now are revealed as eminently risky. Banks
transformed their revenue-generation strategies due to macro- and micro-distress at the onset of
the neoliberal age. These changes also transformed the structural relationships between loan-
making and risk-taking, on one hand, and between banks’ management and absorption of risks,
on the other. That is, banks hit upon strategies that appeared to fundamentally reduce the risks
associated with banking and financial intermediation activities.
However, in adopting these strategies, banks ceased to perform some of their key roles in the
economy as a whole. When banks generate default risks and liquidity risks through loan-making,
and absorb those risks on their balance sheets, there are built-in breaks in tendencies toward
speculative and overly-risk lending. For as default risks build up in the latter stages of an
expansion, banks must consider both that default risk might worsen on marginal loans, at the
same time that the liquidity risks of funding their entire asset portfolio are increasing. When
Director, University of California Center Sacramento (UCCS). Address: UCCS, 1130 K Street Suite
LL22, Sacramento CA 95814, USA. Email: gary.dymski@ucop.edu.
1 See, for example, Tully (2007).
1
banks generate loans – and hence risks – but do not absorb risks, then their fundamental
structural position in the economy is transformed: balance-sheet pressures no longer compel
them to emphasize caution more in the latter stages of a lending cycle.
This strategic re-orientation of banks – in combination with reduced regulatory oversight,
developments in financial technology, and the US’s unique geo-economic circumstances – then
transformed the landscape of racial and social exclusion in US credit markets: what was a
scenario of financial exclusion and loan denial because a scenario of financial exploitation and
loan-making. Households previously denied mortgage credit were now awarded high-cost, high-
risk loans. And when practices pioneered in predatory loan-making to socially excluded
communities were generalized and introduced into the broader housing market, the conditions
were created for the unsustainable explosion of prices in the US housing market, on one hand,
and the unsustainable stretching of the limits of liquidity in financial markets, on the other.
Banks were no longer control points, blocking credit flows to (and preventing capital
accumulation by) minorities and inner-city residents on the basis that these flows would be too
risky. Instead, banks became one of several sets of enablers for high-risk, high-cost loans.
In sum, the sub-prime crisis is in part a consequence of the perverse interaction between
America’s legacy of racial discrimination and social inequality and its hyper-competitive, world-
straddling financial sector. Chickens have come home to roost.
2. Fundamental Risks in Banking Behavior
By definition, banks are financial firms that emit liquid deposits and that create credit. In
performing these two “functions” for the economy, banks take on two characteristic types of
risk: default risk, the possibility that borrowers may not meet their contractual debt-servicing and
principal-repayment obligations in a timely manner; and liquidity risk, which is assumed by any
economic entity that finances a longer-term asset position with liabilities of shorter duration.
Figure 1: Bank structural relationships in the liability-management era
Small bank Large bank
Required reserves
Required
reserves
Demand deposits
Federal Funds lent
Demand deposits Time
deposits
Securities Fed Funds
borrowed
Time deposits Other borrowed
funds
Loans Equity
Loans
Equity
Note: Light-grey shading indicates the extent of default risk; dark-grey shading, that of liquidity risk.
Banks can experience tension between their liquidity-provision and credit-creation functions,
because these functions – and the risks to which they give rise – are interdependent. In
downturns or periods of heightened uncertainty, being liquid commands a premium: it is
preferable to hold assets that are readily convertible into money, than non-monetary assets that
2
may be impossible to sell readily except at a steep discount. Non-bank economic units will be
more able to survive such periods if banks provide them with fresh infusions of credit at
reasonable rates. But to provide such credit, banks must sacrifice their own liquidity (Dymski
1988).
A peculiarity of banking systems is that some of the very institutional mechanisms that enhance
banks’ responsiveness to the economic growth impulses in an upturn also build up the level of
systemic liquidity and default risk. For example, interbank (Federal Funds) and other contingent
borrowing markets provide reserves to banks whose desired level of loan supply exceeds the
capacity inherent in its deposit base – thus expanding the scale of economic activity; but the
resulting enhanced credit supply enhances both liquidity and default risk. This shift is illustrated
in Figure 1: the balance sheet of the small bank on the left contains only some default risk; that
of the large bank on the right represents higher levels of default risk as well as liquidity risk. The
more aggressively the large bank on the right side borrows reserves from the small bank on the
left, the more risk – and potential return – it takes on.
Given this structural situation, it is important to take note of two special pressure points in banks’
management of risk through a business cycle. One moment arises later in the cycle. Banks will
be called on more heavily in the later stages of an expansion to provide credit to facilitate non-
bank units’ continued activity and growth. As uncertainty about the sustainability of ‘good times’
increases, banks generally (both small and large, in the context of Figure 1) will become more
reluctant to increase their default risks. And the increasing likelihood of troubled times, in turn,
suggests that markets for liquidity may be adversely affected. Thus liquidity risk also rises,
leading banks (especially large ones) to consider reducing their dependence on borrowed funds.
The late expansion, of course, is followed by economic downturn. If the banking system is to
diminish the economy’s downward momentum, it must absorb – not shed – risk in such periods.2
When it can perform this function depends on central-bank interventions to make liquidity
plentiful and cheap. If the central bank does not ease liquidity markets, then banks can only lend
(take on more default risk) by taking on even more liquidity risk. If the central bank eases, then
in principle banks will be absorbing more default risk temporarily, even while their liquidity risk
is reduced. In principal, if the borrowers requiring temporary help have solid longer-term
prospects, then banks are not taking on unsustainable risks, but are absorbing and transforming
risks so the non-financial economy can recover its momentum.
In practice, things may be more complicated. In periods of heightened uncertainty, it can be
impossible to differentiate between an illiquid and an insolvent borrower. Further, when
borrowers’ balance sheets are excessively leveraged, it may not be feasible to patiently provide
credit until cash-flows turn positive again. Indeed, even if a longer-term bet is warranted, the
lender providing a credit bridge may not itself survive the intervening period. All these
complications, of course, are of special relevance in considering the current subprime crisis.
A final peculiarity of banking systems, as Alves, Dymski, and Paula (2007) discuss in a
forthcoming paper, is that banking credit-expansion strategies are also interdependent. These
authors show that if one portion of a population of banks is more aggressive in loan-making than
2 Banks can attempt to reduce their net exposure to risk – for example, by matching maturities on assets
and liabilities. But in a crisis, their exposure will be enhanced.
3
another, the more conservative banks – and the system as a whole – will be pulled toward a more
aggressive credit posture – with higher levels of default and liquidity risk – than would result if
all banks followed conservative behavioral rules. To paraphrase Keynes, banks would rather
hang together than hang separately in part because they have no choice. This helps explain why
banks and other financial firms so often appear to imitate one another.
3. The Transformation of the US Banking and Mortgage Markets
Prior to the 1980s, US banks operated with long-standing geographic and product-line
prohibitions, which limited their capacity to respond flexibly to credit demand. While not so
problematic for smaller banks, which were conservative in their lending, it did impinge on large
banks. In the 1960s and 1970s, these banks evolved a strategy of “liability management,”
wherein they supported more lending than their deposit bases would allow by borrowing
systematically in the interbank (Federal Funds) market and tapping into other short-term
borrowing sources. Housing credit was provided primarily by savings and loan companies and
savings banks (“thrifts”), which attracted longer-term consumer savings.
Figure 2: Holders of U.S. Mortgage Debt, 1979-2006 (% of total)
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
1979 1985 1991 1997 2003
Savings institutions
Commercial banks
Insurance companies
Federal agencies
Others
This structure proved unsustainable in the macroeconomic turmoil of the late 1970s. By the late
1970s, stagflation and interest rates well above banks’ regulatory maxima (under Regulation Q)
led to systematic disintermediation – the loss of depositors to innovative savings outlets, such as
money-market money instruments. Their credit supply threatened, large non-financial
corporations created the modern commercial paper market and vastly expanded the scope of
corporate bond markets. The combination of disintermediation and an inverted yield-curve,
however, also decimated the balance sheets of the thrift industry, which had originated and held
most US mortgage debt, as Figure 2 shows.
4
Figure 3: Thrift balance sheets before and after early-1980s competitive deregulation
Pre-deregulation thrift Post-deregulation thrift
Required
reserves Demand deposits Required
reserves Demand deposits
Securities
Risky
Investments
Time
Deposits
Time deposits
Borrowed funds
Mortgage loans
Equity
Mortgage loans
Equity
Note: Light-grey shading indicates default risk, and dark-grey shading, liquidity risk.
This led to the passage, in 1980 and 1982, of legislation designed to modernize, respectively,
commercial-banking and thrift regulation. A period of competitive deregulation between the
federal and state regulators of thrifts followed, leading some states’ thrifts to undertake ill-
advised speculative investments in the mid-1980s. The result was that the problem of thrift
illiquidity was transformed into a crisis of thrift insolvency. This shift in the circumstances of
thrifts is illustrated in Figure 3. Pre-deregulation thrifts absorbed a substantial amount of
liquidity risk. Note that mortgage loans are shown as being default-risk-free: a characterization
that is too strong, while at the same time capturing the spirit of the pre-subprime era. Thrift
deregulation permitted some thrifts, such as Silverado, to take on risky investments (such as
equity participations in speculative housing developments). Such behavior actually created
default risk and increased the extent of liquidity risk.
Consequently, some of the post-deregulation thrifts crashed, often spectacularly. Federal
legislation in 1982 and in 1989 then provided the funding for cleaning up the savings-and-loan
crisis. The size of the thrift industry was vastly reduced, and many insolvent thrifts merged into
commercial banks. The early 1980s’ macro and interest-rate instability also triggered the August
1982 default by Mexico on its oversease loan obligations. In the resulting Latin American debt
crisis, many large US commercial banks suffered losses, and several US money-center banks
failed.
The next several years brought a bank merger wave and further institutional innovations, which
reshaped the competitive and institutional terrain of US banking and mortgage markets. A new
set of “superregional” banks emerged in the newly deregulated environment, which generated
revenues by selling a range of credit and other financial services to stable consumer and business
customers. This upscale retail banking strategy involved a shift in the focus of revenues from
earnings based on interest margin to earnings based on fees from the provision of point-in-time
or through-time financial services.
These shifts toward desirable up-market customers and toward fee-based services are mutually
reinforcing: the customers most sought by banks are targeted for the receipt of standardized
financial services – credit cards, specialized deposit and investment accounts, and mortgage
loans. Both strategic shifts led to bank mergers aimed at market expansion: as a result, much of
the US banking market is being served, over time, by an ever-smaller number of ever-larger
banking firms.
5
Figure 4: Growth Rates of Real GDP and Mortgage Debt Outstanding,
US, 1971-2006 (%)
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
1971 1977 1983 1989 1995 2001
Change in Real Mortgage Debt Outstanding
Real GDP Growth
Securitization and the Mortgage Market. As Figure 4 suggests, housing has always been
cyclically volatile; but surprisingly, the mid-1980s thrift collapse had little sustained effect on
housing finance.3 The reason was that U.S. housing finance was already in the midst of a
transformation from an intermediary-based to a securities-market-based system. Previously,
lenders held mortgages to maturity, and consequently were exposed (as noted above) to default
and liquidity risks. In the new system, lenders made mortgages to sell them. Commercial banks
interested in expanding their share of consumer-banking markets provided the mechanisms for
implementing securitization. The process of originating, servicing, and holding mortgages was
split into its constituent parts, with each part priced and performed separately.
A successful securities-based system housing finance required the commodification of risky
mortgage assets. This required two steps. The first was the standardization of the instruments
being bundled and sold, which required the adoption of standardized mortgage eligibility criteria.
These criteria made ‘relationship’ lending unnecessary, and allowed both a new array of non-
bank, non-thrift lenders to originate mortgage debt, and a new array of institutions to hold it. The
second was the separation of loan-making from risk-bearing. The willingness of wealth-holding
institutions to take on securitized mortgaged debt was accomplished by insuring the ready
availability of government and private underwriting of mortgage debt. Two federally-chartered
agencies, FNMA (the Federal National Mortgage Association) and FHLMC (the Federal Home
Loan Mortgage Corporation) have long provided a secondary market for qualifying mortgages. A
3 For elaboration of the arguments made in this section, see Dymski (2002).
6
third agency, the Government National Mortgage Association (GNMA or Ginnie Mae), provides a
secondary market for FHA, VA, and FmHA mortgages. These agencies have continued to
underwrite most mortgage credit; further, as Figure 2 shows, these agencies hold a significant share
of US mortgage debt.
Figure 5: Thrift / mortgage-investor balance sheets with securitization
Thrift (mortgage originator) Mortgage-investor
Reserves Demand deposits
Securities Time
deposits
Investments from
pension, trust funds
(maturity matched)
Mortgage loans Equity
Mortgage loans (by
maturity of payment
date)
Shares or equity
Note: Light-grey shading indicates default risk, and dark-grey shading, liquidity risk.
In principle, as Figure 5 shows, the creation of a mortgage-investor unit through securitization
radically transforms the apparent extent and distribution of risk in the mortgage system. Compared
with the thrift shown in Figure 3, the mortgage-originating thrift shown in Figure 5 has substantially
less liquidity risk. The reason is that a portion of its mortgage loans is continually being offloaded
onto a mortgage-investor’s balance sheet. This mortgage-investor could be an insurance company, a
pension fund, a sovereign bank, and so on. If the mortgage-investor unit can support its asset
position with maturity-matched borrowed funds (such as pension obligations which will become
due at different points in historical time), that unit should – in principle – have no liquidity risk. If
we continue to assume that mortgage loans are made using standardized lending criteria, so that
they are effectively riskless (or have a small and predictable default rate), then it seems in Figure 5
that the new system for mortgage-origination and mortgage-holding has virtually banished risk from
the housing-finance process.
From the mid-1980s to the mid-1990s, most mortgages were conforming conventional loans,
underwritten by these agencies, and then either held in agency portfolios or sold off. These agencies
have accommodated the larger flow demand for securitized mortgages by increasing their
proportion of pass-through securities – that is, securities whose share holders have claims on the
underlying mortgage cash-flows. The activities of these agencies are supplemented by several
private mortgage insurers that underwrite “non-conforming” loans -- “jumbo” loans larger than are
allowed under FNMA. The current limit of $417,000 for FNMA has, as Figure 2 shows, led in the
last several years to more mortgage paper moving into the “jumbo” loan category. In sum, the
reconfiguration of U.S. housing finance did not require the invention of new institutions: instead,
it required an expansion in the scope of participation in the secondary mortgage-debt market.
The divorce of risk-bearing from loan-absorption was so complete that thrifts were able to
maintain a large share of originations even as they lost deposit share.
What kept mortgage flows so resilient was the United States’ unique position within the global
Neoliberal regime. The transition from the old housing-finance system to the new was
accomplished at a time when the U.S. was both the principal global source of reserve currency
and a preferred safe haven. Further, at that point in time, the U.S. had huge current-account
deficits, which have necessitated systematic capital-account inflows. Mortgage-backed
securities, like Treasury securities, responded to the needs of offshore investors: government-
7
agency underwritten securities denominated in the world’s reserve currency – an attractive
option at a time of recurrent global financial disorganization.
Risks, once created in a borrower-lender relationship, must be borne – if not by the original
issuer, then by some other agent that has underwritten the risk or that has sold an option on it.
However, the new epoch of securitization involved ambiguity regarding the extent and bearing of
risk. It was never clear that mortgage default risk shifted to the purchaser of mortgage-based
securities. Lenders pretended this risk was eliminated, as did buyers of MBS’s. Liquidity risk, in
turn, is generated by mortgage-based securities, especially those issued on a fixed-rate basis.
Implications for the Cyclical and Risk-Absorption Roles of Banks. Banks’ increasing
adoption of upscale retail banking, emphasizing sales of standardized instruments – including
loans – was in process as the mortgage market was itself in upheaval. Loans were increasingly
regarded as quantifiable and as linked to the credit instruments emitted by lenders than to the
lenders themselves. The transformation of the mortgage market also had profound implications
for banking strategy. The virtual disappearance of thrift institutions opened up a new field of
competition – mortgage-loan origination (see Figure 2). The risk “absorption” function of banks
as lenders became ever more remote, while the competition to be risk originators grew ever more
intense. This shift was reflected in the shift from interest-margin to fees as the primary sources of
banks’ net income. Facing banks on this new competitive field were mortgage companies, which
did not make loans to keep them on their books, as had the thrifts; they made loans only to sell
them. Banks followed suit, initially selling “plain vanilla” mortgage-based securities. Things
were about to change, however, due to developments in mortgage instruments pioneered in
minority neighborhoods.
4. The Evolution of Financial Exploitation
Since its founding in the 1930s, the Federal Housing Administration had adopted guidelines that
precluded homes in neighborhoods with significant minority populations from participation,
leading to stagnating housing values and lower rates of homeownership in minority areas. This
began to change in the 1960s due to legislation passed in response to the pressure exerted by
innumerable inner-city grassroots organizations. Two pieces of legislation -- the 1968 Fair
Housing Act and 1974 Equal Credit Opportunity Act -- extended the anti-discrimination
principles of civil rights law to housing and credit markets, respectively. The Home Mortgage
Disclosure Act (HMDA) of 1975 and the Community Reinvestment Act (CRA) of 1977,
respectively, provided a mechanism for monitoring bank loan-making, and precluded “redlining”
– the implicit or explicit refusal of lenders to make mortgage credit available to neighborhoods
with large minority populations. The HMDA required all depository institutions to report
annually on the distribution of their mortgage loans by census tract. HMDA data proved that
bank home-ownership loans were made much less frequently in minority and lower-income
areas. Community advocates demanded that banks, who receive important protections from
government, meet credit needs throughout their market areas, as specified under the CRA.
Depository institutions responded that they did not redline; the problem was a lack of demand to
purchase homes in such areas. Advocates took advantage of the political leverage provided by
the 1989 savings-and-loan bailout bill to require more extensive HMDA reporting: specifically,
an annual account of applications and loans made, with applicant race and gender reported.
8
These data provided the basis for many bargains increasing credit provision in minority and
lower-income areas to be struck between lenders and community advocates.
Figure 6: “Rational” bank redlining in the pre-securitization era
Banks A, B avoid inner-city Bank A lends in inner-city (not B)
Reserves Reserves
Securities
“Inner-city” and
“Suburban” demand
deposits Securities
“Inner-city” and
“suburban” demand
deposits
“Suburban” mortgage
loans “Suburban” time
deposits
“Suburban” time
deposits Borrowed funds
“Suburban”
mortgage loans
Equity
“Inner city” mortgage
loans Equity
Note: Light-grey shading indicates the extent of bank-perceived default risk; dark-grey shading
indicates the extent of bank-perceived liquidity risk.
The advocates for minority and lower-income (“inner city”) communities were pushing banks
and thrifts to make “mainstream” loans to households seeking to own homes and businesses in
need of working capital. From banks’ viewpoint, externalities and coordination problems in the
lending/deposit-taking process prevented their full and free participation in making inner-city
credit markets. Figure 6 illustrates the problem, which takes the form of a prisoner’s dilemma.
Suppose there are two banks, A and B, both with branches in inner-city and suburban (that is,
upper-income, predominantly non-minority) portions of a city. For simplicity, the question is
where they should make mortgage loans. If both banks A and B make mortgage loans in the
same area, home prices there will be stable or increase, and the liquidity risk of owning a home
there will fall (for potential homeowners). If only one bank lends in one area, price and liquidity
spillovers will not be realized. The question is, where to lend? A redlining outcome readily
emerges if residents of one area (the suburbs) have systematically higher levels of financial
assets – and hence more time deposits – than residents of the other area (the inner-city). On the
left-hand side of Figure 6, both lenders capture spillover gains (in greater price stability and
reduced liquidity risk) from one another by lending in the suburbs and avoiding inner-city
lending. If just one bank “bucks the trend” and lends in the inner city, the loans it makes will be
risky, and its suburban loans may even be riskier than otherwise. Because of lower income levels
in the inner city, residents there have fewer time deposits; banks lending there must compensate
by relying more heavily on borrowed funds, ceteris paribus, increasing their liquidity risk. So the
solution of the prisoner’s dilemma is clear – lenders avoid the stagnant inner city and compete
for mortgage loans in the suburbs.
From the 1970s to the mid-1990s, advocates’ investigations of socially unfair outcomes in
banking markets focused, first, on whether all bank customers were provided with equal access
to credit, and second, on whether banking services were available uniformly through banks’
market areas. This first focal point implicitly investigated the treatment of individuals with the
financial means and income to (say) own houses or start businesses; the second focused
implicitly on those without such means. According to the General Accounting Office (2002),
28% of all individuals and 20% of all households lack bank accounts, and thus were “unbanked.”
Minorities are overrepresented among the unbanked; but more than half of unbanked U.S.
households are white.
9
For years, financial services were provided to unbanked and very low-income people by a
plethora of check-cashing stores, finance companies, and pawn-brokers; in many cases, these
were poorly capitalized, locally run, and only in some case operated on a multi-location basis.
However, with the increasing number of lower-income households, and with the growth of the
market for cross-border remittances, this market has been growing – thus attracting the attention
of major financial companies. Banks had only a tiny share (as little as 3%) of the remittance
market (Orozco, 2004), which is a rich source of fees. And according to Katkov, underbanked
and unbanked households generate $6.2 billion in fees (Katkov, 2002) – an average of about
$200 per household per year, even for the very poor.
Banks have recently increased their activities in lower-income markets: in particular, they have
acquired subsidiaries and begun to design special instruments aimed at the lower-income and
minority customers they have until now overlooked. Prominent among these new products have
been have subprime and “predatory” loan instruments. Since the mid-1990s, these instruments
have been growing at a frenetic pace in neighborhoods historically subject to financial exclusion.
These loans often have led to excessive rates of household and firm non-payment, and thus to
foreclosures and personal financial distress – well before the 2007 mortgage-market meltdown.
Initially, these terms were used almost interchangeably. There are two principle categories of
these loans: housing-based loans and payday loans.
Housing-based subprime lending.4 The starting point of these practices came when mortgage
brokers and other lenders began to combine aggressive marketing and sale of second mortgages
with demographic targeting. Predatory mortgages – with excessive fees, high penalties, and high
interest rates – were sold to households that had traditionally been denied access to credit.5
Initially, these were primarily second mortgages. These were attractive to borrowers because
they permitted owners of modest homes to gain access to money for whatever financial
contingencies were being faced.
Soon, loans with these characteristics were being marketed to those seeking to acquire homes.
From the viewpoint of community advocates, these loans’ terms and conditions were predatory;
for bank apologists, they were legitimate responses to some home-seekers’ special risk
characteristics. In effect, a new category of financial exclusion emerged: rather than denying
loans to minority borrowers and those seeking homes in lower-income or minority areas, lenders
and mortgage brokers could now offer them loans at exploitative terms.
Subprime loan practices have heavily impacted the elderly, people of color, and minority
neighborhoods. Many low-income and minority borrowers are obtaining loans at high interest
rates and with very unfavorable terms from housing-related and payday lenders (Williams
(1999). For example, Canner et al. (1999, page 709) found that in 1998, subprime and
manufactured housing lenders accounted for 34 percent of all home purchase mortgage
applications and 14 percent of originations. These lenders’ impact on low-income and minority
individuals is even more pronounced. According to Canner et al., in 1998, subprime and
manufactured housing lenders made a fifth of all mortgages extended to lower-income and
Latino borrowers, and a third of all those made to African American borrowers. According to
ACORN (2000), subprime lending grew 900 percent in the period 1993-99, even while other
4 The next two subsections draw on Dymski (2006).
5 See, for example, California Reinvestment Committee (2001).
10
mortgage lending activity actually declined. A nationwide study of 2000 HMDA data by
Bradford (2002) found that African Americans were, on average, more than twice as likely as
whites to receive subprime loans, and Latinos more than 40%-220% more likely.6
Available evidence suggests that lower-income and minority borrowers are targeted by these
specialized – and often predatory – lenders. Community-reinvestment advocates and consumers
are challenging business practices that sometimes victimize borrowers. As evidence of the
aggressive business practices pursued in this market, Ameriquest Mortgage Company of Orange,
California was forced to settle a consumer protection lawsuit for $325 million in January 2006.
Tellingly, this was second in dollar value, in US history, only to Household Finance
Corporation’s $484 million settlement in 2002 (after its sale to HSBC). The Washington Post
story summarizing the settlement gives some indication of the practices that have plagued this
industry:
“Under the agreement, Ameriquest loan officers will be required to tell borrowers such
things as what a loan's interest rate will be, how much it could rise and whether the loan
includes a prepayment penalty. Loan officers who do not make that disclosure will be
subject to discipline. The company would also be forbidden from giving sales agents
financial incentives for pushing consumers into higher-interest loans or prepayment
penalties.”7
The payday loan market. The payday loan – the practice of advancing workers a portion of the
money they stand to earn from their paychecks – have become common in check-cashing stores.
As with subprime loans, financing is often provided by large bank holding companies. This form
of credit is also spreading very fast, as is the infrastructure of lenders disbursing it. Payday
lenders were unheard of 15 years ago; but now it is estimated there are 22,000 store locations
offering payday loans, with a market volume of $40 billion, in the 37 states that allow this
practice.8 The average fee for payday loan providers for a $100 check is $18. In 2001 there were
15,000 stores in the US offering payday loans, with 70 million transactions and $2.6 billion in
fees -- $37 per transaction, on average, with $173,310 in fees per store location. Fees from this
market will reach $4.4 billion in 2005.
Why has the payday loan industry grown so rapidly? Participants in the payday industry point to
the interaction of two factors. The first is banks’ increasingly high NSF fees – that is, to fees
charged to customers when there are insufficient funds to make all payments for which checks
have been written. The second factor is the increasingly high late fees that are charged for rent,
credit-card, and utility payments. Some $22 billion in NSF fees and $57 billion in late fees were
collected in 2003 (Bair 2005)
Interestingly, the customers for these loans are not the unbanked. Payday-loan customers must
have checking accounts. Some 29% earn less than $25,000/year, and 52% earn $25-50,000/year.
6 Also see United States HUD (2000), Joint HUD-Treasury Task Force (2000), Staten and Yezer (2004),
and McCoy and Wyly (2004).
7 Downey (2006).
8 The statistics on payday lending in this subsection are drawn from a 2005 report by Sheila Bair, written
while she was a visiting professor at the University of Massachusetts, Amherst. Bair, of course, is
currently head of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation.
11
African Americans and military families are overrepresented. Some 41% are homeowners. There
is recurrent use; most customers use payday loans 7-12 times per year.
Lower-income US households have much more volatile incomes than do other households, and
hence need credit to close income-expenditure gaps more frequently than other households.9 But
in obtaining credit, many such households lack the financial ‘track record’ that would make them
‘fundable’ for credit cards or loans (Information Policy Institute, 2005). So some financial firms
are working on developing new sources of information which could qualify households for
higher levels of credit, over longer time-frames. However, the absence of this information has
not inhibited the growth of these credit markets. The reason it has not is the structural
transformation of the markets for lower-income – and ultimately for lower-income and higher-
risk – collateralized loans in the US economy.
Forces shaping US lower-income credit markets. Acquisitions and changing practices in
consumer finance have led to ever more interpenetration between major banking corporations,
finance companies, and subprime lenders. The subprime mortgage loans and payday loans
already had some common structural features that later opened the door to the broader subprime
markets of the 2004-06 period: (1) they were based on some collateral (homes and paychecks),
which had value no matter the income-based cash-flows of the economic units to whom these
loans were made; (2) they represented higher-risk assets, whose holders could anticipate higher
returns in compensation for these risks; (3) the lenders originating these loans needed to move
this paper systematically off their balance sheets. What was needed was a conveyor belt for
taking credit originated by banks, their subsidiaries, or other lenders, converting it into
instruments whose characteristics were readily understood by wealth-holding (or wealth-
leveraging) units seeking out above-market – higher-risk – assets.
The subprime lending industry has grown so explosively in the past several years precisely
because the links required for this chain were established between this industry’s instruments and
the new technologies of securitization and risk-pooling. Many of the largest investment banks on
Wall Street have channeled an ever-increasing amount of funds to subprime lenders; indeed,
these securitizations already averaged $80 billion annually by 1998 and 1999; further, Wall
Street insurers have backed the mortgage-backed securities that subprime lenders have sold off
into the markets.10
Not content to generate fees from securitizing non-prime loans, some bank holding companies
purchased subprime lenders. Citicorp acquired Associates First Capital Corporation, which was
then under investigation by the Federal Trade Commission and the Justice Department.11
Associates First represented a step toward Citi’s goal of establishing its Citifinancial subsidiary
as the nation’s largest consumer finance company.12 In any event, this consumer-lending
9 Gosselin (2004).
10 Henriques and Bergman (2000).
11 In another case, First Union Bancorp bought the Money Store in June 1998. First Union subsequently
closed this unit in mid-2000 in the wake of massive losses (Berman et al. 2006). In 2003, HSBC bought
Household International, parent of Household Finance Company, after the latter settled on charges that it
had engaged in predatory lending.
12 Oppel and McGeehan (2000). This drew an immediate response from fair-lending advocates. For
example, Martin Eakes, founder of the non-profit Self-Help Credit Union in Durham, N.C., commented,
12
subsidiary helped to stabilize Citi’s cash-flow during a period in which most megabanks’
earnings slumped.13
Linked to these forces was a new consumer-banking business model for lower-income
households: riskier customers are provided access to credit in exchange for either fees paid
upfront, or for loans made on the basis of attachable assets. Since homes are most households’
primary asset, especially after mortgage loans have been paid down later in homeowners’ lives,
the growth of the subprime mortgage lending market is readily grasped. The logic of the payday
loan industry is very similar – next month’s paycheck serves as a guarantee against loss for this
new form of lending. Data for the period 1989-2004 from the Survey of Consumer Finances
shows that households in the two lowest-income quintiles have had surging levels of debt, not
paralleled by proportionate increases in asset levels.
Strategically, further key steps toward the creation of the broader subprime crisis had been taken.
The initial premise of securitization was the homogenization of risks – the idea that bundling had
to involve credits whose risk was readily calculable by potential buyers. The loans made were
restricted to borrowers who were expected to pay; and the federal agencies were relied on
heavily to insure the paper underlying the securities.
These premises were all systematically punctured with the emergence of the subprime and
predatory loan markets, for several reasons: the heightened competition for returns in the
financial markets; more relaxed attitudes about risk-taking and risk-holding; and increases in
computability. Consequently, heterogeneous housing-based loans were increasingly originated
and sold off by lenders. These loans were sometimes made to borrowers whose longer-term
viability as payers was doubtful. To compensate for these risks, fees, penalties, and margins were
made sufficiently high that these loans would turn a profit for their holders even if in the longer-
term the relationship between lender and borrower broke down.
Figure 7: Subprime lenders and structured investment vehicles
Subprime lender (mortgage originator) Structured investment vehicle
Reserves Short-term
money-market Short-term money-
market borrowing
Borrowing
Mortgage loans Shares
Collateralized debt
obligations (including
mortgages) with
certain risk, maturity
characteristics
Private-equity or
hedge-fund
investors
Note: Light-grey shading indicates default risk, and dark-grey shading, liquidity risk.
What emerged in the financial markets was a system for originating and then distributing risk.
This is shown in Figure 7. A subprime lender makes mortgage loans, and sells them to banks that
securitize them. This lender is most likely funded by money-market borrowing and by investors
holding shares in its enterprise. Increasingly, the buyers of the loans thus originated were
“Those of us who have worked on the community level have seen the abuses outlined in the F.T.C.
complaint, and many of us believe that Associates is a rogue company and may alone account for 20
percent of all abusive home loans in the nation” (Oppel, 2001).
13 Sapsford et al. (2001), Business Week (2002).
13
structured investment vehicles (SIVs).14 SIVs had some important differences from the
mortgage-securitization model shown in Figure 5. Whereas “plain vanilla” mortgages had
formerly permitted the bundling of homogeneous risks in securitization processes, now many
different forms of collateralized debt could be combined on the asset side of SIVs. This
permitted diverse forms of paper to be moved off lenders’ balance sheets. The liabilities used to
support SIVs also became more complex. Funds might be obtained from private-equity funds,
from hedge funds, or from money markets (especially the commercial paper markets). The
relative transparency associated with pass-through securities was eviscerated in most SIVs.
Whether this meant that investors in SIVs were taking on the default and other risks implicit in
such financial instruments (see Figure 7) was unclear. Credit risk derivatives were used in many
cases to shift risks – or to apparently shift risks – onto third parties.15 In any case, SIVs quickly
became a $400 billion industry. As the Wall Street Journal put it, SIVs “boomed because they
allowed banks to reap profits from investments in newfangled securities, but without setting
aside capital to mitigate the risk.”16
In sum, as these new credit markets emerged, the previous solution to the prisoners’ dilemma
regarding bank lending in inner-city areas was inverted. Before, banks would be reluctant to
make any loans in inner-city areas, leading to credit starvation for their residents. Now, banks
rushed in, sometimes directly and more often through intermediaries, to make and securitize
subprime and payday loans in inner-city areas. Both lenders might choose to make exploitative
loans in the same locales, while making prime loans in others. Both prime-heavy and subprime-
heavy areas were awash with credit. The difference was that much of the debt in subprime-heavy
areas was contracted at terms and conditions that threatened borrowers’ future financial
sustainability. Indeed, banks and markets learned to regard aggressive and even expectationally
unsustainable terms and conditions on borrowers as normal business practices. And these
practices soon migrated from inner-city areas to the broader markets.
5. From the Margins of the City to the Core of Global Finance
Once securitization markets learned to accept asset heterogeneity not backed by iron-clad
underwriting, the door was open for the further evolution both of mortgages and of securities.
The financial markets were no strangers to non-homogeneous risks in securitized mortgage debt:
since the 1970s, REITs (real-estate investment trusts) had been marketed and sold off to
investors. There was already an experience of crisis: incautious investment by the Franklin
National Bank in REITs had led to its failure in 1974 (Sinkey 1981). In many cities, residential
real estate began to take off in value in the late 1990s. An asset-boom mania began to emerge
among homeowners and potential homeowners. Those who had homes wanted bigger ones;
those who didn’t wanted to get into the housing market. While there had been periods of
sustained housing-price increases before in the U.S., and while the US market’s appreciation was
actually less than that experienced in several other countries, a special feeling of desperation
around – especially in markets subject to the fastest rates of price appreciation.
14 According to Mollenkamp et al. (2007), the first SIVs were created for Citigroup in 1988 and 1989.
When SIVs are wholly owned by banks, they are often termed “conduits” (Reilly and Mollenkamp 2007).
15 The Economist (2007a).
16 Mollenkamp, Solomon, Sidel, and Bauerlein (2007).
14
The fact that many potential buyers had neither the income nor the savings to support “plain
vanilla mortgages” within prescribed parameters (no more than 30% of income spent on housing,
and 20% down on any mortgage loan) created a special challenge. Lenders’ and brokers’
successful experience in creating loans for borrowers with very risky parameters suggested the
required solution: to create loans tailored to the special risks of those whose income and down-
payment profiles had not kept pace with many cities’ white-hot housing markets. Since housing
prices were rocketing upward, buyers could be given loans for amounts more than 80% of their
new homes’ prices; or they could be given two loans, one for the 80% -- making the loan
potentially sellable to FNMA -- and another for the other 20% of the sales price.
In effect, the concept of subprime was stretched along a different dimension of the mortgage
instrument. Previously, subprime loans went only to borrowers whose terms and conditions were
less than optimal. From the early 2000s onward, however, subprime came to mean something
more: specifically, it referred to loans made to homeowners who were unable to support “plain
vanilla” mortgage packages. These borrowers might be permitted to take on loans at special
discount rates for limited periods of time. To get potential buyers “into” a home, a loan could be
made at a below-market “teaser” rate for the first year or two of the mortgage. Any gap between
market and “teaser” rates could be amortized, and the entire mortgage refinanced at a risk-
adjusted market rate after the “teaser” rate expired. Housing-price appreciation would eventually
negate the risks of a 100%-financed housing purchase; and anticipated income growth and/or
anticipated housing-price growth could, in turn, offset overly burdensome home payments. Fees
and penalty clauses could be attached as warranted to such paper.
As housing prices and as euphoria about housing-price increases intensified, especially in some
regional hot-spots, buyers were more and more forced into “teaser” rates, hybrid ARMs, and so
on (Wray 2007, p. 9). But housing-price appreciation so dominated the consciousness of buyers
and sellers that the high fees and high expected payments associated with getting into a loan
seemed merely what was necessary to get in while the window of opportunity remained cracked
open. For certainly, future price increases would allow the renegotiation of non-viable terms and
conditions in two years, when that 2/28 mortgage loan “flipped” from below-market entry-level
rate to fixed market rate. But while the rising housing-price/income ratio explains some of the
growing demand for subprime mortgage loans, it does not explain all. Some of this demand was,
in effect, manufactured by mortgage brokers themselves. Brooks and Simon (2007), in a survey
of those acquiring subprime mortgages in 2005 and 2006, found that 55% and 61% of these
mortgagees, respectively, had credit scores high enough to obtain conventional loans. These
authors go on to point out that the fees earned by the mortgage brokers involved in those
subprime loans were substantially higher than those they would have otherwise earned.
And if demand for funds was robust, on the supply side of the housing-finance market, funds
were plentiful. For one thing, macro circumstances remained favorable – the US’s current-
account remained strongly negative, so that funds continued to funnel into the US through its
capital accounts. Foreign fund-holders were familiar with the market for mortgage-backed
securities, which after all had represented the largest financial securities market in the world for
two decades. Many European banks rushed into subprime paper.17 And while East Asian
17 See, for example, Mollenkamp, Taylor and McDonald (2007).
15
sovereign wealth funds invested little in subprime mortgages per se,18 their marginal demand for
more Treasuries kept rates low and permitted other portfolios to buy subprime paper.
Two micro-reasons also worked to maintain a strong supply of funds to support subprime loan
commitments. The first is the adoption of banking strategies that prioritized risk-shedding and
fee-based income – a topic we have discussed above. The second was hyper-competition among
lenders. This hypercompetition was recently dissected by Anderson and Bajaj (2007). These
authors describe the “once-lucrative partnership” between Wall Street and subprime lenders.
These authors quote a Wall Street insider, Ronald Greenspan, as follows: “There was fierce
competition for these loans. .. They were a major source of revenues and perceived profits for
both the investors and the investment banks.” While some banks slowed their involvment as the
market heated up to its peak in mid-2005 (Credit Suisse reduced its underwriting 22% in 2006
compared with 2004), others plunged ahead. For example, Morgan Stanley increased its
subprime underwriting by 25% between 2004 and 2006, developing a special relationship with
New Century Financial, a large subprime lender. According to these reporters, Morgan paid
above-market in order to lock a monthly flow of $2 billion from this firm alone. New Century,
whose subprime loans’ delinquency rate is twice that of other lenders such as Wells Fargo, filed
for bankruptcy in March 2007. They quote Jeffrey Kirch, president of a firm that buys home
loans, as follows, “The easiest way to grab market share was by paying more than your
competitors.” These arrangements were highly lucrative, with managing directors in investment
banks averaging total compensation in 2006 of $2.5 million.
Subprime loan volumes exploded in 2004-2006, even as the housing boom peaked. Data from
the Mortgage Market Statistical Annual, reproduced as Table 1 of Wray (2007, p. 30), tells a
dramatic story (especially in light of the Brooks and Simon data noted above): in the 2001-03
period, mortgage originations totalled $9.04 trillion, of which 8.4% were subprime loans; and
55% of subprime originations, or $418 billion, were securitized. In the 2004-06 period, total
mortgage originations were the same in nominal terms, $9.02 trillion. However, 19.6% of all
originations consisted of subprime loans, of which 78.8% - some $1,391 billion – were
securitized.
It should be noted that the inherently flexible and non-transparent nature of SIVs soon opened
the door for more types of credit to be included on their asset-side balance-sheets.19 For example,
private-equity funds required a huge volume of bridge loans to support their efforts to undertake
leveraged buyouts of ever-larger target firms; these loans could be dropped into SIVs. So too
could be other types of commercial loans, for projects ranging from real-estate acquisition to
construction finance.
The conceptual basis for structured finance. For one shining moment lasting several years,
then, participants in and anslysts of subprime markets imagined that they were reinventing
banking by creating and refining the mechanisms of structured finance. In structured finance,
both assets and liabilities were “tranched,” that is, assets were assembled by recombining
underlying loans and debt instruments, and the financing that backed this synthetic paper was
18China exposure to U.S. subprime ills limited,” Reuters, August 28, 2007. Web-accessed on December
10, 2007 at http://www.reuters.com/article/gc06/idUSPEK26110220070828.
19 As Hyman Minsky put it in a 1987 memo on securitization that Randy Wray unearthed at the Levy
Institute, “That which can be securitized will be securitized” (see Wray 2007, p. 5).
16
similarly assembled by pulling in funds of different durations from different markets. What
wasn’t needed or wanted was sold off. Fender and Mitchell (2005a, p. 2) argued that structured
finance overcomes “adverse selection and segmentation.” Jobst (2003) asserted that
collateralized loan obligations (one form of structured finance) reduce risk for investors and
make investment less costly. He went on to write:
“The implementation of these core aspects of active credit portfolio management lead to
a radical redesign of business processes in bank lending, provided that risk control
routines take into account credit volume. As the origination of loans and portfolio
investment is unbundled, the risk-oriented determination of credit conditions and
increased efficiency in the lending process through standardized credit terms are
essential components of a new organizational model of bank lending.” (Jobst, 2003, p.
79-80)
What was the conceptual basis of this new basis for bank lending? Different interpretations
emerge from contemporary economic theory. Both rely on different interpretations of the
information set available to investors in the markets. Diamond’s (1984) model of banks as
“delegated monitors” is one inspiration. The idea behind this model is that there are economies
of scale in information acquisition about borrowers (agents); so banks emerge as centralized
lenders because, as information specialists, they can more efficiently make appropriate
allocations of available credit than could wealth-owning units operating independently. The need
for information about borrowers is combined in Diamond’s model (drawing on Diamond and
Dybvig 1983) with the occasional need of bank depositors for liquidity. So banks emerge as
providers of liquidity and monitors of creditworthiness.
It might seem that this explanation shows precisely the lack of any need for SIVs and CLOs.
This would be so – but only if banks were the most efficient evaluators of credit risk in the
financial markets. Suppose credit-rating agencies emerge that can evaluate risk even more
efficiently than can banks. Then banks would offload their credit-evaluation function and instead
distribute and acquire packages of securities that allowed them to maximize return while
providing liquidity. Diamond’s model drew renewed attention just as the subprime era was
emerging; for example, he published a new version of his 1984 model in 1996 (Diamond 1996a).
Another conceptual basis for structured finance emerges under the complete-information
assumptions utilized in efficient markets theory. Oldfield provides the clue when he writes,
“Briefly, an underwriter must defeat arbitrage between pass-throughs and derivatives” (2000, p.
445). If information were complete, transactions costless, assets infinitely scaleable, and a
complete set of contingent (derivatives) markets existed, then no structured finance could arise:
any agent seeking the particular combination of risk-return characteristics available through the
acquisition of a given set of securities could efficiently acquire those securities him/herself – no
intermediary (that is, no seller of a structured investment vehicle) would be needed by any
wealth-owning agent. The SIV can efficiently exist only if s/he can create a fund that embodies a
set of contingent and underlying claims that a wealth-owner cannot access directly. The reason
for the efficiency of the SIV can be either transaction costs or the imperfect scaleability of assets,
or both. In effect, in this approach, structured finance vehicles help to make markets more
complete. Oldfield writes:
17
“A structured finance transaction transforms a pool of more or less similar loans into a set
of derivative instruments collateralized by the pool. An underwriter who structures a
transaction has a simple purpose: to sell the set of derivatives for more money than a
direct sale of the pool or a pass-through instrument alone would fetch. The underwriter
accomplishes a transaction by establishing an independent entity, usually a trust, which
becomes the mechanism for structuring the derivatives. This entity represents a passive
financial intermediary” (2000, p. 446).
Partnoy and Skeel (2007) describe it as a question of using “financial engineering to complete
markets. They write:
“Because synthetic CDOs .. essentially create new instruments, instead of using assets
already on bank balance sheets .. complete markets by providing new financial
instruments at lower prices. Synthetic CDOs are regarded as “pure” arbitrage
opportunities, because their tranches typically are priced at higher yields relative to other
similarly rated fixed income investments. Indeed, synthetic CDO tranches are popular
because they offer investors a less expensive way of participating in the bond market,
particularly the market for high yield debt.” (11-12)
Both approaches carry implicit warnings. Going in reverse order, first consider Oldfield’s
approach. Given the extraordinary dexterity of the “wealth-holding agents” that inhabit the world
of high finance, completing financial markets through offering hitherto-unavailable risk-return
combinations requires Oldfield’s “passive intermediary” to assemble what may be a dizzying
array of derivative and stripped assets. Indeed, he goes on to observe, “If the underwriter has
accurate information about investors' particular demands, the proceeds from selling derivative
instruments exceed the underwriter's costs of buying the collateral, structuring the trust's claims,
and selling the derivative instruments” (2000, p. 446). This “if” proved to be quite significant.
Further, Diamond’s work always ponders the problem of banking instability. The classic paper
by Diamond and Dybvig (1983) itself is an exploration of the conditions under which a bank run
may occur. And Diamond published an article exploring the limits of liquidity-provision by
banks in the same year his new account of the Diamond (1984) model was circulated.20
The slim analytical literature on the emerging synthetic credit instruments reflects this
ambivalent view: on one hand, faith that hyper-rational behavior exploiting opportunities to
reduce informational costs or following efficient-markets logic; on the other, lingering
skepticism. Note that in Oldfield’s argument, the only way that an SIV can offer unique risk-
return combinations to the market is by creating opaque combinations of the risk-return
20 The World Bank summary of Diamond (1996b) efficiently summarizes his cautionary point of view in
this paper: “Banks create liquidity by offering claims with a higher short-term return than exist without a
banking system. The amount of liquidity that banks offer depends on the degree of direct participation in
financial markets - that is, on the liquidity of financial markets. Conversely, banks influence the amount
of liquidity offered by financial markets.
As more investors participate in financial markets, allowing markets to provide more liquidity, banks
shrink and banks make fewer long-term loans. Moreover, the banking sector's ability to subsidize those
with immediate liquidity need is reduced.”
18
characteristics of the underlying securities. Leaving aside economies of bundling, there is
something wrong in this calculus, even in efficient-market terms.
And regarding the delegation of credit ratings by the economy’s delegated monitors of
creditworthiness, there was recognition early on of the extraordinary reliance on rating agencies:
“Yet, the rating agencies’ activities have the potential of being particularly significant in
situations where investors face relatively high costs in assessing the structure and risk
profile of a given instrument - that is, in structured finance.” (page 3 in Committee on the
Global Financial System 2005).
An especially interesting example of the ambivalent embrace of the new instruments is the 2005
paper by Engo Fender of the Bank for International Settlements and Janet Mitchell of the
National Bank of Belgium. This paper, which explores risk and the use of ratings in structured
finance, was published in the June 2005 issue of the BIS Quarterly Review (2005b). A working
paper version of this research was circulated in March 2005 (Fender and Mitchell 2005a). The
working paper is longer than the journal article, as is often the case. But what is especially
interesting is that the following two passages from the working-paper version do not appear in
the journal article:
“This paper … argues that certain structural features of structured finance products raise
special governance issues and create important risks that are not directly related to the
default risk of the assets comprising the underlying portfolios, but which may ultimately
be as important to the performance of structured finance products as are the default
properties of the asset pool.” (1)
“… structured finance instruments also transform risk in unique ways via the tranching of
claims, generating exposures to different, transactionspecific "slices" of the underlying
asset pool's loss distribution. As a result of this “slicing” and the contractual structures
needed to achieve it, tranche risk-return characteristics can be quite difficult to assess.”
(2)
This is not to suggest a conspiracy against full disclosure of large banks’ risks; rather, I am
arguing here that analysts of these new instruments, relying on efficient-market and information-
theoretic models, were onto something troubling about the new instruments, but this “something”
was difficult or even impossible to identify under the tight logical restrictions that bind thinking
done in frameworks that assume fully rational and fully informed agents. Fender and Mitchell
(2005a) go on to write:
“ ‘non-default’ risks – i.e. risks that are unrelated to defaults in the collateral pool but
which nevertheless affect the credit risk of the issued tranches. To a certain extent, such
risks, often arising from incomplete contracting problems, also exist for other instruments
of credit risk transfer such as credit default swaps. Yet, the tranching involved in SF
instruments multiplies these risks, in addition to introducing standard adverse selection
and moral hazard problems resulting from the conflicting interests of differing
participants and noteholders.”
19
As already suggested, one important source of ‘non-default’ risk arises from the conflicts
of interest among junior and senior tranche holders, particularly when junior tranche
investors are involved in initial portfolio selection and deal structuring” (7-8)
Ratings, though important, are argued to be inappropriate for gauging the risk of
structured securities, despite the fact that the complexity of structured finance
transactions gives investors incentives to rely more heavily on ratings than for other types
of rated securities.”
This passage too does not appear in Fender and Mitchell (2005b); the skepticism shown here is
softened. For example, the statement in these authors’ BIS Quarterly Review article that most
closely resembles the last sentence is the following:
“It is argued that structured finance ratings, though useful, have intrinsic limitations in
fully gauging the risk of these products, even as their complexity creates incentives to
rely more heavily on ratings than for other rated securities. Market participants and public
authorities need to take account of this in their assessments of structured finance
instruments and their markets.”
Perhaps the editors considered the authors’ 2005a musings as likely to discomfit the markets,
reasoning that the sober advice to “market participants and public authorities” in the 2005b
article would be sufficient to avoid unwanted outcomes. In any event, this softer approach of
admonishing market participants to move within limits set by prudence did not work. More
official or quasi-official institutions than the BIS have reason to look back with regret now.
Indeed, the Wall Street Journal reporter has reported that federal and state authorities missed a
chance to intervene forcefully into the unfolding dynamics: “In 2005, the Securities and
Exchange Commission and New York state's attorney general's office launched separate
investigations into whether Wall Street securities firm Bear Stearns Cos. harmed investors by
improperly valuing complex mortgage securities. Determining the prices of these securities,
often based on mathematical models, involves some guesswork, particularly in distressed
markets” (Siconolfi, 2007).
An Institutionalist Minsky Balance-Sheet Approach. The argument developed here was not
considered; it unfolds on a terrain far removed from efficient markets. We have emphasized
Minsky’s balance-sheet approach. Other elements of Minsky’s financial-fragility framework
have been less evident here: the uncertainty that surrounds time-intensive processes in and out of
the financial markets; the problem of developing and sustaining confidence; the boom-bust
tendencies rooted in the interaction between varying balance-sheet exposures and varying
lender/borrower motivations.21 Here we can view banks’ strategies as implicitly unfolding in
terrains that contain fuzzy and incomplete information, in part because no clean separation can
be made between the realms of social and economic dynamics. That is to say, here we have
grounded our analysis in the analytically imprecise but historically-informed framework of
institutionalist economics.
21 Other authors have developed preliminary analyses of the subprime crisis using these more familiar
aspects of Minsky’s financial fragility hypothesis; see Pollock (2007) and Wray (2007).
20
The very notion that banks have strategies and can sometimes perform very different roles in the
economy is itself, of course, very different from the information-theoretic approaches just
discussed. So is the notion that outcomes like exploitation or exclusion are possible not only
because of transaction or information costs, but because of historical legacies of inequality and
racial oppression. Also unexplored in analyses rooted in efficient markets is the possibility that
agents interacting in markets may make contracts that maximize short-term profits and short-
term benefits for the two sides of the market, respectively, but which may create longer-term
default risk (due to unnoticed underwriting commitments) and foreclosure risk (due to
unrealizable future combinations of income and/or housing-price appreciation). But these
possibilities arise very naturally when Minskyian and institutionalist ideas are brought jointly
into play.
Figure 7: Shifts in Sectoral Risk Generation and Absorption in US Housing Finance
Distribution of real and financial risks
Participating
Sector:
Housing
finance
revenues Before the
1980s Savings &
loan crisis 1990s (prime
loans) 2000s (sub-
prime loans)
Financial Intermediation Sector
Homeowners and
other Households Fees, interest
payments Foreclosure
risk Foreclosure
risk Foreclosure
risk Foreclosure
risk
Commercial
Banks and
Thrifts
Interest
margin until
1990s; fees
Default risk,
liquidity risk
Default risk
Liquidity risk Default risk Default risk
Structured
Finance, SIVs Interest
margin
Default risk,
liquidity risk
Capital (Longer-Term Investment) Markets
Mortgage &
Loan Companies,
Brokers Fees Default risk
Default risk Default risk
Insurance &
Pension Funds Interest
margin Default risk Default risk Default risk
Offshore
investors, private
equity funds
Interest
margin Default risk Default risk Default risk
Money (Short-Term) Markets
Money Markets
(incl. com paper) Interest
margin
Default risk Liquidity risk
Government – fiscal authority, monetary and Central Bank policies
FNMA, GNMA
underwriting Liquidity risk Low interest
rates, strong
dollar
Bailout, low
interest rates
($ collapse)
Note: Risks are written in block letters (risk) when they are originated in one sector but absorbed in
another. Risks are written in italics in the sectors that absorb them.
To reiterate, in the story developed here, the separation of risk-origination from risk-bearing led
to the transformation of banks, from prudential stewards of systemic risk to turnstiles for ever-
higher levels of credit, whether those levels are sustainable for borrowers or not. Figure 7
represents the sectoral shifts in the locus of risk generation and risk absorption that occurred in
21
US housing finance in the past 30 years. In the pre-1980 period, housing finance typically
involved a relationship between a homeowner and a bank or thrift. The houshold took on
foreclosure risk; the lender took on – and absorbed – default and liquidity risk. In the savings and
loan crisis, homeowners’ foreclosure risks rose higher. Central-bank high-interest-rate monetary
policies generated unprecedented levels of liquidity risk, which was absorbed by banks and
thrifts. They unburdened themselves of excessive risk by offloading mortgage loans they had
originated onto insurance and pension funds, and onto offshore investors.
Figure 7 goes on to show that in the 1990s, low interest rates and a strong dollar kept liquidity
risk away. Default risk was generated by both banks and by non-bank lenders as they made
principally “prime” loans, and sold these loans off to pension and insurance funds, and to
offshore investors. Then in the subprime lending of the 2000s, not only was more default risk
generated, but banks’ use of SIVs generated more liquidity risk, which was absorbed in money
markets, especially in the commercial paper markets. Liquidity risk was realized as rates rose;
this pattern of rising rates also induced the realization of more default risk.
The two roots of the crisis identified here played their part in creating the conditions for the
subprime meltdown. Banks, having shed their traditional roles as risk absorbers, were seeking
out ever more ways to generate net income. They created products designed to provide services
to different segments of their customer base in different ways, generating substantial fee-based
income along the way. Their successful direct and indirect forays into higher-risk loan products
for lower-income and minority markets, together with the emergence (and in some cases,
creation) of new outlets for higher-risk debt, opened up the subprime mortgage markets. The
boom market in housing in some US regions then created opportunities to structure subprime
instruments for new homeowners, not just retirees in inner-city neighborhoods. SIVs emerged as
means of using leverage (with lax oversight) to generate off-balance-sheet net interest income.
An apparently endless supply of liquidity provided the fuel for this fire.22
There were two historical ironies embedded in this scenario, ready to flash trickster smiles at the
credit markets once trouble hit. One Achilles heel for SIVs was the optimistic assumptions that
had been made regarding the growth of the price of housing. Alex Pollock (2007) recounts the
following scenario: “According to one report of an investment manager, his firm asked a rating
agency, ‘What if HPA were to [be a negative] 1% to 2% for an extended period of time? They
responded that their models would break down completely’. However, until early 2007, it was
difficult or impossible for most participants in credit and housing markets to perceive the
possibility that something other than positive housing-price growth would continue indefinitely.”
The irony here is that much of the housing on which subprime loans were made, in the era that
wanted to believe housing prices can only go up, was located in or in close proximity to areas
that had historically been subject to mortgage-market redlining.
22 Regarding this point, the comments of Robert Rubin (2007) at a Brookings Institution symposium are
of interest. Rubin observed, “The current disruptions are the product of a greater and greater
underweighting of risk across almost all active classes during recent years. … In recent years, many
people felt liquidity would sustain an environment of low risk weightings for a long, long time. My own
view is that liquidity is not primarily a monetary phenomenon, but rather a psychological phenomenon.
… Thus, when the psychology changes, creditors and investors withdraw from riskier assets, reduce
leverage, reduce exposure, and then as the prices fall and credit tightens, and commentators say the
liquidity has shrunk.”
22
The second irony was that liquidity appeared to be infinite during a period in which the Federal
Reserve was making a sustained effort to tighten credit. The Fed’s efforts were, of course,
overwhelmed by floods of liquidity rooted, in part, in capital-account inflows so strong (linked to
profoundly negative trade balances) that it seemed US policy-makers could ignore economic
dynamics elsewhere in the world. US consumers had a Midas touch – everything they bought
(from abroad) turned into more fuel for the credit supply that permitted them to buy the big-box
houses to store their consumer durables. But once the Fed began to ease credit, with a sense of
desperation, liquidity dried up. Modest shifts in the consumption and investment decisions of
wealth-holders in the rest of the world suddenly echoed loudly throughout Wall Street. Indeed,
lower interest rates that might ease liquidity and default risk in the markets would have to be
navigated in the context of a falling dollar.23
6. The Onset of the Subprime Crises: Have We Been Here Before?
The slide into crisis. Like the coming of the Asian crisis in 1997, the momentum of the
subprime credit crisis has built up through a series of related events spread over a large
geographic area. Some 80 subprime mortgage companies failed in the first seven months of
2007. The big credit-ratings agencies came under pressure to overhaul their methods of assessing
default risk in the US subprime market. (Pittman 2007) As they did so, banking firms in the US
and abroad were affected.
And then, suddenly, the fear that Martin Wolf recently suggested was missing in the run-up to
the crisis emerged with gathering force in the markets.24 On June 20, 2007, Bear, Stearns was
forced to shut down two subprime funds it operated for its investors (Kelly, Ng, and Reilly
2007). Six weeks later, American Home Mortgage closed its doors (Dash 2007a). Meanwhile,
reports of more and more lenders’ involvement in the US proliferated. Throughout this period,
Countrywide Financial, which had originated about one-sixth of all mortgage loans in the US in
recent years, descended more and more visibly into crisis (Hagerty and Richardson 2007).
Alarm bells were sounded ever louder by prominent economists such as Robert Shiller. Nouriel
Roubini, who had risen to prominence through his Asian financial crisis webpage, speculated in
his July 30, 2007 blog entry, “Are We at The Peak of a Minsky Credit Cycle?”:
“It is always risky to call an equity market peak and the beginning of a bear market in
equities; so I will not try to do that. But leaving aside equity valuations, it increasingly
looks like we are at the peak of a credit/debt cycle, in the US and globally.
Specifically, the crucial macro question that we should ask ourselves today is whether we
are at the peak of a Minsky Credit Cycle. Or as the UBS economist George Magnus – an
expert of financial instability - put it: ‘Have we reached a Minsky moment?’”
23 This suggests a modification to Rubin’s characterization of liquidity as a psychological phenomenon. It
is also a structural phenomenon – a property of markets. The mistake made in the build-up to the
subprime meltdown – a mistake perennially observed in financial crises – is to assume liquidity is a
property of an asset. It is a property of a market, and resides in the psychologies and capacities of the
participants in that market.
24 Martin Wolf wrote, “Financial markets, and particularly the big players within them, need fear. Without
it,they go crazy.” The passage is quoted on p. 15 of Wray (2007)).
23
Roubini proceeded to familiarize his readers with Minsky’s biography and with basic elements
of his model. His blogs continued to probe the contours of the crisis, warning that the worst was
to come and that the economy as a whole was threatened. Uncertainty prevailed, particularly
among experts. Alex Pollock of the American Enterprise Institute reflected in an August 2007
essay:
“[W]e know these risky securities are being sold and moved around the financial market,
but where did they go? Who’s got them? Now some of the answers have been revealed.
… two large hedge funds specializing in subprime investments, operated by Bear Stearns,
… have ceased trading and entered bankruptcy with virtually total losses to their
investors. Other hedge funds in the United States, England and Australia have announced
large losses tied to subprime mortgage investments. Such investment losses have also
required the bailout of the German bank IKB, which cost the president of the bank his
job, and the bailout of a French mutual fund. Now everybody is asking, who else took
these risks?”
Whoever had taken these risks, risks were being realized. Between 16% and 24% of the
subprime loans packaged into securities by leading global banks in 2006 are at least 60 days in
arrears as of September 2007.25
As August wore on, the crisis veered overseas. A small German bank IKB failed. IKB had
created an offshore entity, Rhineland Funding, which it funded through short-term commercial
paper, building up a portfolio of $17.5 billion of collateralized debt obligations (CDOs) that
included some higher-risk US subprime mortgage paper. When the CDOs were downgraded,
IKB could not access the money markets, and drew on a line of credit with Deutschebank and
other German banks. These banks exercised their option to cancel their commitment and a
bailout of IKB ensued.26
This does not mean that banks abandoned the field of subprime lending en masse. To the
contrary. Some of the largest banks, such as Goldman Sachs, continued to package and sell
securities backed by subprime mortgages, even while they were reducing their exposure to
subprime debt on their own balance sheets (Anderson and Bajaj 2007). Goldman’s case, these
new originations amounted to $6 billion worth in the first 9 months of 2007; by December, 15
percent of these loans were already delinquent by more than 60 days.
One by one, more and more big banks have been dragged into the crisis. The latest is
Washington Mutual, a giant thrift (Bauerlein and Edwards 2007). A forced rewinding of risks
that they appeared to offload is underway.
25 The specifics are as follows: Deutsche Bank, $28.6 billion underwritten in 2006, 23.8% delinquent;
Morgan Stanley, $36.1b and 23.3%; Barclays, $21.1b and 23.3%; Merrill Lynch, $34.3b and 22.5%; Bear
Stearns, $22.9b and 21.7%; Lehman Brothers, $51.8b and 20.0%; Goldman Sachs, $29.3b and 19.7%;
Credit Suisse, $28.0b and 18.8%; RBS, $47.6b and 18.2%; Countrywide, $34.2b and 18.0%; JPMorgan,
$26.2b and 17.6%; Citigroup, $22.6b and 16.2%. This works out to $73.7 billion of 60-day-delinquent
loans in these securities alone.
26The Economist (2007b).
24
Blaming victims, blaming history, or re-examining victims and history? At this writing,
debate continues over the extent of the damage that the subprime meltdown will cause. Downs
(2007) and Calomiris (2007) have questioned whether this meltdown will have profound effects
on either the economy as a whole or on the housing and housing-finance markets. Among those
drawing the opposite conclusion are Dean Baker, who asks rhetorically, “Housing: Why is it
Hard to See a Bubble?” (2007, p. 10), and Henry Kaufman (2007).27
While that debate churns on, banks are already attempting to find escape routes from their fixes.
One strategy, implemented by HSBC in November 2007, is to bring apparently off-balance-sheet
paper back onto their balance sheets, thus admitting that the risks associated with that paper (and
offloaded to SIVs) did implicitly remain their responsibility (Goldstein 2007). A second strategy
is to seek out capital injections. Also in November 2007, Citibank got a $7.5 billion capital
injection from the Abu Dhabi government, while UBS sold an 11% stack to Singapore
(Bauerlein and Edwards 2007). A third strategy is to create an off-shore fund that can sell shares
to investors willing to absorb risk-laden assets. This last approach, first proposed in mid-October,
has not attracted much industry or political support (Dash 2007b).
Another possibility is government intervention. Several proposals to provide assistance to
impacted consumers and homeowners have been put forward; Wray (2007) presents a good
overview of the proposals made to date. One category of relief proposal for homeowners has
been made most frequently: several states and the Bush administration, have proposed moratoria
on mortgage loan-rate increases for some classes of homeowners with subprime loans. The Bush
plan attempts to restrict relief to those homeowners who are current on payments but who would
sink into foreclosure were the higher rates to which their lenders are contractually entitled to
“kick in.” In principle, keeping people in their homes will reduce the supply of homes hitting
already depressed markets, as well as the number of homeowners who lose their pieces of the
American dream. But as Tom Petruno (2007) pointed out:
“The success of the Bush administration's plan to stem home foreclosures will hinge in
large part on whether the investors who own sub-prime mortgages will play along and
accept lower interest payments to keep people in their houses. That may be asking a lot --
and not just because of many investors' visceral negative reaction to government strong-
arming on the issue of home-loan modifications.
Thanks to the alchemy of modern finance, investors who put up funds for the same
"pool" of thousands of sub-prime mortgages can face very different levels of risk,
depending on the section of the pool they own. Those whose sections would be well-
protected from loss, even if loan defaults soared, may have little incentive to agree to
changes in the terms of the underlying mortgages. That could invite a torrent of investor
lawsuits challenging moves to ease loan terms.”
At this writing, nothing like a solution has emerged. One reason is the deep partisan rifts between
the White House and Congress. While they are rooted in other conflicts, they make consensus
27 There is a further irony in this juxtaposition, since Charles Calomiris is the Henry Kaufman Professor
of Financial Institutions at Columbia University, while Henry Kaufman is Henry Kaufman.
25
difficult on this issue. Another reason for the lack of one agreed pathway out of the crisis is the
inability to assign responsibility.
One essential step in the process of resolving any financial crisis rooted in bad debt is to find the
sector responsible and reform it – whether through tighter regulation, through eliminating or
selling off especially weak institutions, or through some support while asset prices recover. All
these steps were taken in the savings and loan crisis of the 1980s. The debate is about whether to
punish wrong-doers, and on whether to rescue losers among the borrowers, as duped innocents,
or to let loses suffer so as to discourage future outbreaks of such breakdowns in market
discipline. The same debate has arisen now regarding the subprime crisis.
Alex Pollock (2007) has pointed out that the subprime crisis is only, from one point of view, the
latest example of a boom-bust pattern in financial markets. The embedded notion that history
repeats itself, and yet people with access to financial markets learn nothing from it, suggests that
it is useless and even counterproductive to intervene to offset losses. Allen Meltzer expressed
this view clearly in the pages of the Wall Street Journal, writing, “Capitalism without failure is
like religion without sin. The answer to excessive risk-taking is ‘let 'em fail’. … Bailouts
encourage excessive risk-taking; failures encourage prudent risk taking.” (Meltzer 2007).
Two New York Times columnists have weighed in on the other side of the equation. Bob Herbert
(2007) has reminded readers of the roots of the current subprime crisis in racial exclusion and in
unfair, inadequately regulated lending practices. Krugman (2007a, 2007b, 2007c) has also
continually emphasized the culpability and bad faith shown by lenders, and the need to focus on
wronged homeowners as well as a dangerously insolvent banking system. He writes (2007c):
“There are, in fact, three distinct concerns associated with the rising tide of foreclosures
in America. One is financial stability: as banks and other institutions take huge losses on
their mortgage-related investments, the financial system as a whole is getting wobbly.
Another is human suffering: hundreds of thousands, and probably millions, of American
families will lose their homes. Finally, there’s injustice: the subprime boom involved
predatory lending — high-interest loans foisted on borrowers who qualified for lower
rates — on an epic scale.”
As the political calculus on different intervention scenarios is weighed, other roots of the
subprime crisis, which have thus far escaped attention, should be considered as well: historical
patterns of racial redlining and discrimination in credit markets; banks’ strategic transformation
at the dawn of the neoliberal era; and the interaction between these two factors. In the run-up to
the mortgage meltdown, banks created credit without playing their historical role of risk
absorption, permitting them to fan – instead of dousing - the fires of the housing bubble. At the
same time, banks’ continuation of their historical – if contested – legacy of denying equal credit-
market access led to the creation of new instruments of financial exploitation that, once
generalized and transported into a raging home-purchase market, have led the banking system
and the US economy to the edge of a very high cliff. While the destruction of billions of dollars’
worth of bank equity may be some kind of retribution for banks’ failure to turn away from
historical patterns of exclusion and injustice, the question now is how to rebuild an institutional
framework in which all people can find affordable housing and in which banks again play a
productive economic role.
26
References
Alves, Antonio, Gary A. Dymski, and Luiz Fernando Paula, “Banking Strategy and Credit
Expansion: A Post Keynesian Approach,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 2007.
Anderson, Jenny, and Vikas Bajaj, “Wary of Risk, Bankers Sold Shaky Debt,” New York Times,
December 6, 2007, A1.
Bair, Sheila, Low-Cost Payday Loans: Obstacles and Opportunities. Isenberg School of
Management, University of Massachusetts, Amherst. June 2005.
Baker, Dean, “Midsummer Meltdown Prospects for the Stock and Housing Markets,”
Washington D.C.: Center for Economic and Policy Research, August 2007.
Baurlein, Valerie, and Andrew Edwards, “WaMu to Cut Dividend, Slash Jobs,” Wall Street
Journal, December 11, 2007.
Berman, Dennis K., Carrick Mollenkamp, and Valerie Bauerlein, “Wachovia strikes $26 billion
deal for Golden West,” Wall Street Journal, May 8, 2006, A1.
Brook, Daniel, “Triumph of the Wills,” The Nation, December 3, 2007.
Brooks, Rick and Ruth Simon. 2007. “As Housing Boomed, Industry Pushed Loans to a Broader
Market,” Wall Street Journal, December 3, p. A1.
Business Week, “The besieged banker: Bill Harrison must prove J.P. Morgan Chase wasn't a star-
crossed merger” (cover story), April 22, 2002.
California Reinvestment Coalition, Inequities in California's Subprime Mortgage Market. San
Francisco: CRC, 2001.
Calomiris, Charles W., “Not (Yet) a ‘Minsky Moment’,” American Enterprise Institute website,
accessed at http://www.aei.org/docLib/20071010_Not(Yet)AMinskyMoment.pdf on
December 11, 2007.
Canner, Glenn B., Wayne Passmore, and Elizabeth Laderman. "The Role of Specialized Lenders
in Extending Mortgages to Lower-Income and Minority Homebuyers." Federal Reserve
Bulletin, November 1999, pp. 709-723.
Committee on the Global Financial System, “The role of ratings in structured finance: issues and
implications,” Report submitted by a Working Group established by the Committee on
the Global Financial System, Bank for International Settlements, Basel, Switzerland.
January 2005.
Dash, Eric, “American Home Mortgage says it will close,” New York Times, August 3, 2007.
(2007a)
Dash, Eric, “Big Banks Scale Back Plan to Aid in Debt Crisis,” New York Times, December 10,
2007. (2007b)
Diamond, Douglas W., “Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring,” Review of
Economic Studies, vol. 51, July 1984, 393–414.
Diamond, Douglas W. “Financial Intermediation as Delegated Monitoring: A Simple Example,”
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly, 82(3), Summer 1996, 51-68.
(1996a)
27
Diamond, Douglas W. “Liquidity, Banks, and Markets,” Policy Research Working Paper 1566,
Policy Research Department, Finance and Private Sector Development Division.
Washington, DC: The World Bank, January 1996. (1996b)
Diamond, Douglas W., and Dybvig, Philip H., “Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity,”
Journal of Political Economy 91, June 1983, 401–19.
Downey, Kirstin, “Mortgage Lender Settles Lawsuit: Ameriquest Will Pay $325 Million,”
Washington Post, January 24, 2006, P. D01.
Downs, Anthony, “Credit Crisis: The Sky is not Falling,” Policy Brief #164, Economic Studies,
The Brookings Institution, October 31, 2007
Dymski, Gary A., “U.S. Housing as Capital Accumulation: The Contradictory Transformation of
American Housing Finance, Households, and Communities,” in Housing Finance
Futures: Housing Policies, Gender Inequality, and Financial Globalization on the
Pacific Rim. Ed. by Gary Dymski and Dorene Isenberg. M.E. Sharpe, 2002.
Dymski, Gary A., “Financial Exclusion and the Global Transformation of Markets for Core
Banking Services,” Report presented to United Nations Development Program, February
2006.
Dymski, Gary A., and John M. Veitch, “Financial Transformation and the Metropolis: Booms,
Busts, and Banking in Los Angeles,” Environment and Planning A. 28(7), July 1996. Pp.
1233-1260.
The Economist, “At the risky end of finance,” August 21, 2007, 80-82. (2007a)
The Economist, “Sold down the river Rhine,” August 11, 2007, p. 66. (2007b)
Fender, Ingo, and Janet Mitchell, “Risk, Complexity, and the Use of Ratings in Structured
Finance,” working paper, Bank for International Settlements and National Bank of
Belgium, March 2005. (2005a)
Fender, Ingo, and Janet Mitchell, “Structured Finance: Complexity, Risk and the Use of
Ratings,” BIS Quarterly Review, June 2005, 67-87. (2005b)
General Accounting Office, Electronic Transfers: Use by Federal Payment Recipients has
Increased but Obstacles to Greater Participation Remain, Report to the Subcommittee on
Oversight and Investigations, Committee on Financial Services, U.S. House of
Representatives. Report Number GAO-02-913. Washington, DC: General Accounting
Office, September 2002.
Goldstein, Steve, “HSBC Restructures Two SIVs,” Wall Street Journal, November 26, 2007.
Gosselin, Peter, “The Poor Have More Things Today -- Including Wild Income Swings,” Los
Angeles Times, December 12, 2004.
Hagerty, James R., and Karen Richardson, “Countrywide shows even prime loans are beginning
to sour,” Wall Street Journal, July 25, 2007, C1.
Henriques, Diana B., and Lowell Bergman, “Profiting From Fine Print With Wall Street's Help,”
Wall Street Journal, March 15, 2000.
Herbert, Bob, “A Swarm of Swindlers,” New York Times, November 20, 2007.
28
Jobst, Andreas A. “Collateralized Loan Obligations: A Primer,” The Securitization Conduit, 6(1-
4), 2003.
Joint HUD-Treasury Task Force on Predatory Lending, Curbing Predatory Home Mortgage
Lending. Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD),
June 2000.
Katkov, Neil, ATMs: Self-Service for the Unbanked. October. Tokyo: Celent Communications,
2002.
Kaufman, Henry, “Our Risky New Financial Markets,” The Wall Street Journal, August 15,
2007.
Kelly, Kate, Serena Ng and David Reilly, “Two Big Funds At Bear Stearns Face Shutdown As
Rescue Plan Falters Amid Subprime Woes, Merrill Asserts Claims,” Wall Street Journal,
June 20, 2007, A1.
Kindleberger, Manias, Crashes, and Panics. New York: Basic Books, 1978.
Krugman, Paul, “Gone Baby Gone,” New York Times, October 22, 2007. (2007a)
Krugman, Paul, “Banks Gone Wild,” Paul Krugman, New York Times, November 23, 2007.
(2007b)
Krugman, Paul, “Henry Paulson’s Priorities,” Paul Krugman, New York Times, December 10,
2007. (2007c)
McCoy, Patricia, and Elvin Wyly, Special Issue on Market Failures and. Predatory Lending.
Housing Policy Debate 15(3), 2004.
Meltzer, Allen, “Let ‘Em Fail,” Wall Street Journal, July 21, 2007, A6.
Mollenkamp, Carrick, Deborah Solomon, Robin Sidel, and Valerie Bauerlein, “How London
Created a Snarl in Global Markets,” Wall Street Journal, October 18, 2007, page A1.
Mollenkamp, Carrick, Edward Taylor and Ian McDonald, “How Subprime Mess Ensnared
German Bank; IKB Gets a Bailout,” Wall Street Journal, August 10, 2007, page A1.
Oldfield, George S. “Making Markets for Structured Mortgage Derivatives,” Journal of
Financial Economics 57 (2000) 445-471.
Oppel, Jr. Richard A., “Citigroup to Pay Up to $20 Million in Deceptive-Lending Case,” New
York Times, September 7, 2001.
Oppel, Jr., Richard A., and Patrick McGeehan, “Citigroup announces changes to guard against
abusive loan practices,” New York Times, November 8, 2000.
Orozco, Manuel, The Remittance Marketplace: Prices, Policy, and Financial Institutions.
Washington, DC: Pew Hispanic Center, June 2004.
Partnoy, Frank, and David A. Skeel, Jr., “The Promise and Perils of Credit Derivatives,”
Research Paper No. 06-36, Public Law and Legal Theory, University of Pennsylvania
Law School, 2006. 75 University of Cincinnati Law Review (forthcoming. 2007).
Petruno, Tom, “Loan fix requires investors to yield,” Los Angeles Times, December 8, 2007.
Pittman, Mark, “Moody's, S&P Understate Subprime Risk, Study Says (Update2),” Bloomberg
News Service, May 3, 2007.
29
30
Pollock, Alex, “Subprime Bust Expands,” mimeo, American Enterprise Institute, August 6,
2007. The American – A Magazine of Ideas. Accessed at american.com,
http://american.com/archive/2007/august-0807/subprime-bust-expands, on December 11,
2007.
Reilly, David, and Carrick Mollenkamp, “ ‘Conduits’ in Need of a Fix,” Wall Street Journal,
August 30, 2007, page C1.
Rubin, Robert E., “Introductory Remarks,” Recent Financial Market Disruptions: Implications
For The Economy And American Families, The Brookings Institution. Washington, D.C.:
September 26, 2007. (Uncorrected Transcript)
Sapsford, Jathon, Laurie Cohen, Monica Langley, and Robin Sidel, “J.P. Morgan Chase to buy
Bank One,” Wall Street Journal, 2001.
Siconolfi, Michael, “Did Authorities Miss a Chance To Ease Crunch?” Wall Street Journal,
December 10, 2007, C1.
Shim, Ilhyock, and Goetz von Peter, “Distress selling and asset market feedback,” BIS Working
Papers No. 229, Monetary and Economic Department, Bank for International
Settlements, June 2007.
Sinkey, Jr., Joseph F., Problem and Failed Institutions in the Commercial Banking Industry.
Greenwich, Connecticut: .JAI Press, Inc., 1981.
Staten, Michael E., and Anthony M. Yezer, “Introduction to the Special Issue,” “Special Issue:
‘Subprime Lending: Empirical Studies’,” Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics
29:4, 2004, Pp. 359-63.
Tully, Shawn, “Wall Street's money machine breaks down: The subprime mortgage crisis keeps
getting worse-and claiming more victims,” A Fortune special report. Fortune, November
12, 2007.
Wray, L. Randall, “Lessons from the Subprime Meltdown,” Working paper no. 522, Levy
Economics Institute of Bard College, December 2007.
... Segundo Leyshon (2008, p. 447), a exclusão financeira se refere a "those processes by which individuals and households face difficulties in accessing financial services". Posteriormente Dymski (2007aDymski ( , 2007b ampliou este conceito ao incluir não somente o acesso, mas também o uso de serviços financeiros que, muitas vezes, se verifica de forma precária e/ou predatória. ...
... Por fim, a relação entre a fragilização financeira e a exclusão financeira é estabelecida em Dymski (2007b). A partir do princípio de que a exclusão financeira não se refere somente à falta de acesso, mas também a um acesso precário ou predatório aos bens e serviços financeiros, o autor argumenta que nos últimos anos tem ocorrido uma mudança de estratégia no setor bancário, resultando em uma segmentação no mercado de crédito. ...
Article
Full-text available
A identificação da exclusão financeira está muitas vezes sujeita a elevado grau de subjetividade. Entretanto, o critério de separação, entre excluídos e não excluídos, é uma questão pouco explorada. Frequentemente, o limite que separa as duas categorias tem caráter difuso e subjetivo. O presente trabalho tem como objetivo propor uma metodologia, baseada em Análise de Agrupamentos e Redes Neurais, para a delimitação em questão. Utiliza-se, para tanto, dados de uma pesquisa empírica realizada no município de Três Rios (Brasil). Espera-se que esta investigação possa contribuir para o delineamento e execução de políticas voltadas para a promoção da inclusão financeira e bancarização.
... Market-based lending expanded further as market outlets for riskier securities emerged. Large banks built loan-origination-to-securities platforms, packaged and sold aggressive consumer loans (including subprime mortgages) and developed facilities for hedging and position-taking in risk (Dymski, 2010). The removal of all barriers between commercial banking, investment banking and insurance facilitated the global growth of financialisation: US TBTF banks and their overseas competitors grew by innovation and by expanding into new market areas (dos Santos, 2013;Cerpa Vielma et al., 2019). ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper contributes to the understanding of subordinate financialisation in emerging and developing economies by setting out a novel core–periphery framework that elucidates the place of Latin America in the global architecture of finance. This framework builds on the centre–periphery financial model of uneven regional credit and economic growth, originally proposed by Victoria Chick and Sheila Dow in 1988. In the era of deregulated financial flows and market-based credit, the core–periphery relationship has become a three-level hierarchical system, in which Latin American nations occupy a subordinate place. The key drivers of this structural shift within these nations have been the liberalisation of cross-border financial flows and investment, the deregulation of banking and the adoption of private pension systems. These drivers’ adoption can be traced to both push and pull factors: specifically, recurrent financial crises requiring external intervention (especially by the International Monetary Fund (IMF)), and the possibility of engaging with the financial instruments and megabanks driving the globalisation of finance. Participating in this hierarchical system has required importing elements of the financial architecture that evolved in the 1980s in advanced economies and has also arguably deepened this region’s financial dependency and vulnerability.
... It was in the U.S. that the subprime crisis fell like a hammer blow on minority communities. This was due in part to megabank-financed malfeasance and predatory creditmarket practices that had aimed at Black American and Latino communities from their origin in the 1990s (Dymski, 2010). The crisis and the ensuing policy response disproportionately affected minority households (Dymski et al., 2013). ...
Article
This special issue aims to use historical examples to gain insight into the socio-economic impact of, and possibilities of recovery from, the Covid-19 pandemic for Black communities. We approach this question by comparing the impact of the pandemic on Black Britons in the United Kingdom with that of the 2008 subprime crisis on Black Americans. We find that, in both cases, a pattern of racially asymmetric losses and race-neutral policy responses that have systematically ignored the disparate losses borne by Black and racial/ethnic minority communities. Both patterns are manifestations of these countries’ institutional racism. Relying on insights from stratification economics and using the concept of “racial formation” introduced by Harold Baron in 1985, we show how these nations’ historical relationships to slavery and imperialism have led to different structures of racial control. Our review of U.K. government policy includes a critique of the March 2021 report of the U.K. Commission on Race and Ethnic Disparities.
... It was in the U.S. that the subprime crisis fell like a hammer blow on minority communities. This was due in part to megabank-financed malfeasance and predatory creditmarket practices that had aimed at Black American and Latino communities from their origin in the 1990s (Dymski, 2010). The crisis and the ensuing policy response disproportionately affected minority households (Dymski et al., 2013). ...
... Real estate financing is the provision of finance or capital for housing purchase or building. Real estate finance also means the capital required for construction of housing or the resources required to acquire or access housing project by household or the credit supplied by housing finance institutions against some collateral (Dymski, 2007). Internationally, there are various institutions that are involved in the lending of money for real estate projects and these include: commercial banks, mortgage finance firms, saving and loans co-operatives, insurance companies, government parastatals, pension funds, trusts and other real investment institutions (Lwali, 2008). ...
Article
Full-text available
It is generally observed that commercial banks' lending criteria are pro-cyclical in nature. This means that their lending criteria are not very strict in a real estate boom while during the bust they are very strict. As a result of this, commercial banks are more likely to underestimate the default risk of real estate loans during a real estate boom. Such a situation leads to real estate price inflation and this increases the banks' credit risk exposure to the real estate. When there is a sharp drop in real estate prices, commercial banks that have a high proportion of real estate loans in their portfolios or loans to other financial institutions that specialize in real estate lending suddenly find themselves faced by a high exposure to real estate risk. This therefore affects their financial performance in a significant manner. As a result, the country's financial system becomes at risk and exposed. The study sought to evaluate the effects of real estate finance on the financial performance of listed commercial banks in Nigeria. This study adopted a descriptive research design. The population of this study was all the 11 listed commercial banks in Nigeria as at the time of the study. For the purposes of this study, only secondary data was used. The secondary data was sourced from the annual reports that are available from their websites, the NSE and the Central bank of Nigeria website. Data was collected for a period of 5 years from 2013-2017. The study used descriptive statistics and inferential statistics to establish the relationship between the variables and financial performance of commercial banks. The results showed that the model explained 59% of the variance in financial performance as given by the value of R 2. The model was also fit to explain the relationship as the F-statistic of 5.598 was significant at 5% level, p = 0.000. The major finding of the study was that mortgage finance had a strong negative effect on the financial performance of listed commercial banks in Nigeria, β =-2.147, p = 0.054. Further, liquidity and cost of operations also had a strong effect on the financial performance of commercial banks. The study concludes that real estate finance influence the financial performance of listed commercial banks in Nigeria. The study recommends that commercial banks be mindful of the way mortgage financing affects their financial performance. The current levels of mortgage finance have not improved the financial performance of banks and it may therefore be necessary to examine how mortgage finance can be used to improve the financial performance of banks in Nigeria.
Article
Discourses around financial education and literacy in Germany are examined and contextualised within recent theories of financialisation as a social process. Recent campaigns for financial education can be understood as aiming at the establishment of a „Finanzbildungsbürgertum“ (financially educated middle class). This concept can contribute to an understanding of financialisation as a process that comprises social differentiation and appeals to aspirations of social distinction.
Article
The notion of a ‘financial subjectivity’ is fast becoming an important way of understanding how people rationalize the need to take risks in daily life as crucial to personal success. This paper therefore traces the structural changes and institutional fixes – that is, the institutional stabilization of crisis tendencies in capitalism – to understand how individual strategies for making ends meet have been shaped by finance. In particular, I look at regulation theory’s depictions of the ‘ideology of shareholder value’ as partially responsible for the flourishing business sector in which competition and the threat of takeover led to the prioritization of corporate performance over job security and workers’ benefits. However, it is also necessary to understand the particular mechanisms that enable independence from the welfare state at the level of the household, in the form of expanded borrowing and financial services, which I explore further in this paper.
Article
Full-text available
This article reviews the principal features of structured finance instruments. Key to understanding the risk properties of these products is the evaluation of the risks associated with their contractual structure, in addition to the modelling of the credit risk of the underlying asset pools. It is argued that structured finance ratings, though useful, have intrinsic limitations in fully gauging the risk of these products, even as their complexity creates incentives to rely more heavily on ratings than for other rated securities. Market participants and public authorities need to take account of this in their assessments of structured finance instruments and their markets.
Article
Full-text available
This paper aims to clarify the relationship between individual banks and banking industry behaviour in credit expansion. The authors argue that the balance sheet structure of an individual bank is only partially determined by its management's decision about how aggressively to expand credit; it is also determined by the balance sheet positions of other banks. This relationship is shown explicitly by a simple disaggregation of the variables that enter into the economy-wide money multiplier. The approach taken here revives the multi-bank approach to banking analysis pioneered by Wallace and Karmel in the 1960s, which is particularly well-suited to integrating micro and macro levels in Keynesian banking analysis.
Article
Full-text available
In this Article, we begin what we believe will be a fruitful area of scholarly inquiry: an in-depth analysis of credit derivatives. We survey the benefits and risks of credit derivatives, particularly as the use of these instruments affect the role of banks and other creditors in corporate governance. We also hope to create a framework for a more general scholarly discussion of credit derivatives.We define credit derivatives as financial instruments whose payoffs are linked in some way to a change in credit quality of an issuer or issuers. Our research suggests that there are two major categories of credit derivative. First, a credit default swap is a private contract in which private parties bet on a debt issuer’s bankruptcy, default, or restructuring. For example, a bank that has loaned 10milliontoacompanymightenterintoa10 million to a company might enter into a 10 million credit default swap with a third party for hedging purposes. If the company defaults on its debt, the bank will lose money on the loan, but make money on the swap; conversely, if the company does not default, the bank will make a payment to the third party, reducing its profits on the loan.Second, a collateralized debt obligation (CDO) is a pool of debt contracts housed within a special purpose entity (SPE) whose capital structure is sliced and resold based on differences in credit quality. In a “cash flow” CDO, the SPE purchases a portfolio of outstanding debt issued by a range of companies, and finances its purchase by issuing its own financial instruments, including primarily debt but also equity. In a “synthetic” CDO, the SPE does not purchase actual bonds, but instead enters into several credit default swaps with a third party, to create synthetic exposure to the outstanding debt issued by a range of companies. The SPE finances its purchase by issuing financial instruments to investors, but these instruments are backed by credit default swaps rather than any actual bonds.In the Article’s first substantive part, we discuss the benefits associated with both types of credit derivatives, which include increased opportunities for hedging, increased liquidity, reduced transaction costs, and a deeper and potentially more efficient market for trading credit risk. We then discuss the risks associated with credit derivatives, such as moral hazard and other incentive problems, limited disclosure, potential systemic risk, high transaction costs, and the mispricing of credit. After considering the benefits and risks, we discuss some of the implications of our findings, and make some preliminary recommendations. In particular, we focus on the issues of disclosure, regulatory licenses associated with credit ratings, and the special treatment of derivatives in bankruptcy.
Article
This paper distinguishes between securitization, in which simple pass-through instruments are created, and structuring, in which mortgages derivative claims are created. The point is to explain how structuring a transaction brings value to a deal's underwriter. Briefly, an underwriter must defeat arbitrage between pass-throughs and derivatives. The potential for market segmentation and price discrimination by the underwriter is used to analyze the structuring process. In the course of the analysis, the legal rules for trusts, the algebraic rules for structuring, and the limits on permissible price discrimination are discussed. Results for an actual transaction illustrate the important features of the analysis.
Article
In this paper the implications of the two eras of financial transformation in the 20th century -- that of the 1930s and that of the 1980s and 1990s -- for urban growth and inequality in Southern California are examined. It is argued that financial structures have profound effects on the pace and distributional consequences of urban growth, in large part because urban development is characterized by widespread spatial spillover effects. The contemporary era of financial transformation has widened gaps between urban communities and banking customer markets. Banking markets that were once segmented by regulation are now segmented by market dynamics. In consequence, a financial system which once facilitated wealth building for households and communities now deepens social inequality and spatial separation. In this paper the historical and contemporary experience of Los Angeles is used to both develop and illustrate the arguments made.
Article
This paper uses Hyman P. Minsky's approach to analyze the current international financial crisis that was initiated by problems in the U.S. real estate market. In a 1987 manuscript, Minsky had already recognized the importance of the trend toward securitization of home mortgages. This paper identifies the causes and consequences of the financial innovations that created the real estate boom and bust. It examines the role played by each of the key players - including brokers, appraisers, borrowers, securitizers, insurers, and regulators - in creating the crisis. Finally, it proposes short-run solutions to the current crisis, as well as longer-run policy to prevent it (a debt deflation) from happening again.