ArticlePDF Available

Barriers to entry analysis of broadband multiple platforms: Comparing the US and South Korea

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

This paper compares barriers to entry in the broadband markets between the U.S. and South Korea. First, it explores economic conceptions of barriers to entry from the economics literature. Second, it speculates on how the conception of barriers to entry has been dealt with in the telecommunications industry. It clarifies the various industrial factors that could prevent, or make it difficult, to successfully enter the residential telecommunications market. Third, it introduces an analytical framework that can be adopted for evaluating the barriers to entry. Fourth, employing that framework, it examines the broadband markets in the U.S. and in South Korea, focusing on barriers to entry in multiple broadband access platforms. Both the U.S. and South Korea have shown greater barriers to entry in wireline broadband markets such as cable modem and DSL compared to wireless broadband when it comes to a facilities-based entry. South Korea has offered more opportunity to non-dominant ISPs as new entrants and thus, has been able to facilitate more vibrant competition nationwide. This paper concludes with an analysis of the barriers to entry for alternative broadband access platforms in residential high speed Internet services, more specifically, wireless access technologies, including other economic and policy factors in the US and South Korea. The sluggish progress of intermodal and intramodal market competition explains a part of the sluggish demand in the residential high speed Internet access market in the U.S., while the South Korean market was able to grow rapidly due to fierce competition in the market, mostly facilitated by the Korean government's open access rule and policy choices more favorable to new entrants rather than to the incumbents. Furthermore, near monopoly control of the residential communications infrastructure by cable operators and telephone companies manifests itself as relatively high pricing and lower quality in the U.S. The more favorable terms from which the dominant providers have benefited, and government's deregulation, may limit business opportunities for other Internet service providers.
Content may be subject to copyright.
1/39
Barriers to Entry Analysis of Broadband Multiple Platforms:
Comparing the U.S. and South Korea
Paper to be presented at the Telecommunications Policy Research Conference,
September 29-October 1, 2006, Washington, DC
Eun-A Park,
Doctoral Candidate,
College of Communications,
The Pennsylvania State University,
University Park, PA 16802
eup112@psu.edu
Richard Taylor
Professor
College of Communications,
Pennsylvania State University
University Park, PA 16802
rdt4@psu.edu
Abstract
This paper compares barriers to entry in the broadband markets between the U.S. and
South Korea. First, it explores economic conceptions of barriers to entry from the economics
literature. Second, it speculates on how the conception of barriers to entry has been dealt with in
the telecommunications industry. It clarifies the various industrial factors that could prevent, or
make it difficult, to successfully enter the residential telecommunications market. Third, it
introduces an analytical framework that can be adopted for evaluating the barriers to entry.
Fourth, employing that framework, it examines the broadband markets in the U.S. and in South
Korea, focusing on barriers to entry in multiple broadband access platforms. Both the U.S. and
South Korea have shown greater barriers to entry in wireline broadband markets such as cable
modem and DSL compared to wireless broadband when it comes to a facilities-based entry.
South Korea has offered more opportunity to non-dominant ISPs as new entrants and thus, has
been able to facilitate more vibrant competition nationwide. This paper concludes with an
analysis of the barriers to entry for alternative broadband access platforms in residential high
speed Internet services, more specifically, wireless access technologies, including other
economic and policy factors in the US and South Korea. The sluggish progress of intermodal and
intramodal market competition explains a part of the sluggish demand in the residential high
speed Internet access market in the U.S., while the South Korean market was able to grow
rapidly due to fierce competition in the market, mostly facilitated by the Korean government’s
open access rule and policy choices more favorable to new entrants rather than to the incumbents.
Furthermore, near monopoly control of the residential communications infrastructure by cable
operators and telephone companies manifests itself as relatively high pricing and lower quality in
the U.S. The more favorable terms from which the dominant providers have benefited, and
government’s deregulation, may limit business opportunities for other Internet service providers.
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
2/39
1. Introduction
Assessing whether or not there are entry barriers in a certain industry has been one of the
critical methods for examining the presence of market power of the incumbents. Since a variety
of entry barriers to a market will lead prices to increase greater than marginal cost and deter the
entry of more efficient companies, it is detrimental to allocative efficiency and productive
efficiency (Carlton & Perloff, 2005; Blees, et al., 2003).
When it comes to the residential broadband (or high speed Internet) market, the recent
emphasis of the FCC on facilities-based competition and a series of deregulatory decisions have
given rise to the debate as to whether the US competition policy (i.e., the elimination of
mandated open access rules to the incumbents’ networks) will result in a greater competitive
advantage to the incumbents and higher barriers to entry to new entrants (Weiser & Bleha, 2005;
Scott & Aaron, 2005; Cooper, 2005; Kimmelman, 2005; Besing, 2005; Bleha, 2005).
Since 1999, wired access technologies such as fiber and broadband over power line (BPL)
and wireless access technologies such as Wi-Fi, WiMax1 and satellite have been promoted as
would-be competitors in the foreseeable future.2 However, the residential broadband market in
the U.S. is still characterized by a dominant-fringe model as identified in the narrowband
telephone market (Rosenberg and Clements, 2000). It is suggested that the residential broadband
market will be a dominant-fringe cluster model because of the structure of two dominant leaders
in each cluster (the ILECs and cable MSOs) with smaller entrants (Zhang, 2002). The incumbent
sellers will initially retain large market shares with a fringe attempting to shave away the
incumbent’s customers. Traditional economic literature suggests that the smaller players will be
price takers and face some significant challenges in entering these markets.
Despite the significance of entry barriers, there is lack of research over how these new
entrants with alternative technologies enter and serve the market and further, how the FCC’s
competition policy will influence these new entrants in the long run. We only guess that the
impact of entry barriers would be different depending on the type of entrance, i.e., entrants with
facilities and entrants without their own facilities. Also, it would be different between a pure new
starter and an entrant that comes over from the other industry. Among alternative access
technologies, the wireless group has the most potential because of their cost effectiveness
compared to other technologies (CSTB, 2001; Zhang, 2002). The rapid adoption and expansion
of service areas recently through the incumbents, wireless ISPs and municipal governments
shows its possibility.
On the other hand, increasing concern about lagging behind other countries in terms of
1 Worldwide Interoperability for Microwave Access (WiMax). WiMax allows for wireless data speeds of up to 40 Mbps over a
distance of 10 kilometers. Although it requires the availablity of spectrum, WiMax technology has been envisioned as
complementary to Wi-Fi, playing a key role in providing long-range fixed wireless connectivity in rural and remote areas as well
as mobile connectivity over shorter distiances (OECD, 2006).
2 The FCC divides the access technologies into five mutually exclusive categories: “Asymmetric digital subscriber line (ADSL)
technologies, which provide speeds in one direction greater than speeds in the other direction; wireline technologies other than
ADSL, including traditional telephone company high-speed services and symmetric DSL services that provide equivalent
functionality; coaxial cable, including the typical hybrid fiber-coax (HFC) architecture of upgraded cable TV systems; optical
fiber to the subscriber's premises (e.g., Fiber-to-the-Home, or FTTH) and electric powerline; and satellite and terrestrial wireless
systems, which use radio spectrum to communicate with a radio transmitter” (FCC, 2005, p.13).
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
3/39
the broadband penetration rate has been also rising with many academics and research analysts
(Horrigan, 2005; Bleha, 2005; Frieden, 2005a, 2005b). In particular, South Korea has been an
example to look at the impact of fierce competition on a successful penetration rate in the
residential broadband market. For a long time, the Korean government has enforced its
unbundling mandate and line sharing rules on the incumbent network providers both in
narrowband past and broadband currently. Thanks to its more favorable policy towards new
entrants, South Korea has enjoyed more viable competition on both intermodal and intramodal
bases compared to the U.S. (Lau, Kim and Atkin, 2005; Han, Byun & Lee, 2005; Lee & Chan-
Olmsted, 2004). Thus, the key inquiry in the case of South Korea would be the size of entrance
rather than the shape, for example, whether it will be a small entrance in a certain region or a
nationwide entrance regardless of the presence of facilities. As a result, the size of entrance will
determine entry barriers to the residential broadband market in South Korea. Despite vibrant
competition between DSL and cable modems in South Korea, alternative broadband platforms
such as wireless and BPL have not appeared as competitors in the market, just as in the U.S.
Therefore, they have been regarded as complementary access technologies to the incumbents
rather than competitive technologies (Koh, Lee, & Kim, 2005).
Based on this background information, this paper further examines whether there are
barriers to entry for new entrants to enter the residential high speed Internet market in the U.S.
and South Korea by applying barriers-to-entry theories derived from the industrial organization
approach. In particular, the comparison of both countries will offer more insight and useful
implications to policy makers and the industry than when we look only at one country in terms of
broadband competition policy. It roughly reviews each broadband access platform in the U.S.,
with special attention to wireless technologies, and this analysis will be compared to that of
South Korea.3
The research questions are as follows: Which barriers to entry exist to new entrants in the
residential broadband access market?: How have these barriers to entry affected actual entry into
the residential wireless broadband access market?; How are entry barriers to the U.S. broadband
market different from entry barriers to the South Korea broadband market? To answer the
questions, this paper employs a qualitative case study based upon data sources such as
government documents, law reviews, statistical reports, news reports, scholarly theoretical works,
commercial reports, etc.
This paper concludes with an analysis of the barriers to entry for alternative broadband
access platforms in residential high speed Internet services, more specifically, wireless access
technologies, including economic and policy factors in the US and South Korea. It found that the
sluggish progress of intermodal and intramodal market competition explains a part of sluggish
demand in residential high speed Internet access market in the U.S., while the South Korean
market could grow rapidly due to fierce competition in the market, mostly facilitated by Korean
government’s open access rule and policy choices more favorable towards new entrants rather
than to incumbents. Furthermore, near monopoly control of the residential communications
infrastructure by cable operators and telephone companies manifests as relatively high pricing
and lower quality in the U.S. The more favorable terms from which the dominant providers have
benefited, and the government’s deregulation, may limit business opportunities for new entrants.
3 Because of page limitation, each platform would be reviewed only briefly in this paper. Also, it should be noted that this paper
is a part of a whole thesis that goes on.
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
4/39
The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents theoretical perspectives based upon
economic concepts of entry barriers. The section will shed light on how the barriers-to-entry
debate has been developing and which discrepancies exist in a variety of theoretical perspectives.
It also reviews the existing literature that has dealt with this subject regarding the competition
issue in telecommunications. A part of Section 2 considers how the telecommunications industry
is different from other product industries. With these foundations about barriers to entry, Section
3 introduces an analytical framework which can be used for evaluating the existence of entry
barriers in the telecommunications industry and discusses each step. Section 4 examines
broadband markets in the U.S. and South Korea briefly and identifies possible entry barriers
based upon the literature. The last section discusses the commonalities and differences between
the two countries, and sets out the conclusions.
2. Literature Review
2.1. Historical debates on the definition of entry barriers
Entry barriers do not have any coherent and widely-accepted definition. Indeed, there is
few economic terms which have as much controversy over their definition. A barrier to entry is
a multifaceted term which can be defined in various ways and distinguished by many different
groups: natural barriers versus artificial barriers (White, 1989), natural barriers versus strategic
barriers to entry (Woroch, 1990), structural barriers versus strategic barriers (Blees, et al., 2003;
McAfee et al., 2004), and more precisely, economic, antitrust, standalone and ancillary barriers
(McAfee et al., 2004).4 Also, it can be viewed from the perspective of the entering firm and
from the perspective of incumbent firms. Historically various viewpoints have kept their own
perspectives different from one another in light of structural features, entry impacts on market
performance and the value of incumbency. The historical explanation about the term can be
found in McAfee et al. (2004) and in Geroski, et al. (1990) in more detail (see table 1).
Table 1. Various definitions of barriers-to-entry
Scholars Emphasis Features
Bain (1956) -Anything that allows incumbent firms to
earn above-normal profits without the threat
of entry.
-Failure to articulate a consistent theory
-positive
Stigler (1968) -Differential costs between the incumbents
and new entrants
-Narrower than Bain’s definition; Far
stricter
-positive
Ferguson (1974) -The incumbents’ ability to set prices above
marginal cost and to earn monopoly return
Advertisements are not a barrier depending
on a case.
Fisher (1979) -Anything that prevents entry when entry is
socially beneficial.
-Accepting Bain’s and Ferguson’s
definition.
4 To date, barriers-to-entry has been discussed in two different, sometimes overlapping streams of literature: industrial
organization and strategic management (Blees et al., 2003). Strategic management literature takes the perspective of individual
companies and describes what they can do to enhance their performance. Although the strategic-management literature
contributes to the understanding of the rationale behind the strategic actions of companies to create barriers to entry, this paper is
more interested in the whole telecommunications industry rather than individual firm’s strategic actions. Therefore, most
literature reviewed here was derived from the industrial organization model of the structure-conduct-performance framework
even though these theoretical underpinnings have been criticized for their intrinsic defects (Carlton, 2005).
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
5/39
-Incumbents’ unnecessarily high profits
without entry
-Normative
-an initial capital requirement not a barrier
Von Weizsacker
(1980)
-Differential costs between incumbents and
entrants
-Any advantage over an entrant that an
incumbent firm enjoys if that advantage
produces a welfare loss.
-Based on Stigler’s definition
-Normative definition
-Only if its consequences are undesirable,
the advantage is a barrier to entry.
Baumol, Panzar &
Willig (1982)
-anything that reduce the sum of
consumers’ and producers’ surplus, while
phenomena such as fixed costs and scale
economies deed not do so (p.282).
-Incumbents can have costs lower because
of the superior efficiency.
-Such a cost difference is not a barrier to
entry.
Gilbert (1989) -A rent derived from incumbency -Defining entry barriers from the
perspective of incumbents
-Sunk costs: both a barrier to exit and a
barrier to entry
Carlton & Perloff
(1994)
-Both costs of entering and the time
required to enter
-Incorporates a time dimension
-Based on Stigler’s definition
Church & Ware
(1999)
-A structural characteristic of a market that
protects the market power of incumbents by
making entry unprofitable
-Distinguish between structural and
strategic barriers
-Only structural barriers are barriers to
entry
McAfee, Mialon &
Williams (2004) Distinguishing the concept of barriers to
entry into economic, antitrust, standalone,
and ancillary ones
More precise and sophisticated distinctions
Source) Adapted from MaAfee, et al. (2004), Baumol, Panzar & Willig (1982)
2.2. Bain’s structural barriers and Stigler and Chicago school’s barriers
In the economic literature, the most controversial distinction has been whether the
definition of a barrier to entry follows either Bain’s or Stigler’s. To put it simply, the concept of
barriers to entry has been defined differently based on whether it focuses on above-normal
profits of incumbents or cost difference between incumbents and new entrants. The conception
of barriers to entry in the industrial organization literature goes back to Bain (1956). He focused
on the consequences of barriers to entry, i.e. a higher price than the price hypothetically
attributed to long-run equilibrium in pure competition. Bain (1956) defined it as follows:
A barriers-to-entry is an advantage of established sellers in an industry over potential entrant
sellers, which is reflected in the extent to which established sellers can persistently raise their
prices above competitive levels without attracting new firms to enter the industry (p.3).
Based upon this definition, Bain identified important market characteristics that can have
significant effect on the condition of entry: economies of scale, capital requirements, absolute
cost advantages, and differentiation advantages (Bain, 1956). However, a slightly different
perspective in the industrial-organization literature (Chicago school) looks at the costs that must
be borne by an entrant to a market that need not be borne by an incumbent already operating in
the market (asymmetry of costs). Emphasizing differential costs between incumbents and new
entrants, this perspective was initiated by George S. Stigler. He rejected Bain’s basic contention
that scale economies and capital requirements are barriers to entry, and developed his own
definition, below.
A barriers-to-entry is a cost of producing (at some or every rate of output) which must be borne
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
6/39
by firms which seek to enter an industry but is not borne by firms already in the industry (Stigler,
1968, p.67).
This implies that the incumbents and entrants are not equally efficient after the costs of
entering are taken into account (i.e., the conditions for entering for the incumbents were less
difficult than for later entrants). A barrier to entry exists only if the potential entrant’s long-run
costs after entry are greater than those of the incumbent. The practical distinction between the
two definitions lies in the way economies of scale are treated as a barrier to entry. In Bain’s
definition, economies of scale are a barrier to entry because entry will lead to a price reduction
and the post-entry profits are likely to be lower than the incumbents’ pre-entry profits. In the
Stigler definition, scale economies do not represent a barrier to entry if they imply penalties from
sub-optimal levels of production that are the same for the incumbents and the entrant. In any
given industry, entrants and incumbents enjoy the same scale economies as they expand their
output. With equal access to technology, therefore, economies of scale are not a barrier to entry
according to Stigler (McAfee, et al., 2004). Also, advertising and capital requirements create
barriers for Bain because they seem correlated with high profit rates, but so long as these inputs
are available on equal terms to all who wish to employ them, they create no barriers for Stigler
(Demsetz, 1982, p.48).
Table 2. Bain’s and Stigler’s definitions of entry barriers
Barriers Bain’s definition Stigler’s definition
Economies of scale O X
Switching costs O O
Brand loyalty O O
Capital costs O X
Absolute cost advantages O O
Informational advantages O
Organizational advantages O X
Asset specificity O O
Patent, intellectual property O X
Regulatory barrier (license) O
Structural barriers to entry
Essential facilities O X
Intense advertising O X
Sunk costs O X
R&D costs O X
Reputation O X
Contracts to block distribution O O
Excess capacity O X
Price discrimination O X
Tying O X
Collective product proliferation O X
Lobbying to raise entrant’s cost O X
Exclusive patent cross-licensing O X
Vertical foreclosure O O
Strategic barriers to entry
Predatory behaviors O X
Source) Kim & Lee (2005) O a barrier to entry depends on the situation X not a barrier to entry
On the other hand, the Stiglerian conception of entry barriers is based on a powerful
analytic point: entry barrier analysis should distinguish desirable from undesirable entry. If
prospective entrants face precisely the same costs that incumbents faced but still find entry
unprofitable, then this market has probably already attained the appropriate number of players,
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
7/39
even though monopoly profits are being earned. In this case, the socially desirable solution to the
problem of oligopoly performance in this market is not to force entry of a further number of
entrants but rather to look for alternative measures that make collusion more difficult
(Hovenkamp, 1999, p.40).
As shown in the table 1, the various definitions of barriers to entry can be distinguished
into Bain’s (Bain, Ferguson, Fisher and Gilbert) and Stigler’s definition (Stigler, von Weizsacker,
Carlton and Perloff) (Table 2). In theoretical perspective, Stigler’s definition is more
sophisticated than Bain’s. Thus, it has been widely accepted in the dominant definition of a
barrier to entry in the economics literature. It should be noted, however, that the real application
in competition policy has adopted Bain’s definition more widely than Stigler’s. Bain’s definition
has been incorporated in the Horizontal Merger Guidelines of the Department of Justice (DOJ)
and the Federal Trade Commission (FTC). Excluding some exceptions, most of the U.S. antitrust
cases have been based upon Bain’s approach (Hovenkamp, 1999). Hovenkamp (1999) suggests
that the reason for this wider acceptance of Bain’s definition is that Bain’s approach is more
likely to be free of the value judgment of what constitutes socially desirable entry (Hovenkamp,
1999, p.40).
This paper incorporates Bain’s approach rather than Stigler’s approach because the
Bain’s approach could consider much broader industrial factors which make new entry difficult
and also allow incumbents to wield their market power by setting up prices above the
competition level. On this occasion, the Stigler’s definition would be much more strict and
narrow despite its precision. For example, economies of scale, advertising and capital
requirements cannot be barriers under Stigler’s conception; otherwise they would be barriers
under Bain’s range of barriers. Indeed, every possible market factor that can produce a profit
difference could belong to barriers to entry according to Bain (table 2).
On the other hand, McAfee, Mialon & Williams (2004) distinguished entry barriers into
four different groups to avoid the confusion caused by the various definitions above: economic,
antitrust, standalone, and ancillary barriers. These groups embrace both Bain’s and Stigler’s
approach altogether into a barriers-to-entry model. While agreeing on the difficulty of measuring
the variables, they have been successful at catching all plausible barriers for consideration as
avoiding unnecessary controversy.
According to their categorization, scale economies are ancillary barriers to entry that
reinforce other barriers to entry such as customer switching costs and brand loyalty. A
standalone barrier to entry is a cost that constitutes a barrier to entry by itself. For example,
brand loyalty, absolute cost advantage, price discrimination, tying and lobbying to raise entrants’
costs. An ancillary barrier to entry refers to a cost that reinforces other barriers to entry if they
are present, such as economies of scale, capital costs and informational advantage. For example,
scale economies can reinforce customer switching costs and brand loyalty. An economic barrier
to entry is a cost that must be incurred by a new entrant and that incumbents have not had to
incur, or a cost-time tradeoff that must be faced by a new entrant and that is less favorable to the
new entrant than it was to incumbents when they entered the market. An antitrust barrier to entry
is a cost that delays entry, and thereby reduces social welfare relative to immediate but equally
costly entry. According to the distinction of McAfee et al. (2004), structural barriers and
strategic barriers can be categorized into either economic barriers or antitrust barriers
respectively. Economic and antitrust barriers can be distinguished into either standalone or
ancillary barriers as well (table 3). Thus, these definitions are more comprehensive and precise as
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
8/39
they embrace various definitions discussed in the previous literature.
Table 3. Classification of entry barriers by McAfee et al. (2004)
Economic barriers to entry Antitrust barriers to entry
Standalone Ancillary Standalone Ancillary
Economies of scale
Switching costs
Brand loyalty
Capital costs
Absolute cost advantages
Informational advantages
Organizational advantages
Structural
barriers to
entry
Asset specificity
Intense advertising
Contracts to block
distribution
Excess capacity
Price discrimination
Leave-only marketing
Tying
Collective product
proliferation
Lobbying to raise entrant’s
cost
Strategic
barriers to
entry
Exclusive patent cross-
licensing
On the contrary, Carlton (2005) points out that Bain’s conception of entry barriers is
based on an incorrect theoretical footing of a simple structure-conduct-performance framework.
Stigler also paid no attention to dynamics or sunk costs and only focused on the long-run steady
state. Carlton suggests, therefore, that the conception of entry barriers has to incorporate a time
dimension and market dynamics in barriers to entry models such as adjustment costs, sunk costs
and uncertainty in the market. Even though these variables are hard to measure, this model
embraces more realistic dimensions. We incorporate Carlton’s insights into an evaluative
framework for assessing barriers to entry in a market, which will be addressed in the following
section.
In sum, the previous economic literature has discussed which industrial factors should be
included as barriers to entry in general terms. In particular, most of these studies have focused on
which industry has more (or higher) barriers compared to other industries (Bain, 1956;
Schmalensee, 1989; Carlton & Perloff, 2005). Important as it is in many antitrust contexts to go
beyond the Bain and Stigler definitions to take into account the dynamics of entry (as Carlton,
2005 and McAfee et al., 2004), economists unfortunately seem to have produced very little
potentially relevant theory and essentially no systematic empirical analysis of factors that slow
entry. They also fail to articulate which barriers are more important compared to other barriers
in an industry, although the importance of barriers in deterring entry of competitors into markets
varies by products and industries (Karakaya and Stahl, 1989; Yang, 1998). The effect of a
structural industry factor on entry will vary enormously across industries as well. Thus, to further
elucidate the presence of barriers to entry, the contextual factors of an industry should be
considered. In particular, the telecommunications market featuring two-way networks and
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
9/39
network externalities (Economides and White, 1994) has been described as having a
distinguished structure and its own barriers. An important feature of networks (and of services
provided over networks) is that they are typically composed of various complementary
components that are combined to create composite goods (or systems) that are substitutes for
each other. Thus, traditional approaches that dealt exclusively with substitutes or complements
fail, and new theoretical and empirical analysis are required (Economides, 1996). Furthermore,
given the importance of a time dimension and contextual factors emphasized by Carlton (2005),
a case study would be appropriate to integrate them into the evaluation of barriers to entry. Next
section outlines the unique features of telecommunications market and how these features are
relevant to broadband access.
2. 3. Barriers to entry in the telecommunications market
Explicitly identifying the presence of barriers to entry and their characteristics is very
important not only for the systematic evaluation and prediction of market competition but also
for imposing a priori obligations on the incumbents with market power and establishing a proper
competition policy.
Telecommunications networks can be characterized by high threshold levels of
investment, which causes the existence of substantial sunk costs and a high fixed to variable cost
ratio, significant economies of scale and scope, and externalities (Miller, 1995; Brock, 1981). As
related in the previous discussion, economies of scale have been one of the most important
features in the telecommunications network industry regardless of whether it is considered an
entry barrier or not. In addition, although Stigler’s definition has been well accepted among
modern economists, some economists identify the scale economies as a critical barrier (Geroski,
et al., 1990; Nahata & Olson, 1989; Gabel, 2002).
For instance, Gabel (2002) enumerates three sources of economies of scale in the local
telecommunications market and defines the economies of scale as a critical barrier to entry. First,
new entrants have to install facilities such as putting up poles, digging trenches, or laying conduit.
In this case, economies of scale exist because of the high capital and construction costs that
require at least a minimum scale, and would be an additional barrier to entry because the fixed
costs are also sunk once the facilities are built.5 Second, the back office fixed cost of setting up a
billing and operational support system will be a source of economies of scale. Third, the
economies of scale exist in customer acquisition costs because any company incurs certain
minimum expenses that are largely independent of the number of customers served such as
developing an advertising and marketing campaign for a particular geographic area.
Geroski et al. (1990) argue that if economies of scale permit established firms to limit the
market available to new entrants, then they are a source of entry barriers. For example, they
show an example when production involves substantial sunk costs. In this way, strategy and
structure may interact to create barriers and to sustain profitable operations by incumbents.
5 Sunk or irreversible costs deter entry because they increase the risk associated with entry. Incumbent firms have a strategic
advantage if the entrant must incur costs that are not part of the forward-looking opportunity costs of the incumbent. These
additional costs create a barrier to entry because the incumbent firms’ opportunity costs are lower than the entrants’ costs and
therefore, the incumbents will be able to underprice their potential rivals (Baumol, Panzar & Willig, 1982; cited in Gabel, p.3).
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
10/39
Nahata & Olson (1989) empirically introduced a situation in which scale economies can act as a
barrier to entry. Within the context of the Cournot model with scale economies, there exist a
critical number of incumbent firms such that industry cost and demand conditions require a new
firm to enter at so large a size that post-entry prices lead to economic losses. The potential
entrant would not enter the market even if incumbent firms earn supra-normal profits. The
conditions under which scale economies serve as a barrier to entry can be defined solely in terms
of demand and cost elasticities and the number of firms in the industry. Nahata and Olson’s
econometric model shows that the role of scale economies in providing supra-normal profits
generally diminishes as the number of firms in an industry increases. Thus, according to Nahata
and Olson (1989), economies of scale will usually be a significant barrier to entry only when the
critical number of firms is fairly small. Although there is no barrier in the Stigler sense of the
term, scale economies provide incumbent firms with supra-normal profits and prevent the entry
of one additional firm. The current residential broadband market in the U.S. seems to bear a
striking similarity with this situation.
In particular, telecommunications networks are distinguished by economies of scale with
sunk costs. More recently, Sidak (2006) summarizes economic characteristics of broadband
networks as follows: First, a broadband network requires substantial sunk investment. The sunk
investment must be made continuously over time. Second, a broadband network exhibits
economies of scale. The large sunk costs of building a broadband network imply that the
marginal cost of providing service to one more consumer is very low. However, marginal cost
pricing is insufficient to recover even the average variable cost of the network, much less the
average total cost, which would be necessary to recover the sunk costs of building the network.
Third, a broadband network exhibits economies of scope. In other words, there are synergistic
‘common costs’ to producing multiple products over the same network. Fourth, differential
pricing can increase economic welfare because it enables a firm to lower the price to consumers
who would otherwise be priced out of the market if the firm were constrained to charge a higher
uniform price.
A research report about barriers to entry for Small and Medium-sized Enterprise (SMEs)
(Blees, et al., 2003) analyzed relevant literature and found that incumbents are the most powerful
party when the height of entry barriers is concerned. This report argues that incumbents can
control most influential barriers in various ways. While incumbents may raise barriers by
blocking distribution channels, by increasing advertising and selling expenditures, by increasing
their span of control over resources, by increasing switching cost, by aggressive or limit-pricing,
by increasing excess capacity, etc., entrants may lower only one barrier, namely the brand-name
barrier by aggressive marketing and advertising. However, government can influence
significantly the height of certain barriers: by setting rules and regulations concerning the access
to existing distribution channels, by limiting or expanding the access to essential facilities such
as infrastructure and networks, and by prohibiting seller concentration (pp.138-139).
As indicated in the literature, either DSL lines or cable networks are representative
telecommunications networks with substantial sunk costs, economies of scale and scope. Thus,
in broadband access market, if a new entrant is going to enter into the nationwide market,
barriers to entry would be very high to entrants that could not realize economies of scale. But
barriers to entry would be rather lower to entrants with economies of scale compared to entrants
without scale economies. Even though new access technologies, like wireless, satellite and
power-line, are able to overcome some kinds of barriers inherent in the residential broadband
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
11/39
access market, they still need to prevail over scale economies to be profitable enough to survive
in the market.
2.3.1. Determinants of market entry in local telecommunications markets
Previous literature in telecommunications has mostly discussed the determinants of
market entry into local telecommunications market and there is little literature that only deals
with barriers issue in the telecommunications industry. The previous studies of entry
determinants, thus, will shed light on understanding which market factors will behave as entry
barriers and which factors are more important than others. Understanding what industrial factors
have intervened (or encouraged) a new entry will help comprehend the barriers in the residential
broadband access market.
First of all, as Ford et al. (2005) indicate, two critical factors drive the entry decision:
post-entry profitability and entry costs. Firms will enter a market only if it is profitable to do so.
The authors identify that market size, the intensity of price competition, the level of product
differentiation and the existence of rival networks will determine the post-entry profit of a new
entrant. The factors that influence the post-entry profit, therefore, determine new entry. Other
econometric models and empirical evidence also support this view: first, market size is related to
new entry of Competitive Local Exchange Carriers (CLECs) (Beard, Ford & Koutsky, 2005;
Alexander & Feinberg, 2004; Greenstein & Mazzeo, 2003; Zolnierek, Eisner & Burton, 2001).
Beard et al. (2005) examined the entry pattern of CLECs in the US local exchange markets and
found that a larger market is likely to cause an additional CLEC’s entry. Greenstein and Mazzeo
(2003) also examined the entry strategies of CLECs and found that market size is positively
correlated with the entry of CLECs. Alexander and Feinberg (2004) discovered that an increase
in population increases the likelihood of new entry in their study about the determinants of entry
in local exchange markets. Zolnierek et al. (2001) also support the outcome that a new local
exchange competitor is more likely to enter into highly populated urban areas. Since size is
associated with the local demand potential, a higher local demand potential with high income
and high population density tends to an increase of CLEC’s entry (Clarke, Hassett, Ivanova &
Kotlikoff, 2004; Rosston & Wimmer, 2001). Clarke et al. (2004) revealed that there was
additional CLEC’s entry in both high income and high density markets. Rosston and Wimmer
(2001) also found that CLECs are more likely to enter into high income and densely populated
markets. This positive relationship between market size and new entry can be applied to the
broadband market as well, indicating that the new entrance in the residential broadband market
must start from the urban areas with large populations and spread out gradually, unless providers
are reluctant to enter rural and remote areas.
Second, entry costs are negatively associated with new entry into the U.S. local exchange
markets, suggesting that a decrease in entry costs leads to a higher probability of entry (Ford, et
al., 2005; Xiao and Orazem, 2005; Rosston & Wimmer, 2001). Ford, et al. (2005) identify four
different types of entry costs, which would determine the number of new entrant: technological
entry costs, strategic entry costs, regulatory entry costs and presence of spillover. Technological
entry costs include any expenditure to build up networks, including sunk cost. Strategic entry
costs can arise due to the incumbents’ deterring strategies such as excessive advertising. In
particular, in the convergent telecommunications market, Ford et. al. (2005) emphasizes spillover
effects which are reductions in entry costs arising from the ability of a firm to use its existing
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
12/39
assets to provide service in a related market. Historically entrants owning their existing assets are
likely to enter the other market. This indicates that without spillover effects, entry would not
have occurred. Also, only those firms with assets can afford to enter (Ford, et al., 2005, p.34).
This further indicates that higher costs will deter additional entries and new entrants de novo are
likely to enter the market in smaller scale than the existing companies.
Xiao and Orazem (2005) recently examined market structure and competitive conduct in
local markets for high speed Internet service from 1999 to 2003. They found unreasonable
variation in firms’ competitive conduct over time. Once the market has one to three firms, the
next entrant has little effect on competitive conduct. Also, they found that entry costs for early
entrants are smaller than for later entrants, implying the existence of early mover advantages in
this market. Thus, they conclude that sunk costs are a main determinant of entry thresholds so
that ignoring sunk costs leads to biased measures of entry thresholds and misleading inferences
about firms’ competitive conduct. These findings indicate that there will not be much difference
in the existing companies’ competitive conduct with the third competitor, and new entrants
should decide their entrance based more upon strategic barriers established by the first mover’s
advantage such as a highly recognized brand name and sunk cost.
Third, regulation and competition policy will greatly influence a decision of new entry
(Alexander & Feinberg, 2004; Brown & Zimmerman, 2004; Rosston & Wimmer, 2001; Abel &
Clements, 2001). Alexander and Feinberg (2004) observed that the probability of the entry of
CLECs is higher in the markets where the ILEC is regulated by the traditional regulatory method,
such as rate-of-return regulation. Although the Telecommunications Act of 1996 induced entry,
the competitive effect was limited by strategic non-price behavior of incumbents in local
telecommunications markets. Thus, they argue that, to the extent that regulatory policies can
prevent the exercise of the strategic entry-deterring activity, regulators can play an important role
in determining how much entry does occur. Brown and Zimmerman (2004) also examined the
effect of the FCC’s section 271 decision on new entry into the local exchange market and found
that the decision had increased new entry into local exchange markets before and while the
approval was granted. Rosston and Wimmer (2001) examined the effect of the federal subsidy
policy on competition in local exchange markets and found that the presence of federal high-cost
support increases the probability of new entry.
As indicated in the literature above, regulatory policies more favorable towards new
entrants to eliminate entry barriers such as open access rules (e.g., unbundling and resale
entrance) and subsidy assistance (e.g., universal service support) increased entrance into the local
telecommunications market. Since CLECs tend to provide DSL services altogether with a local
telephone service, a higher number of CLECs indicates a higher number of broadband
competitors in the residential market. Thus, higher barriers to entry for CLECs imply higher
barriers to entry to Internet access service providers that may enter the market by either resale or
unbundling. However, it is suggested that the FCC’s “systematic elimination of pro-competitive
regulation” has led to the declining market share of CLECs in the wired broadband access
service (Marcus, 2006, p.31). As a percentage of all ADSL lines, CLEC ADSL lines steadily
declined to 4.3% in 2004 from 5.4% in 2003.
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
13/39
2.3.2. Incumbents’ strategies for deterring new entry
Several studies have also examined the pre- and post-entry strategies of an incumbent in
the US local exchange markets. Pre-entry deterrence of an incumbent in a market can be found in
Nix and Gabel (1993), and Rosenberg and Clements (2000). For example, Rosenberg and
Clements (2000) found that an ILEC deters entry by reducing or eliminating the potential
competitor’s profit opportunities by imposing high costs. Nix and Gabel (1993) also suggested
that, historically, a telephone carrier (e.g., AT&T) did not adopt a price strategy to deter new
entry when the company had an increasing threat of competition, but instead, leveraged patent
litigation to deter new entry.
Other studies have examined the relationship between new entry and an incumbent’s
post-entry reaction in a market (Kaserman, Mayo, Blank & Kahai, 1999; Koski & Majumdar,
2002; Loomis & Swann, 2005; Woroch, 2000). Kaserman et al. (1999) examined the effect of
the entry of facilities-based inter-exchange carriers (IXCs) on the pricing of Regional Bell
Operating Companies (RBOCs)’ local residential telephone services and found that entry was not
significantly influence the local residential rates of RBOCs. Loomis and Swann (2005) examined
the effect of the emergence of CLECs on ILECs in U.S. local exchange markets using a Cournot
response function and found that the expansion of a CLEC has a greater competitive impact on
ILECs, while the expansion of an ILEC has a relatively smaller impact on CLECs. Woroch
(2000) examined the effect of new entry on the digital infrastructure investment in the U.S. local
exchange markets and found that the entry of CLECs leads to subsequent investment of an ILEC,
and the investment of the ILEC leads to additional entry of CLECs. Also, after entry occurred,
ILECs were more likely to respond with aggressive advertising and withdrawal of diversification
rather than an aggressive pricing (Koski & Majumdar, 2002).
As suggested in the previous literature, it seems evident that the incumbents in the local
telecommunications network market have had great competitive pressure on their
telecommunications services but they are more likely to respond to it by employing intense
advertising or other leverage for the purpose of erecting barriers rather than to compete on price
directly.
3. Analytical Framework: Evaluation of the presence of barriers to entry
The evaluation of barriers to entry in telecommunications has been used to either evaluate
the market power of the incumbents or limit requested mergers in light of their impact on market
competition. The Office of Fair Trading in the U.K. earlier published a report suggesting the best
practices to assess barriers to entry in a market and proposing methods of measuring entry
barriers (OFT,1994).
Adjusting the OFT’s “seven step procedure for assessing entry conditions” to the
telecommunications market, Kim and Lee (2005) suggested eight evaluation steps of barriers to
entry and conducted a case study about South Korea’s retail broadband access market. The eight
evaluation steps are: (1) the establishment of market boundary and production substitutability; (2)
market conditions and the record of entry and exit; (3) absolute cost advantages of the
incumbents; (4) sunk cost, economies of scale and capital requirements; (5) product
differentiation, advertising, switching cost, and network externalities; (6) vertical foreclosure and
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
14/39
exclusion; (7) predatory behavior; (8) entry impediments such as certification requirements and
required time to build up brand name.6 Each step will be examined with essential questions as
following:
Step 1. Market definition and entry by production substituters
First, it should be determined whether one or more firms in a market face competition
from 1) existing rivals and 2) from potential new entrants. So-called “production substituters” are
included in the definition of relevant market and the focus here is entirely on demand
substitutability. The following questions need to be answered: Are there potential suppliers or
production substituters that could switch easily and quickly to the supply of the relevant market?
Are there neighboring industries or markets which use a similar production technology? Are
there producers which use similar distribution channels and distribution networks that could start
production or acquire the relevant market? Are there firms which produce the relevant product in
other geographical markets? Has there been import substitution in the past in response to
changes in domestic or external market conditions?7 More questions follow: Has there been
product substitution in the past in response to a price increase in the relevant market? Is there
idle capacity in the industry? Are there large buyers who could easily supply themselves? Are
there vertically integrated firms who could easily increase their production to serve the open
market? If one or more of these questions yields a positive answer, then this may be prima facie
evidence of an absence of serious entry problems.
Step 2. Market conditions and historical entry
Factual information about the recent performance of firms in the relevant market is a
useful guide in the assessment of entry conditions. What has been the recent history of entry and
exit in the relevant market? What has been the recent trend of profitability of the industry? How
effective has entry been in constraining the exercise of market power? Have market conditions
changed recently? If recent market history exhibits substantial entry via investment in new
capacity on a large scale, then there is a priori little reason to suspect that significant barriers to
entry exist. However if successful entry has been exclusively large-scale, then the existence of
scale economies may be suggested. If entry has been small-scale, short-lived or merely by
acquisition, more investigation will be required. Empirically most entry is of this type, so it is not
enough simply to observe or count recent entry episodes. Rather some measure of scale and
significance of entry must be used. The profitability of firms and time required for a new entry,
and changes of market competitiveness such as a change in the number of active firms should be
questioned.
Step 3. Assessment of absolute (cost) advantages
Absolute cost advantages can be defined as costs which must be born by the entrant but
which are not born by incumbents. They correspond to the cost asymmetries between firms
6 The following 8 steps are mostly derived from the Office of Fair Trading (1994)’s enumerated discussion about barriers to entry.
7 However, this question is not applicable in the telecommunications market because the ownership from outside of the domestic
boundary would be strictly controlled by the government.
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
15/39
which would normally be captured under the Stiglerian definition of barriers to entry. Examples
include exclusive or superior access by an incumbent firm to particular necessary inputs such as
patents, copyright, exclusive contracts with input suppliers, ownership of a network, etc. Most
legal and regulatory barriers to entry come under this heading. Cost asymmetries due to superior
efficiency of incumbents, however, should not be included.
Step 4. Sunk cost, economies of scale and capital requirements
The interaction of sunk costs with economies of scale to create barriers occurs in the
telecommunications market (Gabel, 2002; Sidak, 2006). If entry requires that some costs be sunk
then what matters to entrants is the expected price post-entry. This will be determined by a
number of factors, but perhaps the most important is the nature or intensity of expected post-
entry competition in the market. Hence an important, if subtle and difficult, question which must
be addressed in any serious analysis of barriers to entry is: What is the nature and what are the
instruments of market competition? How has the market reacted to entry in the past? Price wars,
accommodation, collusion, etc.? How has the market responded to exit in the past? Price
increases, output reductions, reestablishment of stable or collusive pricing strategies etc.? How
sunk are costs? Short-term, long-term? What is the proportion of sunk costs to total costs?
Step 5. Product differentiation, advertising, switching costs and network
externalities
Product differentiation is common in any industry because it could be used strategically
to have an advantage over competitors and to weaken price competition (Ford, et al., 2005).
When products are homogeneous, the competition would be likely to arise on price. So, to avoid
fierce price competition, firms tend to pursue product differentiation. In industries where
products are differentiated, however, advertising, brand proliferation and goodwill have been
identified as possible important sources of (strategic) barriers to entry in some circumstances. If
sunk costs are required to advertise or establish a market presence, etc. then entry is in general
more risky, and incumbents may be in a position to exploit first mover advantages. The rapid
development of technologies has made it possible to produce a variety of services in the
telecommunications industry and this makes product differentiation and advertising more critical
strategic barriers to entry. This indicates that, despite the differences of access technologies, the
broadband access service refers a homogeneous and price-sensitive high speed Internet.
Ford, et al. (2005) also suggests that product differentiation between intra-modal
competitors would be less than between intermodal competitors by illustrating a study about
competition between cable TV and DBS. The study reveals that the competitive effect of the
intramodal competitors is three times greater than that of the intermodal competitors.8
Some critical questions can be addressed as follows: Are products highly differentiated?
Associated with brand names? How important is R&D in the industry? Is product development
important? How important is advertising? What is the ratio of advertising expenditure to sales
8 DBS providers reduced cable prices by about 5%, whereas the terrestrial video rival reduces price by about 16% (GAO, 2005).
US Government Accountability Office (GAO) (2005). Direct broadcast satellite subscribership has grown rapidly, but varies
across different types of markets. Report to the Subcommittee on Antitrust, Competition Policy and Consumer Rights. Committee
on the Judiciary, U.S. Senate.GAO-05-257. (cited in Ford, et al., 2005, p.24)
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
16/39
revenue? Do consumers face switching costs, i.e. are they locked in to a specific supplier, or is it
more costly for them to purchase from alternative suppliers for reasons unrelated to price and
production costs? How large are switching costs? And what strategies are available to firms to
create consumer loyalty, i.e. exclusive contracts, loyalty rebates and discounts, price-matching
strategies, etc.?
Step 6. Vertical foreclosure and exclusion
A long list of practices can be identified as vertical restraints such as vertical integration
and vertical mergers, exclusive dealing and contracting, exclusive territories and franchising,
exclusive/long term contracts with customers, refusal to supply, and product tying and bundling.
This list is not all-inclusive but is suggestive of the range of practices which have been
considered to raise antitrust concerns by creating entry barriers. The difficulty posed for
competition authorities by these analyses is to identify when these types of conduct and other
vertical restraints, are likely to have serious anticompetitive effects. Gabel (2002) detects that
without vertically integrated structure, new entrants based on structural separation are likely to
fail because they would increase rather than reduce uncertainty.
In particular, the telecommunications industry has shown a strong trend of vertical
integration by networks. To communicate in the telecommunication network, the sender and the
receiver has to be connected through the physical networks with the premises. In most countries,
a monopolist which owned both the last mile9 and interconnected networks had been providing
the end-to-end service. Plausible questions are as follows: What is the nature of incumbent
relations with input suppliers or distributors/retailers/buyers? Are there exclusionary contracts?
Tying arrangement? Territorial exclusion? Long-term contracts? Loyalty rebates? Most-favored
clauses? Are there scarce inputs needed for the production of the relevant product(s) which are
controlled by incumbent firms? What is the market structure of essential input markets, and are
incumbents able to exert market power in these markets, either individually or jointly? Must
potential entrants be vertically integrated? Does the vertical restraint raise an entrant’s costs
significantly? Has the interconnection among network providers been mandated?
Step 7. Predatory behavior
Predatory behaviors such as predatory pricing can be a part of strategic barriers that
incumbents wield to deter the entry of new entrants. In particular, predatory pricing refers to a
strategy to set the price below the reasonable cost either to squeeze rival firms out of the market
or to deter the entry of potential competitors. If it were successful, the incumbent would be able
to dominate the market and enjoy monopolistic pricing. Distinguishing predatory from normal
competitive behavior is a subtle task and need not be attempted if the preconditions for rational
predatory behavior are not satisfied. In particular, for predation to be rational a firm must be able
to exercise significant market power post-exit (or merger) in order to recoup the losses (in
foregone profits) incurred by the predatory behavior. Thus the first step is an analysis of market
structure with a view to determining when predatory behavior could be a rational strategy.
Relevant questions would include: What is the market share of the (alleged) predatory firm?
9 The wireline bottleneck facilities linking the public telecommunication networks with virtually every home and business
premises nationwide.
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
17/39
What are the sizes of other firms in the industry? Are there any other important barriers to entry?
Can the predator target price cuts where its rival is most vulnerable, and minimize its own
foregone profits? If the preconditions for successful predation are not met, then the inquiry in
most cases needs go no further.
Step 8. Assessment of entry impediments
Entry impediments are any factors which delay the process of entry into a market without
increasing the (sunk) costs of entry, or creating an asymmetry between incumbents and entrants.
They are not entry barriers that afford persistent incumbent supra-normal profits, but they may
be important to antitrust decisions to allow a merger for example, because they influence the
amount of time that incumbents may exercise market power before entry occurs. Good examples
of entry impediments are licensing, certification or product registration requirements which
involve little or no actual costs, but take significant amounts of time to satisfy. Other examples
include the time required to obtain contracts (i.e. where the market’s products are sold via long
term contracts), set up production facilities, or gain a market share large enough to significantly
influence the behavior of incumbents. However it should be noted that the distinction between
entry barriers and entry impediments is not always sharp.
Figure 1. Evaluative steps to determine entry conditions
Defining market
Market conditions
Historical entry
Absolute cost
advantages
Sunk costs,
economies of scale,
capital requirements
Product differentiation
Advertising
Switching costs
Network externalities
Predatory behaviors
Entry impediments
Vertical foreclosure
Vertical exclusion
1
4
3
2
5
6
7
8
The presence of relevant markets and
production substituters
-Exclusive dealing and contracting
-Exclusive territories and franchising,
-Exclusive/long term contracts w/ customers
-Refusal to supply
-Product tying and bundling
-Substantial sunk costs
-The intensity of expected post-entry
competition
-Cost asymmetries b/w incumbents and new
entrants
-Most legal and regulatory barriers
-The profitability of firms
-Time required for a new entry
-Change of market competitiveness
-Predatory pricing
-the market share of the (alleged) predatory
firm
-Time required to obtain contracts, set up
production facilities, or gain a market share -
licensing, certification or product registration
requirements
Defining market
Market conditions
Historical entry
Absolute cost
advantages
Sunk costs,
economies of scale,
capital requirements
Product differentiation
Advertising
Switching costs
Network externalities
Predatory behaviors
Entry impediments
Vertical foreclosure
Vertical exclusion
1
4
3
2
5
6
7
8
The presence of relevant markets and
production substituters
-Exclusive dealing and contracting
-Exclusive territories and franchising,
-Exclusive/long term contracts w/ customers
-Refusal to supply
-Product tying and bundling
-Substantial sunk costs
-The intensity of expected post-entry
competition
-Cost asymmetries b/w incumbents and new
entrants
-Most legal and regulatory barriers
-The profitability of firms
-Time required for a new entry
-Change of market competitiveness
-Predatory pricing
-the market share of the (alleged) predatory
firm
-Time required to obtain contracts, set up
production facilities, or gain a market share -
licensing, certification or product registration
requirements
The presence of relevant markets and
production substituters
-Exclusive dealing and contracting
-Exclusive territories and franchising,
-Exclusive/long term contracts w/ customers
-Refusal to supply
-Product tying and bundling
-Substantial sunk costs
-The intensity of expected post-entry
competition
-Cost asymmetries b/w incumbents and new
entrants
-Most legal and regulatory barriers
-The profitability of firms
-Time required for a new entry
-Change of market competitiveness
-Predatory pricing
-the market share of the (alleged) predatory
firm
-Time required to obtain contracts, set up
production facilities, or gain a market share -
licensing, certification or product registration
requirements
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
18/39
4. Analysis: The Broadband Market and Barriers to Entry
Step 1. Market definition and production substituters
In the U.S., broadband is defined as a service or facility with an upstream (customer-to-
provider) and downstream (provider-to-customer) transmission speed of more than 200 kilobits
per second (kbps). The FCC has used the term “high-speed” to describe services and facilities
with over 200 kbps capability in at least one direction.10 Even though the definition has often
been criticized as not being able to incorporate real advanced features of current broadband
technologies, the FCC has not responded to this voice yet (Turner, 2005). Thus, the broadband
market will be defined as a high-speed Internet service market with a rather moderate speed.
Under the definition, every kind of access service currently available must be included in the
range of the broadband service even though the speed is often not enough for VOIP and video
that require much faster bandwidth.11 Although only a few technologies, i.e., cable modem and
xDSL have dominated the U.S. residential broadband market until now, the FCC has encouraged
broadband deployment across multiple platforms based on different technologies. In particular,
WiMax and fiber optic access technologies are the most promising of all in the near future.
In South Korea, the relevant market for the residential broadband service refers a market
for Internet access service of which the download speed is more than 1 Mbps (MIC, 2002). This
includes DSL, cable modem, B-WLL,12 Ethernet LAN, satellite Internet and so on. A geographic
market for residential broadband in South Korea was defined as the whole nation because pricing
and service quality of different platforms are very similar across districts. Although the majority
of the area of both countries is covered by cable modem or ADSL, there exists a set of new
entrants or prospective entrants such as wireless broadband providers and BPL providers in the
residential broadband access market.
Step 2. Market conditions and historical entry
The U.S.
In the U.S., the residential broadband market has been dominated by cable and incumbent
telephone companies. While new entrants, based upon wireless, satellite and BPL technologies,
have been gradually increasing, aggressive marketing of telephone companies and the rather
stable dominance of cable companies have left them behind in terms of market share. While the
market share of coaxial cable access from 1999 to 2004 slightly increased from 51.3% to 56.4%,
ADSL share increased from 13.4% to 36.5% during the same period of time. Instead, other
wireline technologies including symmetric DSL and fiber, wireless and powerline have been
rapidly decreasing (from 22.1% to 3.9% and from 11.3% to 1.8%, respectively). Incumbent local
exchange carriers (ILECs) still represented about 96% of facilities-based ADSL high-speed lines
10 The FCC. (2002). Inquiry concerning the deployment of advanced telecommunications capability to all Americans in a
reasonable and timely fashion and possible steps to accelerate such deployment pursuant to Section 706 of the
Telecommunications Act of 1996. CC Docket No. 98-146 (February 6, 2002). Retrieved from
http://www.fcc.gov/Bureaus/Common_Carrier/Reports/fcc99005.txt (Figliola, 2006).
11 A telecom research company reports that 42.8 million people subscribed for either cable or DSL broadband at the end of 2005,
up 9.6 million from a year before. Also, it recognizes the new explosion of consumer-generated content such as MySpace pages
and YouTube videos, and the demand for more bandwidth (Fox, 2006, March 22).
12 Broadband Wireless Local Loop.
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
19/39
in service as of Dec. 31, 2004. When all technologies are considered, ILECs still provide about
38% of high-speed connections to end users (FCC, July 2005).13
The incumbent telephone companies (ILECs) have started aggressive pricing and
differentiated broadband service as one with different connection speeds. Cable companies have
reduced prices in specific markets for existing video customers but mostly have kept their normal
broadband pricing (Rosenbluth, 2006, August 24). While, in the first quarter of 2006, the
average price for broadband service was $39.45 a month from the five top cable operators, the
top four telephone companies’ pricing was $35.38. Telecom DSL pricing has declined, on
average, 7% from approximately $38 in the first quarter of 2006 (A report from Kagan Research
LLC, cited in Rosenbluth, 2006).
According to a recent report of the FCC, the number of high-speed Internet service
providers significantly increased from 105 providers in Dec., 1999 to 552 providers in Dec.,
2004 (table 4). If providers with less than 250 lines are included, the number of providers
amounts to 1269 in June, 2005. ADSL providers have led the major growth by recording more
than eleven times increase in numbers since 1999. Since the FCC data in June 2005 started to
include small companies with less than 250 lines, this indicates that small providers are still
dependent on DSL lines or cable lines rather than other access technologies. Interestingly, while
the number of ADSL and cable modem providers has consistently increased, that of all other
technologies has been rapidly decreasing since Dec. 2004. Furthermore, since this data did not
separate residential and business services, it is hard to estimate the number of entrants in the
residential broadband access service market with only the FCC data.
Table 4. Providers of high-speed lines by technology, the U.S. (Dec. 1999-June 2005)
ADSL Growth Cable Modem Growth All other Growth Total Growth Total
Dec 1999 28 43 65 105
June 2000 47 68% 36 -16% 75 15% 116 10%
Dec 2000 68 45% 39 8% 87 16% 136 17%
June 2001 86 26% 47 21% 98 13% 160 18%
Dec 2001 117 36% 59 26% 122 24% 203 27%
June 2002 142 21% 68 15% 138 13% 237 17%
Dec 2002 178 25% 87 28% 169 22% 299 26%
June 2003 235 32% 98 13% 217 28% 378 26%
Dec 2003 274 17% 110 12% 246 13% 432 14%
June 2004 298 9% 129 17% 281 14% 485 12%
Dec 2004 352 18% 147 14% 312 11% 552 14%
June 2005 759 116% 227 54% 205 -34% 1269 130%
Growth Rates (Dec.1999-Dec.2004) 1157% 242% 380% 426%
13 More recent market reports estimate that as of March 2006, AT&T Inc. (through its SBC segment) had the greatest number of
DSL subscribers among the telecom carriers, with 7.8 million total, which is up 30% from a year earlier. Verizon had about 6.1
million DSL and other higher-speed broadband customers, up 48% from a year earlier, and independent ILEC CenturyTel’s
broadband line count climbed 61% to nearly 313,000. However, despite telephone companies’ recent progress, cable companies
have taken the larger share of the high-speed Internet connection market. As of the first quarter of 2006, cable television firms
(such as Comcast Corp. and Cox Communications Inc.) accounted for 56% of traditional broadband connections, while DSL
comprised the remaining 44%. In 2006, telecom carriers such as Verizon and AT&T also were adding wireless broadband
customers, but these are not part of this counting (Rosenbluth, 2006, August 24).
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
20/39
Source) FCC (2006) * All other includes Symmetrical DSL (SDSL), traditional wireline, fiber, satellite, fixed and mobile wireless, and power
line. **For data through Dec. 2004, only those providers with at least 250 lines per state were required to file. Thus, it seems reasonable to look at
the growth rate from Dec. 1999 to Dec. 2004.
Here we examine recent movements of alternative technologies such as wireless, satellite
and BPL in the broadband access market.
Wireless residential broadband
According to an industrial report (Gibbons & Ruth, 2006), there are low barriers to entry
in the Wi-Fi access market. Relative ease of obtaining equipment, an unlicensed and free Wi-Fi
spectrum, and relative availability of technical know-how have combined to act positively
towards municipalities’ deployment plans. Also, a few of smaller ISPs and big ISPs14 have
rapidly started or experimented with wireless broadband services based on WiMax technology,
which is more advanced than Wi-Fi (FCC, 2005, September 30).15 For example, Clearwire,
TowerStream and Nextel have started trial wireless broadband services since 2004. Both wireline
and wireless carriers are trying to incorporate WiMax in their networks because this enables
them to get out of paying huge access costs, or to lower operating costs. The problem is that this
development has been driven by large carriers for business customers while smaller WISPs tend
to serve residential and small business users (Selwyn, et al., 2005). Although broadband wireless
still has a very small market penetration, the wireless broadband connection has been growing
faster than other broadband access options.16
Meanwhile, many municipalities have entered or plan to enter the residential broadband
access market adopting Wi-Fi technology or all-fiber networks (Balhoff & Rowe, 2005;
APPANET, 2004). Historically, some municipalities have already entered communications
markets by providing high-speed Internet and video services to their territories through public
utilities or contracts with private companies (APPANET, 2004). More recently, several big cities
and municipalities announced plans to deploy mesh networks using Wi-Fi technology17 (Harrell,
2006, Jan. 27; Woolley, 2005, July 4). Mesh networks use lots of small, cheap transmitters that
are easily mounted on a streetlight or telephone pole. Each transmitter can only send signals
short distances, often just a few hundred feet, but a mesh of them can cooperate to relay a signal
far across town, handing it from point to point like a baton in a relay race. Minneapolis,
Philadelphia and Tempe have committed to setting up wireless networks and Boston and San
Francisco are also exploring the idea. Madison, Wisconsin just signed a deal with AOL to build
and run a mesh network (Woolley, 2005, July 4). The recent municipalities’ efforts to deploy
their own networks have been controversial but seem inevitable in that municipalities’ initiatives
attract incumbents rather than pits itself against them (Gibbons & Ruth, 2006). A new study
released by CFA, CU, and other public-interest groups shows that community Internet providers,
14 Independent Internet service providers (ISPs) could subscribe to local telephone service lines through which their customers
transmit computer-generated information to them. The ISP transforms data transmitted in telephone signal format into data
packets and routes the traffic over its own packet-switched network to the intended destination, often via transmission over
backbone long-distance networks to another ISP network. (Zelinski, 2004).
15 WiMax is the complementary technology to Wi-Fi. It has a service range of up to 50 km and provides data rates of up to 280
Mbps per base station. WiMax can be used for Internet calling, video, and chatting (Leon & Wang, 2005, Nov. 3).
16 While satellite and terrestrial wireless technologies only occupied less than 0.15% of total lines of high speed Internet, the
growth rate of satellite and wireless in 2004 was 30% compared to 9% of power line (FCC, 2005).
17 Wireless Fidelity (Wi-Fi) is an extension of wireless local area networks (WLANs) and makes use of low-power transmitters in
unlicensed frequency bands. Although the coverage area for WLANs is limited to small areas (about 100 m), rapidly improving
cost-performance makes it a viable option for public services in locations such as hotspots (i.e., restaurants, coffee shops, hotels,
airports, convention centers, etc.), rural communities, and dense urban areas.
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
21/39
or even the threat of municipal entry, could provide the competition necessary to keep rates low
and quality of service high.18
Moreover, small ISPs have recently been threatened by the challenges ahead, especially
as the number of dial-up subscribers has been dropping, following financial pressures, and as the
regulatory movements against them have been shored up (van Gorp, Maitland, & Hanekop,
2006). Smaller broadband providers usually do not prefer being a facilities-based provider
because of the necessity of a huge amount of capital in facility investment. The FCC’s recent
abolition of its line sharing rule may make it harder for smaller ISPs to compete in broadband
Internet service. Thus, unless WISPs can find ways to substantially differentiate their services,
there is no way for them to grow as a national competitor. Furthermore, the potential of advanced
wireless technologies has been adopted by the incumbent telephone companies as a strategic tool
for boosting their voice services. Even though municipalities have tried to add in wireless
broadband into their communities, most of them still rely on the incumbent networks and private
ISPs. When smaller WISPs do not have their own facilities, a non-line sharing rule will make
them depend on their competitors’ will to allow them to access to the last mile networks and
facilities. Or they may eagerly seek for a chance to circumvent the bottleneck.
In South Korea, wireless broadband usually refers to the Internet access on cellular
phones rather than the residential fixed wireless service. Residential wireless broadband services,
using either B-WLL or wireless LAN technologies, have gained a very small portion of market
share. Usually, incumbents provide wireless broadband Internet access to medium and low
density housing complexes using B-WLL technology and in high traffic areas (such as hotels and
commercial centers) using wireless local area network (WLAN) technology. In the residential
broadband market, however, the wireless technologies have been generally complementary to the
existing HFC or xDSL broadband services. An actual vision for the future wireless Internet
service is WiBro, a kind of mobile WiMax service. WiBro (wireless broadband service) has
drawn great attention because it can provide a certain level of space and portability to the high-
speed Internet and wireless LAN. WiBro enables the user to access the Internet using portable
wireless devices, and to use various forms of information and contents at a high speed. WiBro is
expected to have a significant effect on society and culture as long as it overcomes the
shortcomings of wireless LAN and mobile communication, and provides both the high speed
data service of the wireless LAN and the portability of the mobile communication service. In Jan.
2005, the MIC of South Korea has selected three service providers: KT, SK Telecom and Hanaro
Telecom (NCA, 2005).
Satellite
Broadband satellite is a capital-intensive business. As its subscriber base grows,
additional satellites should be launched. Robust margins are required to repay that capital
investment. The business of satellite broadband is similar to EchoStar’s DISH business. With 10
million customers, the company’s profitability is based on how aggressively they are in the
18 Feld, H., Rose, G., Cooper, M., & Scott, B. (2005). Connecting the public: the truth about municipal broadband. Retrieved
Feb. 23, 2006, from
http://www.freepress.net/docs/mb_white_paper.pdf#search=%22Connecting%20the%20Public%3A%20The%20Truth%20About
%20Municipal%20Broadband%22
For example, community Internet providers are charging lower prices than Bell DSL service providers are charging: $16 in
Chaksa, Minnesota, $20 in Rio Rancho, New Mexico, Moorhead, Minnesota and Lompoc, California, and an estimated $15 in
Philadelphia (Cited in Cooper, et al., 2005).
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
22/39
subscriber acquisition game. Satellite broadband will be similar to satellite TV but more
profitable than that because broadband service does not require costs for contents. (Satellite
News, 2004, Sep. 13). Recently, WildBlue, in a strategic relationship with Liberty Media,
entered the high-speed Internet access market via satellite to homes and small businesses in June,
2005 focusing on rural or remote communities not currently served, or underserved by other high
speed providers. The residential broadband service using satellite has been limited in its speed,
up to 1 Mbps, and its uplink transmission, which should be made over telephone lines or mobile
telephone networks. Thus, this service seems restricted to remote areas which find it difficult to
receive fixed-line broadband Internet services like xDSL and cable modems.
BPL
A recent Congressional report (Figliola, 2006) enunciates the advantages and
disadvantages of BPL. First, BPL is less expensive to deploy than the cable and telephone
companies’ broadband offerings. Second, it does not require upgrades to the actual electric grid,
and third, it is not limited by certain technical constraints of its competitors. Also, thanks to the
ubiquity of the electrical grid, BPL has been expected to be able to fill the gap in the broadband
access market, in particular, rural areas in which there is relative lack of service (David, et al.,
2005). In fact, companies in the U.S. and other countries have pilot tested BPL and many are
now deploying it commercially (Figliola, 2006).
However, critics have expressed ongoing concern that BPL could interfere with licensed
radio spectrum such as amateur radio, government, and emergency response frequencies. In
addition to the frequency interference issue, legal and regulatory uncertainty has delayed the
entrance of BPL providers in the residential market. Although the FCC is not licensing BPL
services, BPL services are still regulated in the same sense that any business is regulated and
many other laws regarding contracting or doing business electronically. Also, state governments
have regulated on various aspects of electric utilities such as rights of way and access to multi-
tenant facilities (David, et al., 2005).
Zelinski (2004) points out that BPL has had to have some problems resolved to deploy
smoothly such as 1) harmful radio interference; 2) access issue; and 3) cross-subsidies issue.
Interestingly, Zelinski (2004) argues that BPL providers should be allowed to build up new
platforms with proprietary protocols and designs different from those employed by cable and
telephone companies. To encourage economic entry by BPL providers, “regulators should
support flexible, creative designs (of BPL), and should not mandate standardization” (Zelinski,
2004) (e.g., TCP-IP protocol use). Also, government should allow vertical integration by
broadband transport operators into applications and content to make the platform of a profit-
maximizing broadband transport operator more valuable.
Since electric utilities provide a regulated monopoly transmission and distribution service,
their provision of a competitive BPL service would present a risk of cross-subsidy by the former
to the latter. Whether the government allows electric utilities provide the broadband service
directly or independent BPL providers to get access to the distribution system are not clear yet.
In particular, since BPL systems use facilities occupying public rights-of-way, the regulation by
local governments is likely. With technical problems, e.g., radio frequency interference,
regulatory and policy uncertainty are one of the biggest barriers to BPL providers.
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
23/39
South Korea
In South Korea, Internet access (and its management service) market had shown
explosive growth rates over the early years of broadband access but since 2000, it has been rather
stagnant. Fierce competition among five residential broadband providers has led to price
decrease and free installation service. As a result, despite an increase in subscribers that amount
to 42.84 million, the sales revenue slipped by 8.5% to 822.5 billion won over the previous year
in 2003. Instead, the sales revenue for ISP service has slightly grown 9.9% to 379.9 billion won
in 2003 compared to the previous year (MIC, 2003).
Table 5. Broadband Internet market shares in South Korea (%)
Providers Access Technologies Entry 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Aug.
2005
Korea
Telecom (KT)
xDSL/Apt. LAN/Satellite June ’99 5.1 43.9 49.7 47.3 50.0 51.0 51.8
Hanaro
Telecom
xDSL/Cable
Modem(HFC)*/Apt. LAN
April ’99 33.3 28.0 26.4 27.6 24.4 23.1 23.1
Thrunet HFC/Apt. LAN July ’98 56.2 19.3 16.8 12.5 11.6 10.8 7.8
Onse Telecom HFC/Apt. LAN Aug. ’00 - 1.8 2.7 4.3 3.8 3.3 3.1
Dreamline xDSL/HFC/Apt. LAN Sept. ’99 5.3 3.9 2.3 1.6 1.3 1.1 1.1
Dacom HFC/Apt. LAN 1999 - 2.3 1.6 1.4 1.8 1.7 2.1
Others xDSL/HFC/Apt. LAN - - - 5.2 7.1 9.0 10.9
Source) NIC (2005). * HFC refers to cable modem service based on the optical fiber network to a node.
The total number of ISPs increased from 83 in 2001 to 101 in 2002 but it has been
decreasing since. Currently 78 commercial Internet networks exist. ISPs, which own and operate
their own Internet backbone networks, include KT (KORNet), Dacom (BORANet), Onse
(Shinbiro), Hanaro Telecom (HANANet), Thrunet, Enterprise Networks (GNGIDC), Dreamline
(DreamX), Samsung Networks and LG Powercom (NCA, 2005, 2006).
As for the high-speed Internet market share, as shown in table 5, KT has dominated the
market with 51.8% and Hanaro Telecom follows with a 23% market share. Other indicates
smaller ISPs such as regional cable system operators (hereinafter, cable SOs), which take over
the market quickly since 2001 with a 10% market share. Table 5 also reveals that ISPs in South
Korea have provided the service based upon multiple platforms utilizing wireless (e.g.,
apartment LAN using B-WLL), cable and telephone networks at the same time. Only KT has
used satellite for providing rural and remote user access to the high-speed Internet.
On the other hand, the broadband market structure has kept changing since entry. For
instance, SK telecom entered the residential broadband market in 2000 but exited in 2001
because it failed to obtain enough subscribers to survive in the market. While in the market, SK
telecom had a very limited market share, about 0.6% (total 44,346). In Dec. 2001, Hanaro
merged with Dreamline as a result of restructuring among the major ISPs. Also, Hanaro acquired
Thrunet in Dec. 2005, which was in legal protection. Thus, the market share of Hanaro will be
about 32% including Dreamline and Thrunet. Currently, two dominant providers exist in the
residential broadband market, i.e., KT and Hanaro Telecom.
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
24/39
Table 6. High-speed Internet service subscribers (South Korea) 2006
Unit: persons
Provider Xdsl HFC Apartment
LAN Satellite Total
KT 5,509,576 - 757,090 2,616 6,269,282 (51%)
Hanaro Telecom 937,031 2,147,083 500,030 - 3,584,144 (29%)
Onse Telecom - 305,534 37,734 - 343,268 (3%)
LG Powercom* - 218,462 111,646 - 330,108 (3%)
Dacom - 86,031 121,227 - 207,258 (2%)
Dreamline 40,417 49,248 11,032 - 100,697 (1%)
Value Added Service
Providers **
11,454 1,178,128 19,018 - 1,208,600 (10%)
Resellers 36,650 42,105 168,913 - 247,668 (2%)
Total 6,535,128 4,026,591 1,726,690 2,616 12,291,025 (100%)
Source) MIC, Jan. 2006, cited in NIDA (2006) * New entrance in Sept. 2005 ** Cable SOs
However, the new entries of LG Powercom in September 2005 and cable SOs will bring
more competition into the picture. LG Powercom, which was established in 2000 with optical
fiber networks and cable TV Networks from Korean Electric Power Corp. (KEPCO) entered the
broadband market. The Hybrid Fiber Coaxial (HFC) networks of LG Powercom can provide up
to 155 Mbps Internet access service to residential users (NCA, 2005). Also, the entrance of
regional cable SOs in small regions has been increasing. In June 2004, there were about 118
regional cable SOs and a significant number of those have provided residential broadband
service to mostly apartment complexes.
Similarly as in the U.S. case, the SOs have bundled cable television and high speed
Internet at cheaper price than what it would be without the bundle. SOs have entered the market
in a certain area (surrounding SO franchise area), rather than on a national scale. Currently, the
most prospective entrants are still regional SOs on a small scale and, main telecommunications
companies do not seem to enter sooner or later on a national scale. Since 2002, certain providers
have achieved marginal profits but in general, none of those providers has achieved supra-normal
profits (Kim & Lee, 2005).
In South Korea, the residential broadband market has shown a high percentage of growth
rates for last several years but it has been decreasing recently. Since technological advances and
service evolution have been much faster than other wireline telecommunications services,
substantial competitive pressure exists on broadband access service providers. Even before any
return on investment can be realized in the market, broadband service providers have to invest in
other technologies. This might result in weaker competitiveness of providers with relatively
weak financial capability. The weak competitiveness may be the reason behind the market
restructuring.
As previously indicated, while there is vibrant competition between DSL and cable
modems in South Korea, alternative broadband platforms, such as wireless and BPL, have not
yet appeared as competitors in the market. Rather, they have been complementary convergence
access technologies to the incumbents rather than as competitive technologies (Koh, Lee, & Kim,
2005). In fact, the advanced broadband infrastructure has referred to HFC or FTTH rather than
ADSL, wireless and satellite. Furthermore, thanks to the speedier service of VDSL (Very high
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
25/39
bit rate DSL), ADSL subscribers have been migrating to the VDSL service.19 However, it is
obvious that, in each residential market segment, more than five providers have been competing
for subscribers including a new entrant, LG Powercom.
Step 3. Assessment of absolute (cost) advantages
There is no doubt that the ownership of essential facilities such as the last mile networks
will bring absolute cost advantages to incumbents. Incumbents have exclusive or superior access
to inputs such as patents, spectrum, essential facilities and networks. Whether there are essential
facilities in a market has been a threshold to tell whether there is a monopolist in control of a
facility essential to other competitors. New entrants must get reasonable access to that facility if
it is feasible to do so. Without the access, new entrants have to face a substantial cost
disadvantage in contrast to incumbents with substantial cost advantages. In case incumbents have
no incentive to provide new entrants (or competitors) access to essential facilities (e.g., the last
mile networks), the government may set rules concerning access to influence the height of the
barrier (Blees, et al., 2003).
Historically, access to essential facilities by new entrants has been limited in the U.S.
Several reports recently published by consumer advocates groups and researchers (Selwyn, et al.,
2005; Turner, 2005, 2006; Marcus, 2006) point out some restraints and lack of competition in the
last mile. First, cable overbuilds have occurred in a limited number of locations, but only a
single cable system is available at 96.3% of all US households. Total number of residential
broadband providers appears to ensure enough choice to a consumer. For example, there are SBC
(AT&T), Verizon, Bell South and other telecom companies and Comcast, Time Warner, Cox,
and Charter and other cable companies. However, as indicated in a report (Selwyn, et al., 2005),
from the standpoint of an individual user, the total number of players available nationwide is not
relevant. What is relevant is the specific choice available to a particular user in the user’s own
specific geographic market. The vast majority of households have only one cable company and
one phone company offering high speed Internet service to their location. Turner, et al. (2005;
2006) shows that contradicting the rosy picture painted by the Federal Communications
Commission and Congress, the U.S. broadband policy has failed by leaving Americans with
higher prices, slower speeds and no meaningful competition for high-speed Internet service.
In light of ensuring access to essential facilities, South Korea has been very determined
and aggressive. First, telecommunications operators in South Korea are classified into three
groups: facilities-based service providers such as wire-line operators; specialized service
providers such as Internet telephony; and value-added service providers such as those offering
broadband Internet connection. Based on this classification, the telecom firms are governed by
different regulatory systems with various entry conditions and limitations (Lee & Chan-Olmsted,
2004). For example, facilities-based telecommunications service providers are required to
provide interconnection from the local exchange and long distance exchange. Specifically, only
KT is subject to mandatory interconnection from the local exchange and long distance exchange,
but all other facilities-based service providers should, when requested, provide an
interconnection agreement. In contrast, value-added service providers, including those offering
19 VDSL (Very high bit rate DSL), which covers relatively short transmission distance (0.3Km~1.5Km) compared to ADSL but
can offer speed up to 26 Mbps symmetrically compared to ADSL, which is limited to upload speed 8Mbps and download 640
kbps. Thanks to much speedier service, VDSL is gaining great popularity in South Korea (NCA, 2005).
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
26/39
broadband Internet access, have no entry regulation or unbundling requirement. Now that South
Korea has opened the broadband Internet access market fully to competition, it also means
minimal regulation for broadband Internet connection providers (Lee & Chan-Olmsted, 2004).
The government also abolished major regulations for Internet services and lowered market
entry barriers. Any company can enter the broadband market with a variety of services, although
critics maintain that there were already too many service providers for a market of Korea’s size
(KISDI, 2005). Consequently, the Korean government’s policy makers are more inclined to
push for competition through mandatory price cuts and lowered service costs that will stimulate
the adoption and usage of communication services. The ensuing intensification of competition
has enabled significant price reductions, while the entry of new players has provided customers
with a wide range of choices (Yan and Thong, 2003, cited in Lau, Kim and Atkin, 2005).20
According to Kim and Lee (2005), there exist no essential facilities in the broadband
market in South Korea. Although the network in the last mile is an essential facility for DSL
providers, there are many different alternative technologies to new entrants such as cable,
wireless, satellite and power line. In addition, considering Local loop unbundling (LLU),
facilities provision rules, LG Powercom’s cable TV network for rent, there is no need to concern
about essential facilities.
In addition, the revision of the Broadband Cable Television Law in January 1999 enabled
cable SOs to compete in the residential local broadband market against incumbents, adding more
competitive pressure to the access market. The revised law permitted one cable operator to own
up to a maximum of 7 companies, allowed vertical integration and access to telephone company
facilities for telecommunications. It opened a path for cable operators to provide cable Internet
and cable telephony services by resale or their own networks (Lee & Schejter, 2005). Also, the
government adopted two cable companies in a franchised area and allowed them to compete in
cable television and other communications services.
The competition between two broadband cable television services in one area led to the
absorption of the majority of narrowband cable subscribers by the broadband operators,
endeavoring to sell economic tiers. Since second licenses were given in 2002, the penetration of
broadband cable television has maintained a remarkable growth rate, reaching 57.0 percent of
households in June 2003 and rose to 69.0 percent in June 2004, despite competition from satellite
broadcasting. While the Korean Electronic and Telecommunication Basic Law21 requires cable
SOs to get a license from the Ministry of Information and Communications (MIC) to provide
cable telephony services, there is not any regulation for a cable system operator to provide
broadband services through telephone company networks.
An amendment to the Telecommunications Business Act in 200222 defines Internet
access service as a basic telecom service, which requires either license or registration to provide
the residential high-speed Internet service. Although new entrants should build up a certain scale
of networks and obtain the license, this process of licensing is not necessarily an entry barrier,
but makes the time of entrance rather delayed. A license does not invoke any additional sunk
cost to a potential entrant but increases the necessary time for entrance. Instead, value-added
20 Yan, X., Thong, J., 2003. Tariff-quality equilibrium and its implications for telecommunication regulation.
Telecommunications Policy, 27, 301–315.
21 Cheonki Tongsin Kibonbop
22 Sec. 3, revised on July 20th, 2004.
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
27/39
service providers do not have sunk cost because they have no networks and are required only to
register to get a license.
On the other hand, while KT has shown in a bid of VDSL modem provider, KT has much
superior negotiation power in supplies and appliances markets than other providers. This power
makes it possible for KT to enjoy the absolute cost advantage. In a bid for supplying 50 Mbps
VDSL equipment, equipment manufacturers argued against price discounts KT asked because of
the price increase of raw materials. Thus, KT, not equipment manufacturers, directly contacted
the raw material providers to get lower price (Digital Times, 2003, September 22). It is rare that
the buyer of equipment has a price negotiation with raw material providers. Thus, this case
shows that KT has superior market power as an equipment buyer.
Step 4. Sunk cost, economies of scale and capital requirements
The necessary facilities required to provide broadband service are routing facilities for
inter-exchange, transmission and last mile networks. If we define sunk costs as in the U.S.
Merger Guidelines, they are “the acquisition costs of tangible or intangible assets that cannot be
recovered through redeployment of these assets outside the relevant markets”, and determine the
Internet service market as the relevant market, the transmission and last mile facilities are able to
be recycled in other services markets. Therefore, these are not sunk costs.
However, routing facilities are sunk costs because they could not be recycled for other
purposes except for the Internet access service itself. If the relevant market were limited to the
high-speed Internet market, routing facilities and equipment could be recycled in the narrowband
Internet market. In this case, routing facilities and equipment are not sunk costs. However,
considering that the narrowband Internet access market in South Korea has been rapidly fading
and there has been no new investment in the narrowband market, the relevant market should be
defined as the Internet service market (Kim & Lee, 2005). Thus, routing facilities must be sunk
costs in this case. In contrast, in the U.S., the narrowband service has been still viable in the
Internet access market. Thus, the routing facilities may be recycled in this market so that they are
not sunk.
Economies of scale and economies of scope
Both in the U.S. and in South Korea, dominant telecommunications providers continue to
control the last mile networks, indicating that there exist both economies of scale and economies
of scope because the presence of fixed costs enables average cost decreasing with an increasing
number of subscribers (Miller, 1995; Brock, 1981). At the same time, network operators could
use the network for other various services. Unlike local telephone service, national coverage is
not a necessary requirement for Internet access services. However, the limitation of service
availability is still a disadvantage in competition. For new entrants, the extent of the network
coverage by incumbents could become a barrier to expanding new entrants’ businesses because
of incumbents’ pre-occupation over subscribers and first-mover advantages (Xiao & Orazem,
2005).
Although absolute cost advantages of the incumbents exist resulting from economies of
scale and scope, their importance has been declining because of dropping costs for service
provision and development of niche markets thanks to technological innovation. Kim and Lee
(2005) estimated the minimum viable scale of entry (MVS) of residential broadband market by
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
28/39
using Stigler’s survival test and concluded that at about 25-30% of market size would be the
MVS in the Korean market. To achieve the MVS, new entrance would require a tremendous
amount of capital. In particular, assuming that a new entrant cannot reap profits for a while,
capital requirements would be greater.
However, as for firms with economies of scope, such as LG Powercom and SOs which
can provide a cable television service together, additional capital for entering the residential
broadband market may be not so much required. Also, there are potential new entrants
originating from non-telecom businesses that can ensure financial assets when entering the
market. For example, Korea Electric Power Co. (KEPCO) owns power line communications
networks (PLC) through which it can provide broadband access service.
Step 5. Product differentiation, advertising, switching costs and network
externalities
It is well known that price and speed are more critical elements than differences of access
technologies when normal users select a provider. The US broadband providers, in particular
ILECs, have differentiated the high-speed Internet depending on speed as intending to expand
available customer base. AT&T has offered standard and preferred plans, which provide 1.5
Mbps ($29.95) and 3 Mbps ($39.95) respectively with a full year service (AT&T homepage). In
July 2006, AT&T started to offer a new 6 Mbps service for $27.99 a month to customers signing
up for a full year of service. The company also has offered three months of free broadband
service and satellite service (through its partnership with EchoStar’s Dish Network) to cable
broadband subscribers if they switch over from a rival cable provider since July 2005. Verizon
is also offering DSL service (at its introductory speed of 768 kilobits per second) free for the first
month of service and for $14.95 a month for the remainder of the year. Its 3 Mbps service —
nearly four times faster — was priced at $29.99 a month with a full year service. However, the
seemingly generous offerings have been criticized as baits to allure dial-up users. And a real
price war has not occurred in the broadband market (Turner, 2006).
In South Korea, since most service providers offer services at similar price, speed and
added services, product differentiation among providers rarely exists. According to some surveys
conducted by KISDI in 2003 and in 2004, there was no difference among the top three
companies, i.e., KT, Hanaro and Thrunet in terms of individual users’ perceptions of the service
satisfaction level (KISDI survey, 2003, 2004, cited in Kim & Lee, 2005).
Brand recognition
In terms of brand recognition, KT among the dominant providers has shown the highest
recognition rate in a survey in 2004 by recording 61%. This is a big difference compared to the
second provider, Hanaro, which recorded a 26% recognition rate. Additionally, a logit
regression analysis on the reason for selecting a service provider indicated that brand name
recognition has influenced customers’ selection decision. For example, KT showed a positive
and significant relationship between the firm’s brand image/trust and the selection decision
whereas Hanaro and Thrunet showed negative but significant relationships (KISDI, 2003, cited
in Kim & Lee, 2005). Also, a favor level test showed the order of KT, Hanaro, Thurunet, Dacom,
Onse and regional cable TV system operators (SOs) in terms of users’ favor level (KISDI 2004
survey, cited in Kim and Lee, 2005). Although there is no a comparable survey in the U.S., we
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
29/39
can easily estimate that dominant telephone and cable companies’ brand recognition and brand
power must be huge in the U.S. as well.
Switching costs
In the case of switching a provider, the remnant contract time, subscription fee, and
replacement cost for equipment have been barriers to switching a provider on the customer side.
Thus, service providers have offered subscription fee waiver, free use for a limited time, and so
on to win the needed number of subscribers in South Korea. Also, given that modems have been
standardized, switching costs of broadband service access have been minimal. Similarly, in the
U.S., switching costs between DSL and cable modem has been ignorable. However, satellite has
required a substantial amount of installation fee, on average, a few of hundreds.
Network externalities
Although Internet networks are open and interoperated networks, either when the
transmission volume is not enough at the interconnection point or when the interconnection
speed is not enough in the last mile, to subscribe for networks with more subscribers would be
more advantageous in using advanced applications such as file sharing (P2P) and Web storage
services. Further, content providers would find more advantage using networks with a greater
numbers of subscribers. Therefore, both direct and indirect network externalities will exist.
Step 6. Vertical foreclosure and exclusion
Since vertically integrated providers may preclude new entrants from entering the market
by refusing to provide last mile networks or excluding a specific new entrant, the South Korean
government has legislated LLU (Local Loop Unbundling) and facilities-sharing rules. New
entrants can enter the market by leasing the networks of LG Powercom, originated from
KEPCO’s optical fiber networks, on which SOs have already based their platforms. Thus, given
the relevant rules and legislation to block vertical foreclosure, to prevent new entrants from
entering the market through vertical integration would be difficult in South Korea.
Although vertical integration has not been a big concern in the U.S., current regulatory
decisions of the FCC and the dominant status of incumbents may make vertical foreclosure and
exclusion more plausible. As a vertically integrated entity, a dominant ILEC may have an
incentive to maximize profits by using their leverage in the form of a price squeeze. Furthermore,
the opportunity to run a classic price squeeze will be readily available in the form of excessive
access charges.
Several economists also suggest that foreclosure effects are more likely to be present in
situations when one of the markets (i.e., upstream or downstream) is highly concentrated (Bolton
& Whinston, 1991; Bork, 1978).23 With telecom networks and cable networks on the customer
side, the last mile, has been highly concentrated, vertical foreclosure effects such as refusal to
supply and exclusive dealing and tying arrangement are very likely. As Zelinski (2004) points
out, cable companies have segmented the market by offering higher speeds than telephone
companies for higher prices than telephone companies charge for DSL services. Cable
companies have bundled proprietary content and applications with their cable modem and
23 Bolton, P., & Whinston, M. (1991). The foreclosure effects of vertical mergers. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical
Economics, 147, 207-226; Bork, R. (1978). The antitrust paradox. New York: Basic Books, cited in OFT (1994).
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
30/39
traditional television service offerings.
Indeed, product tying and bundling by incumbent providers have been criticized (Selwyn,
et al., 2005; Cooper, et al., 2005). Critics say that incumbent ILECs will not sell a consumer
DSL on a stand-alone basis. Users will be forced to buy their voice service in order to get a DSL
service. This practice is also common in cable, which sells broadband for $40-50 on average.
Including its television service, it costs total $80-100 per month (Cooper, et al., 2005).
Also, the telephone companies have had success in bundling a variety of communications
services under one bill. An industry report by Standard & Poor’s reveals that aided by the
inclusion of broadband connectivity (through its DSL offering) and satellite TV service (through
its relationship with EchoStar Communications Corp.), AT&T’s revenues per retail consumer
line rose 5.7% in the 12 months ended March 2006. AT&T had DSL penetration of
approximately 29% of its consumer primary access lines, up from 21% in June 2005.24 In March
2004, SBC and EchoStar began a co-branded, multi-channel television service that became part
of SBC’s local and long-distance bundled services. As of June 2006, the newly formed AT&T
Inc. had 533,000 video subscribers and had extended its relationship with a more traditional,
sales-agency approach that provided motivation for subscriber growth. In July 2006, AT&T was
offering customers a quad-pack of its services (wireless through Cingular, wireline, broadband,
and satellite TV) for $125 a month (Rosenbluth, 2006, August 24).
The partnership between AT&T and EchoStar expanded in July 2006, as AT&T launched
a television service called Homezone. The service will allow AT&T broadband subscribers to
download hundreds of movies for a fee from the Movielink Web site and then view them on a
TV set. The Internet service will be connected to a television set-top box by wired or a wireless
connection and to an EchoStar satellite dish.
Verizon also made an agreement with EchoStar for the marketing and sale of its Dish
Network subscriptions. As of March 2006, Verizon had 485,000 satellite TV customers through
its triple-play bundle of wireline voice, broadband, and video. By mid-2006, Verizon was
offering high-speed broadband and video service using its newly constructed fiber-to-the-
premises (FTTP) network to customers in multiple markets, and the company had begun its
initial launch of its fiber-based service.
Satellite partnerships are not just for the telecom carriers operating in metropolitan
markets. In July 2005, rurally based TDS Telecommunications Co. announced an agreement
with EchoStar to offer satellite service to its telephone customers under one bill (Rosenbluth,
2006, August 24). Utilizing the existing products will not only bring absolute cost advantages to
incumbents, vertically integrated providers may have incentives to block new entrants in the
broadband market by leveraging their market power.
Step 7. Predatory behavior
Koski and Majumdar (2002) examined whether new entry into the U.S. local exchange
markets affects the behavior of Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers (ILECs) in terms of pricing,
advertising and the extent of diversification. The authors found that the reaction strategy of
24 These figures exclude secondary phone lines that are often used for dial-up Internet connections, as well as lines for enterprise
customers (Rosenbluth, 2006, August 24).
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
31/39
ILECs is not related to an aggressive pricing but related to advertising, and ILECs cut back the
extent of diversification when they face with the entry of a new competitor. However, as
previously shown in the broadband market, ILECs have provided DSL services at a dial-up price.
Although cable companies have not straightforwardly responded with price to the competitive
pressure, new entrants may feel inappropriate to enter the residential market because of lack of
profitability.
When a firm wants to conduct predatory pricing in the market, it should have a certain
degree of market power and financial ability. This is called the theory of the “long purse”. After
a competitive firm exits, the dominant firm should be able to increase its price to recover the loss.
There is a possibility that, if KT, a dominant provider, reduce the price below marginal cost or
average cost for a certain period of time, it would obtain a significant share of market and make
competitors exit. Despite intended exits, however, KT would not increase its service price unless
the market comes to monopoly. The reasons are as follows: First, even though it may succeed in
excluding new entrants or marginal competitors, to make the second or third companies exit
would be difficult. It is possible that survivors from competition would make KT harder to
increase price by taking subscribers away from KT and make KT fail to raise profits even after a
price increase. Second, SOs have been increasing their market share by offering cheaper
services surrounding certain areas (which are mostly their franchising areas). However, KT has
responded with quality and service competition to this competitive pressure rather than price
competition. Once KT competes with SOs in price, KT should bring down its own price. In this
case, the whole profits KT can obtain would be diminishing, although it could take subscribers
away from SOs.
On the other hand, if KT competes in a certain area with quality, value-added services,
and giveaways, KT may lure more new subscribers away without influencing the revenue
derived from the existing customers. Considering the facts, we can assume that the incumbent
provider would compete with quality and service rather than with price by engaging in predatory
pricing. KT would have more incentive to raise rivals costs by increasing prices of transmission
and land lines for rent rather than predatory pricing. This is analogous to the competition
between DSL and cable companies in the U.S.
Step 8. Assessment of entry impediments
In the broadband access market of South Korea, the only discernable barrier to entry was
nothing but obtaining a license. In the residential broadband access market, if a new entrant was
going to enter nationwide on a large scale, barriers to entry would be much higher to entrants
without economies of scale compared to entrants with economies of scale. On the other hand,
entry barriers would be rather low to an entrant that tries to enter on a small scale like value-
added or special service providers that can lease facilities from the facilities-based operators.
In contrast, it is notable that the U.S. has much higher barriers to new entrants that want
to enter on either DSL or cable network platforms. Even though wireless, satellite and BPL have
provided alternative technologies to new entrants, entering the residential market without
economies of scale and scope as like early entrants, and without regulatory certainty would be
too risky to decide to enter.
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
32/39
5. Conclusion
This paper has shown some commonalities and differences between the U.S. and South
Korea in terms of entry barriers in the broadband access market. In particular, the following
differences are conspicuous and deserve to be mentioned:
First, the qualifying speed of broadband is very different between the U.S. and South
Korea. Although the U.S. definition, i.e., at least 200 kbps in one direction can have the effect of
expanding the relevant market, the broadband content and applications markets have been
limited by accommodating the speed. However, it is well-known that the speedier access service
in South Korea has resulted from the effect of vigorous market competition rather than the
government’s requirement (Lau, Kim and Atkin, 2005; Lee & Chan-Olmsted, 2004).
Second, in South Korea, reciprocal access to networks of each other has been easier than
in the U.S. Mandated open access rules have been taken advantage of by new entrants in South
Korea and led to more concrete competition among intermodal and intramodal providers. When
companies vigorously compete against one another, they have incentives to beat the competition
through lower prices and are driven to make the investments necessary to improve quality or
develop new services. The market forces firms to invest and price aggressively, for fear of falling
behind. Vigorous competition ensures that we all pay fair prices for the goods and services we
enjoy. Unfortunately, the telecommunications marketplace in the U.S. is anything but
competitive (Cooper, et al., 2005).
Third, more than three providers have always been available to Korean residential users.
Although the US and South Korea share a commonality of insufficient entrance of a third
platform, they are different in terms of competition levels. The existence of more than three
providers for residential users has not only provided more options to customers but also created
more competitive pressure.
Fourth, the Korean government’s protection policy makes new entrants face rather low
barriers to entry. The Korean government has thought that at least three competitors need to exist
in a market and leveraged KT, once a public company, to provide collocation facilities and
essential facilities to new entrants to restrain the dominant market power of KT.
In particular, Lee and Chan-Olmsted (2004) conclude that facility-based competition
seems to work better than simple local loop unbundling in inducing competition in South Korea.
Thus, the authors suggest that policies that encourage the development of alternative broadband
technologies and introduce a collaborative governmental role in the building of major broadband
infrastructure might be effective in speeding up the deployment of broadband Internet. It is
evident that the market competition is more influential than government’s command control but,
as shown in the South Korean case, what is more important is how the government can assist in
incubating viable competition (Frieden, 2005).
Barriers to entry exist under very diverse conceptions about what they are depending on
the views of different economists and scholars. Although the Stiglerian conception of entry
barriers has been more precisely defined as focusing on cost differentials between entrants and
incumbents, the Bainian approach is more applicable for investigating barriers in the
telecommunications market. Because, first, economies of scale, sunk costs, and advertising are
critical sources of barriers to entry in the telecommunications network industry and second, these
will all be excluded under the Stiglerian approach. How these barriers influence the entry
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
33/39
decisions of new potential entrants has not been apparent. By empirical evidence from previous
literature, we can assume that the barriers will vary depending on the scale of entrance, potential
local demands, and specific characteristics of the market. Also, as far as there are incumbents
with economies of scale and sunk costs, their responses to potential entrants will be erecting
strategic barriers through advertising and service/quality competition rather than price reduction
in the telecommunications market.
The Telecommunications Act of 1996 mandates that the FCC eliminate and identify
market entry barriers “for entrepreneurs and other small businesses in the provision and
ownership of telecommunications services and information services, or in the provision of parts
or services to providers of telecommunications services and information services.”25 Therefore,
the Commission has a statutory duty and an obligation in the public interest to identify and
eliminate market entry barriers for small telecommunications businesses. In general, the
Commission has interpreted market entry barriers to include, inter alia, “barriers that impede
entry into the telecommunications market by existing small businesses, and obstacles that small
telecommunications businesses face in providing service or expanding within the
telecommunications industry . . . .”
Above all, barriers to entry is a very important issue at the moment in that the US has
adopted non-open access rules in advanced telecommunications networks which deliver high-
speed Internet to residence areas and ruled out most small scale non-facilities based providers.
Even though wireless, satellite and other access technologies have been said to be able to
overcome the last mile problems, they may still face entry barriers. The residential broadband
market has been called monopoly or at best, duopoly for a long time thanks to the enormous
height of entry barriers such as scale economies and sunk costs, which come from burdensome
underground wiring and essential facilities.
Generally, big companies can overcome certain barriers to entry more easily (e.g.,
economies of scale) and they may be able to influence the competitive positions in an industry to
a greater extent than smaller companies can. Small companies are often the first and most
directly affected by the harm caused by price fixers and market allocators or anticompetitive
behavior of incumbents (Golodner, 2001). The size of the entry (in terms of new production
capacity), thus, influences the consequences for the incumbent. Incumbents might allow small
entrants or fringe companies in the market in order to keep bigger competitors out of the market.
If an entrant enters with a large production capacity, it poses a serious threat to the incumbents.
In such circumstances, incumbents are more likely to react aggressively to the entrant, for
example by lowering their prices. Therefore, the size of the (potential) entrant is expected to
influence the reaction of the incumbents. Barriers to entry have an effect on the entry decision of
potential entrants as well. If the barriers to entry are too high, small firms or start-ups might
decide not to enter the market. This might have a negative effect on competition and on the
dynamics of the market, and might result in high prices and/or low quality and innovation.
A more recent study about Internet Service Providers (ISPs) (van Gorp, Maitland, &
Hanekop, 2006) reveals the challenges ISPs face and their responsive strategies. By examining
the Dutch broadband market and surveying European ISPs, it found that ISPs’ offerings of
broadband services are more likely to be driven by competitive forces than by proactive
25 47 U.S.C. § 257
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
34/39
strategies, although most ISPs started their role as a technological mediator in the market.
Interestingly, they conclude that ISPs’ position in the market is likely to be threatened by
infrastructure providers when infrastructure providers come to be aware of the potential of
Internet access and expand their service areas. The market power of infrastructure providers will
bring further competitive pressure on independent ISPs in the broadband access market in the
future.
Thus, this study raises another question, in increasing market competition, whether or not
independent ISPs will be able to gain enough market share in fixed Internet access services. The
challenges ISPs face indicate the increasing importance of owning facilities or network
infrastructure in the broadband age (Andy Ng, et al., 2004). Andy Ng, et al. (2004) studies the
industry structure of the residential broadband market and argues that owning the optical last
mile network is strategically important because of its monopolistic nature and the technical
scalability to meet future bandwidth demand. As a result, the last mile operator will seize
substantial market power in the broadband service value chain (Andy Ng, et al., 2004).
High degrees of entry barriers from high customer acquisition costs and economies of
scale in network operations in the local telecommunications market induce the strategy of buying
or acquiring existing telephone companies rather than building a new network. If there is an
industry that firms can only enter if they make a large capital expenditure, a firm will not enter if
the profits that it anticipates in the long run will not be sufficient to justify the initial capital
requirement. Therefore, as shown in the transaction between GTE and CenturyTel in 1999, new
entrants are often willing to pay a premium for the purchase of networks and customers (Gabel,
2002). Although new entrants with facilities such as wireless, powerline and satellite may come
from the existing companies with deep pockets, to overcome barriers, e.g., enormous capital
requirements, economies of scale and sunk costs of residential telecom networks would not be
that easy. Despite the market expansion of various broadband access technologies, it seems
unclear whether new entrants with facilities gain enough post-entry profits to compete with
incumbents in the residential broadband access market and how new entrants without facilities
are ever going to enter the market without a way to access residential users. xDSL or cable
modem, duopoly-centered policies can give more advantages to certain access platforms, and to
duplicated investment.
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
35/39
References
Abel, J., & Clements, M. (2001). Entry under asymmetric regulation. Review of Industrial Organization,
19, 227-242.
Alesina, A., Ardagna, S., Nicoletti, G., & Schiantarelli, F. (2003). Regulation and investment. NBER
working paper series, no. 9560. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Andy Ng., P.T., Lu, D., Li, C. K., & Harry Chan, H. Y. (2004). A strategic perspective on future
residential broadband market. Technovation, 24(8), 665-669.
APPANET (2004). State barriers to community broadband services. Retrieved Feb. 10, 2006, from
http://www.appanet.org/legislative/index.cfm?ItemNumber=9998 (updated December 2004)
Bain, J. S. (1954). Economies of scale, concentration, and the condition of entry in twenty
manufacturing industries. The American Economics Review, 44(1), 15-39.
Bain, J. S. (1956). Barriers to new competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Balhoff, M. J., & Rowe, R. C. (2005, September). Municipal Broadband - Digging Beneath the Surface.
Balhoff & Rowe, LLC. Retrieved Feb. 3, 2006, from
http://balhoffrowe.com/pdf/Municipal%20Broadband--
Digging%20Beneath%20the%20Surface.pdf
Baumol, W, Panzar, J., & Willig, J. (1982). Contestable markets and the theory of industry structure.
New York: Harcourt College Pub.
Beard, R., Ford, G., & Koutsky, T. (2005). Mandated access and the make-or-buy decision: the case of
local telecommunications competition. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 45, 28-
47.
Besing, R. G. (2005). The intersection of Sherman Act section 2 and the Telecommunications Act of
1996: what should Congress do?. 2005 Symposium: the Telecommunications Act of 1996: a case
of regulatory obsolescence: participant issue paper, CommLaw Conspectus, 13(1).
Blees, J., Kemp, R., Maas, J., & Mosselman, M. (2003). Barriers to entry-differences in barriers to entry
for SMEs and large enterprises. Research Report H200301, SCientific AnaLysis of
Entrepreneurship and SMEs (SCALES). Retrieved March 13, 2006, from
http://www.eim.net/pdf-ez/H200301.pdf
Bleha, T. (May/June 2005). Down to the wire. Foreign Affairs, 84 (3), 111-.
Brock, G. W. (1981). The telecommunications industry: the dynamics of market structure. Cambridge,
Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Brown, K. S., & Zimmerman, P. R. (2004). The effect of Section 271 on competitive entry into local
telecommunications markets: An initial evaluation. Information Economics and Policy, 16, 215-
233.
Carlton, D. W. (2005). Barriers to entry. NBER working paper series. No.1645.
Carlton, D. W., & Perloff, J. M. (2005). Modern Industrial Organization. The Fourth Edition, New York:
Pearson Addison Wesley.
Carlton, D., & Perloff, J. (1994). Modern industrial organization. Reading, New York, NY:
HarperCollins College Publishers.
Church, J., & Ware, R. (1999). Industrial organization: a strategic approach. Boston, MA: Irwin
McGraw-Hill.
Clarke, R., Hassett, K., Ivanova, Z., & Kotlikoff, L. (2004). Assessing the economic gains from telecom
competition. NBER Working Paper Series, w10482.
Cooper, M. (2004). Expanding the digital divide & falling behind on broadband: why a
telecommunications policy of neglect is not benign. Retrieved November 20, 2005, from
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
36/39
http://www.consumerfed.org/topics.cfm?section=Communications&Topic=Internet
Cooper, M. (2005). Broken promises and strangled competition: the record of baby Bell merger and
market opening behavior. Retrieved July 30, 2005 from
http://www.consumerfed.org/publications2.cfm?type=studies
Cooper, M., Kimmelman, G., & Mierzwinski, E. (2005, May 9). In the matter of Verizon
Communications Inc. and MCI Inc. applications for approval of transfer of control. Petition to
deny of Consumer Federation of America, Consumers Union, and U.S. Public Interest Research
Group. Retrieved July 12, 2006, from www.pirg.org/consumer//media/mciopposition.pdf
David, S. L., Stern, M. L., & Towle, H. K. (2005). Broadband over power line: key legal issues for
utilities. The Electricity Journal, 18(4), 64-71.
Demsetz, H. (1982). Barriers to entry. The American Economic Review, 72(1), 47-57.
Economides, N. (1996). The economics of networks. International Journal of Industrial Organization,
14(6), 673-699.
Economides, N., & White, L. J. (1994). Networks and compatibility: implications for antitrust. European
Economic Review, 38 (3/4), 651-662.
Faulhaber, G. R., & Hogendorn, C. (2000). The Market Structure of Broadband Telecommunications.
Journal of Industrial Economics, 48(3), 305-329.
Ferguson, C. H. (2004). The broadband problem: Anatomy of a market failure and a policy dilemma.
Washington, D. C.: Brookings Institution Press.
Ferguson, J. M. (1974). Advertising and competition: theory, measurement, fact. Cambridge: Ballinger.
Figliola, P. M. (2006). Broadband over powerlines: regulatory and policy issues. CRS Report for
Congress. Retrieved July 1, 2006, from Congressional Research Service Reports DB.
Fisher, F. M. (1979). Diagnosing monopoly. Quarterly Review of Economics and Business, 19, 7-33.
Ford, G. S. (2004). You’re not impaired because you are impaired. Perspectives-Phoenix Center for
Advanced legal & economic public policy studies, 04-05. Retrieved June 2, 2006, from
www.phoenix-center.org
Forsberg, B. (2005, March 13). The future is South Korea-tech firms try out latest in world’s most
wired society. San Francisco Chronicle, B1.
Frieden, R. M. (2005a). Lessons from broadband development in Canada, Japan, Korea and the United
States. Telecommunications Policy, 29 (8), 595-613.
Gabel (2002). Why is there so little competition in the provision of local telecommunications services?
An examination of alternative approaches to end-user access. Retrieved June 20, 2006, from
http://napaconsulting.com/Reports/ITC/LastMileDone.pdf
Geroski, P., Gilbert, R. J., Jacquemin, A. (1990). Barriers to entry and strategic competition. New York,
N.Y. : Harwood Academic Publishers.
Gibbons, J., & Ruth, S. (2006). Municipal Wi-Fi: big wave or wipeout?. IEEE Internet Computing,
10(3), 66-71.
Gilbert, R. (1989). Mobility barriers and the value of incumbency. In R. Shmalensee & R. D. Willig
(Eds.). Handbook of Industrial Organization (pp.475-535). Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Golodner, A.M. (2001), Antitrust, innovation, entrepreneurship and small business, Small Business
Economics, 16, 31-35.
Greenstein, S., & Mazzeo, M. (2003). Differentiation strategy and market deregulation: local
telecommunication entry in the late 1990s. NBER Working Paper Series, W. 9761.
Hahn, R. W. (2001). A primer on competition policy and the new economy. the AEI-Brookings Joint
Center, Working Paper 01-03. Retrieved from
http://aei.brookings.org/publications/abstract.php?pid=119
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
37/39
Harrell, J. (2006, Jan. 27). Suffolk County aims for a wireless Web network. Long Island Business News,
p.1.
Hausman, Jerry (2002). From 2G to 3G: Wireless competition for Internet-related services. In Crandall,
Robert & James Allerman (eds.).. Broadband: Should we regulate high-speed Internet access?
Washington, D.C.: Brookins Insstitute, 106-128.
Hovenkamp, H. (1999). Federal Antitrust Policy (2nd Ed.). St. Paul: Minn.
Karakaya, F., & Stahl, M. (1989). Barriers to entry and market entry decisions in consumer and
industrial goods markets. Journal of Marketing,53(2), 80-91.
Kaserman, D., Mayo, J., Blank, L., & Kahai, S. (1999). Open entry and local telephone rates: The
economics of intraLATA toll competition. Review of Industrial Organization,14, 303-319.
Kim, J. H., & Lee, S. K. (2005). Barriers to entry in telecommunications market: Conception and
evaluation. KISDI Issue Report 05-15. Retrieved Feb. 20, 2006, from http://www.kisdi.re.kr
(Korean Version).
Kim, S., & Litman, B. (1999). An economic analysis of the US wireless telephone industry: responses to
new technologies. Telematics and informatics, 16 (1), 27-
Kimmelman, G. (2005). On behalf of consumers union and the consumer federation of america on sbc-
at&t and verizon-mci mergers remaking the telecommunications industry, Senate Judiciary
Committee, March 15, 2005. 2005 Symposium: the Telecommunications Act of 1996: a case of
regulatory obsolescence: participant issue paper, CommLaw Conspectus, 13(1).
Koski, H., & Majumdar, S. (2002). Paragons of virtue? Competitor entry and the strategies of
incumbents in the U.S. local telecommunications industry. Information Economics and Policy,
14, 453-480.
Lee, S., & Schejter, A. (2005). The Evolution of cable regulatory policies and their consequences:
comparing South Korea and Israel. A paper presented at the colloquium at Penn State University
(November 2, 2005).
Lent, L. S. (2004). The transformation of the telecommunications industry. A paper presented at the
32rd Annual Telecommunications Policy Research Conference, George Mason University
School of Law, Arlington, Virginia (October 1-3, 2004).
Leon, K., & Wang, N. (2005, Nov. 3). Industry surveys-telecommunications: wireless. Standard & Poors.
Retrieved June 1, 2006, from Multex DB.
Loomis, D. G., & Swann, C. M. (2005). Intermodal competition in local telecommunications markets.
Information Economics and Policy, 17(1), 97-113.
Marcus, J. S. (2006). Is the USA dancing to a different drummer?. Intermedia, 34(3), 26-35.
McAfee, R. P., Mialon, H. M., & Williams, M. A. (2004). What is a barrier to entry?
R Preston McAfee, Hugo M Mialon, Michael A Williams. The American Economic Review, 94
(2), 461-465.
Miller, E. S. (1995). Is the public utility concept obsolete?. Land Economics, 71(3), 273-285.
Nahata, B., & Olson, D. O. (1989). On the definition of barriers to entry. Southern Economic Journal,
56(1), 236-239.
National Computerization Agency (NCA). (2005). White paper Internet Korea 2005. Retrieved May 3,
2006, from http://www.nca.or.kr
National Internet Development Agency of Korea (NIDA). (2006). 2006 Korea Internet White Paper.
Retrieved September 1, 2006, from http://www.mic.go.kr
Nix, J., & Gabel, D. (1993). AT&T’s strategic response to competition: Why not preempt entry? The
Journal of Economic History, 53, 377-387.
Prieger, J. E. (2003). The supply side of the digital divide: Is there equal availability in the broadband
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
38/39
Internet access market?. Economic Inquiry, 41(2), 346-361.
Rosenberg, E., & Clements, M. (2000). Evolving market structure, conduct, and policy in local
telecommunications. Columbus, OH: The National Regulatory Research Institute.
Rosenbluth, T. (2006, August 24). Telecommunications: wireline. Standard & Poor’s Industry Surveys.
Retrieved September 1, 2006, from Standard & Poor’s NetAdvantage DB.
Rosston, G. L., & Wimmer, B. S. (2001). From C to shing C: Competition and cross-study in
communications. In B. M. Compaine & S. Greeenstein (Eds.), Communications Policy in
Transition: The Internet and beyond (pp.241-261). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Satellite News (2004, Sep. 13). WildBlue CEO counting on pent-up rural broadband demand. Satellite
News, 27(35), 1.
Savage, S. J., & Waldman, D. (2005). Broadband Internet access, awareness, and use: Analysis of
United States household data. Telecommunications Policy, 29 (8), 615-633.
Schmalensee, R. (1989). Inter-industry studies of structure and performance. In R. Schmalensee and R.
D. Willig (Eds.). Handbook of Industrial Organization Volume II (pp.951-1009). Amsterdam ;
New York : North-Holland: Elsevier Science Publishers B.V.
Scott, B. & Aaron, C. (2005). The United States of Broadband. Retrieved on September 29, 2005, from
http://www.tompaine.com/print/the_united _states_of_broadband.php
Selwyn, L.L., Golding, H. E., & Thompson, H.A. (2005). Confronting telecom industry consolidation. A
regulatory agenda for dealing with the implosion of competition. The National Association of
State Utility Consumer Advocates (NASUCA). Retrieved June 20, 2006, from
http://www.econtech.com/NASUCA%20Whitepaper%20April%202005.pdf#search=%22%22hi
gh-speed%20Internet%20market%20share%22%22
Sidak, J. G. (2006, Feb. 7). Testimony of J.Gregory Sidak. Committee on Commerce, Science, and
Transportation. United States Senate. Retreived March 30, 2006, from
http://commerce.senate.gov/pdf/sidak-020706.pdf.
Spiwak, L.J. (1999). Do the FCC policies promote or deter entry? that is the only question. Phoenix
Center Policy Paper Number 6. Retrieved June 2, 2006, from www.phoenix-center.org
Stigler, G. (1968). The organization of industry. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
The FCC (2006, July). Local telephone competition: status as of December 31, 2005. Industry Analysis
and Technology Division, Wireline Competition Bureau, Federal Communications Commission.
Retrieved July 30, 2006, from http://www.fcc.gov/wcb/iatd/stats.html
The FCC. (July 2005). High-speed services for Internet Access: status as of December 31, 2004.
Retrieved September 20, 2005, from http://www.fcc.gov/wcb/iatd/comp.html
The U.S. Department of Justice (DOJ) (1992) Horizontal guideline. Issued on April 2, 1992, Revised on
April 8, 1997. Retrieved May 20, 2006, from
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/hmg.htm
Turner, S. D. (2005). Broadband reality check-The FCC ignores America’s digital divide. Free Press.
Retrieved April 30, 2006, from
http://freepress.net/docs/broadband_report.pdf#search=%22Broadband%20reality%20check-
The%20FCC%20ignores%20America%E2%80%99s%20digital%20divide%22
Turner, S. D. (2006). Broadband reality check II- the truth behind America’s digital decline. Free Press.
Retrieved September 12, 2006, from http://www.freepress.net/docs/bbrc2-final.pdf
Van Gorp, A. F., Maitland, C. F., & Hanekop, H. (2006). The broadband Internet access market: The
changing role of ISPs. Telecommunications Policy, 30(2), 96-111.
Van Schewick, I. B. (2005). Towards an economic framework for network neutrality regulation. A paper
presented at the 33rd Annual Telecommunications Policy Research Conference, George Mason
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
39/39
University School of Law, Arlington, Virginia (Sep. 23-24, 2005).
Von Weizsacker (1980). A welfare analysis of barriers to entry, Bell Journal of Economics, 11(2), 399-
420.
Vos, E. (2005). March 2005 Report. Reports on municipal wireless and broadband projects. Retrieved
June, 2006, from http://www.muniwireless.com
Wallsten, S. (2006). Broadband and unbundling regulations in OECD Countries, the AEI-Brookings
Joint Center, working paper 06-16, 2006, 6.
http://aei.brookings.org/admin/authorpdfs/page.php?id=1284
White, D. L. (1989). Shaping antitrust enforcement: greater emphasis on barriers to entry. Brigham
Young University Law Review, 830, 823-851.
Wolley, S. (2005, July 4). Backwater Broadband. Forbes,176 (1), p. 064.
Woroch, G. A. (2000). Competition’s effect on investment in digital infrastructure. Presented at the
Xiao, M., & Orazem, P. F. (2005). Do entry conditions vary over time? Entry and competition in the
broadband market: 1999-2003. Retrieved Feb. 23, 2006, from
http://econ.arizona.edu/downloads/Seminars/05_Xiao.pdf
Yang, G. (1998). Barriers to entry and industrial performance in China. International Review of Applied
Economics, 12(1), 39-51.
Yoo, C. S. (2004, July 11). The economics of net neutrality: why the physical layer of the Internet
should not be regulated. Retrieved Feb. 28, 2006, from http://www.pff.org/issues-
pubs/pops/pop11.11yoonetneutrality.pdf
Zielinski, C. A. (2004). Barriers to entry: the fight against PowerLine Communications: and for a
reasonable regulatory policy for new broadband technology. Public Utilities Fortnightly.
Retrieved Feb. 5, 2005, from
http://www.allbusiness.com/periodicals/article.asp?ID=278451&Page=1&
Zolnierek, J., Eisner, J., & Burton, E. (2001). An empirical examination of entry patterns in local
telephone markets. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 19, 143-159.
Eun-A Park & Richard Taylor_TPRC 2006
ResearchGate has not been able to resolve any citations for this publication.
Article
Full-text available
The present article is an attempt to resolve the controversies concerning the concept of barriers to entry. We begin by contrasting the definitions of an entry barrier proposed in the economics literature. We then introduce a classification system to clear up the existing confusion, and we employ it to assess the nature of the barriers posed by scale economies and sunk costs.
Article
Full-text available
This study tests six market entry barriers in consumer, and industrial markets, i.e., cost advantages of incumbents, product differentiation of incumbents, capital requirements, customer switching costs, access to distribution channels, and government policy. The market entry decisions of 137 executives from 49 major U.S. corporations were modeled with a decision making instrument consisting of 32 market entry opportunities. Each respondent's decisions were modeled using regression analysis. The differences concerning the importance of the six market entry barriers for early and late entry into consumer, and industrial goods markets were investigated. The results indicate that marketing executives use all six barriers in making market entry decisions. The cost advantages of incumbents is considered to be the most important relative to other market entry barriers. Important differences were also discovered among the other five barriers. Furthermore, the importance of barriers also differs for entry into consumer versus industrial goods markets.
Chapter
A collection of research reports on policy issues involving telecommunications, particularly the Internet. Until the 1980s, it was presumed that technical change in most communications services could easily be monitored from centralized state and federal agencies. This presumption was long outdated prior to the commercialization of the Internet. With the Internet, the long-forecast convergence of voice, video, and text bits became a reality. Legislation, capped by the Telecommunications Act of 1996, created new quasi-standards such as "fair" and "reasonable" for the FCC and courts to apply, leading to nonstop litigation and occasional gridlock. This book addresses some of the many telecommunications areas on which public policy makers, corporate strategists, and social activists must reach agreement. Topics include the regulation of access, Internet architecture in a commercial era, communications infrastructure development, the Digital Divide, and information policy issues such as intellectual property and the retransmission of TV programming via the Internet.
Book
As the Internet revolution continues to unfold and transform telecommunications, pressure is building for faster, less expensive, and more widely accessible broadband service. Such a development would facilitate improved and less expensive traditional applications such as voice telephony and web browsing. It would also enable new and useful applications such as Internet-based television, videoconferencing, and software distribution. Broadband has great potential to improve efficiency and productivity, even to improve national security in some cases. Broadband service and affordability, however, have consistently lagged well behind demand and progress in information technology, with damaging results. The Internet revolution remains incomplete and threatens to stagnate if the situation continues. In The Broadband Problem, economist and technology entrepreneur Charles H. Ferguson explains the causes and ramifications of this damaging bottleneck, and he offers suggestions on improving the current state of affairs. He asserts that current telecommunications law and policy have not provided sufficient levels of new entry, competition, and innovation in the local telecom market. The continuing dominance of ILECs (incumbent local exchange carriers) in that market impedes the healthy, and much-needed, development of an efficient broadband market. The result of these policy and market failures is inadequate technological progress, innovation, and productivity in advanced Internet services and telecommunication services generally. The broadband problem is holding us back, and thus must be addressed and solved. With this important volume, Charles Ferguson has contributed mightily to that mission.
Article
We analyze the salient features of networks and point out the similarities between the economic structure of networks and the structure of vertically related industries. The analysis focuses on positive consumption and production externalities, commonly called network externalities. We discuss their sources and their effects on pricing and market structure. We distinguish between results that do not depend on the underlying industry microstructure (the macro approach) and those that do (the micro approach). We analyze the issues of compatibility, coordination to technical standards, interconnection and interoperability, and their effects on pricing and quality of services and on the value of network links in various ownership structures. We also briefly discuss the issue of interconnection fees for bottleneck.
Article
We investigate whether the presence of new competitors has influenced the behaviour of U.S. incumbent local exchange carriers (ILECs) with respect to pricing, advertising and the extent of diversification that they engage in. This issue is explored empirically, using data for the major local exchange carriers for the years 1994 to 1998. The period straddles periods of both absence and presence of competition in the industry, since the Telecommunications Act of 1996 has opened hitherto closed markets to competitive local exchange carriers (CLECs). While a recent Federal Communications Commission (FCC) report on local competition documents vigorous entry during the past years, the market share of the entrants is insubstantial. Our results indicate that the threat provided by market entrants has notably influenced the strategic behaviour of ILECs. The findings show that the incumbent U.S. local operators, particularly the larger ILECs, aggressively protect their profit streams from traditional business. The evidence demonstrates that the ILECs have responded to the Telecommunications Act 1996, and to the threat of market entry it has created, through entry deterrence. This strategic behaviour has been successful in providing ILECs with protection of their monopolistic markets so far.