ArticlePDF Available

Abstract and Figures

The study investigated the proposal by Duflo et al. (2009) that rural households may be stochastically present-biased and face small fixed costs in input markets, causing them to under-invest in inputs. Supply of inputs at harvest time may then lead to higher investments than when inputs are supplied at planting time. Investment in inputs at harvest time can potentially serve as a commitment device (DellaVigna 2009). Experiments were run at harvest time and planting time to assess how a given budget was allocated for inputs or for food. Households were found to be willing to spend a significantly higher proportion of a given budget on inputs at planting time than at harvest time. A large gap between WTP and WTA prices still supports that input sales at harvest time may enhance input investments.
Content may be subject to copyright.
1
Cash Constraints and Sticky Input Expenditures:
-Experimental Evidence from Malawi
By
Stein T. Holden and Rodney Lunduka
School of Economics and Business
Norwegian University of Life Sciences
P. O. Box 5033, 1432 Ås, Norway
Email: stein.holden@umb.no
Tel: +47-64965699
Fax: +47-64965701
Abstract
The study investigated the proposal by Duflo et al. (2009) that rural households may be
stochastically present-biased and face small fixed costs in input markets, causing them to under-
invest in inputs. Supply of inputs at harvest time may then lead to higher investments than when
inputs are supplied at planting time. Investment in inputs at harvest time can potentially serve as
a commitment device (DellaVigna 2009). Experiments were run at harvest time and planting
time to assess how a given budget was allocated for inputs or for food. Households were found to
be willing to spend a significantly higher proportion of a given budget on inputs at planting time
than at harvest time. A large gap between WTP and WTA prices still supports that input sales at
harvest time may enhance input investments.
Key words: Malawi, input subsidies, cash constraints, time inconsistency, input delivery timing.
JEL Classification codes: Q12, Q18
2
1.
Introduction
Malawi has implemented a large-scale agricultural input subsidy program since 2005 after a
period with severe food shortages and the program has contributed to increased food availability,
higher real wages, economic growth and poverty reduction (Dorward and Chirwa 2011). The
targeted input subsidy program distributes coupons (providing more than 90% subsidy in the
2008/09 season) to about two million of about two and a half million smallholder farm
households where priority should be given to poor and vulnerable households (Dorward et al.
2008; Ricker-Gilbert and Jayne 2008; 2009; MoAFS 2008).
Important reasons for the reintroduction of large-scale subsidies were that the inputs were not
affordable for the poor smallholder farmers and that it was cheaper to import fertilizer than to
import food. The fact that the country managed to quickly switch from being a “beggar for food”
to becoming a net exporter has also been very important for the national pride. While the
program contributed to national and household food security and maize export to neighboring
countries, the costs of the program also rose sharply with the increasing international fertilizer
and oil prices. The budgetary costs of the input subsidy program therefore increased from 50
million US$ in 2005/06 to 360 million US$ in 2008/09 or close to 15% of Malawi’s total
government expenditure. There is therefore a need to reduce the costs of the program without
reducing the food production. This paper investigates one possible approach to reducing such
costs without affecting the food production negatively.
An important reason for advocacy of fertilizer subsidies is that rural households in Malawi are
very poor and typically lack cash resources to buy profitable inputs and this causes too low input
use. Poverty in combination with liquidity constraints may cause high discount rates and this
may lead to low investment (Holden et al. 1998). Time inconsistent behavior in form of present
3
bias has been observed in many social experiments and may also contribute to explain low input
use and investment levels in developing countries (Duflo et al. 2009).
The seasonality of rain-fed agricultural production which dominates in Malawi make food
shortages seasonal and food has to be stored from one harvest season and up to the next harvest
season. More than 60% of the rural households in Malawi are still net buyers of maize (the main
staple food) after the introduction of the subsidy program. At planting time they may face a
dilemma between using scarce cash resources to buy food to meet more immediate needs or to
buy inputs to meet next year’s needs. Time inconsistent behavior may then cause too low
investment in inputs. The two standard approaches to deal with this problem have been to
provide credit for input purchase or to subsidize the inputs. Input credit programs have had
greater success in reaching net sellers than net buyers of agricultural outputs, however, as
payback has often been in form of production output. Input credit programs have also faced large
moral hazard problems contributing to high default rates and covariate risk has made it hard to
sustain such programs in environments with substantial weather risk.
Use of subsidies could then be a way of internalizing the externality related to sub-optimal input
use and such subsidies could enhance both productivity and equity. One may, however, question
whether such subsidies are the most appropriate and cost-effective instrument to address this
market failure. Duflo et al. (2009), based on a study and social experiments in Kenya, found that
poor households are willing to invest in response to small, time-limited discounts in form of free
delivery of fertilizer just after harvest. Their finding may indicate that distribution and selling of
fertilizer just after harvest can be a better system than selling fertilizers at planting time when
households may no longer have sufficient cash from the selling of their harvest. Buying of inputs
at harvesting time for the next growing season may then serve as an commitment device
4
(DellaVigna 2009) and reduce the need for subsidies. It could also reduce the pressure on the
input delivery system at planting time and reduce to risks of too late delivery of inputs with
subsequent productivity losses.
This study investigates the willingness of rural households in Malawi to allocate funds for input
purchase at harvest time and whether this willingness is as high or higher at harvest time than at
planting time. Rural households do not face food shortages at harvest time and may then be more
willing and able to spend funds on inputs. On the other hand, net buyers of food may still prefer
to buy additional food at harvest time when food prices are at their lowest. More than 60% of
rural households in Malawi are net buyers of food also after the input subsidy program has been
implemented (Holden and Lunduka 2010a). It is therefore not obvious that the willingness to buy
inputs at harvest time is high or higher than at planting time.
There may be reasons to worry that the large scale input subsidy program in Malawi has
undermined household incentives to spend funds on inputs. On the other hand, access to
subsidized inputs is constrained and the subsidized prices therefore do not reflect the true shadow
prices of inputs for the households. A novel contribution of this paper was to use an experimental
approach to elicit shadow prices for fertilizers in a context where actual prices paid were
endogenous and dependent on unobservable household characteristics.
Cash constraints may limit the ability of households to purchase inputs. The experiments were
designed to control for this to obtain estimates of marginal expenditure shares and unconstrained
shadow prices for fertilizer inputs. In addition an experiment was conducted to assess the gap
between WTP and WTA prices for an input package where this gap could be assessed.
5
The results showed that households were willing to allocate a significantly larger share of the
given budget to fertilizer purchase and a significantly lower share to food purchase at planting
time than at harvesting time. Households had high WTP prices for fertilizer when relieved from
their cash constraint. Only 20-25% of the households were willing to buy the input package at
the commercial price while only 10-20% of households who were lucky to win the input package
were willing to resell the package at the commercial price if it first were given to them. The gap
may be explained as a cash constraint rather than as an “endowment effect” (Plott and Zeiler
2005; 2007; Horowitz and McConnel 2002).
The paper is organized as follows. Part 2 gives an overview of the setting with the input subsidy
program. Part 3 presents a theoretical framework followed by a description of the experimental
approach in part 4. The results are presented and discussed in part 5, followed by the
conclusions.
2. The setting
Malawi is a small landlocked country in Southern Africa where more than 80% of the
households depend on agriculture for their livelihood. Weather risk and bad policies have
contributed to severe household and national food insecurity. The last severe food shortages
occurred in 2004/05 with the consequence that the newly elected president, Bingu wa Mutharika,
embarked upon a comprehensive input subsidy program quite contradictory to the
recommendations from IMF and the World Bank. Arguments for the subsidy program were that
it is cheaper to import fertilizer than to import food. Food production in the country increased
dramatically and Malawi became a net exporter of food (maize) in the following years and the
program has been coined a success story (Denning et al. 2009).
6
The rural population in Malawi constitutes 88% of the total population and the country has one
of the highest rural population densities in Africa of about 2.3 persons per ha. The average farm
size is about 1.12ha. Farm sizes are smaller in the southern region of the country where
population density is higher (SOAS 2008). The incidence of poverty is also higher in the
southern region where 64% of the households are estimated to fall below the poverty line against
52% at the national level. Maize is the main staple crop grown by 97% of the rural households
(SOAS 2008). Some households also grow cash crops such as tobacco, sugarcane and cotton but
such crops are on average grown on less than 10% of the farm area while maize covers 65-70%
of the farm area (Holden and Lunduka 2010a).
More than 60% of the rural households in the central and southern regions of the country are net
buyers of maize even with the input subsidy program (Holden and Lunduka 2010b). Access to
input subsidies has, however, reduced the food deficit of net buyers of food and more households
have become self-sufficient or even net sellers (ibid.). Most of the agricultural production is
rain-fed and the rainfall is uni-modal with a rainy season from December to April. This implies
that the planting season is in December and harvesting season is in May-June for the main staple
crop, maize.
The Government of Malawi has increased its budget share for agriculture from 6.1% in the
period 200-2005 to 15.9% in 2006-2009 and is aiming to increase it further to 24% by 2015 with
the implementation of the Agricultural Sector Wide Approach (ASWAp) (GoM 2010).
The Ministry of Agriculture and Food Security (MoAFS) in Malawi has developed targeting
criteria for the distribution of input subsidies that emphasize targeting land-owning rural resident
households and particularly poor and vulnerable households (MoAFS, 2008). The MoAFS is
7
issuing and distributing free coupons through their local staff in collaboration with local leaders
to identified beneficiary households. Households receiving the coupons can take the coupon to
the nearest depot where inputs are sold and pay a small amount (MK
1
500 per 50 kg bag in the
2009/10 season) to get the inputs. In the 2008/09 season about 2 million input packages were
distributed to the about 2.5 million rural households in the country, indicating coverage of close
to 80% of the households. A recent study (Holden and Lunduka 2010a) has identified substantial
leakages of coupons, secondary markets for coupons and cheap fertilizers, and substantial
targeting errors. Access to inputs and the actual prices paid therefore depend on household
characteristics, including households’ social capital in terms of social networks, access to
information and ability to negotiate. Wealthier households have been found to be more
successful while female-headed households have been less successful in obtaining subsidized
inputs (Dorward et al. 2008; Holden and Lunduka 2010a).
The costs of fertilizer subsidies to the Malawian government have increased with the increase in
international fertilizer prices. In 2006/07 the fertilizers represented 40% of the agricultural
budget (Dorward et al., 2008). With the very high fertilizer prices in 2008/09 the spending on
fertilizer imports and the fertilizer subsidy program exceeded the initial budget by more than
100% (Logistic Unit, 2009). Table 1 gives an overview of the costs of the input subsidy program
versus some benchmarks. After the 2008/09 the country has experienced shortages of foreign
exchange which also have lead to fuel shortages. Tobacco is the main export crop but tobacco
export is also limited by international agreements. Maize exports have to some extent
compensated for the fertilizer import cost.
1
1 US$=140 Malawi Kwacha(MK).
8
Table 1. Costs of the Farm Input Subsidy Program
Year Costs (million US$)
Cost of importing food in drought year 2004/05
110
Cost of fertilizer subsidy program 2005/06
50
Cost of fertilizer subsidy program 2006/07
91
Cost of fertilizer subsidy program 2008/09
360
Total donor assistance to Malawi 2007 500
Sources: Harrigan 2005; Dorward et al. 2008; Denning et al. 2009; Logistic Unit 2009.
The donor community sees the input subsidy program as a temporary solution to the food
insecurity problems of the country and provides conditional support to the program as general
budget support or through funding of particular elements of the program such as the seed
component.
Malawi’s president argues that the subsidies have come to stay and has become the chairman of
the African Union and other African countries are looking to Malawi and consider implementing
similar policies. International fertilizer prices are again on the increase, however, and there is a
need to keep the budgetary costs down. The main argument for the program is that rural
households cannot afford to buy the inputs if they are not subsidized and their removal will lead
to new food shortages. Provision of credit has been an alternative approach that also has given
mixed results due to high default rates. It is in this perspective that this study explores the
alternative proposal to sell inputs at harvest time to reduce the need for subsidies and provide a
commitment devise that can reduce the need for credit as well.
9
3. Theoretical framework
Duflo et al. (2008) found that small investments in fertilizers generated returns of 36 percent on a
seasonal basis equivalent to 70 percent per year without changes in additional practices in a
study in Kenya. They were puzzled that farmers invested so little in fertilizers when profits were
so large and the technology is well known and divisible. One possible explanation could be fixed
costs related to buying and learning about the technology but they found that these could not be
large enough to provide an explanation. They therefore looked for a behavioral explanation in
form of present-bias such as has been observed also in relation to investments in pension plans in
the United States (Choi et al. 2008) and drew on models of procrastination in psychology and
economics. Strong presence bias has been observed among poor rural households in developing
countries and is related to liquidity constraints and poverty (Holden et al. 1998). Empirical
evidence shows that the discounted utility model (Samuelson 1937) represents a poor fit to the
reality of inter-temporal choices (Frederick et al. 2002).
Laibson (1997) and O’Donoghue and Rabin (1999) have formulated an alternative
( , )
β δ
preference model
1)
2 3
1 2 3
....
t t t t t
U u u u u
βδ βδ βδ
+ + +
= + + + +
where the difference from the standard discounted utility model is the parameter β≤1 which
captures self-control problems. The model has also been expanded by O’Donoghue and Rabin
(2001) to handle naïve expectations (overconfidence) related to future self-control.
We take this alternative
( , )
β δ
preference model as a basis for analyzing behavior of poor rural
producer-consumer households who make consumption and investment decisions facing cash
constraints and imperfections in factor markets. Self-control problems could cause the timing of
10
offering of investment opportunities to rural households to matter for how much they are willing
to invest, like suggested by Duflo et al.(2008). This could cause households to be willing to
invest more if offered to buy inputs at harvest time rather than waiting and offering them to buy
the inputs at planting time when the inputs are to be used but when also more of the cash
resources have been spent on other items. Purchase of inputs at harvest time may be a self-
control device leading to higher investments.
The model covers three points in time, first harvest time (t=1), planting time (t=2), and second
harvest time (t=3). Households are offered to allocate a fixed budget, Y, for food consumption, C,
input investments, F, or other goods expenditure, X, such that Y=C+F+X. This offer is made
either at harvest time (t=1) or at planting time (t=2) and the budget offered at the two points in
time is the same, Y
1
=Y
2
. For a household i that receives the offer at harvest time (t=1), it will
allocate the budget as Y
1
=C
1
+F
1
+X
1
such that it maximizes expected utility. Producer-consumer
households do not have an immediate need for food at harvest time. If they prefer to spend extra
funds on food at this point in time it is done in order to save the food and consume it later, e.g. at
planting time. With
( , )
β δ
preferences, the expected utility of the food expenditure at first
harvest time (t=1) may be formulated as:
1 1 1
2
( ) ( )
U C u C
βδ
=
. On the other hand, if the offer is
made at planting time, food expenditure may be for immediate consumption and the utility may
be formulated as:
2
( ) ( )
U C u C
=
. The expected utility of the allocation of the budget for
inputs when the offer is made at harvest time (t=1) and when inputs only can be used in the
following planting time and yield benefits after the next harvest time (t=3), can be formulated as:
(
)
{
}
1 1 2 1
3
( ) 1
F
U F u r F
βδ
= + where r
F
is the expected return to input investment. When the
11
budget offer is made at planting time the expected utility may be formulated as:
(
)
{
}
2 2 2
3
( ) 1
F
U F u r F
βδ
= + . Optimal budget allocations at the two points in time imply:
2)
1 1 1 1 2 2 2 2
1 1 2 2
( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
and
U C U F U C U F
Y Y Y Y
= =
Substituting in the expected utilities with
( , )
β δ
preferences yields
(
)
{
}
2 1
13
2
1 1
1
( )
which reduces to
F
u r F
u C
Y Y
βδ
βδ
+
=
3)
(
)
{
}
1
13
2
1 1
1
( )
F
u r F
u C
Y Y
δ
+
=
for harvest time budget allocation decisions and to
4)
(
)
{
}
2
23
2
2 2
1
( )
F
u r F
u C
Y Y
βδ
+
=
for planting time budget allocation decisions.
It follows that, ceteris paribus,
1 2 1 2
and if 1
C C F F
β
< > <
. Offering of inputs at harvest time
may then be a commitment devise that enhances input expenditure and use.
But what if food prices vary systematically across seasons and typically are much lower at
harvest time than at planting time such that
1 2
p p
<
? We then get
5)
(
)
{
}
1
1 1 3
2
1 1
1
( )
F
u r F
u p C
Y Y
δ
+
=
12
6)
(
)
{
}
2
2 2 3
2
2 2
1
( )
F
u r F
u p C
Y Y
βδ
+
=
It then follows that
1
1 2 1 2
2
and only if
p
C C F F
p
β
< > <
and households with rational price
expectations will allocate more of a given budget for inputs relative to food at planting time than
at harvest time when
1
2
< 1
p
p
β
.
Transaction costs in commodity markets cause selling prices to be lower than buying prices and
this is likely to be the case both for food and inputs. However, transaction costs are typically
relatively larger in input markets than in food markets (Binswanger and Rosenzweig 1986).
Rural households are therefore likely to be hesitant to sell inputs and food that they have bought
and they are not likely to do so unless they have been exposed to some form of shock because
7)
(
)
{
}
1
1
1 1 32
2
1 1 1
1
( )
( )
F
Fs
u r F
u p F
u p C
Y Y Y
δ
+
= >
where
Fs Fb
p p
<and represent the selling and buying prices of inputs. Such a gap between selling
and buying prices is sufficient for input expenditures to be “sticky”. This could also facilitate
higher input investments if inputs are offered at harvesting time when food prices are lower than
if inputs only are offered at planting time when also the available cash budget may have become
lower,
2 1
Y Y
<
. A severe shock may, however, destabilize the inter-temporal balance and cause
households to resell the inputs at a lower price. The risk that they would do so depends on how
the shock would affect a number of the parameters that become household-specific in the
reformulated model:
13
8)
(
)
{
}
1
1 1 3
2
1 1
1
( )
F
i i i
i
u r F
u p C
Y Y
δ
+
=
9)
(
)
{
}
2
2 2 3
2
2 2
1
( )
F
i i i i
i
u r F
u p C
Y Y
β δ
+
=
This implies that the discount factor,
i
δ
, the expected return to inputs,
F
i
r
, and the present bias
parameter,
i
β
, are household specific and may be affected by shocks. Shocks may cause the
discount rate and the present bias parameter to increase and the expected return to inputs to
decrease. A possible consequence of a shock could then be distress sales of assets or inputs that
were bought at harvest time and before the shock occurred and this may further affect expected
returns.
The discount rate, the present bias parameter and the expected return functions cannot be directly
observed but experiments are constructed to assess the existence of presence bias and whether
this can be utilized to design a commitment device something which also depends on the
transaction costs in the input market. It is commonly assumed that poor people have high
discount rates and have a tendency towards stronger present bias and are more vulnerability to
shocks and empirical evidence is also in line with this (Holden et al. 1998). Wealth accumulation
substitutes for missing markets and alleviates constraint sets (Yesuf and Bluffstone 2009). This
implies that risk aversion that is related to wealth also can affect input decisions as poorer
households tend to be more risk averse and less able and willing to go for risky investments.
Loss aversion may also cause households to be willing to take less risk when they face a
downside risk versus a situation where they do not face such downside risk (Binswanger 1980;
Wik et al. 2004; Yesuf and Bluffstone 2009). Risk and risk aversion may therefore also affect
14
input demand and the responses in our experiments but this was not directly tested in our
experiments. It could, however, be an interesting area for follow up research.
4. Experimental methods and data
The survey covered a random sample of 450 households in two districts in Central Malawi
(Kasungu and Lilongwe) and four districts in Southern Malawi (Chiradzulu, Machinga, Thyolo,
and Zomba) (Lunduka, 2010). About 89% of the Malawian population lives in Central and
Southern Malawi. Our survey should therefore be fairly representative of a large share of the
population. The data were collected in three rounds, in 2006, 2007 and 2009. Only 378 of the
initial 450 households were found and interviewed in the third round. The experiments were
added to the survey instrument in the 2009 survey round.
The budget allocation experiment was hypothetical. The households were asked to allocate a
cash amount of MK 10 000
2
that they were free to decide on how to use among a) buying
fertilizer, b) buying food, c) buying other important/urgent commodities, d) investing or saving
for later use. The households were exposed to this experiment either at harvest time (June) or at
planting time (December) for a part of the sample.
A real experiment was conducted where the households had the choice between 5 kg (1/10
th
of a
bag) basal fertilizer and a varying amount of money determined by the throw of a dice. The
amount of money varied between MK 200 and 1500. These amounts range from 50 to 375
percent of the commercial price of fertilizer at the time of the experiments.
The next experiment involved randomly allocating the households with an input package for
maize production consisting of one bag of basal fertilizer, one bag of urea, and one bag of hybrid
2
The daily wage in unskilled rural employment was about MK 300 at the time of the survey. An input package of 2
bags of fertilizer and seeds costed about MK 9 000.
15
maize seeds, or if they were not lucky to “win” the package, they were offered the opportunity to
buy the same package. The allocation of the package for free was determined by the toss of a
coin. The lucky winners were then offered the possibility of reselling the package at an amount
determined by throwing a dice. Similarly, those that were not lucky were offered to buy the
package at an amount determined by throwing the dice. The price range for the package was
from MK1000 (full subsidy) to MK9000 (no subsidy) based on the price and subsidy rates
decided by the Malawian government for the 2009/10 growing season. The experiment should
establish whether there is a gap between WTP and WTA prices when households’ cash
constraints are affecting the WTP prices unlike in the real experiment where the households had
the choice between 5 kg fertilizer and a randomized amount of cash. However, the cash
constraint effect may be confounded with an “endowment effect” such that we have to be careful
with the interpretation here (Plott and Zeiler, 2005; 2007; Horowitz and McConnell, 2002). In
any case the experiment investigates the incentives to resell an input package when prices are
known and exogenously given. A gap between WTA and WTP prices implies a lower probability
that inputs are resold when they first have been acquired.
To assess factors affecting budget allocation priorities Tobit models were used because there
were substantial number of zero responses for each commodity (demands for fertilizer and food).
To further investigate factors that affect households’ choices between cash and fertilizer the data
from the price experiment were regressed on household characteristics, and geographical
location (district). Random effects logit models were used for this. Similar econometric analysis
was also made for the WTA and WTP for the input package.
16
5. Experimental results and discussion
The basic findings from the experiments are presented in this section. In the hypothetical budget
allocation experiment households were asked how they would allocate a cash amount of MK
10 000 that they were free to decide on how to use among; a) buying fertilizer; b) buying food;
c) buying other important/urgent commodities; and d) saving and investing in business.
Summary statistics by type of expenditure and time of the experiment are summarized in Table
2. It can be seen that the allocation for fertilizer was significantly higher at planting time than at
harvest time while the opposite was the case for food. Econometric analyses of the determinants
of household allocation for fertilizers and food are analyzed with Tobit models with district fixed
and random effects in Table 3 below.
We see also from the regression analyses in Table 3 that the willingness to allocate money for
fertilizer out of a given budget in December (planting time) was significantly higher than at
harvest time in June-July. The difference was a large as about 30% of the total budget. The
willingness to allocate money for food was significantly lower at planting time in December than
at harvest time in June-July. This could be because food prices are lower at harvest time than at
planting time.
Significant wealth effects are also observed. Households with better quality houses and higher
asset values allocated significantly more cash for fertilizer. This is in line with the general theory
that poverty can reduce the willingness and ability to invest and result in higher discount rates as
immediate needs are given higher priority. There was a weak indication that households with
smaller farm sizes were willing to allocate a larger share of the budget for fertilizers as farm size
was negative and significant at 10% level in one of the models. Land shortage may increase the
need to intensify farm production by use of more fertilizer.
17
Table 2. Allocation of a budget of MK10000 by type of expenditure and time of experiment
Time of experiment
Fertilizer
Food
Other needs
Save-Invest
Harvest time Mean 4295 2453 1660 1592
Standard error
175 128 113 133
Sample size 280 280 280 280
Planting time Mean 6563 1510 1296 630
Standard error
368 246 233 161
Sample size 79 79 79 79
18
Table 3. Determinants of preferences for cash allocation for fertilizer versus for food
purchase
Fertilizer Fertilizer Food Food
Tobit FE Tobit RE Tobit FE Tobit RE
Sex of household head -764.337 -687.772 467.864 325.096
1=Male (466.93) (471.07) (442.62) (435.59)
Age of household head 5.155 3.255 16.786 20.124*
(12.74) (12.87) (11.77) (11.67)
Education of household head
-3.978 -13.579 75.582 90.943*
(55.38) (56.00) (51.82) (51.22)
Male labor force -5.402 -2.376 143.88 131.412
(184.27) (185.98) (173.54) (174.03)
Female labor force -288.516 -271.198 258.526 237.836
(259.15) (261.42) (240.79) (240.66)
Number of children 36.521 25.317 -25.654 -3.996
(125.88) (127.07) (118.02) (117.92)
Quality of house 189.232*** 171.256** -110.244* -87.779
(71.51) (71.65) (66.8) (63.42)
Value of assets 0.024* 0.025** -0.02 -0.023*
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Tropical livestock units 153.458 154.448 -179.843 -172.627
(134.68) (135.56) (137.46) (136.11)
Farm size, ha -355.437* -333.911 -2.137 -38.862
(207.91) (209.07) (207.46) (205.57)
19
Planting time sample 3158.241** 2973.820**** -703.682 -1506.842****
(1264.25) (810.56) (1183.85) -438.66
Zomba 393.888 105.355
(601.16) (550.8)
Chiradzulu 258.717 174.888
(728.75) (668.59)
Machinga 786.018 -19.367
(710.67) (650.58)
Kasungu 577.093 -987.958
(1324.12) (1231.86)
Lilongwe 2688.630**** -755.839
(630.03) (588.18)
Constant 2237.240** 3284.361*** 1321.053 881.817
(1099.29) (1062.01) (1017.71) (909.9)
Sigma_u 772.114*** 0.000
Constant (293.77) (251.36)
Sigma_e 3118.604**** 3149.101**** 2823.361****
2838.961****
Constant (130.97) (133.43) (139.62) (140.45)
Prob > chi2 0.000 0.002 0.010 0.004
Number of observations 344 344 344 344
Left censored observations 41 41 107 107
Note: Standard errors in parentheses. Significance levels: *:10%, **:5%, ***:1%, ****:0.1%. Models with district fixed effects and random
effects.
We may ask whether the lower willingness to spend the given budget on fertilizer at harvest time
than at planting time could be due to the lower food prices at harvest time. While we cannot test
20
this directly, we have assessed the food prices at harvest time vs. at planting time in the previous
two years as price expectations may be formed on the basis of these relative price changes. The
prices are summarized in Table 4.
Table 4. Average monthly maize prices at harvest time and planting time by year
Month 2007 2008
June (Harvest time) 14.55 37.91
December (Planting time) 30.01 63.35
Source: MoAFS (2009)
It can be seen that maize prices were much higher (near double) at planting time as compared to
at harvest time. This should give a good reason for net buyers of food to buy the additional maize
requirement at harvest time rather than later and this effect dominates the eventual effect of
present bias causing low fertilizer demand at planting time.
The results from the real experiment for the choice between 5 kg fertilizer and randomized
amounts of cash varying between MK 200 and 1500 are summarized in Figure 1 and Table 5.
We see that the preference for fertilizer was reduced from above 90 percent for the two lowest
amounts of money to about 40 percent for the two highest amounts of money where we recall
that the highest price is 375% of the commercial price of fertilizer at the time of the experiment.
This illustrates that there is a substantial demand for small amounts of fertilizer among many
households where they are willing to forsake cash that they have available. The input subsidy
program appears not to have undermined the valuation of these inputs. The high prices also
indicate that few households are willing to resell inputs unless the price offered is raised high
above the commercial price for fertilizer. The results may also indicate that input demand could
21
be stimulated by offering fertilizers in smaller bags than the standard 50 kg bags. Repacking and
selling in small bags could potentially be a lucrative business.
The logit model (Table 5) assessing the factors correlated with the choices in the real experiment
revealed that households with more male labor force and higher asset endowment and smaller
farm size were significantly more likely to prefer fertilizer rather than cash, ceteris paribus. This
indicates that poverty in labor and assets reduces the shadow price of fertilizer while land
scarcity increases the shadow price of fertilizer. Offering the experiment at planting time rather
than at harvest time also increased the probability that households preferred fertilizer rather than
cash. This is consistent with the finding in the hypothetical budget allocation experiment.
Figure 1. Choice experiment between receiving 5 kg basal fertilizer and a varying amount
of cash.
0
20
40
60
80
100
120
200
400
600
900
1200
1500
Percentage prefering fertilizer to amount of
money in MK
22
Table 5. Real experiment for choice between 5 kg basal fertilizer and a random amount of
cash
Real experiment
Cash amount offered -0.003****
(0.0003)
Sex of household head -0.139
1=Male, 0=Female (0.380)
Age of household head 0.0001
(0.010)
Education of household head
-0.042
(0.050)
Male labor force 0.291*
(0.150)
Female labor force -0.129
(0.230)
Number of children -0.123
(0.100)
Quality of house 0.024
(0.060)
Value of assets 0.00004***
(0.000015)
Tropical livestock units 0.116
(0.090)
23
Farm size, ha -0.301**
(0.140)
Planting time dummy 1.387**
(0.670)
District dummies:
Zomba 1.503***
(0.550)
Chiradzulu 0.710
(0.570)
Machinga -0.255
(0.560)
Kasungu -0.191
(0.710)
Lilongwe 0.178
(0.510)
Constant 2.980****
(0.880)
Prob > chi2 0.000
Number of observations 341
Note: Standard errors in parentheses. Significance levels: *:10%, **:5%, ***:1%, ****:0.1%.
The next experiment involved randomly allocating the households with an input package for
maize production consisting of one bag of basal fertilizer, one bag of urea (top dressing), and one
bag of hybrid maize seeds, or if they were not lucky to “win” the package, they were offered the
24
opportunity to buy the same package. The allocation of the package for free was determined by
the toss of a coin. The lucky winners were then offered the possibility of selling the package at
an amount determined by throwing a dice. The fitted values of the responses, with a 95%
confidence interval, are presented as the upper line in Figure 2. The unlucky ones were offered to
buy the package at an amount also determined by throwing a dice. The fitted responses to this
offer with a 95% confidence interval are presented in Figure 2 (the lower line). The y-axis
indicates the probability that respondents prefer the package to the cash amount offered. The
cash amounts varied according to the scale on the x-axis, from MK1000 (full subsidy) to MK
9000 (no subsidy).
Figure 2 demonstrates that very few were willing to sell the package even at the highest amount
of money offered which was equivalent to the commercial price of the inputs. This also indicates
that households value the input package highly. Figure 2, however, also demonstrates that many
households face problems buying such an input package due to their cash constraints and only
slightly above 20 percent were willing to buy the package at the full commercial price and only
about 50 percent were willing to buy it at a 50 percent level of subsidy (half price). Although the
difference between the WTA and WTP responses could partly be due to the “endowment effect”,
the responses in the real experiment with fertilizer should not create such an endowment effect as
households were offered the choice between cash or fertilizer without being given any of these
first. Their response probabilities were close to those in the WTA experiment for those who had
been endowed with the input package for prices close to the commercial price of fertilizer. This
should indicate that the gap between the lines in Figure 2 primarily is due to a cash constraint
effect. The confidence intervals in the graph demonstrate the significance of the difference
between the WTA and WTP prices.
25
Figure 2. Ratio preferring input package to cash in WTA (upper line) and WTP (bottom
line) experiments with varying cash amounts (MK).
Conclusion
Overall this study revealed that rural Malawian households value fertilizers highly even though
they have been exposed to very high fertilizer subsidies over several years. More than 50 percent
of the households preferred small amounts of fertilizer to a cash amount that was 50 percent
higher than the current commercial price for fertilizer during our experiments carried out in
2009. Access constraints for commercial as well as subsidized fertilizer may explain these
remarkably high shadow prices together with the nature of these experiments which were
designed to avoid a direct effect of households’ cash constraint.
0 .5 1
0 2000 4000 6000 8000 10000
95% CI Fitted values
Fitted values
26
The study tested out Duflo et al.’s (2009) proposal to stimulate input demand by supplying inputs
at harvest time rather than at planting time. A hypothetical budget allocation experiment revealed
that households were willing to allocate about 40 percent of a cash budget of MK10000 for
fertilizer at harvest time while this budget share increased to about 60 percent at planting time. A
real choice experiment between cash and fertilizer revealed a significantly higher share of
households preferring fertilizer to cash at given prices at planting time than at harvest time. This
may imply that the price difference effect due to lower food price at harvest time than at planting
time dominates over the potential present bias effect.
However, the facts that households were willing to allocate a substantial budget share to input
purchase at harvest time and were not likely to resell these inputs later, point in direction of a
potential positive effect of this approach on input demand especially if or when the input subsidy
program has to be scaled down.
On the other hand, when households were offered a full input package consisting of two bags of
fertilizer and a bag of hybrid seeds, the share of households preferring the input package rather
than the cash amount declined to 22 percent when the WTP price increased to MK9000,
equivalent to the commercial price of the package. This demonstrates the significance of the cash
constraint that households face. When households who have been offered the same package for
free were asked about their WTA selling price, more than 80 percent of the households preferred
to keep the package even when they were offered a WTA price of MK9000, equivalent to the
commercial price. This fits well with the finding of Holden and Lunduka (2010) who found that
a very small share of the households that were given subsidized fertilizers resold these inputs in
the informal market. This implies that such input expenditures are “sticky” and sale of inputs at
harvest time may serve as a commitment device (DellaVigna, 2009).
27
Due to high international fertilizer and oil prices which recently have contributed to fuel and
foreign exchange shortages, Malawi may face problems sustaining the input subsidy program
even though it has contributed substantially to improve national and household food security. An
advantage of distributing inputs at harvest time is also that the same trucks that collect the maize
can at the same time bring out the inputs and thus save on the transportation costs. One would
also reduce the credit default problems that are linked to supplying inputs on credit at planting
time.
Acknowledgements
We acknowledge valuable comments from Kjell Arne Brekke, Erik Sørensen and participants at
the Norwegian Economists’ Annual Conference in Bergen January 2011. Remaining errors are
our own. We acknowledge funding of this project through the NOMA MSc-program and
valuable efforts of students and enumerators during the fieldwork and data cleaning. The project
has also been supported and funded by the Embassy of Norway and NORAD.
References
Binswanger, H. P. And M. R. Rosenzweig (1986). Behavioural and Material Determinants of
Production Relations in Agriculture. J. Dev. Stud. 22, 503-539.
Choi, J., D. Laibson and B. Madrian (2008). $100 Bills on the Sidewalk: Suboptimal Investment
in 401(k) Plans. NBER Working Paper No. 11554.
DellaVigna, S. (2009). Psychology and Economics: Evidence from the Field. J. Econ. Lit. 47(2),
315–372.
28
Denning, G., P. Kabembe, P. Sanchez, A. Malik, R. Flor, R. Harawa, P. Nkhoma, C. Zamba, C.
Banda, C. Magombo, M. Keating, J. Wangila, and J. Sachs (2009). Input Subsdies to Improve
Smallholder Maize Productivity in Malawi: Toward an African Green Revolution. Plos Biology
7, 1. www.plosbiology.org
Dorward, A., E. Chirwa, V. Kelly, T. Jayne, R. Slater, and D. Boughton (2008). Evaluation of
the 2006/07 Agricultural Input Subsidy Programme, Malawi. Final Report. Study undertaken for
the Ministry of Agriculture and Food Security, Malawi, DFID, USAID and Future Agricultures
Consortium.
Duflo, E., M. Kremer and J. Robinson (2008). How High are Rates of Return to Fertilizer?
Evidence from Field Experiments in Kenya. Am. Econ. Rev. Papers (Papers and Proceedings
Issue) 98 (2): 482–488.
Duflo, E., M. Kremer and J. Robinson (2009). Nudging Farmers to Use Fertilizer: Theory and
Experimental Evidence from Kenya. NBER Working Paper No. w15131.
Frederick, S., G. Loewenstein and T. O'Donoghue (2002). Time Discounting and Time
Preference: A Critical Review. J. Econ. Lit. 40 (2), 351-401.
Government of Malawi (2010). Malawi CAADP Post Compact Review. Country Technical
Review Report. Lilongwe.
29
Harrigan, J. (2005). Food Security Policies and Starter Pack: a Challenge for Donors? In S. Levy
(ed.) Starter Packs: A Strategy to Fight Hunger in Developing Countries? CABI Publishing,
Wallingford.
Holden, S. T. and Lunduka, R. (2010a). Too Poor to be Efficient? Impacts of the Targeted
Fertilizer Subsidy Program in Malawi on Farm Plot Level Input Use, Crop Choice and Land
Productivity. Report to NORAD. Noragric Report No.55, Norwegian University of Life
Sciences, Ås.
Holden, S. T. and Lunduka, R. (2010b). The Political Economy of Input Subsidies in Malawi:
Targeting Efficiency and Household Perceptions. Paper presented at the NFU-conference, Oslo,
25-26. November, 2010.
Holden, S. T., Shiferaw, B. and Wik, M.(1998). Poverty, Market Imperfections, and Time
Preferences: Of Relevance for Environmental Policy? Env. & Dev. Econ. 3, 105-130.
Horowitz, J. K. and K. E. McConnell (2002). A Review of WTA/WTP Studies. J. Env. Econ.&
Mgmt. 44, 426-447.
Laibson, D. (1997). Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting. Q. J. Econ. 112 (2), 443-477.
Logistic Unit (2009). Final Report. Implementation of Agricultural Input Subsidy Programme
2008/09. Logistic Unit, April 2009.
30
Lunduka, R. (2010). Land Rental Markets, Investment and productivity under customary land
tenure systems in Malawi. Unpublished PhD-dissertation, Department of Economics and
Resource Management, Norwegian University of Life Sciences, Ås, Norway.
O’Donoghue, T. and M. Rabin (1999). Doing It Now or Later. Am. Econ. Rev. 89 (1), 103-124.
O’Donoghue, T. and M. Rabin (2001). Choice and Procrastination. Q. J. Econ. 116 (1), 121-160.
Plott, C. R. and K. Zeiler (2005). The Willingness to Pay-Willingness to Accept Gap, the
“Endowment Effect,” Subject Misconceptions, and Experimental Procedures for Eliciting
Valuations. Am. Econ. Rev. 95(3), 530-545.
Plott, C. R. and K. Zeiler (2007). Exchange Asymmetries Incorrectly Interpreted as Evidence of
Endowment Effect Theory and Prospect Theory? Am. Econ. Rev. 97(4), 1449-1466.
Ricker-Gilbert, J. and T. S. Jayne (2008). The Impact of Fertilizer Subsidies on National
Fertilizer Use: An Example from Malawi. Paper presented at the American Agricultural
Economics Association Annual Meeting, Orlando, July 27-29, 2008.
Ricker-Gilbert, J. and T. S. Jayne (2009). Do Fertilizer Subsidies Affect the Demand for
Commercial Fertilizer? An Example from Malawi. Contributed Paper presented at the
International Association of Agricultural Economists Conference, Beijing, China, August 16-22,
2009.
Samuelson, P. (1937). A note on measurement of utility. Rev. Econ. Stud. 4, 155-161.
31
School of Oriental and African Studies (SOAS), Wadonda Consult, Overseas Development
Institute and Michigan State University (2008). Evaluation of the 2006/7 Agricultural Input
Supply Programme, Malawi: Final Report. London, School of Oriental and African Studies;
March 2008.
Wik, M., Aragie, T. K., Bergland, O. and Holden, S. T. (2004). On the Measurement of Risk
Aversion from Experimental Data. Applied Econ. 36, 2443-2451.
Yesuf, M. and R. A. Bluffstone (2009). Poverty, Risk aversion, and Path Dependence in Low-
income Countries: Experimental Evidence from Ethiopia. Am. J. Ag. Econ. 91(4), 1022-1037.
... Farmers who produce less food than what they consume (net buyers) make up 50% or more of total farm families in Africa (Dorward, Chirwa, & Poulton, 2008). Although agriculture growth has improved, more than 60% of rural households in Malawi are net buyers of food (Ellis & Manda, 2012;Holden & Lunduka, 2011). Thus regardless of the many social protection programs and policies that have of late been implemented in Malawi they have not reduced vulnerability, suggesting a systemic policy implementation failure . ...
... Malawian agriculture is predominantly rain-fed and provides 90% of the staple food maize (Cooper et al., 2008;Jayanthi et al., 2013). The rainfall is unimodal, from early December to early April, and rain-fed maize occupies 52% of cropped area (Holden & Lunduka, 2011;Smale, Heisey, & Leathers, 1995). Climate variability has brought with it new challenges including shifts in seasons, long dry spells, droughts and floods (Cooper et al., 2008;Hansen, 2002). ...
Article
Full-text available
Malawi agriculture has undergone various policy regimes targeted at improving productivity and food self-sufficiency. Policy influence has often come from the World Bank and other donors who have pushed for a costly and state minimalist policy, against government wish for a welfarist approach. This situation has created a long-standing schism between the Bank and Government since the signing of the first SAP loan in 1981, thus affecting implementation of agricultural policies. This has resulted in food market reforms being partial and often reversed, with state marketing boards still playing a major role. These have created instability in maize prices and stocks in the national strategic grain reserve, often resulting in food crises and putting into question the achievements of the farm input subsidy program in achieving food security. This paper analyses the impact of Malawi agricultural policies on crop productivity over the past fifty years (1964-2014) and the resulting food security status of the country by drawing on national level data. This is confounded by the fact that up to 38% of Malawians still do not get adequate food supplies and the percentage of stunted children is high at 42.4%. Dietary diversification, improved research and technology development and transfer, upscaling of irrigation and policy consistency are critical to achieving national and household food security. Equally, development and empowerment of the private sector is the panacea for a strong maize marketing system that would deliver stable supply and pricing.
... One explanation for this endowment effect is loss aversion: the disutility of relinquishing something one owns is greater than the utility of acquiring it (Camerer, 2003;Gintis, 2009). However, recently, the endowment effect has been questioned, and a careful experimental design is required to ensure that such an effect is not due to the experimental design Zeiler, 2005, 2007) or simple credit constraints and diminishing utility (Holden and Lunduka, 2011). ...
Article
This study investigates attitudes towards legalizing land sales and Willingness to Accept (WTA) sales prices and compensation prices for land among smallholder households in the southern highlands of Ethiopia. Household panel data from 2007 and 2012 are used. The large majority of the sample prefers land sales to remain illegal, and the resistance to legalizing land sales increased from 2007 to 2012. While resistance against land sales was strongest among the most land poor in 2007, the relatively more land rich had become more negative towards legalizing land sales in 2012. Younger age and more education were not associated with a more positive attitude towards legalizing land sales. In the same period, perceived median real land values increased sharply but also exhibit substantial local variation with higher land values in areas with better market access. Stated minimum land sales prices increased with farm size in 2012. The substantial increase in perceived land values, high economic growth and outmigration of youth have yet to persuade the rural population in southern Ethiopia to open the land sales market.
... One explanation for this endowment effect is loss aversion: the disutility of relinquishing something one owns is greater than the utility of acquiring it (Camerer, 2003;Gintis, 2009). However, recently, the endowment effect has been questioned, and a careful experimental design is required to ensure that such an effect is not due to the experimental design Zeiler, 2005, 2007) or simple credit constraints and diminishing utility (Holden and Lunduka, 2011). ...
Technical Report
Full-text available
This study investigates attitudes towards legalizing land sales and Willingness to Accept (WTA) sales prices and compensation prices for land among smallholder households in four different areas in the Oromia and SNNP Regions in the southern highlands of Ethiopia. Household panel data from 2007 and 2012 are used. The large majority of the sample prefers land sales to remain illegal, and the resistance to legalizing land sales increased from 2007 to 2012. In the same period, perceived median real land values increased sharply but also exhibit substantial local variation. Land loss aversion is associated with higher land values and less willingness to sell land if land sales were to become legal. The substantial increase in perceived land values, high economic growth and outmigration of youth have yet to persuade the rural population in southern Ethiopia to open the land sales market.
Article
Malawi has over the last 6 years embarked on a comprehensive targeted fertilizer and seed subsidy program to boost its agricultural production and to enhance household and national food security. The program aims to target coupons for purchase of subsidized fertilizers and seeds to poor rural households. This study provides evidence on the extent of leakages of coupons and fertilizers and the targeting efficiency of the program. While the program enhances food production and food security, it does not target the poor better than a program that distributes inputs randomly and corruption, and targeting errors lead to local frustration and conflicts. The same basic problems of establishing a credible population base, developing clear targeting criteria, establishing a system for beneficiary selection and targeting, leakages of coupons higher up in the system, cost-efficient import and timely distribution of the inputs, and illegal markets for coupons and fertilizers were as serious during our study (2007–2009) as during the Starter Pack program and Targeted Inputs Program (1998–2003). Corruption appears to be the elephant in the room in the negotiations between donors and the Government of Malawi about how to set higher standards such as transparency and accountability at all levels of the program.
Article
Full-text available
Willingness to accept (WTA) is usually substantially higher than willingness to pay (WTP). These constructs have been studied for roughly 30 years and with a wide variety of goods. This paper reviews those studies. We find that the less the good is like an “ordinary market good,” the higher is the ratio. The ratio is highest for non-market goods, next highest for ordinary private goods, and lowest for experiments involving forms of money. A generalization of this pattern holds even when we account for differences in survey design: ordinary goods have lower ratios than non-ordinary ones. We also find that ratios in real experiments are not significantly different from hypothetical experiments and that incentive-compatible elicitation yields higher ratios.
Article
Full-text available
In this essay we develop a framework for analysing the major institutions governing the production and exchange of output and the primary factors of production in rural areas. The analysis incorporates general considerations of risk and information constraints jointly with the principal material attributes of agriculture and of agricultural production factors. The framework is used to analyse barriers to the existence of the major intertemporal and factor markets. It is applied specifically to land-scarce environments for which it provides an internally consistent explanation for many of the well-documented institutional features of such settings. In addition, the analysis provides new implications for, among other phenomena, the inter-relationships among ownership holdings, operational scale, family size and factor productivity; for the scarcity of animal rental markets and use of animals as collateral; for the renting out of land by small landowners; and for the existence of plantations for certain crops.
Article
Full-text available
Hyperbolic discount functions induce dynamically inconsistent preferences, implying a motive for consumers to constrain their own future choices. This paper analyzes the decisions of a hyperbolic consumer who has access to an imperfect commitment technology: an illiquid asset whose sale must be initiated one period before the sale proceeds are received. The model predicts that consumption tracks income, and the model explains why consumers have asset-specific marginal propensities to consume. The model suggests that financial innovation may have caused the ongoing decline in U. S. savings rates, since financial innovation increases liquidity, eliminating commitment opportunities. Finally, the model implies that financial market innovation may reduce welfare by providing “too much” liquidity.
Article
Full-text available
Attitudes towards risk are measured for households in Northern Zambia using an experimental gambling approach with real payoffs that at maximum were equal to 30% of average total annual income per capita. The results of the experiment show decreasing absolute risk aversion and increasing partial risk aversion. Determinants of risk aversion are investigated using random effects interval regression model exploiting the panel data structure of the repeated experiments. Wealth indicator variables are found to be significant, and partial relative risk aversion decreases as wealth increases. Females are found to be more risk averse than males.
Article
Part I: Nonstandard Preferences This first part of a larger work devoted to the modern behavioral economics considers economic aspects of nonstandard preferences that characterize deviations from the standard model of rational decision-making. The author emphasizes the problems of self-control and the context-dependence of human behavior. He then shows how to apply theoretical ideas to the study of savings, labor market, stock exchange, and other domains of economic behavior.
Article
In most low-income countries, rural households depend on mixed rain-fed agriculture&sol;livestock production, which is very risky. Due to numerous market failures, there are few ways to shift risks to third parties. The literature has focused on what determines the responses of households in such environments. Of special concern are path dependencies in which households experiencing failure are prone to further failure and potential poverty traps. This paper estimates levels and determinants of risk aversion in the highlands of Ethiopia. We find high risk aversion and evidence that constraints have important impacts on risk-averting behavior with perhaps significant implications for long-term poverty. The results also suggest the possibility of path dependence and offer insights into links between risk aversion and poverty traps. Copyright Copyright 2009 Agricultural and Applied Economics Association.
Article
There is an emerging consensus among macro-economists that differences in technology across countries account for the major differences in per-capita GDP and the wages of workers with similar skills across countries. Accounting for differences in technology levels across countries thus can go a long way towards understanding global inequality. One mechanism by which poorer countries can catch up with richer countries is through technological diffusion, the adoption by low-income countries of the advanced technologies produced in high-income countries. In this survey, we examine recent micro studies that focus on understanding the adoption process. If technological diffusion is a major channel by which poor countries can develop, it must be the case that technology adoption is incomplete or the inputs associated with the technologies are under-utilized in poor, or slow-growing economies. Thus, obtaining a better understanding of the constraints on adoption is useful in understanding a major component of growth.
Article
Recent models of procrastination due to self-control problems assume that a procrastinator considers just one option and is unaware of her self-control problems. We develop a model where a person chooses from a menu of options and is partially aware of her self-control problems. This menu model replicates earlier results and generates new ones. A person might forgo completing an attractive option because she plans to complete a more attractive but never-to-be-completed option. Hence, providing a nonprocrastinator additional options can induce procrastination, and a person may procrastinate worse pursuing important goals than unimportant ones. © 2000 the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology