ArticlePDF Available

Abstract and Figures

For a long list of investment "biases,'' e.g., home bias, loss aversion, and performance chasing, we find that genetic differences explain up to 45% of the variation across individual investors. The genetic factors that influence investment biases are also found to affect behaviors in other, non-investment, domains. This evidence is consistent with a view that investment biases are manifestations of innate and evolutionary ancient features of human behavior. The environment an investor experiences also affects investment biases, either directly or as a moderator of genetic predispositions. For example, we find that work-related experience with finance seems to reduce genetic predispositions to investment biases, while general education does not. Finally, even genetically identical investors, who grow up in the same family environment, often differ substantially in their investment behaviors due to individual-specific experiences or events.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2009094Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2009094
Why Do Individuals Exhibit Investment Biases?
Henrik Cronqvist and Stephan Siegel
First draft: September 19, 2011
This draft: February 19, 2012
Abstract
We find that a long list of investment biases, e.g., the reluctance to realize losses, performance
chasing, and the home bias, are “human,” in the sense that we are born with them. Genetic
factors explain up to 50% of the variation in these biases across individuals. We find no evi-
dence that education is a significant moderator of genetic investment behavior. Genetic effects
on investment behavior are correlated with genetic effects on behaviors in other domains (e.g.,
those with a genetic preference for familiar stocks also exhibit a preference for familiarity in other
domains), suggesting that investment biases is only one facet of much broader genetic behaviors.
Our evidence provides a biological basis for non-standard preferences that have been used in as-
set pricing models, and has implications for the design of public policy in the domain of investments.
We are thankful for comments from seminar participants at Caltech, Copenhagen Business School, Erasmus
University, Institute for Financial Research (SIFR), Maastricht University, Tilburg University, and valuable discussions
with Peter Bossaerts, Colin Camerer, Peter Cziraki, David Hirshleifer, Arvid Hoffmann, Søren Hvidkjær, Manjari
Quintanar-Solares, Lasse Pedersen, Thomas Post, Paolo Sodini, Elvira Sojli, Oliver Spalt, Per Str¨omberg, Frank Yu,
and Paul Zak. We acknowledge generous research funding from the 2011-12 Faculty Research Award of the Betty F.
Elliott Initiative for Academic Excellence, College of Business, The University of Michigan - Dearborn. We thank
Florian M¨unkel, Lucas Perin, and Lew Thorson for excellent research assistance, and Jack Goldberg (Twin Registry
at University of Washington) and Nancy Segal (Twin Studies Center at California State University, Fullerton) for
advice related to twins studies. This project was pursued in part when Cronqvist was Olof Stenhammar Visiting
Professor at SIFR, which he thanks for its support. Statistics Sweden and the Swedish Twin Registry (STR) provided
the data for this study. STR is supported by grants from the Swedish Research Council, the Ministry of Higher
Education, AstraZeneca, and the National Institute of Health (grants AG08724, DK066134, and CA085739). Any
errors or omissions are our own.
Cronqvist: McMahon Family Chair in Corporate Finance, George R. Roberts Fellow, and Associate Professor of Fi-
nancial Economics, Claremont McKenna College, Robert Day School of Economics and Finance (hcronqvist@cmc.edu);
Siegel: Visiting Assistant Professor of Finance, W. P. Carey School of Business, Arizona State University; Assistant
Professor of Finance and Business Economics, Michael G. Foster School of Business; University of Washington
(ss1110@uw.edu).
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2009094Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2009094
I Introduction
The list of investment biases that individuals exhibit is long. Individuals are, for example, reluctant
to realize losses (Odean (1998)), trade too much (Odean (1999)), extrapolate recent superior
performance (Patel, Zeckhauser, and Hendricks (1991) and Benartzi (2001)), are insufficiently
diversified (French and Poterba (1991)), and have a preference for skewness and lottery-type stocks
(Kumar (2009)). These biases have been attributed to psychological mechanisms: Mental accounting
combined with prospect theory for the reluctance to realize losses (Thaler (1985) and Kahneman and
Tversky (1979)), overconfidence for excessive trading (Fischhoff, Slovic, and Lichtenstein (1977) and
Griffin and Tversky (1992)), representativeness and the hot hands fallacy for excessive extrapolation
of past performance (Tversky and Kahneman (1974) and Griffin and Tversky (1992)), ambiguity
aversion and familiarity for lack of diversification (Ellsberg (1961) and Heath and Tversky (1991)),
and cumulative prospect theory for skewness preferences (Tversky and Kahneman (1992)).
Despite this long list of investment biases, little research has been devoted to understanding
why individuals exhibit these behaviors.
1
Are we born with these investment biases, i.e., are they
innate so that we are genetically endowed with them? Or do we exhibit them as a result of our
upbringing, learning, or specific environmental experiences? The origins of investment biases have
implications for models of investor behavior and asset prices, the extent to which market incentives
may be expected to reduce investment biases, and the design of public policy. In this study, we
therefore take a first step towards uncovering the origins of investment biases.
Empirically separating the explanation that we are born with investment biases from the
alternative that they are learned is very challenging. We therefore use empirical methodology
previously used extensively in quantitative behavioral genetics (see, e.g., Neale and Maes (2004)
for a review), and more recently in finance and economics research (e.g., Barnea, Cronqvist, and
Siegel (2010) and Cesarini et al. (2010)).
2
Our method involves examining data on the investment
behaviors of identical and fraternal twins.
1
Throughout the paper, we will refer to these behaviors as “biases” because they constitute non-standard preferences
and beliefs from the perspective of standard models used in financial economics.
2
An incomplete list of studies in economics which use data on twins include Taubman (1976), Behrman and
Taubman (1989), and Ashenfelter and Krueger (1994).
2
Our data set from the world’s largest twin registry, the Sweden Twin Registry, matched with
very detailed data on the twins’ investment behaviors, enables us to decompose differences across
individuals into genetic versus environmental components. This decomposition is based on an
intuitive insight: Identical twins share 100% of their genes, while the average proportion of shared
genes is only 50% for fraternal twins. If identical twins exhibit more similarity with respect to
these investment behaviors than do fraternal twins, then there is evidence that these behaviors are
influenced, at least in part, by genetic factors.
We can summarize our results as follows. First, a long list of investment biases are ”human” in
the sense that we are born with them. We base this conclusion on empirical evidence that genetic
factors explain up to 50% of the variation in these biases across individuals. Second, we find no
evidence that education is a significant moderator of genetic investment behavior, i.e., genetic
predispositions to investment biases can not be easily educated away. Finally, genetic effects on
investment behavior are correlated with genetic effects on behaviors in other domains (e.g., those
with a genetic preference for familiar stocks also exhibit a preference for familiarity in other domains),
suggesting that genetic investment biases is only one facet of much broader individual behavior.
The paper is organized as follows. Section II reviews related research. Section III describes our
data sources, reports summary statistics, and defines our measures of investment biases. Section
IV reports our results and robustness checks. Section V reports evidence on extensions, e.g.,
gene-environment interactions effects. Section VI concludes.
II The Origins of Investment Biases
A The Evolution of Non-Standard Preferences and Beliefs
If investment behaviors are genetic, then they propagate from generation to generation. This raises
the question of why biases would survive natural selection and not “die out.” Some economists’
answer is that the the psychological mechanisms behind these behaviors are fitness maximizing, i.e.,
they maximize the likelihood of human survival and reproduction. More specifically, several recent
models show that behaviors such as loss aversion and overconfidence are fitness maximizing (e.g.,
3
Rayo and Becker (2007), McDermott, Fowler, and Smirnov (2008), Brennan and Lo (2009), and
Johnson and Fowler (2011)).
3
That is, the approach of these models is to characterize the end point
of a natural selection process in which the fitness-maximizing utility function has come to dominate
all other utility functions.
It should be emphasized that the evolution of human preferences started, not in a modern
environment, but in a hunter-gatherer society hundreds of thousands of years ago. Some economists
have therefore argued that preferences that were fitness-maximizing in such an environment may
not be optimal in today’s modern environment, potentially explaining why individuals exhibit
investment (and other) biases. As Rayo and Becker (2007) conclude (p. 304):
“[W]hen talking about fitness-maximizing [utility] functions, we refer to functions that optimized
genetic multiplication during hunter-gatherer times (before agriculture and animal domestication
were developed). In modern times, on the other hand, we presumably share most of the innate
characteristics of our hunter-gatherer ancestors. But since the technological landscape has
changed so rapidly since the rise of agriculture, our [utility] functions need no longer optimally
promote the present multiplication of our genes.”
B Born with Biases
Some evidence suggests that the psychological mechanisms behind investment biases are partly
genetic. First, the same biases found in humans are also found in genetically close animals. For
example, Chen, Lakshminarayanan, and Santos (2006) show that capuchin monkeys exhibit loss
aversion, and Lakshminarayanan et al. (2011) find that capuchins have a preference for gambles
in which good outcomes are framed as gains rather than payoff-identical gambles in which poor
outcomes are framed as losses. As capuchins lack experience with markets and money, Chen et al.
(2006) and Santos (2008) conclude that the biases are more likely to be genetic rather than learned:
“[L]oss aversion is an innate and evolutionarily ancient feature of human preferences, a function
of decision-making systems that evolved before the common ancestors of capuchins and humans
diverged” (Chen et al. (2006), p. 520).
3
Other models of the natural selection of certain preferences and human behaviors include Rogers (1994), Waldman
(1994), Robson (1996a,b, 2001a,b), and Netzer (2009). Some of these papers explain why humans have utility functions
and time and risk preferences, while others explain why biases may have evolved and survived natural selection
(e.g., Waldman (1994)). Some evolutionary models have also appeared in financial economics (e.g., Luo (1998) and
Hirshleifer and Luo (2001)). For example, Hirshleifer and Luo (2001) model the effect of natural selection and the
long-term survival of overconfident investors in a competitive securities market.
4
Second, some biases are also found in children at a very early age. For example, Harbaugh,
Krause, and Vesterlund (2001) find evidence of loss aversion in children as young as five, and there
is no evidence that the behavior disappears significantly with age, at least not through college age.
This result also suggests that loss aversion is genetic, assuming that these children do not learn
such behavior before age five.
C The Biological Basis for Investment Biases
In this subsection, we review recent empirical evidence regarding the genetic and neuroscientific
basis for well-recognized investment biases.4Table 1 summarizes our review.
C.1 Insufficient Diversification
A lot of existing evidence shows that individual investors diversify their portfolios much less than is
recommended by standard models in financial economics. For example, they overweight stocks from
the home market (e.g., French and Poterba (1991)). Such a home bias has not been easy to explain
based on standard models (e.g., Lewis (1999)).5
Ambiguity aversion and familiarity (e.g., Ellsberg (1961), Heath and Tversky (1991), and Fox
and Tversky (1995)) is an alternative approach to explain lack of diversification. Individual investors
may find their own home stock market to be much more familiar – and less ambiguous – than
international stock markets. Investors overweight familiar securities, and invest little to nothing
in ambiguous securities. As a result, their portfolios seem insufficiently diversified compared to
predictions of standard models.
Based on recent research in the intersection of economics and neuroscience, we predict that
ambiguity aversion and familiarity bias are partly genetic. A gene association study by Chew
4
For extensive reviews of research at the intersection of neuroscience, genetics, and economics, we refer to Camerer,
Loewenstein, and Prelec (2005) and Benjamin et al. (2008).
5Home bias is not the only example of insifficient diversification. Huberman (2001) finds that investors are much
more likely to hold shares in their local U.S. Regional Bell Operating Companies (RBOCs) than in out-of-state RBOCs.
Grinblatt and Keloharju (2001a) find that investors are more likely to hold and trade stocks of firms which are located
close to them geographically, which use their native language for company reporting, and whose CEO has their own
cultural background. Studies of voluntary contributions by employees in 401(k) plans find a strong bias towards
holding own company stock (e.g., Benartzi (2001)). There is no clear information explanation for the results in French
and Poterba (1991), Huberman (2001), and Benartzi (2001), and Grinblatt and Keloharju (2001a) argue against such
an explanation.
5
et al. (2011) identifies the genes that affect ambiguity aversion and familiarity. In addition, the
neuroimaging study by Hsu et al. (2005) shows that certain parts of the brain were predictably
more active under the condition of familiarity than under the condition of ambiguity.
C.2 Excessive Trading
One of the most important stylized facts about individual investors is that some of them trade too
much (e.g., Odean (1999)), i.e., they trade much more than may be justified on rational grounds,
and such excessive trading may result in losses for the investor (e.g., Odean (1999), Barber and
Odean (2000), and Barber, Lee, Liu, and Odean (2009)). Excessive trading has been found to be
related to individual characteristics that are partly genetic, such as overconfidence and sensation
seeking (e.g., Barber and Odean (2001) and Grinblatt and Keloharju (2009)). Table 1 reports
references to research that finds a relation between genes, overconfidence, and sensation seeking.
C.3 Disposition Effect
Prior research has shown that individual investors exhibit a “disposition effect,” i.e., they are
reluctant to realize losses on their investments (e.g., Odean (1998), Grinblatt and Keloharju (2001b),
Barber et al. (2007), and Dhar and Zhu (2006)).
6
Shefrin and Statman (1985) argue that a
combination of mental accounting (Thaler, 1985) and prospect theory preferences similar to those
in Kahneman and Tversky (1979) makes investors more likely to sell stock investments with a gain
than those with a loss.
There are several reasons based on existing research to expect that we are born to exhibit a
disposition effect. First, a recent gene association study by Zhong et al. (2009) identifies the specific
genes that affect the concavity and convexity of the prospect theory value function in the gain and
loss domains. Second, neuroimaging studies report evidence on the neural basis of loss aversion and
the disposition effect (Tom et al. (2007) and Frydman, Barberis, Camerer, Bossaerts, and Rangel
(2011)). Finally, the evidence, discussed above, of significant loss aversion and framing effects in
animals that are genetically close to humans also suggests that we are born with the disposition
6
Even professional traders at the Chicago Board of Trade and the Chicago Mercantile Exchange have been found
to exhibit the disposition effect (Coval and Shumway (2005) and Locke and Mann (2005)).
6
effect (e.g., Chen, Lakshminarayanan, and Santos (2006) and Lakshminarayanan et al. (2011)).
C.4 Performance Chasing
Pre-existing research has shown that individual investors often extrapolate recent good stock or
fund performance even when it shows little to no persistence (e.g., Patel, Zeckhauser, and Hendricks
(1991), Benartzi (2001), and Cronqvist and Thaler (2004)). In their work on representativeness,
Tversky and Kahneman (1974) find that people expect that a sequence of outcomes generated by a
random process will resemble the essential characteristics of that process even when the sequence
is short. Griffin and Tversky (1992) provide an extension documenting that people focus on the
strength or extremeness of the evidence with insufficient regard of its credence, predictability, and
weight. In contrast to the other investment biases we study, we are not aware of much research
in neuroeconomics that directly links excessive extrapolation to genes.
7
As a result, our work is
one of the first attempts to analyze the extent to which we are hard-wired to exhibit excessive
extrapolation in the context on investments.
C.5 Skewness Preference
Several existing studies show that individual investors exhibit a strong preference for stocks with
positive skewness, i.e., they like lottery-type stocks (e.g., Kumar (2009)).
8
Such behavior is expected
if investors make decisions based on cumulative prospect theory (Tversky and Kahneman (1992)
and Barberis and Huang (2008)). Under cumulative prospect theory, investors evaluate risk using
a value function that is concave over gains and convex over losses, using probabilities that are
transformed from objective probabilities by applying a weighting function which overweights the
tails of the distribution it applies it to.
There are several reasons based on existing research to expect that we are born with a preference
for skewness. First, studies have found that the preference to gamble has a significant genetic
7
Two contemporaneous twin studies use a questionnaire and the “Linda question” (Tversky and Kahneman, 1983)
to study the genetics of representativeness, but their respective conclusions are very different: Cesarini et al. (2011)
report a correlation among identical twins’ responses of 0.252 (
p
-value
<
0
.
01), compared to
0
.
082 in Simonson
and Sela (2011). For fraternal twins, Cesarini et al. (2011) report a correlation of 0.048, compared to 0.451 (
p
-value
<0.05) in Simonson and Sela (2011). These differences raise concerns about inferences based on questionnaires
8
For an example of skewness preferences from another domain than investments, see Golec and Tamarkin (1998).
7
component (e.g., Slutske et al. (2000) and Ib´nez et al. (2003)). Second, a recent gene association
study by Zhong et al. (2009) finds that a specific gene results in a preference for gambles with a
small probability of a very large payoff. Again, we refer to Table 1 for details.
D Learning to be Biased
The investment behaviors discussed above may alternatively originate from our upbringing and
social learning, as opposed to genes. In models of “direct vertical socialization” children are born
without defined preferences, and they are first exposed to their parents’ socialization (e.g., Bisin and
Verdier (2001)). If parent-child socialization does not succeed, the child is influenced by a random
role model in the population (e.g., teachers, co-workers, etc.). These models have been used to
explain parent-child similarity with respect to, e.g., religion and labor supply preferences (e.g., Bisin
and Verdier (2000) and Fernandez, Fogli, and Olivetti (2004)), but they may extend to investment
behavior. That is, children may learn certain investment behaviors from their parents.
The environment may influence investment biases in other ways than through upbringing and
social learning. For example, in the model by Gervais and Odean (2001) individual investors learn to
be biased by becoming overconfident because of their past idiosyncratic investment successes. That
is, there is evidence to expect that individual-specific experiences also affect investment behavior.
III Data
A Data Sources
Our data set is constructed by matching a large number of twins from the Swedish Twin Registry
(STR), the world’s largest twin registry, with data from individual tax filings and other databases
by Statistics Sweden. In Sweden, twins are registered at birth, and the STR collects additional
data through in-depth interviews.
9
Importantly, STR’s data enables us to determine the zygosity of
9
STR’s databases are organized by birth cohort. The Screening Across Lifespan Twin, or “SALT,” database
contains data on twins born 1886–1958. The Swedish Twin Studies of Adults: Genes and Environment database, or
“STAGE,” contains data on twins born 1959–1985. In addition to twin pairs, twin identifiers, and zygosity status, the
databases contain variables based on STR’s telephone interviews (for SALT), completed 1998–2002, and combined
telephone interviews and Internet surveys (for STAGE), completed 2005–2006. For further details about STR, we
refer to Lichtenstein et al. (2006).
8
each twin pair: Identical or “monozygotic” (MZ) twins are genetically identical, while fraternal or
“dizygotic” (DZ) twins are genetically different, and share on average 50% of their genes.10
Until 2007, taxpayers in Sweden were subject to a wealth tax on assets other than businesses.
Prior to the abolishment of this tax, all Swedish banks, brokerage firms, and other financial
institutions were required by law to report to the Swedish Tax Authority information about
individuals’ portfolios (i.e., stocks, bonds, mutual funds, derivatives, and other securities) held as of
December 31 and also all sales transactions during the year.
We have matched the twins with portfolio and sales transaction data between 1999 and 2007,
providing us with detailed information on investment behavior. For each individual, our data set
contains all securities held at the end of the year (identified by each security’s International Security
Identification Number (ISIN)), the number of each security held, the dividends received during
the year, and the end of the year value. We also have data on which securities were sold over the
year, and in the case of stocks, the number of securities sold and the sales price.
11
Security level
data have been collected from several sources, including Bloomberg, Datastream, Morningstar, SIX
Telekurs, Standard & Poor’s, and the Swedish Investment Fund Association.
B Sample Selection and Summary Statistics
We follow prior research on investment biases by analyzing equity investments, i.e., equity and
mixed mutual funds and individual stocks. We exclude individuals who do not participate in equity
markets. Our empirical methodology also requires that we exclude incomplete pairs of twins.
We have 15,208 adult twin pairs in which each twin has at least one year of non-missing equity
holdings data. Panel A of Table 2 reports summary statistics for our data set, which by construction
corresponds to 30,416 individuals. Opposite-sex twins are the most common (37%); identical male
twins are the least common (13%). The distribution in the table is consistent with what would be
expected from large samples of twins (e.g., Bortolus et al. (1999)), and we have also checked that
10
Zygosity is based on questions about intrapair similarities in childhood. One of the questions was: Were you and
your twin partner during childhood “as alike as two peas in a pod” or were you “no more alike than siblings in general”
with regard to appearance? The STR has validated this method with DNA analysis as having 98 percent accuracy on
a subsample of twins. For twin pairs for which DNA has been collected, zygosity status is based on DNA analysis.
11
Sales transaction data are not available for 2001 and 2002, and we do not have the exact dates of any of the sales
transactions in our data set.
9
the twins are not significantly different from non-twins in terms of socioeconomic characteristics or
investment behavior (not tabulated).
Panel B reports summary statistics separately for identical and fraternal twins. All variables
are defined in Appendix Table A1. Socioeconomic characteristics are averaged over those years an
investor is in our data set.
12
While identical and fraternal twins are relatively similar with respect
to socioeconomic characteristics, we observe substantial cross-sectional variation. We find that
the average (median) investor holds about 4 (2) equity securities with a combined value of about
$20,000 ($4,000) in the portfolio.
13
About 80% hold at least one equity mutual fund, and about
40% hold at least one stock.
C Measures of Investment Biases
C.1 Insufficient Diversification
We measure Diversification by the proportion invested in mutual funds, but not invested in individual
stocks. We measure an individual’s Home Bias by the proportion Swedish securities in the equity
portfolio. For each investor and year, we add the market value of Swedish stocks and the Swedish
equity allocation of mutual funds, and divide by the total market value of equity holdings. We
classify stocks as Swedish or foreign based on the country in which the stock is registered, as reflected
by the ISIN. For mutual funds, we collect annual fund-specific data from Morningstar. For funds
not covered by Morningstar we infer the fund’s investment focus from the fund’s name. Finally,
to reduce measurement error, we calculate the equally weighted average Diversification and Home
Bias across all years the individual is in the data set. In Table 3, we report summary statistics
for both measures, showing that on average investors hold about 70% of their equity portfolio in
mutual funds and about 50% in Swedish assets. Focusing on direct stock holdings, the home bias
increases to about 94%.
12The educational variables are based on the maximum, not an average.
13
We use the average end-of-year exchange rate 1999-2007 of 8.0179 Swedish krona per U.S. dollar to convert
summary statistics. When we estimate models in Section IV, all values are in Swedish krona, i.e., not converted to
dollars. In terms of size, the portfolios in our data set are comparable to those in other data sets of a broad set of
individual investors. For example, in Grinblatt and Keloharju (2009) the average (median) investor holds about 2 (1)
equity securities with a combined value of about EUR 24,600 (EUR 1,600) in the portfolio
10
We note that the home bias may be explained by transactions costs, some of which may have
a genetic component. For example, high transactions costs for investors with insufficient wealth
may effectively constrain them from investing in certain international stock markets. A genetic
component of home bias may thus simply reflect that wealth has a genetic component. When we
estimate our models in Section IV we therefore control for measures of the cross-sectional variation
in transactions costs, e.g., wealth. In addition, while investors may overweight the home market
because of information they have, we do not consider this to be very likely. First, during our sample
period Sweden represents about 1% of the world equity market, while the home bias, on average,
is 75 times larger; this discrepancy can not be easily attributable to an information explanation.
Second, there is little evidence that individual investors outperform in their local stock investments
(e.g., Seasholes and Zhu (2010)). If individual investors do not outperform even in their local stock
investments, it seems unlikely that the home bias represents information about Sweden versus other
markets.
C.2 Excessive Trading
One of the most important stylized facts about individual investors is that some of them trade
too much (e.g., Odean (1999)). A question in this context is then what “too much” trading is.
Individuals may trade for different reasons, most importantly portfolio rebalancing due to liquidity
demands, which may partly be related to factors that are genetic. For example, deteriorating health,
which is partly genetic, may result in more trading to liquidate a portfolio. As a result, a genetic
component of trading may thus simply reflect that liquidity demand has a genetic component. When
we estimate our models in Section IV we therefore control for an extensive set of socioeconomic
characteristics which may correlate with liquidity demands and thus trading. As a result, the
measure of trading we decompose may be considered an “excessive trading” measure.14
We measure Turnover, i.e., an individual’s propensity to trade and turnover her investment
portfolio in the spirit of Barber and Odean (2000, 2001). Specifically, for direct stock holdings, we
divide, for each individual investor and year, the sales volume (in Swedish krona) during the year
14
Grinblatt and Keloharju (2009) use a similar approach of controlling for socioeconomic characteristics in their
analysis of the effect of sensation seeking, measured by the number of speeding tickets, on trading.
11
by the value of directly held stocks at the beginning of the year. Since we do not have sales price
information for mutual funds, we also construct a turnover measure using the number of sales during
the year divided by the number of equity securities in the investor’s portfolio at the beginning of the
year. In each case, Turnover is defined as the average annual turnover using all years with equity
holdings data for an investor.15
Table 3 reports summary statistics, and we find that the turnover for stocks in our data is
similar to that reported by Grinblatt and Keloharju (2009) for a large sample of individual investors
in Finland, and Agnew, Balduzzi, and Sund´en (2003) for a large set of retirement savings accounts
in the U.S. Not surprisingly, the average turnover is significantly lower in our data set than the
turnover Barber and Odean (2001) report for investors based on data from a large U.S. discount
brokerage firm.
C.3 Disposition Effect
We measure the Disposition Effect in the spirit of Odean (1998) and Calvet et al. (2009a,b).
Specifically, at the end of each year during which we observe at least on sales transaction, we classify
all securities in an investor’s portfolio as winners or losers based on the security’s raw return during
the year.
16
Finally, following Odean (1998), we calculate the difference between the proportion of
gains realized to the total number of realized and unrealized gains (PGR) and the proportion of
losses realized to total losses (PLR). The larger the difference between PGR and PLR, the more
reluctant is the investor to realize losses.
In Table 3, we report summary statistics. We calculate our measure of the disposition effect
separately for stocks only as well as for stocks and equity mutual funds. We find that the average
and median investor in individual stocks exhibits a disposition effect between 3 and 7%. When
considering holdings of stocks and equity mutual funds the average disposition effect is close to zero.
Most importantly, given that the PGR – PLR difference is bounded by
1 and +1, the standard
15
It is well-recognized that the distribution of turnover may be skewed. To avoid that our analysis may be influenced
by a few outliers, we exclude observations for which turnover is higher than the top 1% of the distribution of individual
investor turnover.
16
We use returns to identify winners and losers as we do not observe purchase prices. Odean (1998) points out
there are several possible choices of a reference point (e.g., average, first, highest, or most recent), but finds that the
results are similar for each choice.
12
deviation of about 0.40 for both identical and fraternal twins shows that there is significant variation
across individuals with respect to the reluctance to realize losses.
C.4 Performance Chasing
We measure Performance Chasing by an individual’s propensity to purchase securities that have
performed well in the recent past. More specifically, each year we sort stocks and equity mutual
funds separately into return deciles using the raw returns during the year. For each investor that
has purchases securities during our sample periods, we calculate performance chasing as the fraction
of purchased securities with returns in the top two deciles. The higher that fraction, the more the
individual chases performance by overweighting securities with higher recent performance.
17
In
Table 3, we report summary statistics, and find consistent with other research that a significant
portion of investors seems to chase past performance.
C.5 Skewness Preference
We measure an individual’s Skewness Preference in the spirit of Kumar (2009). Specifically, for each
investor and year we calculate the fraction of the portfolio that is invested in “lottery” securities.
We define a security as a lottery security if it has a below median price as well as above median
idiosyncratic volatility and skewness.
18
Skewness Preference is then the fraction of lottery securities
averaged over all years with portfolio data. Summary statistics in Table 3 suggest that on average
about 5% of an investor’s portfolio is held in lottery securities. Importantly, there is substantial
variation across investors.
17
All investors may not be performance chasers. Barber and Odean (2008) find that individuals invest dispropor-
tionately in stocks that have caught their attention, e.g., stocks with very high or very low recent returns.
18
We use a the world market return, the squared world market return, the local Swedish market return and the
squared local market returns factor in our asset pricing model to determine a security’s idiosyncratic error term.
Regressions are performed every year using the last 24 months of return data.
13
IV Results
A Evidence from Correlations
Using investment behaviors constructed for the direct equity holdings, Figure 1 reports the correlation
for each measure between twins. We draw several conclusions from the evidence. First, for each
measure, we find that the correlation is significantly greater between identical than fraternal twins.
This difference indicates that investment biases are explained, in part, by a significant genetic
component, but genes do not completely explain these behaviors because the correlation for identical
twins is significantly different from one. On average, the difference in correlations is 0.2. Second,
the correlations for same-sex fraternal twins are greater than those for opposite-sex twins.
19
Finally,
the correlation between twins and random age- and gender-matched non-twins is close to zero (on
average, 0.004). This is to be expected if either genes or the common parental environment affects
investment biases.
B Empirical Methodology
To decompose the cross-sectional variation in investment behaviors into genetic and environmental
components, we model each measure of an investment bias
yij
for twin
j
(1 or 2) of pair
i
as a possibly
nonlinear function of observable socioeconomic characteristics
Xij
as well as three unobserved effects.
We assume that
yij
is a function of an additive genetic effect,
aij
, an effect of the environment
common to both twins (e.g., parenting),
ci
, and an individual-specific effect,
eij
, also capturing
idiosyncratic measurement error:
yij =f(Xij , aij , ci, eij ).(1)
We assume that
aij
,
ci
, and
eij
are uncorrelated with one another and across twin pairs and normally
distributed with zero means and variances
σ2
a
,
σ2
c
, and
σ2
e
, respectively, so that the total residual
variance σ2is the sum of the three variance components.
Identifying variation due to
aij
,
ci
, and
eij
separately is possible due to constraints on the
covariances from genetic theory. Consider two twin pairs
i
= 1
,
2 with twins
j
= 1
,
2 in each pair,
19We examine difference between same-sex and opposite-sex twins in the robustness section
14
where the first is a pair of identical twins and the second is a pair of fraternal twins. The genetic
effects are:
a
= (
a11, a21 , a12, a22
)
0
. Analogously, the common and individual-specific environmental
effects are:
c
= (
c11, c21 , c12, c22
)
0
and
e
= (
e11, e21 , e12, e22
)
0
. Identical and fraternal twin pairs differ
in their genetic similarity. Identical twins are genetically identical, and the correlation between
a11
and
a21
is set to one. Fraternal twins share on average only 50% of their genes, such that
the correlation between
a21
and
a22
is 0.5. For both identical and fraternal twin pairs, a common
environment is assumed. As a result, we use the following covariance matrices:
Cov(a) = σ2
a
1 1 0 0
1 1 0 0
0 0 1 0.5
000.5 1
,Cov(c) = σ2
c
1 1 0 0
1 1 0 0
0 0 1 1
0 0 1 1
,Cov(e) = σ2
e
1 0 0 0
0 1 0 0
0 0 1 0
0 0 0 1
.
For the measures of investment biases in this study, we assume that fis a linear function:
yij =β0+βXij +aij +ci+eij ,(2)
where
β0
is an intercept term and
β
measures the effects of the observable socioeconomic character-
istics (
Xij
), e.g., age, education, income and wealth. We use maximum likelihood to estimate the
model using Mplus (Muth´en and Muth´en, 2010). Reported standard errors are bootstrapped with
1,000 repetitions.
Finally, we calculate the variance components
A
,
C
, and
E
.
A
is the proportion of the total
residual variance in an investment bias that is due to an additive genetic factor:
A=σ2
a
σ2
a+σ2
c+σ2
e
The proportions attributable to the common environment (
C
) and individual-specific environmental
effects (E) are computed analogously.
15
C Empirical Decomposition of Investment Biases
We use the model in equation (2) to empirically decompose the variation in investment behaviors
across individuals into genetic and environmental components. We follow pre-existing research
and control for several standard observable socioeconomic characteristics (e.g., Agnew (2006) and
Calvet, Campbell, and Sodini (2009b)). Some of these characteristics, for example wealth, have
been found to have a genetic component. By controlling for these characteristics, we attempt to
capture variation across individuals that is attributable to differences in preferences, as opposed to
differences in individual observable characteristics that are genetic.
Table 4 reports the estimated coefficients on the included control variables, and most importantly,
the variance components
A
,
C
, and
E
for each of the investment behaviors. We draw several
conclusions from the evidence in the table. First, 26-45%, depending on investment behavior, of the
variation in investment biases across individual investors is attributable to our genes, as opposed to
the environment. That is, we are to a significant extent born with the investment bias we examine
in this paper. Second, as the
C
component is very close to zero for each bias, we find very little
evidence that upbringing (or other aspects of the common environment) affects investment biases.
That is, the notion that children learn investment biases from their parents is inconsistent with
the data.
20
Finally, we find that over 50% of the variation across individuals is attributable to
individual-specific experiences.
We find that modeling a genetic component,
aij
in equation (2), improves the fit of a model
that explains the cross-sectional variation in investment biases. Specifically, while we only report
results for “ACE models” in the table, we have also estimated a “CE model,” in which
A
is set to
zero and an “E model,” in which both
A
and
C
are both set to zero. To compare the fit of these
models, we compute the Satorra-Bentler scaled
χ2
and test for the difference in
χ2
for an ACE
versus CE model and a CE versus E model. We conclude that modeling an unobservable genetic
factor significantly improves the fit of a model that attempts to explain the variation in investment
biases across individual investors.
20
The evidence of an insignificant
C
component is consistent with evidence from behavioral genetics research (e.g.,
Bouchard et al. (1990)) and recent research on risk preferences (e.g., Barnea, Cronqvist, and Siegel (2010) and Cesarini
et al. (2010)).
16
D Size of Portfolio
Some of the portfolios we have analyzed so far are small relative to the individual’s total assets. In
Table 5, we therefore exclude all individuals for whom the equity portfolio does not constitute at
least 20% of their total assets. This reduces the sample size significantly, but it enables us to exclude
those for whom the equity portfolio is insignificant and who may therefore not have strong incentives
to carefully consider their investment behaviors. We include the same individual socioeconomic
characteristics as previously, but we only report the variance components
A
,
C
, and
E
. Overall,
we find that the
A
components of the investment biases increases. They are 30-53%, depending
on investment behavior. That is, we find a significant genetic effect on investment behavior also
among those for whom the equity portfolio is significant and who may have the strongest incentives
to carefully consider their investment behaviors.
E Impact of Delegated Portfolio Management
Does delegated portfolio management reduce the effect of genes on investment biases? On the one
hand, individual investor may attribute mutual fund losses, not to oneself, but to the managers of
the funds, and as a result any genetic predisposition to, e.g., loss aversion may not be as strong for
mutual funds as for individual stock investments. On the other hand, portfolio management comes
with its own agency problems (e.g., Bergstresser, Chalmers, and Tufano (2009)).
Our analysis so far has involved only individual stocks, but in Table 6 we also include mutual
fund investments. We first report in the table that the extent to which individuals diversity their
portfolios is genetic (
A
= 39%). We then re-estimate the models previously reported for stock
investments only, but find that the
A
components of the investment biases do not change very
much. We conclude that delegated portfolio management does not seem to be a way for individual
investors to significantly “debias” themselves from investment biases they may be born with.21
21For evidence on behavioral biases of mutual funds investors, see, e.g., Bailey et al. (2010).
17
F Robustness Checks
F.1 Opposite-Sex Twins
We noted when discussing Figure 1 above that the correlations for same-sex fraternal twins are
greater than those for opposite-sex twins. A concern is that opposite-sex twins make fraternal twins
more different compared to identical twins, which may result in an upward bias of
A
. We included
gender as a control in all of the previously estimated models, but as a robustness check, we also
exclude opposite-sex fraternal twins from our sample, and re-estimate the models. Panel A of Table
7 shows that our results do not change much compared to the estimates previously reported in
Table 4.
F.2 Model Misspecification
One concern with some of the reported
C
components in Table 4 is that they are exactly zero. This
is because we constrain the variances to be non-negative, but suggests that the models may be
misspecified. As a robustness check, we therefore re-estimate the model in equation (2), but without
the non-negativity constraints on the variances. Panel B shows that the the
C
components are
very small (
3
.
9% to
7
.
6%) and not statistically significant from zero, reducing concerns about
misspecification bias.
A related concern is that some of the measures of investment behaviors are censored (e.g., Home
Bias is between 0 and 1), but we have checked and found that a Tobit model specification results in
unchanged, or sometimes stronger, Acomponents (not tabulated).
F.3 Model Assumptions
One concern is the model assumption that the common environment is not more important for
identical twins than for fraternal twins.22
Parenting.
If the parents of identical twins treat their twins more similarly than the parents
of fraternal twins treat their twins, then
A
may be upward biased. Researchers have used twins
22
See, e.g., Goldberger (1979), Taubman (1981), and Bouchard and McGue (2003) for a further discussion of model
assumptions and some of the common concerns with respect to analysis of data on twins.
18
reared apart, i.e., twins separated at birth or early in life, for which there is no common parental
environment, to address this problem. While we do not have sufficiently many reared apart twin
pairs in our sample to perform any statistical analysis, we note that other researchers report that
an analysis of reared apart twins does not change the conclusions (e.g., Bouchard et al. (1990)).
Social Interaction. If identical twins interact more than fraternal twins, and if such interaction
impacts their investments (e.g., Bikhchandani, Hirshleifer, and Welch (1998) and Hong, Kubik, and
Stein (2004)), then
A
may be upward biased. We address this concern using two robustness checks.
First, we exclude twin pairs with significant, i.e., more than 50%, portfolios similarity. Panel C
reveals that our results are generally robust to excluding twins with similar portfolios. Second, we
sort twin pairs into deciles based on social interaction, in particular the communication frequency
between twins, and randomly exclude twins until we have equally many identical or fraternal in each
decile. Panel D of Table 7 reports that the
A
components are generally still large and statistically
significantly. Only for Performance Chasing, we no longer find a significant genetic effect once we
control for social interaction. As Hirshleifer (2010) points out, investors are more likely to exchange
information about securities that have done particularly well, suggesting that more communication
between identical twins might indeed lead to more similar behavior with respect to Performance
Chasing. To see whether or not this finding obtains in the overall portfolio, we repeat the analysis
using stocks and mutual funds. For the combined portfolio, we find that controlling for social
interaction between twins still leads to a substantial and significant
A
component and a small and
insignificant
C
component.
23
Hence, it is also possible that our finding for Performance Chasing
with respect to directly held stocks is an outcome of the specific, relatively small sample used in the
analysis in Panel D.
Another model assumption is random mating. While economists have examined non-random
mating based on, e.g., education, we are not aware of any studies of mating based on investment
behavior. Positive assortative mating between the twins’ parents make fraternal twins more similar
relative to identical twins and would bias Adownwards.
23
Specifically, using 12,736 observations, we estimate
A
to be 0.247 (
s.e.
= 0
.
055), while
C
is estimated to be 0.022
(s.e. = 0.041).
19
F.4 Measurement Error
Measurement error in
yij
is captured by
eij
in the model in equation (2). As a result, the
A
component may be downward biased if there is significant measurement error in data. Because
our data set comes from the Swedish Tax Agency, which in turn obtain their data directly from
financial institutions, we consider measurement error to be rare in our data. In addition, we have
attempted to reduce measurement error by averaging all measures of investment biases across all
years with available data for an individual.
F.5 Amount of Environmental Variation
A remaining concern is that an estimated genetic component is not a universal constant, but
an estimate relative to the amount of genetic and environmental variation in the sample. The
variance decomposition we perform and therefore our estimates of the relative importance of genetic
variation are from a specific country, i.e., Sweden, during a specific time period, i.e., 1999–2007.
It is possible that the relative contribution of genetic and environmental variation differs between
different countries. We are not able to address this concern explicitly as we have data from only one
country, but we note that there is indeed a significant amount of variation is both the investment
behaviors and various individual socioeconomic characteristics in our data.
V Extensions
We have reported evidence that genetic effects explain each of the investment biases we examine.
In this section, we report two extensions. First, we examine whether some factors moderate the
genetic effect on investment behaviors (“gene-environment interactions”).
24
Second, we examine
whether genetic effects on investment behavior are correlated with genetic effects on non-financial
behaviors (“genetic correlations”).
24For an extensive review of research on gene-environment interactions, we refer to Rutter (2006).
20
A Gene-Environment Interactions
Education is a potentially significant moderator for genetic effects. For example, Johnson et al. (2010)
show, in another context than ours, that education reduces expressions of genetic predispositions
to poor health. That is, individuals may be born with a propensity to poor health, but education
reduces such propensities. In this paper, it is natural to examine the extent to which education
moderates genetic effects on investment behavior.
We use the gene-environment interaction model by Purcell (2002). Figure 2 provides a graphical
description of the model. In contrast with the model outlined in equation (2), a moderator (
M
)
interacts with the unobservable genetic and environmental factors of the investment behavior (
y
).
The model allows for the moderator and the investment behavior to be correlated via exposure of the
investment behavior to the unobservable genetic and environmental factors of the moderator. In a
first stage (not tabulated), we use regressions to remove the effect of the socioeconomic characteristics
used as control variables in Table 4, with the exception of the moderators.
Figure 3 reports results with education (measured as number of years of education) as the
moderator. We do not find that education is a significant moderator of genetic investment biases.
The coefficient
alphau
in Table 8 is not statistically significant. This evidence is important in that
it suggests that genetic predispositions to investment biases is not altered by general education.
Our education result raises the question of whether experience, specifically with respect to
finance, reduces genetic investment biases. We estimate separate models for individuals with
financial experience. Specifically, we use data on individuals’ occupation, based on the International
Standard Classification of Occupations (ISCO-88) by the International Labour Organization (ILO),
and available for a subset of our sample. For those twins with finance experience, we find in
Table 9 a smaller genetic effects on Diversification,Home Bias,Trading, and Performance Chasing
measured on all holdings of stock and equity mutual funds.
25
We note that the similar occupational
environment experienced by this subset of twins appears to generate commonality in their behavior.
Our conclusion is that finance experience seems to reduces genetic effects on investment biases.
25We still have too few twin pairs that have finance occupation to estimate a separate model for Loss Aversion.
21
B Genetic Correlations
We also examine whether genetic effects on investment behavior are correlated with genetic effects
on behaviors in domains other than investments. A specific example is the preference for familiarity.
Individuals may exhibit a preference for the familiar in many different domains, including investments,
choice of home location and culture. We examine if a preference for the familiar in the investment
domain is correlated with a preference for familiarity in some other domains, and most importantly,
whether the correlation is genetic.
In Table 10, we report results from bivariate models that allow us to jointly decompose the
variation in home bias and in another behavior and to analyze whether both behaviors are correlated
through the same genetic predisposition. We consider two measures of familiarity preferences in
domains other than investments: Home location distance to the birth place and an indicator for
whether the individual’s spouse is born in the same state an the individual himself or herself.
Note that the model controls for individual socioeconomic characteristics that may determine both
investment behavior and the other outcomes, e.g., income and wealth.
We report several results from this exercise. First, familiarity in some other, non-investment,
domains also has a significant genetic component: 40% for home location choice and 15% for spouse
choice. Second, the measures of investment and non-investment domain familiarity are correlated.
Those with more home bias in their investment portfolios have a stronger preference for a home
location close to their birth place and a spouse who is from that region. Finally, we find that
this correlation has a large genetic components, and the genetic correlation with distance to birth
location is statistically significant at the 5%-level.
This evidence is important because it suggests that investment biases are facets of much broader
individual behavior. For example, we are born with more or less of a preference for the familiar,
which affects behavior across both the investment and other domains.
22
VI Conclusion
We find that a long list of investment biases, e.g., the reluctance to realize losses, performance
chasing, and the home bias, are ”human,” in the sense that we are born with them. We base
this conclusion on empirical evidence that genetic factors explain up to 50% of the variation in
these biases across individuals. The psychological mechanisms behind the investment biases have
apparently survived natural selection over hundreds of thousands of years, presumably because they
maximize (or in a hunter-gatherer society used to maximize) the likelihood of human survival and
reproduction (e.g., Rayo and Becker (2007) and Brennan and Lo (2009)). But in our current society,
and when applied in the domain of investments, they may not always be appropriate.
One implication of our evidence is that it provides a biological basis for modeling investors with
non-standard preferences. In a series of papers, Barberis, Huang, and Santos (2001), Barberis and
Huang (2008), and Barberis and Xiong (2009)) develop models of the asset pricing implications of
investors exhibiting some of the behaviors we analyze. If individuals are genetically endowed with
certain non-standard preferences, asset pricing models should reflect such preferences.
Two other result are worth emphasizing. First, we find no evidence that general education
is a significant moderator of genetic investment behavior, i.e., the role of genetic predispositions
to investment biases does not seem to depend on the level of education. Second, genetic effects
on investment behavior are correlated with genetic effects on behaviors in other domains (e.g.,
those with a genetic preference for familiar stocks also exhibit a preference for familiarity in other
domains), suggesting that genetic investment biases is only one facet of much broader individual
behavior.
In recent years, significant research and public policy efforts have been devoted to financial
literacy (e.g., Thaler and Benartzi (2004), Lusardi and Mitchell (2007), and Campbell et al. (2011)),
which raises the question: Does our result that investment biases are partly genetic, and our result
that genetic investment biases are not significantly moderated by education, make policy initiatives
irrelevant? No, but our evidence has implications for the design of policy initiatives. It suggests that
policy should recognize that many individuals indeed exhibit investment biases, and that altering
such biases can be difficult.
23
Zhong et al. (2011) Tom et al. (2007) DeMartino et al. (2006) Cesarini et al. (2009) Fulker et al.
(1980) Hsu et al. (2005)
References
Agnew, J., Balduzzi, P., Sund´en, A., 2003. Portfolio choice and trading in a large 401(k) plan.
American Economic Review 93 (1), 193–215.
Agnew, J. R., 2006. Do behavioral biases vary across individuals? Evidence from individual level
401(k) data. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 41 (4), 939.
Ashenfelter, O., Krueger, A. B., 1994. Estimates of the economic returns to schooling from a new
sample of twins. American Economic Review 84 (5), 1157–1173.
Bailey, W., Kumar, A., Ng, D., 2010. Behavioral biases of mutual fund investors. Journal of Financial
Economics 102, 1–27.
Barber, B., Lee, Y., Liu, Y., Odean, T., 2007. Is the aggregate investor reluctant to realise losses?
Evidence from taiwan. European Financial Management 13 (3), 423–447.
Barber, B., Lee, Y., Liu, Y., Odean, T., 2009. Just how much do individual investors lose by trading?
Review of Financial Studies 22 (2), 609.
Barber, B., Odean, T., 2008. All that glitters: The effect of attention and news on the buying
behavior of individual and institutional investors. Review of Financial Studies 21 (2), 785–818.
Barber, B. M., Odean, T., 2000. Trading is hazardous to your wealth: The common stock investment
performance of individual investors. Journal of Finance 55 (2), 773–806.
Barber, B. M., Odean, T., 2001. Boys will be boys: Gender, overconfidence, and common stock
investment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116 (1), 261–292.
Barberis, N., Huang, M., 2008. Stocks as lotteries: The implications of probability weighting for
security prices. American Economic Review 98 (5), 2066–2100.
Barberis, N., Huang, M., Santos, T., 2001. Prospect theory and asset prices. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 116 (1), 1–53.
Barberis, N., Xiong, W., 2009. What drives the disposition effect? An analysis of a long-standing
preference-based explanation. Journal of Finance 64 (2), 751–784.
Barnea, A., Cronqvist, H., Siegel, S., 2010. Nature or nurture: What determines investor behavior?
Journal of Financial Economics 98, 583–604.
Behrman, J., Taubman, P., 1989. Is schooling “mostly in the genes”? Nature-nurture decomposition
using data on relatives. Journal of Political Economy 97, 1425–1446.
Benartzi, S., 2001. Excessive extrapolation and the allocation of 401 (k) accounts to company stock.
Journal of Finance 56 (5), 1747–1764.
24
Benjamin, D., Chabris, C., Glaeser, E., Gudnason, V., Harris, T., Laibson, D., Launer, L., Purcell,
S., 2008. Genoeconomics. The National Academies Press, Ch. 15, pp. 304–335.
Bergstresser, D., Chalmers, J., Tufano, P., 2009. Assessing the costs and benefits of brokers in the
mutual fund industry. Review of Financial Studies 22 (10), 4129–4156.
Bikhchandani, S., Hirshleifer, D., Welch, I., 1998. Learning from the behavior of others: Conformity,
fads, and informational cascades. Journal of Economic Perspective 12 (3), 151–170.
Bisin, A., Verdier, T., 2000. Beyond the melting pot: Cultural transmission, marriage, and the
evolution of ethnic and religious traits. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (3), 955–988.
Bisin, A., Verdier, T., 2001. The economics of cultural transmission and the dynamics of preferences.
Journal of Economic Theory 97 (2), 298 – 319.
Bortolus, R., Parazzini, F., Chatenoud, L., Benzi, G., Bianchi, M., Marini, A., 1999. The epidemiology
of multiple births. Human Reproduction Update 5 (2), 179.
Bouchard, T., McGue, M., 2003. Genetic and environmental influences on human psychological
differences. Journal of Neurobiology 54 (1), 4–45.
Bouchard, T. J., Lykken, D. T., McGue, M., Segal, N. L., Tellegen, A., 1990. Sources of human
psychological differences: The Minnesota study of twins reared apart. Science 250, 223–228.
Brennan, T. J., Lo, A. W., 2009. The origin of behavior. Working Paper, MIT Sloan School of
Management.
Calvet, L. E., Campbell, J. Y., Sodini, P., 2009a. Fight of flight? Portfolio rebalancing by individual
investors. Quarterly Journal of Economics 124, 301–348.
Calvet, L. E., Campbell, J. Y., Sodini, P., 2009b. Measuring the financial sophistication of households.
American Economic Review 99, 393–398.
Camerer, C., Loewenstein, G., Prelec, D., 2005. Neouroeconomics: How neuroscience can inform
economics. Journal of Economic Literature 43, 9–64.
Campbell, J., Jackson, H., Madrian, B., Tufano, P., 2011. Consumer financial protection. Journal of
Economic Perspectives 25 (1), 91–114.
Cesarini, D., Johannesson, M., Lichtenstein, P., Sandewall, O., Wallace, B., 2010. Genetic variation
in financial decision making. Journal of Finance 65, 1725–1754.
Cesarini, D., Johannesson, M., Lichtenstein, P., Wallace, B., 2009. Heritability of overconfidence.
Journal of the European Economic Association 7 (2-3), 617–627.
Cesarini, D., Johannesson, M., Magnusson, P. K. E., Wallace, B., 2011. The behavioral genetics of
behavioral anomalies. Forthcoming Management Science.
Chen, M. K., Lakshminarayanan, V., Santos, L. R., 2006. How basic are behavioral biases? Evidence
from Capuchin monkey trading behavior. Journal of Political Economy 114 (3), 517–537.
25
Chew, S. H., Ebstein, R. P., Zhong, S., 2011. Ambiguity aversion and familiarity bias: Evidence
from behavioral and gene association studies. Forthcoming Journal of Risk and Uncertainty.
Coval, J., Shumway, T., 2005. Do behavioral biases affect prices? Journal of Finance 60 (1), 1–34.
Cronqvist, H., Thaler, R. H., 2004. Design choices in privatized social-security systems: Learning
from the Swedish experience. American Economic Review 94 (2), 424–28.
DeMartino, B., Kumaran, D., Seymour, B., Dolan, R., 2006. Frames, biases, and rational decision-
making in the human brain. Science 313 (5787), 684.
Dhar, R., Zhu, N., 2006. Up close and personal: Investor sophistication and the disposition effect.
Management Science 52 (5), 726–740.
Ellsberg, D., 1961. Risk, ambiguity, and the savage axioms. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 643–669.
Fernandez, R., Fogli, A., Olivetti, C., 2004. Mothers and sons: Preference formation and female
labor force dynamics. Quarterly Journal of Economics 119 (4), 1249–1299.
Fischhoff, B., Slovic, P., Lichtenstein, S., 1977. Knowing with certainty: The appropriateness of
extreme confidence. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance
3 (4), 552.
Fox, C. R., Tversky, A., 1995. Ambiguity aversion and comparative ignorance. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 110 (3), 585–603, english.
French, K. R., Poterba, J. M., 1991. Investor diversification and international equity markets.
American Economic Review 81 (2), 222–226.
Frydman, C., Barberis, N., Camerer, C., Bossaerts, P., Rangel, A., 2011. Testing theories of investor
behavior using neural data. Working paper, Caltech.
Fulker, D. W., Eysenck, S. B. G., Zuckerman, M., 1980. A genetic and environmental analysis of
sensation seeking. Journal of Research in Personality 14, 261–281.
Gervais, S., Odean, T., 2001. Learning to be overconfident. Review of Financial Studies 14 (1), 1–27.
Goldberger, A., 1979. Heritability. Economica 46 (184), 327–347.
Golec, J., Tamarkin, M., 1998. Bettors love skewness, not risk, at the horse track. Journal of Political
Economy 106 (1), 205–225.
Griffin, D., Tversky, A., 1992. The weighting of evidence and the determinants of confidence.
Cognitive Psychology 24, 411–435.
Grinblatt, M., Keloharju, M., 2001a. How distance, language, and culture influence stockholdings
and trades. Journal of Finance 56 (3), 1053–1073.
Grinblatt, M., Keloharju, M., 2001b. What makes investors trade? Journal of Finance 56, 589–616.
Grinblatt, M., Keloharju, M., 2009. Sensation seeking, overconfidence, and trading activity. Journal
of Finance 64, 549–578.
26
Harbaugh, W., Krause, K., Vesterlund, L., 2001. Are adults better behaved than children? Age,
experience, and the endowment effect. Economics Letters 70 (2), 175–181.
Heath, C., Tversky, A., 1991. Preferences and beliefs: Ambiguity and competence in choice under
uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 4 (1), 5–28.
Hirshleifer, D., 2010. Self-enhancing transmission bias and active investing, working paper, University
of California, Irvine.
Hirshleifer, D., Luo, G., 2001. On the survival of overconfident traders in a competitive securities
market. Journal of Financial Markets 4 (1), 73–84.
Hong, H., Kubik, J. D., Stein, J. C., 2004. Social interaction and stock-market participation. Journal
of Finance 59 (1), 137–163.
Hsu, M., Bhatt, M., Adolphs, R., Tranel, D., Camerer, C., 2005. Neural systems responding to
degrees of uncertainty in human decision-making. Science 310 (5754), 1680.
Huberman, G., 2001. Familiarity breeds investment. Review of Financial Studies 14 (3), 659–680.
Ib´a˜nez, A., Blanco, C., Perez de Castro, I., Fernandez-Piqueras, J., S´aiz-Ruiz, J., 2003. Genetics of
pathological gambling. Journal of Gambling Studies 19:1, 11–22.
Johnson, D. D. P., Fowler, J. H., 2011. The evolution of overconfidence. Nature.
Johnson, W., Kyvik, K. O., Mortensen, E. L., Skytthe, A., Batty, G. D., Deary, I. J., 2010. Education
reduces the effects of genetic susceptibilities to poor physical health. International Journal of
Epidemiology 39 (2), 406–414.
Kahneman, D., Tversky, A., 1979. Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica
47 (2), 263–292.
Kumar, A., 2009. Who gambles in the stock market? Journal of Finance 64 (4), 1889–1933.
Lakshminarayanan, V., Chen, M., Santos, L., 2011. The evolution of decision-making under risk:
Framing effects in monkey risk preferences. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 47, 689–693.
Lewis, K., 1999. Trying to explain home bias in equities and consumption. Journal of Economic
Literature 37 (2), 571–608.
Lichtenstein, P., Sullivan, P. F., Cnattingius, S., Gatz, M., Johansson, S., Carlstr¨om, E., Bj¨ork, C.,
Svartengren, M., Wolk, A., Klareskog, L., de Faire, U., Schalling, M., Palmgren, J., Pedersen,
N. L., 2006. The Swedish twin registry in the third millennium: An update. Twin Research and
Human Genetics 9, 875–882.
Locke, P., Mann, S., 2005. Professional trader discipline and trade disposition. Journal of Financial
Economics 76 (2), 401–444.
Luo, G., 1998. Market efficiency and natural selection in a commodity futures market. Review of
Financial Studies 11 (3), 647–674.
27
Lusardi, A., Mitchell, O. S., 2007. Financial literacy and retirement preparedness: Evidence and
implications for financial education. Business Economics 42, 35–44.
McDermott, R., Fowler, J., Smirnov, O., 2008. On the evolutionary origin of prospect theory
preferences. Journal of Politics 70 (2), 335–50.
Muth´en, L., Muth´en, B., 2010. Mplus user’s guide (sixth edition).
Neale, M. C., Maes, H. H. M., 2004. Methodology for Genetic Studies of Twins and Families. NATO
ASI Series D: Behavioural and Social Science. Kluwer Academic Publishers B.V., Dordrecht, The
Netherlands.
Netzer, N., 2009. Evolution of time preferences and attitudes toward risk. American Economic
Review 99, 937–955.
Odean, T., 1998. Are investors reluctant to realize their losses? Journal of Finance 53 (5), 1775–1798.
Odean, T., 1999. Do investors trade too much? American Economic Review 89, 1279–1298.
Patel, J., Zeckhauser, R. J., Hendricks, D., 1991. The rationality struggle: Illustrations from financial
markets. American Economic Review 81 (2), 232–236.
Purcell, S., 2002. Variance components models for geneenvironment interaction in twin analysis.
Twin Research 5, 554–571.
Rayo, L., Becker, G., 2007. Evolutionary efficiency and happiness. Journal of Political Economy
115 (2).
Robson, A. J., 1996a. A biological basis for expected and non-expected utility. Journal of Economic
Theory 68 (2), 397–424.
Robson, A. J., 1996b. The evolution of attitudes to risk: Lottery tickets and relative wealth. Games
and Economic Behavior 14, 190–207.
Robson, A. J., 2001a. The biological basis of economic behavior. Journal of Economic Literature 29,
11–33.
Robson, A. J., 2001b. Why would nature give individuals utility functions? Journal of Political
Economy 109, 900–914.
Rogers, A. R., 1994. Evolution of time preference by natural selection. American Economic Review
84 (3), 460–81.
Rutter, M., 2006. Genes and behavior: Nature/nurture interplay explained. Blackwell Publishers,
Oxford, UK.
Santos, L., 2008. The evolution of irrationality: Insights from non-human primates. Oxford Studies
in Epistemology 2, 87–107.
Seasholes, M., Zhu, N., 2010. Individual investors and local bias. Journal of Finance 65 (5), 1987–
2010.
28
Shefrin, H., Statman, M., 1985. The disposition to sell winners too early and ride losers too long:
Theory and evidence. Journal of Finance, 777–790.
Simonson, I., Sela, A., 2011. On the heritability of consumer decision making: An exploratory
approach for studying genetic effects on judgment and choice. Journal of Consumer Research
37 (6), 951–966.
Slutske, W. S., Eisen, S., True, W. R., Lyons, M. J., Goldberg, J., Tsuang, M., 2000. Common
genetic vulnerability for pathological gambling and alcohol dependence in men. Archives of General
Psychiatry 7, 666–673.
Taubman, P., 1976. The determinants of earnings: Genetics, family, and other environments: A
study of white male twins. American Economic Review 66 (5), 858–870.
Taubman, P., 1981. On heritability. Economica 48 (192), 417–420.
Thaler, R. H., 1985. Mental accounting and consumer choice. Marketing Science 4 (3), 199–214.
Thaler, R. H., Benartzi, S., 2004. Save more tomorrow: Using behavioral economics to increase
employee savings. Journal of Political Economy 112, 164–187.
Tom, S., Fox, C., Trepel, C., Poldrack, R., 2007. The neural basis of loss aversion in decision-making
under risk. Science 315 (5811), 515.
Tversky, A., Kahneman, D., 1974. Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science 211,
453–458.
Tversky, A., Kahneman, D., 1983. Extensional versus intuitive reasoning: The conjunction fallacy
in probability judgment. Psychological Review 90 (4), 293–315.
Tversky, A., Kahneman, D., 1992. Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of
uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 5 (4), 297–323.
Waldman, M., 1994. Systematic errors and the theory of natural selection. American Economic
Review, 482–497.
Zhong, S., Chark, R., Ebstein, R., Chew, S., 2011. Imaging genomics for utility of risks over gains
and losses. Neuroimage.
Zhong, S., Israel, S., Xue, H., Sham, P., Ebstein, R., Chew, S., 2009. A neurochemical approach to
valuation sensitivity over gains and losses. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences
276 (1676), 4181.
29
Table 1
The Neuroscientific and Genetic Basis of Investment Biases
Investment behavior Psychological mechanism(s) Gene(s) Empirical evidence
Insufficient diversification Ambiguity aversion DRD5 (microsatellite marker); ESR2 (CA repeat) Chew et al. (2011)
Familiarity SLC6A4 (5-HTTLPR indel) Chew et al. (2011)
Neural basis for ambiguity aversion (Hsu et al. (2005))
Excessive trading Overconfidence NA Twin study design: Cesarini et al. (2009)
Sensation seeking Multiple SNPs in 4 dopamine genes Derringer et al. (2010)
Twin study design: Fulker et al. (1980)
Disposition effect Prospect theory 9-repeat vs. 10-repeat allele of DAT1 Zhong et al. (2009); Zhong et al. (2011)
10-repeat vs. 12-repeat allele of STin2 Zhong et al. (2009); Zhong et al. (2011)
Loss aversion in Capuchin monkeys (Chen et al. (2006))
Neural basis for loss aversion (Tom et al (2007))
Neural basis for the disposition effect (Frydman et al. (2011))
Mental accounting / Framing NA Narrow framing in Capuchin monkeys (Lakshminarayanan et al. (2011))
Neural basis for framing (De Martino et al. (2006))
Performance chasing Excessive extrapolation NA
Hot hands fallacy NA
Skewness preference Cumulative prospect theory Monoamine oxidase A (4 repeat) Zhong et al. (2009)
Twin study design: Slutske et al. (2000)
Table 1 provides information on existing evidence from neuroscience and behavioral genetics with respect to investment behaviors examined in this study.
Table 2
Summary Statistics
Panel A: Number of Twins by Zygosity and Gender
All Twins
Male Female Total Same Sex:
Male Same Sex:
Female Opposite
Sex Total
Number of twins (N)30,416 4,066 5,206 9,272 4,522 5,326 11,296 21,144
Fraction (%) 100% 13% 17% 30% 15% 18% 37% 70%
Panel B: Socioeconomic Characteristics and Equity Portfolio Characteristics
All Twins
Variable NMean Median Std. Dev. Mean Median Std. Dev.
30,416 47.08 48.00 17.64 53.06 55.00 15.51
30,416 0.15 0.00 0.35 0.20 0.00 0.40
30,416 0.22 0.00 0.41 0.26 0.00 0.44
30,416 0.58 1.00 0.49 0.47 0.00 0.50
30,416 0.06 0.00 0.23 0.06 0.00 0.24
17,395 11.22 11.00 3.26 11.11 11.00 3.29
30,416 0.40 0.00 0.48 0.29 0.00 0.44
30,416 0.46 0.00 0.50 0.54 1.00 0.50
30,416 0.09 0.00 0.28 0.11 0.00 0.30
30,416 0.05 0.00 0.21 0.07 0.00 0.24
30,416 31,379 25,476 27,592 35,203 27,678 35,449
30,416 40,759 14,537 155,296 48,062 17,342 442,298
30,416 124,351 71,883 252,478 142,603 83,504 576,198
30,416 31,802 16,020 68,330 30,396 13,759 149,778
30,416 92,549 42,961 223,277 112,207 56,417 516,665
30,416 0.89 0.99 0.18 0.89 0.99 0.18
30,416 3.56 2.33 3.80 3.62 2.25 3.97
30,416 16,841 3,662 109,292 24,815 4,159 663,773
12,378 3.32 1.89 3.91 3.42 1.89 4.15
12,378 22,558 2,825 163,360 29,218 2,819 543,596
23,870 2.41 1.89 1.84 2.34 1.80 1.86
23,870 7,018 2,059 20,160 7,788 2,292 17,304
16,643 0.17 0.00 0.37 0.16 0.00 0.36
30,122 112.82 0.00 212.65 109.84 0.00 213.93
11,009 0.57 1.00 0.49 0.60 1.00 0.49
Age
Identical Twins Fraternal Twins
Identical Twins Fraternal Twins
Net Worth (USD)
Fraction of Equity Assets included
Less than High School
Widowed
High School
College or more
Total Debt (USD)
Divorced
No Education Data available
Years of Education
Single
Married
Disposable Income (USD)
Financial Assets (USD)
Total Assets (USD)
Number of Stocks and Equity Mutual Funds
Value of Stocks and Equity Mutual Funds
Number of Stocks
Value of Stocks (USD)
Number of Equity Mutual Funds
Value of Equity Mutual Funds (USD)
Distance to Birthplace (km)
Spouse from Home Region
Finance Occupation (Broad)
Table 2 Panel A provides information on the number of identical and non-identical twins used in this study. Panel B provides summary
statistics for several socioeconomic characteristics and portfolio characteristics, separately for identical and non-identical twins. All variables
are defined in detail in Appendix Table A1.
Table 3
Investment Behaviors
All Twins
NMean Median Std. Dev. Mean Median Std. Dev.
Stocks
Home Bias 12,378 0.94 1.00 0.16 0.94 1.00 0.15
Turnover 11,508 0.20 0.03 0.35 0.17 0.02 0.33
Disposition Effect 2,268 0.05 0.03 0.41 0.07 0.03 0.41
Performance Chasing 6,672 0.15 0.00 0.22 0.14 0.00 0.22
Skewness Preference 12,378 0.04 0.00 0.10 0.03 0.00 0.10
Stocks and Equity Mutual Funds
Diversification 30,416 0.70 0.93 0.38 0.67 0.89 0.39
Home Bias 30,416 0.51 0.47 0.30 0.53 0.49 0.31
Turnover 28,108 0.27 0.17 0.38 0.25 0.14 0.37
Disposition Effect 5,922 0.01 0.00 0.40 0.00 0.00 0.39
Performance Chasing 25,530 0.10 0.00 0.16 0.10 0.00 0.16
Skewness Preference 30,416 0.05 0.00 0.10 0.06 0.00 0.10
Identical Twins Fraternal Twins
Table 3 reports summary statistics for the main measures of financial behavior, Diversification, Home Bias, Turnover, Loss Aversion,
Performance Chasing, and Skewness Preference. All variables are defined in detail in Appendix Table A1.
Table 4
Decomposition of Investment Behaviors
Home
Bias Turnover Disposition
Effect Performance
Chasing Skewness
Preference
Intercept 0.955 0.134 0.132 2.313 0.004
0.021 0.039 0.168 0.564 0.010
Male 0.004 0.062 -0.007 0.062 0.008
0.003 0.008 0.002 0.056 0.002
Age 0.004 0.031 0.011 0.092 0.015
0.007 0.014 0.040 0.111 0.004
Age - squared 0.000 -0.005 0.000 -0.008 -0.002
0.001 0.001 0.004 0.011 0.000
High School -0.001 0.000 -0.010 -0.117 0.001
0.002 0.004 0.012 0.093 0.001
College or More -0.012 0.022 -0.032 -0.156 0.005
0.003 0.008 0.026 0.080 0.002
No Education Data Available -0.026 0.037 -0.025 -0.002 0.010
0.005 0.010 0.034 0.057 0.003
Married -0.001 -0.001 -0.054 -0.051 0.002
0.004 0.009 0.025 0.057 0.003
Second Net Worth Quartile Indicator -0.001 -0.005 -0.056 0.122 0.003
0.003 0.007 0.021 0.081 0.002
Third Net Worth Quartile Indicator 0.001 -0.011 -0.006 0.200 -0.002
0.003 0.008 0.029 0.084 0.002
Highest Net Worth Quartile Indicator -0.010 -0.025 -0.007 0.294 -0.004
0.004 0.008 0.026 0.087 0.002
Log of Disposable Income -0.001 -0.002 -0.004 0.117 0.000
0.001 0.002 0.013 0.044 0.000
Number of Trades (Sales) 0.003
0.014
Number of Holdings -0.003
0.001
A Shar
e
0.453 0.257 0.297 0.311 0.281
0.052 0.029 0.077 0.090 0.051
C Share 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.096 0.000
0.027 0.008 0.041 0.065 0.028
E Share 0.547 0.743 0.703 0.593 0.719
0.037 0.027 0.052 0.038 0.034
R20.010 0.014 0.020 0.009 0.000
N12,378 11,508 2,268 6,672 12,378
Table 3 reports results from maximum likelihood estimation. The different Financial Behaviors are modeled as
linear functions of observable socioeconomic variables and random effects representing additive genetic effects
(A), shared environmental effects (C), as well as an individual-specific error (E). For each estimated model, we
report the coefficient estimates for the socioeconomic variables, the variance fraction of the combined error term
explained by each unobserved effect (A Share – for the additive genetic effect, C Share – for common
environmental effect, E Share – for the individual-specific environmental effect) as well as the corresponding
bootstrapped standard errors (1,000 resamples). Only direct stock holdings are considered in the measurement of
the different financial behaviors. All variables are defined in Appendix Table A1. R
2
denotes the coefficient of
variation. N provides the number of observations used in each estimation.
Table 5
Individuals with at Least 20% of Total Assets Invested in Risky Financial Assets
Model NA - Share C - Share E - Share
Home Bias 2,574 0.525 0.116 0.359
0.168 0.122 0.072
Turnover 2,306 0.447 0.000 0.553
0.129 0.069 0.084
Disposition Effect 866 0.451 0.000 0.549
0.095 0.030 0.087
Performance Chasing 1,814 0.296 0.220 0.484
0.171 0.132 0.069
Skewness Preference 2,574 0.350 0.047 0.603
0.164 0.128 0.079
Variance Components
Table 5 reports results from maximum likelihood estimation for the subset of investors
with at least 20% of total assets invested in risky financial assets. The different Financial
Behaviors are modeled as linear functions of observable socioeconomic variables (see
Table 4 for a list of the variables included) and random effects representing additive
genetic effects (A), shared environmental effects (C), as well as an individual-specific
error (E). For each estimated model, we report the variance fraction of the combined error
term explained by each unobserved effect (A Share – for the additive genetic effect, C
Share – for common environmental effect, E Share – for the individual-specific
environmental effect) as well as the corresponding bootstrapped standard errors (1,000
resamples). All variables are defined in Appendix Table A1. N provides the number of
observations used in each estimation.
Table 6
Delegated Portfolio Management
Model NA - Share C - Share E - Share
Diversification 30,416 0.389 0.022 0.589
0.032 0.021 0.014
Home Bias 30,416 0.361 0.000 0.639
0.013 0.003 0.012
Turnover 28,108 0.258 0.000 0.742
0.022 0.009 0.018
Disposition Effect 5,922 0.198 0.000 0.802
0.039 0.015 0.032
Performance Chasing 25,530 0.272 0.000 0.728
0.019 0.002 0.019
Skewness Preference 30,416 0.273 0.000 0.727
0.036 0.018 0.024
Variance Components
Table 6 reports results from maximum likelihood estimation. The different Financial
Behaviors are modeled as linear functions of observable socioeconomic variables and
random effects representing additive genetic effects (A), shared environmental effects
(C), as well as an individual-specific error (E). For each estimated model, we report the
coefficient estimates for the socioeconomic variables, the variance fraction of the
combined error term explained by each unobserved effect (A Share – for the additive
genetic effect, C Share – for common environmental effect, E Share – for the individual-
specific environmental effect) as well as the corresponding bootstrapped standard
errors (1,000 resamples).Financial behaviors are derived from all holdings of stocks and
equity mutual funds. All variables are defined in Appendix Table A1. R
2
denotes the
coefficient of variation. N provides the number of observations used in each estimation.
Table 7
Robustness Checks
Panel A: Opposite-Sex Twins
Model NA - Share C - Share E - Share
Home Bias 7,916 0.462 0.012 0.526
0.085 0.063 0.041
Turnover 7,412 0.279 0.000 0.721
0.060 0.039 0.033
Disposition Effect 1,548 0.315 0.000 0.685
0.087 0.052 0.056
Performance Chasing 4,390 0.326 0.089 0.584
0.102 0.080 0.040
Skewness Preference 7,916 0.289 0.000 0.711
0.056 0.036 0.036
Panel B: Model Misspecification
Model NA - Share C - Share E - Share
Home Bias 12,378 0.509 -0.047 0.538
0.102 0.072 0.042
Turnover 11,508 0.354 -0.076 0.722
0.077 0.051 0.033
Disposition Effect 2,268 0.365 -0.054 0.689
0.150 0.104 0.060
Skewness Preference 12,378 0.331 -0.039 0.708
0.102 0.071 0.041
Variance Components
Variance Components
Panel C: Excluding Similar Portfolios
Model NA - Share C - Share E - Share
Home Bias 9,902 0.235 0.000 0.765
0.058 0.025 0.043
Turnover 8,990 0.217 0.000 0.783
0.044 0.021 0.033
Disposition Effect 1,714 0.110 0.029 0.861
0.087 0.047 0.061
Performance Chasing 5,208 0.199 0.062 0.739
0.088 0.061 0.040
Skewness Preference 9,902 0.120 0.053 0.827
0.068 0.052 0.032
Panel D: Controlling for Social Interaction
Model NA - Share C - Share E - Share
Home Bias 6,228 0.321 0.093 0.586
0.123 0.096 0.046
Turnover 5,836 0.208 0.052 0.739
0.085 0.063 0.037
Disposition Effect 1,192 0.233 0.046 0.721
0.121 0.080 0.070
Performance Chasing 3,516 0.066 0.309 0.625
0.094 0.079 0.039
Skewness Preference 6,228 0.152 0.123 0.725
0.106 0.090 0.039
Variance Components
Variance Components
Table 7 reports results from maximum likelihood estimation for financial behaviors measured
on direct stock holdings only. The different Financial Behaviors are modeled as linear
functions of observable socioeconomic variables (see Table 2 for a list of the variables
included) and random effects representing additive genetic effects (A), shared
environmental effects (C), as well as an individual-specific error (E). For each estimated
model, we report the variance fraction of the combined error term explained by each
unobserved effect (A Share – for the additive genetic effect, C Share – for common
environmental effect, E Share – for the individual-specific environmental effect) as well as
the corresponding bootstrapped standard errors (1,000 resamples). Panel A presents
results for the subset of twin pairs that exclude opposite-sex twin pairs. Panel B allows the
variance components to take on negative values in case the shared environmental
component is estimated to be zero in Table 4. Panel C reports results for the subset of twin
pairs for whom the sum of the absolute value of portfolio weight differences is at least one.
In Panel D, twin pairs are sorted into ten bins based on contact frequency between them
(contact frequency ranges from zero to 360 times per year). By randomly dropping identical
or fraternal twins, we ensure that each bin has the same number of identical and fraternal
twin pairs. All variables are defined in Appendix Table A1. N provides the number of
observations used in each estimation.
Table 8
Gene-Environment Interactions: Educaiton
Estimate s.e. Estimate s.e. Estimate s.e. Estimate s.e. Estimate s.e.
Education
a_m 0.2300 0.010 -0.2340 0.010 -0.2370 0.020 -0.2280 0.013 0.2300 0.010
c_m 0.1560 0.012 0.1520 0.013 0.1360 0.029 0.1440 0.017 0.1560 0.012
e_m 0.1820 0.004 0.1800 0.004 0.1710 0.008 0.1780 0.006 0.1820 0.004
Financial Behavior
a_c -0.0070 0.037 -0.0370 0.031 -0.1440 0.181 0.1090 0.035 -0.0030 0.009
alpha_c -0.0010 0.031 0.0210 0.024 0.1320 0.138 -0.0720 0.027 0.0000 0.006
a_u 0.0500 0.061 0.0550 0.054 -0.0990 0.195 -0.0070 0.100 0.0280 0.008
alpha_u 0.0230 0.058 0.0100 0.032 -0.0890 0.143 -0.0330 0.075 0.0050 0.007
c_c 0.0120 0.036 0.0210 0.035 -0.1070 0.232 0.1240 0.038 0.0120 0.010
chi_c -0.0120 0.031 -0.0230 0.026 0.1050 0.167 -0.0940 0.028 -0.0080 0.007
c_u 0.0580 0.045 0.0700 0.043 0.0560 1.221 -0.0700 0.062 0.0000 0.020
chi_u -0.0570 0.031 0.0000 0.027 -0.0370 0.810 -0.0040 0.049 0.0000 0.010
e_c -0.0040 0.020 -0.0110 0.024 -0.0910 0.110 0.0090 0.029 0.0020 0.007
epsilon_c 0.0000 0.017 0.0060 0.020 0.0750 0.088 -0.0030 0.024 0.0000 0.005
e_u -0.0950 0.013 0.2010 0.013 0.5460 0.061 0.2250 0.017 0.0740 0.004
epsilon_u -0.0270 0.011 0.0650 0.011 -0.1670 0.049 -0.0400 0.014 0.0030 0.003
N
Skewness
Preference
6,804
Home Bias Disposition Effect Performance
ChasingTurnover
6,804 3,4946,348 1,304
Table 8 reports parameter estimates and standard errors (s.e.) from maximum likelihood estimation of gene-environment interactions models
(see Figure 2 for a presentation of the model). The moderator variable is education as measured by years of education (divided by 10 for
computational reasons). All measures of biases are based on direct stock holdings only. In a first stage (untabulated), we have removed (via
linear regression) the effect of control variables listed in Table 2, with the exception of those related to education. N provides the number of
observations.
Table 9
Occupational Financial Experience
Model NA - Share C - Share E - Share
Diversification 622 0.000 0.222 0.778
0.104 0.090 0.069
Home Bias 622 0.000 0.206 0.794
0.088 0.082 0.073
Turnover 582 0.000 0.110 0.890
0.106 0.067 0.088
Performance Chasing 562 0.026 0.106 0.868
0.102 0.068 0.078
Skewness Preference 622 0.187 0.000 0.813
0.091 0.042 0.079
Variance Components
Table 9 reports results from maximum likelihood estimation for subsets of twins that
have occupational experience in finance. The different Financial Behaviors are modeled
as linear functions of observable socioeconomic variables and random effects
representing additive genetic effects (A), shared environmental effects (C), as well as
an individual-specific error (E). For each estimated model, we report the coefficient
estimates for the socioeconomic variables, the variance fraction of the combined error
term explained by each unobserved effect (A Share – for the additive genetic effect, C
Share – for common environmental effect, E Share – for the individual-specific
environmental effect) as well as the corresponding bootstrapped standard errors (1,000
resamples).Financial behaviors are derived from all holdings of stocks and equity
mutual funds. All variables are defined in Appendix Table A1. R
2
denotes the coefficient
of variation. N provides the number of observations used in each estimation.
Table 10
Genetic Correlations
Home
Bias Distance to
Birthplace Home
Bias Spouse from
Home Region
A
- Share 0.455 0.400 0.364 0.146
0.059 0.085 0.116 0.092
C - Share 0.000 0.210 0.000 0.192
0.039 0.061 0.066 0.067
E - Share 0.545 0.389 0.636 0.662
0.031 0.036 0.081 0.041
Correlation
Genetic Correlation
Correlation of Common Environment
Correlation of Individual Environment
N2,56612,180
0.010
0.022
0.240
0.239
0.0350.021
-0.106
0.036
-0.069
-0.031
0.009
Model I Model II
0.031
0.000 0.000
Table 10 reports results from maximum likelihood estimation of bivariate model. Home Bias
(measured for direct holdings of stocks) and Distance to Birthplace (Model I) or Spouse from Home
Region (Model II) are modeled jointly as a linear function of observable socioeconomic
characteristics (Home Bias only - see Table 2 for a list of socioeconomic variables included) as well
as three random effects representing additive genetic effects (A), shared environmental effects (C),
as well as an individual-specific error (E). For each model, we report the variance fraction explained
by each random effect (A Share – for the additive genetic effects, C Share – for shared
environmental effects, E Share – for the individual-specific random effect), the overall correlation
both variables in a given model as well as the correlation between the genetic and individual specific
environmental effects of each variable. Corresponding standard errors are bootstrapped with 1,000
resamples. Whenever at least A, C, or E Share is estimated to be zero, the corresponding
correlation is set to zero. All variables are defined in Appendix Table A1. N provides the number of
observations used in each estimation.
Table 10 reports results from maximum likelihood estimation of bivariate model. Home Bias
(measured for direct holdings of stocks) and Distance to Birthplace (Model I) or Spouse from Home
Region (Model II) are modeled jointly as a linear function of observable socioeconomic
characteristics (Home Bias only - see Table 2 for a list of socioeconomic variables included) as well
as three random effects representing additive genetic effects (A), shared environmental effects (C),
as well as an individual-specific error (E). For each model, we report the variance fraction explained
by each random effect (A Share – for the additive genetic effects, C Share – for shared
environmental effects, E Share – for the individual-specific random effect), the overall correlation
both variables in a given model as well as the correlation between the genetic and individual specific
environmental effects of each variable. Corresponding standard errors are bootstrapped with 1,000
resamples. Whenever at least A, C, or E Share is estimated to be zero, the corresponding
correlation is set to zero. All variables are defined in Appendix Table A1. N provides the number of
observations used in each estimation.
Appendix Table A1
Definition of all Variables
V
ariable Descri
p
tion
T
yp
es of Twins
Identical Twins Twins that are genetically identical, also called monozygotic twins. Zygosity is determined by the Swedish
Twin Registry based on questions about intrapair similarities in childhood.
Non-identical Twins Twins that share on average 50% of their genes, also called dizygotic or fraternal twins. Non-identical twins
b f th f it Z it i d t i d b th S di h T i R i t b d
can
b
e o
f
th
e same sex or o
f
oppos
it
e sex.
Z
ygos
it
y
i
s
d
e
t
erm
i
ne
d
b
y
th
e
S
we
di
s
h
T
w
i
n
R
eg
i
s
t
ry
b
ase
d
on
questions about intrapair similarities in childhood.
Investment Biases & Tradin
g
Behavio
r
Diversification Diversification is defined as the proportion invested in mutual funds, but not invested in individual stocks.
To reduce measurement error, we calculate the equally weighted average Diversification across all years
the individual is in the data set.
Home Bias Home Bias is defined as the equity portfolio share of Swedish securities.In particular, at the end of each
year and for each investor, we add the market value of all Swedish stocks in the investor's portfolio to the
market value of the Swedish equity allocation of all mutual funds held by the investor. We divide the value
of these Swedish e
q
uit
y
holdin
g
s b
y
the total market value of direct
(
i.e. stocks
)
and indirect
(
i.e. e
q
uit
y
qy g y ( ) ( qy
allocation of mutual funds) equity holdings. We classify stocks as Swedish or foreign based on the country
in which the stock is legally registered, as reflected in the country code of a given stock's ISIN. For mutual
funds, we collect annual fund-specific data from Morningstar on the fund's total equity allocation as well as
on the fund's equity allocation to Sweden. For equity or mixed mutual funds that are not covered by
Morningstar we infer the fund's investment focus from the fund's name. By default, we assume that the
fund is fully invested in international equities. Only if the fund name suggests an investment focus on
Swedish equity, we classify the fund as Swedish. Finally, to improve the precision of our measure, for each
investor we calculate the equally weighted average Home Bias across all years with non-missing data.
Turnover For direct stock holdings, we divide, for each individual investor and year, the sales volume (in Swedish
krona) during the year by the value of directly held stocks at the beginning of the year. Since we do not
have sales price information for mutual funds, we also construct a turnover measure using the number of
sales during the year divided by the number of equity securities in the investor's portfolio at the beginning
of the year. In each case, Turnover is defined as the average annual turnover using all years with equity
holdings data for an investor. To avoid that our analysis is affected by outliers, we drop observations for
which Turnover is higher than the top one percentile of the Turnover distribution.
Loss Aversion We measure the Disposition Effect as the difference between the ratio of realized to unrealized gains and
the ratio of realized to unrealized losses (see Odean (1998) and Dhar and Zhou (2006)). Securities are
classified as losses and gains based on the raw return during a given year. We categorize gains and
losses as realized if the number of units held decreases relative to the previous year, and unrealized
otherwise Finally using all years with at least one sales transaction we count for each investor the total
otherwise
.
Finally
,
using
all
years
with
at
least
one
sales
transaction
,
we
count
for
each
investor
the
total
number of realized and unrealized gains and losses. The Disposition Effect is then the difference between
the ratio of realized to unrealized gains and the ratio of realized to unrealized losses.
Performance Chasing Performance Chasing is measured by an individual's propensity to purchase securities that have
performed well in the recent past. Specifically, each year we sort stocks and equity mutual funds
separately into return deciles using the raw returns during the year. For each investor that has purchased
securities during our sample periods, we calculate performance chasing as the fraction of purchased
securities with returns in the top two deciles. The higher that fraction, the more the individual chases
performance by overweighting securities with higher recent performance.
Skewness Preference Skewness Preference is measured in the spirit of Kumar (2009). For each investor and year we calculate
the fraction of the portfolio that is invested in
``
lottery
"
securities We define a security as a lottery security
the
fraction
of
the
portfolio
that
is
invested
in
lottery
securities
.
We
define
a
security
as
a
lottery
security
if it has a below median price as well as above median idiosyncratic volatility and skewness. We use a the
world market return, the squared world market return, the local Swedish market return, and the squared
local market returns factor in our asset pricing model to determine a security's idiosyncratic error term.
Regressions are performed every year using the last 24 months of return data. Skewness Preference is
the fraction of lottery securities averaged over all years with portfolio data.
Socioeconomic Characteristics
Male An indicator variable that equals one if an individual is male and zero otherwise. Gender is obtained from
Statistics Sweden.
Age The average age over the years an individual is included in our sample. Age is obtained from the Statistics
Sweden.
Less than High School An indicator variable that equals one if an individual has not completed high school (gymnsasium) zero
otherwise. Educational information is obtained from Statistics Sweden.
High School An indicator variable that equals one if an individual has completed high school (gymnasium) but has not
attended university, zero otherwise. Educational information is obtained from Statistics Sweden.
College or more An indicator variable that equals one if an individual has attended university, zero otherwise. Educational
information is obtained from Statistics Sweden.
No Education data available An indicator variable that equals one if no educational data are available for an individual, zero otherwise.
Educational information is obtained from Statistics Sweden.
Years of Education
The number of years of education based on the highest completed degree The variable is obtained from
Years
of
Education
The
number
of
years
of
education
based
on
the
highest
completed
degree
.
The
variable
is
obtained
from
the Swedish Twin Registry and available only for a subset of twins.
Married The average (over the years an individual is included in our sample) of an annual indicator variable that
equals one if an individual is married in a given year and zero otherwise. The marital status is obtained
from the Statistics Sweden.
V
ariable Descri
p
tion
Disposable Income The average individual disposable income (over the years an individual is included in our sample), as
defined by Statistics Sweden, that is, the sum of income from labor, business, and investment, plus
received transfers, less taxes and alimony payments. Expressed in nominal Swedish Krona (SEK) (unless
indicated otherwise). The data are obtained from Statistics Sweden.
Financial Assets The average end-of-year market value of an individual's financial assets (over the years an individual is
included in our sample) as reported by Statistics Sweden, expressed in nominal Swedish Krona (SEK)
(unless indicated otherwise). Financial assets include checking, savings, and money market accounts,
(direct and indirect) bond holdings, (direct and indirect) equity holdings, investments in options and other
financial assets such as rights convertibles and warrants
financial
assets
such
as
rights
,
convertibles
,
and
warrants
.
Total Assets The average end-of-year market value of an individual's financial and real assets (over the years an
individual is included in our sample) as reported by Statistics Sweden, expressed in nominal Swedish
Krona (SEK) (unless indicated otherwise).
Net Worth The average difference between the end-of-year market value of an individual's assets and her liabilities
(over the years an individual is included in our sample), as reported by Statistics Sweden. Expressed in
nominal Swedish Krona (SEK) (unless indicated otherwise).
Number of Stocks and Equity Mutual Funds The average end-of-year number of holdings of distinct individual stocks and equity mutual funds (over the
years an individual is included in our sample), as reported by Statistics Sweden.
Value of Stocks and Equity Mutual Funds The average end-of-year market value of holdings of individual stocks and equity mutual funds (over the
years an individual is included in our sample), as reported by Statistics Sweden. Expressed in nominal
Swedish Krona (SEK) (unless indicated otherwise).
Number of Stocks The average end-of-year number of holdings of distinct individual stocks (over the years an individual is
included in our sample), as reported by Statistics Sweden.
Value of Stocks The average end-of-year market value of holdings of individual stocks (over the years an individual is
included in our sample), as reported by Statistics Sweden. Expressed in nominal Swedish Krona (SEK)
(unless indicated otherwise).
Number of Equity Mutual Funds The average end-of-year number of holdings of distinct equity mutual funds (over the years an individual is
included in our sample), as reported by Statistics Sweden.
Value of Equity Mutual Funds The average end-of-year market value of holdings of equity mutual funds (over the years an individual is
included in our sample), as reported by Statistics Sweden. Expressed in nominal Swedish Krona (SEK)
(unless indicated otherwise)
(unless
indicated
otherwise)
.
Contact Intensity The number of contacts per year between twins. The number is calculated as the average of the numbers
reported by both twins. If only one twin provides a number, this number is used. The data are obtained
from the Swedish Twin Registry.
Distance to Birthplace (km) The driving distance in kilometers to the state of birth. We define this distance to be the average distance
to the center of all municipalities within the state of birth weighted by their population. The distance is
obtained from Google Maps. The population numbers are obtained from Statistics Sweden.
Spouse from Home Region An indicator variable available for married individuals that takes on the value of one if the spouse was born
in the same state as the individual and zero otherwise.
0.25
0.35
0.45
0.55
Figure 1
Correlations by Genetic Similarity
Identical Twins Fraternal Twins Fraternal Twins - Same Sex Fraternal Twins - Opposite Sex Random Match
-0.15
-0.05
0.05
0.15
Home
Bias Turnover Disposition Effect Performance
Chasing Skewness
Preference
Figure 1 repots Pearson correlation coefficients for Home Bias, Loss Aversion, Performance Chasing, and
Turnover between twins for different types of twin pairs as well as for twins randomly matched with non-twins
controlling for age and gender. Measure are calculate using holdings and transactions of direct stock holdings
only. All variables are defined in Appendix Table A1.
Figure 2 presents a graphical presentation of the gene-interaction model proposed by
Purcell (2002). M symbolizes the moderator and y the financial behavior we study. A,
C, and E correspond to the unobservable genetic and environmental factors. See
Purcell (2002) details.
Figure 3
Education as a Moderator
Figure A: Home Bias Figure B: Turnover
Figure C: Disposition Effect Figure D: Performance Chasing
Figure E: Skewness Preference
Figure 3 presents results of the gene-interaction model proposed by Purcell (2002). In each of the four panels, Education acts as the moderator. The x-axis
represents years of education, while the y-axis represents the variance. See Table 8 for detailed estimation results.
0
0.005
0.01
0.015
0.02
0.025
0.03
810 12 14 16
Var(A)
Var(C)
Var(E)
0
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
0.25
810 12 14 16
Var(A)
Var(C)
Var(E)
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.05
0.06
810 12 14 16
Var(A)
Var(C)
Var(E)
0
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.08
0.1
0.12
810 12 14 16
Var(A)
Var(C)
Var(E)
0
0.001
0.002
0.003
0.004
0.005
0.006
0.007
0.008
810 12 14 16
Var(A)
Var(C)
Var(E)
... The susceptibility to framing in decision-making varies substantially across individuals (De Martino et al., 2006; Kahneman and Tversky, 1979; Roiser et al., 2009; Sharp and Salter, 1997). Twin studies have established that the susceptibility to framing is moderately heritable (Simonson and Sela, 2011; Cesarini et al., 2012; Cronqvist and Siegel, 2012), suggesting that genetic factors are a strong factor underlying the individual difference in susceptibility to framing. In this study, we aimed to investigate whether a genetic polymorphism, COMT Val158Met (rs4680), which is related to negativity bias during emotion processing, was associated with individual susceptibility to framing. ...
... Previous research has shown that the individual difference in susceptibility to framing can be attributable to the differences in gene expression, with moderate heritability (Simonson and Sela, 2011; Cesarini et al., 2012; Cronqvist and Siegel, 2012 ). However, how genes influence this individual difference is still unknown. ...
Article
Full-text available
Individuals tend to avoid risk in a gain frame, in which options are presented in a positive way, but seek risk in a loss frame, in which the same options are presented negatively. Previous studies suggest that emotional responses play a critical role in this "framing effect." Given that the Met allele of COMT Val158Met polymorphism (rs4680) is associated with the negativity bias during emotional processing, this study investigated whether this polymorphism is associated with individual susceptibility to framing and which brain areas mediate this gene-behavior association. Participants were genotyped, scanned in resting state, and completed a monetary gambling task with options (sure vs risky) presented as potential gains or losses. The Met allele carriers showed a greater framing effect than the Val/Val homozygotes as the former gambled more than the latter in the loss frame. Moreover, the gene-behavior association was mediated by resting-state functional connectivity (RSFC) between orbitofrontal cortex (OFC) and bilateral amygdala. Met allele carriers showed decreased RSFC, thereby demonstrating higher susceptibility to framing than Val allele carriers. These findings demonstrate the involvement of COMT Val158Met polymorphism in the framing effect in decision-making and suggest RSFC between OFC and amygdala as a neural mediator underlying this gene-behavior association. Hum Brain Mapp, 2016. © 2016 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
... Other model specifications that use categories for education (< HS, HS, some college, college) decade-length age categories, and a dummy to separate larger households from smaller household generate similar non-signficant results. This is consistent with the findings of Cronqvist and Siegel (2012) who find that general education explains a minuscule fraction of the variation in financial biases. It is also consistent with a casual observation of the first table Almenberg and Gerdes (2012), in which there is no clear pattern between α as a function of education or income. ...
Article
Exponential- growth bias (EGB) is the tendency for individuals to partially neglect compounding of exponential growth. We develop a model wherein biased agents misperceive the intertemporal budget constraint, and derive conditions for overconsumption and dynamic inconsistency. We construct an incentivized measure of EGB in a US-representative population and find substantial bias, with approximately one third of subjects estimated as the fully biased type. The magnitude of the bias is negatively associated with asset accumulation, and does not respond to a simple graphical intervention.
... This finding provides a microfoundation for the result documented byCronqvist and Siegel (2012) that there exists more similarity in the propensity to display investment biases among identical twins, relative to fraternal twins, suggesting that suboptimal behavior may have a genetic component.4 SeeGennaioli and Shleifer (2010) for a model of "local thinking" that is consistent with the observed importance of salience for belief formation. ...
Article
The goal of this study is to ask whether investors learn differently from gains (positive news) versus losses (negative news), whether learning performance is better or worse when people are actively investing in a security or passively observing the security’s payoffs, and whether there are personal characteristics that correlate with learning performance. The experimental evidence documented here indicates that the ability to learn from financial information is on average worse in the loss domain, in particular if the investor has personally experienced the prior outcomes of the financial asset considered. Within individual, learning from gains versus losses, or during active versus passive involvement, are not perfectly correlated, indicating that there exists heterogeneity across people with respect to the type of financial information or context to which they are the most sensitive. Learning performance is determined by acquired financial expertise as well as by genetic factors related to memory and cognitive control.
Article
Behavioral finance has emerged from the divergences observed to explain and address the traditional theories of finance and serves as supplement to classical finance by introducing behavioral aspects to decision‐making. This study provides academics with a comprehensible and complete synopsis of the evolution of behavioral finance, as well as critical insight is provided. The synopsis was based on the search for publications in Web of Science ( WoS ) and Scopus and the use of R, Gephi and Tree of Science ‐ToS‐ software, using citation analysis, graphos and classification analysis. The results showed psychological aspects, investment in stocks and cognitive biases with the highest visibility. A tree‐like structure of hierarchization was developed by ToS. The clusters of publications with the greatest literary contribution were analyzed and the publications with the greatest visibility in each cluster identified. This study provides insights into the current trend in finance towards better understanding of the essential factors in the investor´s decision making.
Article
Full-text available
Source preference in which equally distributed risks may be valued differently has been receiving increasing attention. Using subjects recruited in Berkeley, Fox and Tversky (1995) demonstrate a familiarity bias in source preference—betting on a less than even-chance event based on San Francisco temperature is valued more than betting on a better than even-chance event based on Istanbul temperature. Neophobia is associated with the amygdala which is GABA-rich and is known to be modulated by benzodiazepines as anxiolytic agents that enhance the activity of the GABAA receptor in processing anxiety and fear. This leads to our hypothesis that familiarity bias in decision making may be explained by polymorphic variations in this receptor mediated by anxiety regulation in the amygdala. In two companion studies involving Beijing-based subjects, we examine 10 single nucleotide polymorphisms (SNPs) of GABRB2 (coding for GABAA receptor, beta 2 subunit) and find 7 SNPs each showing negative association between familiarity bias—preference for betting on parity of Beijing temperature over Tokyo temperature—and having at least one minor allele (less than 50% prevalence). In an imaging genetics study of a subsample of subjects based on the SNP with the most balanced allelic distribution, we find that subjects’ familiarity bias in terms of risk aversion towards bets on the parity of the temperature of 20 Chinese cities is negatively associated with their post-scanning familiarity ratings of the cities only for those with no minor allele in this SNP. Moreover, familiarity bias is positively associated with activation in the right amygdala along with the brain’s attention networks. Overall, our findings help discriminate between ambiguity aversion and familiarity bias in source preference and supports our gene–brain–behavior hypothesis of GABAergic modulation of amygdala activation in response to familiarity towards the source of uncertainty.
Article
We examine the effect of financial asset allocation and asset liquidity on individuals’ health. Earlier literature finds empirical evidence and provides theoretical justification of the impact of health on financial decisions but speculates that reverse causality is unlikely. Through panel data methods and an instrumental variable approach, we refute this claim and establish a causal effect of financial choices on physical and mental health outcomes. Our findings suggest that accounting for endogeneity changes the results from a basic specification. Stock holdings no longer significantly affect health while ownership of time accounts and retirement accounts have a strong positive effect on health outcomes. An exploration of the channels driving these effects provides confidence that the potential stress caused by the risk level of financial assets as categorized by the literature is not the primary driver of health outcomes. However, the findings support the time preference channel, i.e. willingness to forego financial satisfactions today in return for greater financial well-being in the future causes beneficial physical and mental health outcomes. There is also some support for the allostatic load hypothesis as well as a dopamine substitutability hypothesis.
Article
Full-text available
This study aims to describe investor behavior in stock, mutual fund, and bank deposit. The psychology elements that are used in this research are mental accounting, representativeness, familiarity, considering the past, overconfidence, data mining, social interaction, fear and greed, status quo, and emotion. This research uses primary data with a help of questionnaire. The total respondent of this research is 110 people. Data collected by spreading questionnaire manually and online with the help of Google doc. The results showed that most of the respondents give positive respond to all of the elements. The element that has the highest mean value is familiarity element. It means that the respondent think that before they invest in something, they need to know first about that investment.
Article
Full-text available
Enskilda individer ställs inför allt fler val i samhället. Valfrihet är viktigt men alla konsumenter har inte samma möjligheter att göra välinformerade val. Den växande mängden av finansiell information ställer också allt större krav på individens förmåga att sålla och bearbeta information. Därtill har produkterna blivit mer komplexa vilket ökat konsumenternas informationsunderläge. Därför är det viktigt att ha ett bra beslutsunderlag när man gör sina val. Regelverket kring finansiella tjänster har ökat markant, samtidigt som den teknologiska utvecklingen gjort det möjligt att sprida information på ett sätt som förr varit omöjligt. Finansmarknadskommittén har gett ekonomie doktor Anders Anderson och juris doktor Fredric Korling uppdraget att skriva en rapport som dels kartlägger och analyserar befintliga informationskrav, dels ger förslag som syftar till att förbättra dessa i förhållande till konsumenters möjligheter att ta till sig finansiell information. Rapporten har diskuterats vid möten i Finansmarknadskommittén och kommer att vara diskussionsunderlag vid ett seminarium i juni i år. Slutsatserna i rapporten är författarnas egna. Det är min förhoppning att rapporten ska medverka till ökad kunskap och även fungera som ett värdefullt bidrag i debatten om utformning av god konsumentinformation, både i Sverige och på EU-nivå. Stockholm 5 juni 2012 Johanna Lybeck Lilja Statssekreterare Ordförande Finansmarknadskommittén
Article
Full-text available
This paper investigates the dynamics of individual portfolios in a unique data set containing the disaggregated wealth of all households in Sweden. Between 1999 and 2002, we observe little aggregate rebalancing in the financial portfolio of participants. These patterns conceal strong household-level evidence of active rebalancing, which on average offsets about one-half of idiosyncratic passive variations in the risky asset share. Wealthy, educated investors with better diversified portfolios tend to rebalance more actively. We find some evidence that households rebalance toward a greater risky share as they become richer. We also study the decisions to trade individual assets. Households are more likely to fully sell directly held stocks if those stocks have performed well, and more likely to exit direct stockholding if their stock portfolios have performed well; but these relationships are much weaker for mutual funds, a pattern that is consistent with previous research on the disposition effect among direct stockholders and performance sensitivity among mutual fund investors. When households continue to hold individual assets, however, they rebalance both stocks and mutual funds to offset about one-sixth of the passive variations in individual asset shares. Households rebalance primarily by adjusting purchases of risky assets if their risky portfolios have performed poorly, and by adjusting both fund purchases and full sales of stocks if their risky portfolios have performed well. Finally, the tendency for households to fully sell winning stocks is weaker for wealthy investors with diversified portfolios of individual stocks. © 2009 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
Article
Full-text available
A number of recent papers have examined the environmental and genetic sources of individual differences in economic and financial decision making. Here we contribute to this burgeoning literature by extending it to a number of key behavioral anomalies that are thought to be of importance for consumption, savings, and portfolio selection decisions. Using survey-based evidence from more than 11,000 Swedish twins, we demonstrate that a number of anomalies such as, for instance, the conjunction fallacy, default bias, and loss aversion are moderately heritable. In contrast, our estimates imply that variation in common environment explains only a small share of individual differences. We also report suggestive evidence in favor of a shared genetic architecture between cognitive reflection and a subset of the studied anomalies. These results offer some support for the proposition that the heritable variation in behavioral anomalies is partly mediated by genetic variance in cognitive ability. Taken together with previous findings, our results underline the importance of genetic differences as a source of heterogeneity in economic and financial decision making. This paper was accepted by Brad Barber, Teck Ho, and Terrance Odean, special issue editors.
Article
Despite our species' impressive cognitive sophistication, adult humans are nevertheless notoriously bad at making normatively rational economic decisions. Much work has examined the nature of biased decisions such as framing effects, the endowment effect, and the peak-end principle in adult humans; however, research examining the origins of these biases is still in its infancy. This paper examines existing work on origins of economic biases – that is, whether these biases are shared with non-human primates. We survey recent work using a comparative approach to address the evolutionary origins of several classic biases, such as loss aversion, reference-dependence, the endowment effect and the peak-end principle. Novel evidence is provided that the peak-end principle – a bias involved in retrospective evaluations – is also found in capuchin monkeys. These studies suggest that such biases emerged long ago in our evolutionary history, and shed light on the psychological mechanisms behind biased decision-making.
Article
Reviews the book, Genes and behavior: Nature-nurture interplay explained by M. Rutter (see record 2006-01387-000). Surveying developments in behavior genetics, Michael Rutter provides an integrative synthesis in writing that is both important and timely. The book aims to offer a nontechnical account of the "various ways in which genetic influences on behavior may be important." To do so, Rutter reviews what is known of environmental influences and how genes and environments might work across development. The book is effectively organized. A first group of five chapters is devoted to quantifying the strength of genetic and environmental influences and illustrating study designs that do so. A second group of three chapters discusses specific genes known to influence behavior outcomes and offers a readable discussion of how such genes might actually work during behavioral development. Before a final summary, there are two provocative chapters; one discussing the role of GE interaction and correlation, and another focused on what environments can do to gene expression. This highly readable and largely nontechnical book provides the reader with insightful understanding of contemporary behavior genetic research. It deserves to be widely read. (PsycINFO Database Record (c) 2012 APA, all rights reserved)
Article
Individual investors often invest actively and lose thereby. Social interaction seems to exacerbate this tendency. In the model here, senders' propensity to discuss their strategies' returns, and receivers' propensity to be converted, are increasing in sender return. The rate of conversion of investors to active investing is convex in sender return. Unconditionally, active strategies (high variance, skewness, and personal involvement) dominate the population unless the mean return penalty to active investing is too large. Thus, the model can explain overvaluation of 'active' asset characteristics even when investors have no inherent preference over them.