ArticlePDF Available

The Non-Obvious Problem: How the Indeterminate Non-Obvious Standard Produces Excessive Patent Grants

Authors:

Abstract

The dominant current perception in patent law is that the core patent requirement that an invention be non-obvious is applied too leniently, resulting in a proliferation of patents on trivial inventions that actually retard technological innovation in the long run. This article reveals that the common wisdom is only half correct. The non-obvious standard is not too low, but both too high and too low. It is indeterminate. Three principal factors produce nonobviousness indeterminacy: a failure to identify the quantum of innovation necessary to satisfy the standard, a failure to define the baseline level of ordinary skill against which to measure an innovation, and the epistemic infeasibility of requiring a technologically lay decision-maker to make a judgment from the perspective of a more highly trained and educated person of ordinary skill in the art. This article introduces a mathematical model of innovation and patenting in order to analyze the effects of non-obvious indeterminacy. Based on this model, indeterminacy in non-obvious decisions has several dramatic, and unexpected, consequences. First, indeterminacy results in too many patents being granted in total and in many patents being granted on obvious inventions. Second, indeterminacy leads to too many patent applications being filed on obvious inventions and to too few applications being filed on non-obvious inventions. Third, uncertainty causes more patents to be litigated than is optimal, and leads to incorrect litigation outcomes. Fourth, indeterminacy leads to inefficiently low incentives to research and develop great advances, and excessively high incentives to invest in mundane innovation. All of these effects occur even assuming that the non-obvious standard is applied correctly on average. That many of the current patent system ills may result from indeterminacy rather than from too low a non-obvious standard has significant consequences for the patent system and for current recommendations for patent reform. Perhaps most critically, arguments for raising (or lowering) the non-obvious threshold, a mainstay of recent legal and economic analysis, may be somewhat inapposite, unless and until we can establish greater specificity in the standard. The article concludes with several recommendations for improving determinacy in nonobviousness decisions, including differentiating non-obvious analysis and developing a substantive non-obvious standard.
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 57 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 58 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 59 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 60 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 61 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 62 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 63 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 64 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 65 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 66 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 67 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 68 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 69 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 70 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 71 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 72 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 73 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 74 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 75 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 76 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 77 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 78 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 79 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 80 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 81 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 82 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 83 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 84 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 85 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 86 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 87 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 88 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 89 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 90 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 91 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 92 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 93 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 94 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 95 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 96 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 97 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 98 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 99 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 100 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 101 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 102 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 103 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 104 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 105 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 106 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 107 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 108 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 109 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 110 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 111 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 112 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 113 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 114 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 115 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 116 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 117 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 118 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 119 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 120 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 121 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 122 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 123 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 124 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 125 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 126 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 127 2008-2009
HeinOnline -- 42 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 128 2008-2009
... Classiquement, on suppose qu'il existe une échelle d'inventivité et que le critère d'activité inventive correspond à un « seuil » qui sépare les degrés techniques non inventifs de ceux inventifs. Mais la dimension binaire du critère d'activité inventive ne se formule pas en une séparation en deux d'un échelonnement de l'activité inventive(Mandel, 2008) (voirfigure 15).Le caractère binaire procède en fait de la norme et de sa dualité. Ce point permet en particulier de mieux saisir que la métaphore « raising the bar » souvent utilisée pour évoquer le besoin de durcir les critères d'évaluation (ou de manière générale d'améliorer la qualité des brevets) est en fait trompeuse car elle laisse supposer que le critère est évalué selon un degré qu'il est possible de moduler. ...
... Il est davantage une allégorie générique de certaines relations admises ou non entre diverses connaissances, qui permettent à l'examinateur de reconstruire un schéma de raisonnement permettant ou non d'aboutir à l'invention examinée.Cette dimension « construite », ou peut-être encore « conventionnelle » (mais a priori non arbitraire), de l'homme du métier montre aussi la relative autonomie des acteurs en charge de l'évaluation des brevets : ces derniers produisent de facto une doctrine de l'invention qui leur est propre -et bien qu'en étroite interaction avec les inventeurs et les objets inventés, leur mode d'examen n'est délégué ni à l'expert ni aux pairs. La construction de cet espace de circulation cognitive de l'homme du métier entretient une opacité : et les débats s'intensifient à son propos, notamment aux États-Unis, où les juristes s'interrogent sur l'usage de cette figure et sur l'impact de cette dernière sur la qualité de l'évaluation(Mandel 2006;Mandel 2008;Meurer et Strandburg 2008;Eisenberg 2004;Lemley et Sampat 2008). Une voie reste cependant peu explorée par cette littérature juridique : si l'homme du métier modélise bien un raisonnement de conception « normal », ne peut-on alors tenter de caractériser ce raisonnement de conception, plutôt que de s'attarder sur les capacités attendues de l'homme du métier ? ...
Thesis
Les brevets en tant que savoir nouveau et inventif alimentent les processus d’innovation : l’organisation et le soutien des capacités inventives des entreprises joueraient donc un rôle majeur. Comment les brevets pourraient-ils alors nous apprendre ce qu'est l’activité inventive et plus largement une gestion des capacités inventives ? Il existe une littérature abondante sur le phénomène de l’invention technique (histoire, psychologie, sociologie, philosophie) mais pourtant le lien entre ce phénomène et l’émergence d’un droit spécifique de l’invention, nommément le droit du brevet, est peu abordé. Dans cette thèse, nous considérons que l’apparition des institutions brevets marque l’émergence d’une norme de gestion associée à l’activité inventive. En étudiant cette norme de gestion et les acteurs de l’écosystème associé (examinateurs de brevets, conseils en propriété industrielle), la thèse se propose donc de questionner le rapport entre brevet et activité inventive. Par une étude des critères de brevetabilité, des pratiques d’examen et de la structure de la classification brevets, la thèse montre l’existence de quatre régimes d’invention technique, stabilisant pour certaines périodes une certaine structure de l’état de l’art (classification) permettant de distinguer les apports techniques des inventeurs. Ce travail révèle également le rôle d’une classe d’acteurs particuliers, les Conseils en Propriété Industrielle, en caractérisant une capacité propre au raisonnement inventif : la capacité de discernement. La thèse explore alors comment outiller cette capacité et les impacts d’une telle capacité pour la gestion des capacités inventives.
... Attention has also been drawn to the relatively low bar of the non-obviousness test for grants of utility patents to varieties per se [97][98][99]. The granting of utility patents (UP) to plant varieties per se under the tenets of i) DUS status and ii) the inability to predict the genetic or phenotypic outcomes from crossing and selection, has effectively created a new sui generis system that is fundamentally different from that provided by UPOV. ...
Preprint
Full-text available
This review examines the categorization of Essentially Derived Varieties (EDV) introduced in the 1991 revision of the Convention of the Union internationale pour la protection des obtentions végétales (UPOV). Challenges in the implementation of the concept and progress made on a crop-by-crop basis to provide greater clarity and more efficient implementation are reviewed. The current approach to EDV remains valid provided i) clarity on thresholds can be achieved including through resource intensive research on an individual crop species basis and ii) that threshold clarity does not lead to perverse incentives to avoid detection of essential derivation. However, technological advances leading to new varieties resulting from the simultaneous introduction or change in expression of more than “a few” genes will so challenge the concept to require a new Convention. Revision could include deletion of the concept of essential derivation and revision on a crop-by-crop basis of the breeder exception. Countries that allow utility patents for individual plant varieties per se should consider removing that possibility unless plant breeders utilize those encouragements for risk taking and investment to broaden the germplasm base upon which the long-term sustainability of plant breeding resides.
... 1,8 While the activity in which the PHOSITA is presumed to be ordinarily skilled is still one of the most critical dimensions in both patent prosecution and patent litigation processes, this perspective has remained largely unexamined despite being a fundamentally important aspect in patent law. 10 This aspect of the PHOSITA involves more than a mere inquiry as to the specific field or skill level; it also involves an understanding of what the skilled person does within that field (art). Traditionally, the PHOSITA has been alleged to be skilled within a particular field at repetitive processes that produce expected results without complications or undue experimentation. ...
Article
Full-text available
A " person having ordinary skill in the art " (PHOSITA) or " a person skilled in the art " is a legal construct that is extensively used in patent law as a tool to homogenize and standardize the estimation and evaluation of patentability requirements i.e. nonobviousness, insufficient disclosure, interpretation of the claimed invention in the prosecution of patent applications, patent litigation, and infringement proceedings. Currently, the legal definition and average experience of a hypothetical claim of the PHOSITA for any invention field is not clearly defined. In this article we discuss the theoretical fundamental role played by the PHOSITA in the prosecution process of the patent application at both the United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO) and the European Patent Office (EPO), and show the impact of the person skilled in the art in a number of cases in the patent prosecution process for the heavily regulated pharmaceutical industry. Introducing the definition and average knowledge of the PHOSITA into the patent application prosecution process could provide a quality control mechanism that would improve the reliability of pharmaceutical patent prosecution decisions and minimize the risk of bias and conflict of interest at the claimed invention.
Chapter
While growing disparities in wealth and income are well-documented across the globe, the role of intellectual property rights is often overlooked. This volume brings together leading commentators from around the world to interrogate the interrelationship between intellectual property and economic inequality. Interdisciplinary and globally oriented by design, the book features economists, legal scholars, policy analysts, and other experts. Chapters address the impact of intellectual property rights on economic inequality, the effect of economic inequality on the protection and enforcement of these rights, and the potential use of innovation law and policy to help reduce economic inequality. The volume also tackles timely issues like race and gender disparities and the North-South divide in innovation. This book is available as Open Access on Cambridge Core.
Article
The of the inventive step requirement, which apparently guarantees the growth of innovation and pursues industrial and economic development, despite enjoying some benefits, has always faced challenges, and in some cases such challenges are in conflict with the basis of the patent system, and it shows that the patent system is not always socially useful. The analysis of the mentioned challenges is mainly based on the economic principles and assessment tools of the requirement, i.e., examiners and person having ordinary skill in the art. Iran's patent system can also be criticized in terms of legislation and implementation and needs to be reformed. In this article, we intend to first examine the economic pathology regarding the assessment of the inventive step requirement in the patent system, then present the appropriate criterion that is similar to the copyright system, and explain the necessary suggestions.
Chapter
Patents on plants are debated in politics and society. This section discusses the country-specific implementation of the exclusion of plants and products-of-nature from patentability, the issue of novelty for plants obtained by breeding processes, and the issue of non-obviousness in the context of US variety patents. It discusses specific challenges of both plant biotech patent and patents on plants with “native traits” and obtained by essentially biological processes, including Rule 28 (2) EPC and the G 3/19 “Pepper” decision. Specific issues related to the clarity requirement (Article 84 EPO) and deposits of biological material are also addressed. In the context of scope of protection and enforceability the research and the breeder’s exemption, the extension of method claims to products, and the emerging topic of post-patent use of GM events are discussed.
Article
Artificial intelligence (AI) holds promise as the next breakthrough technology and as the basis of the so‐called 4th industrial revolution. Although patent laws have proven resilient to technological change, it is foreseen that AI will affect intellectual property rights, in particular patent rights, and their management. This chapter sheds light on the rise of AI and addresses the impact of AI technologies on the patent system, in relation to the different criteria of patentability. It provides a brief overview of what is being referred to as AI and presents some data on AI‐related patents. The chapter reviews patent legislation in the United States and in Europe, as well as case laws. It examines the challenges posed by AI‐enabled inventions for patent regimes. The chapter also presents and discusses some insights from the economic analysis of patents, and shows how it may provide some guidelines to address the legal issues faced by AI.
Article
Artificial intelligence systems are being increasingly employed in pharmaceutical R&D to develop new drugs and medical treatments. In such a scenario, the patentability of new pharmaceutical inventions seems more and more problematic, given that the computational power of AI increases the likelihood that a new chemical composition is deemed to be obvious. In this article I argue that with the advent of AI-generated inventions both EU and US patent law cannot rely exclusively on the traditional standard of the “person having ordinary skill in the art” to evaluate the non-obviousness condition of patentability. However, I also maintain that a legislative reform is not necessary. Rather, judges should start to more strongly consider the so-called “secondary considerations” of non-obviousness that have been intermittently and inconsistently applied both in US and EU case law.
Chapter
“The inherent problem was to develop some means of weeding out those inventions which would not be disclosed or devised but for the inducement of a patent.” – A unanimous Supreme Court in Graham v. John Deere, Introduction, The opening quotation is one of the most memorable and insightful lines from arguably the most important patent law case of the twentieth century, the Supreme Court’s 1966 decision in Graham v. John Deere. Graham’s preeminent place in the patent canon is well justified, because it is the Supreme Court’s seminal opinion on a patent law doctrine – the “nonobviousness” requirement – that is typically introduced as “the most important of the basic patent requirements,” “central to determining patentability,” “the key to defining what is a patentable invention,” or simply “the ultimate condition of patentability.” The basic rule of nonobviousness is easy enough to recite: Under 35 U.S.C. § 103, a patent may not be granted on an invention that “would have been obvious at the time the invention was made to a person having ordinary skill in the art.” But the apparent simplicity of the requirement belies the complexities and difficulties that have historically bedeviled the doctrine. The inducement standard, as articulated in Graham, appears to be vitally important to understanding the statutory nonobviousness requirement, because it offers a simple explanation for why society should deny patents on some innovations: If the innovation would be created and disclosed even without patent protection, denying a patent on the innovation costs society nothing (because the innovation would be developed anyway) and saves society from needlessly suffering the well-known negative consequences of patents, including the restriction on output caused by a patentee’s exclusive rights and the administrative and litigation costs associated with running a patent system.
Article
Full-text available
Without the benefit of paralinguistic cues such as gesture, emphasis, and intonation, it can be difficult to convey emotion and tone over electronic mail (e-mail). Five experiments suggest that this limitation is often underappreciated, such that people tend to believe that they can communicate over e-mail more effectively than they actually can. Studies 4 and 5 further suggest that this overconfidence is born of egocentrism, the inherent difficulty of detaching oneself from one's own perspective when evaluating the perspective of someone else. Because e-mail communicators "hear" a statement differently depending on whether they intend to be, say, sarcastic or funny, it can be difficult to appreciate that their electronic audience may not.
Article
At the beginning of the nineteenth century, all countries having patent systems required patentable inventions to be both new and useful. Now those two fundamental requirements have been joined by a third: Patentable inventions must also be nonobvious. The nonobviousness requirement is considered to be so central to patent policy that it has frequently been called the doctrine of invention, inventive step or simply the patentability requirement. This Article traces how this defining doctrine of invention was itself invented by the world legal culture. For scholars of intellectual property law, this history provides significant insights into the proper functioning and continued development of the doctrine. But the case study also gives much more general insights into the process of legal development, showing how one successful doctrine grew up and conquered the world while many failed doctrines with promising beginnings withered. The history reveals that the legal system itself is capable of generating true legal innovations - i.e., intellectual advances that are objectively better ways for accomplishing the purposes of the law. Such legal innovations can take decades, even centuries, to develop, and flawed doctrines can remain stable law for large portions of a century before their downfall. The case study has obvious relevance to the great debate over the so-called positive theory of the economic analysis of law and suggests that economic analysis should have a more unabashedly normative component, which might facilitate innovation and progress in law.
Article
This Article presents a novel body of research in cognitive psychology called coherence-based reasoning, which has thus far been published in journals of experimental psychology. This cognitive approach challenges the stalemated conflict between the Rationalist and Critical models of decision making that have dominated legal scholarship for over a century. The experimental findings demonstrate that many legal decisions fit into neither of these models. Based on a connectionist cognitive architecture, coherence-based reasoning shows that the decision-making process progresses bi-directionally: premises and facts both determine conclusions and are affected by them in return. A natural result of this cognitive process is a skewing of the premises and facts toward inflated support for the chosen decision. The Article applies this research to four important aspects of the trial. It argues that the current doctrine in these areas is based on misconceptions about human cognition, which lead to systematic legal errors. By identifying the cognitive phenomena that lie at the root of these failings, the research makes it possible to devise interventions and introduce procedures that reduce the risk of trial error.
Article
For the first time in thirty years, the Supreme Court will consider the core patent requirement that an invention be non-obvious. At the heart of the case lies the challenge of how to insulate non-obvious decisions from the distortion of the hindsight bias. This Article reports the latest empirical studies in a line of hindsight research, which present experimental data bearing directly on the issue before the Court: how individuals make non-obvious decisions under existing Supreme Court and Federal Circuit precedent. The study results indicate that the Federal Circuit's suggestion, teaching, or motivation requirement, the precedent challenged before the Supreme Court in KSR v. Teleflex, does not produce erroneous non-obvious outcomes. This result contradicts the claims of the petitioners in KSR and other critics of the suggestion requirement. On the other hand, the results do not demonstrate that the suggestion test ameliorates the hindsight bias in the manner usually claimed by its supporters. An additional study indicates that the Supreme Court's Graham framework does not resolve the hindsight problem either. Given the substantial and confirmed prejudicial effect of the hindsight bias, the Article concludes that the suggestion test should be retained for several reasons: it does not appear to cause the harms hypothesized by its critics, it potentially reduces the hindsight bias for complex technology inventions, and the problem the test confronts (erroneous decisions that an invention is obvious in hindsight) is known and significant while the problem the test is alleged to create (over-compensation for the hindsight bias) is unconfirmed and conjectural. The Article concludes with a recommendation for bifurcating the non-obvious decision at the Patent and Trademark Office. Combined with an earlier proposal for jury trials, these recommendations present the only known means for eliminating the hindsight effect and producing patent decisions that comport with the Patent Act and Supreme Court precedent.
Article
The Supreme Court's KSR decision transforms the way we think about patent law's ordinary artisan. The ordinary artisan, the Supreme Court states, is also a person of ordinary creativity, not an automaton. This transformation, which sweeps aside a contrary precept that had informed the Federal Circuit's nonobviousness jurisprudence for a generation, raises a key question: How do we fill out the rest of our conception, in a given case, of the ordinary artisan's level of skill at the time the invention was made? Reaching back to a large vein of case law typified by Judge Learned Hand's decisions about nonobviousness, as well as an all-but-forgotten nonobviousness bill that died in committee in 1948, I show that the modern level of skill inquiry can comfortably rely on evidence of long-felt, unmet need in the art and the failure of others to meet that need. For it remains true, as Judge Hand once observed, that "the best test of what persons of routine ingenuity can do is what they have done."
Article
This Article reports the results of a much needed study on the United States Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit's nonobviousness jurisprudence. The study takes a look at all Federal Circuit cases over a four year period considering the nonobviousness of a patent claim. The study first takes a macro-level look at collected data, investigating whether the Federal Circuit has lowered the nonobviousness requirement. The study also takes a micro-level look at the reasoning for the court's findings, focusing on the impact of the suggestion test on the court's nonobviousness analysis. The results of the macro-level study provide at most a weak inference that the nonobviousness requirement is still strong, particularly in the context of appeals from the United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO). The micro-level study, in contrast, provides strong evidence that the suggestion test plays a fairly small role in the court's nonobviousness jurisprudence. These findings are significant for two reasons. First, two recent reports - one by the Federal Trade Commission in 2003 and the other by the National Research Council in 2004 - and briefing in a currently pending Supreme Court case, KSR International Co. v. Teleflex, Inc., all come to opposite conclusions. They assert that the Federal Circuit lowered the nonobviousness requirement and point to the Federal Circuit's suggestion test as the reason for this bias towards findings of nonobvious. Second, the study reported in this Article is one of the first to empirically assess these recent claims about the Federal Circuit's jurisprudence. Questions about the Federal Circuit's nonobviousness case law are currently being considered by the Supreme Court in KSR and will be considered by Congress, the USPTO, and court in the future, and this Article provides valuable data to inform the Court and future decision-makers.
Article
Although patent law purports to cover all manner of technologies, we have noticed recent divergence in the standards applied to biotechnology and to software patents: the Federal Circuit has applied a very permissive standard of obviousness in biotechnology, but a highly restrictive disclosure requirement. The opposite holds true for software patents, which seems to us exactly contrary to sound policy for either industry. These patent standards are grounded in the legal fiction of the "person having ordinary skill in the art" or PHOSITA. We discuss the appropriateness of the PHOSITA standard, concluding that it properly lends flexibility to the patent system. We then discuss the difficulty of applying this standard in different industries, offering suggestions as to how it might be modified to avoid the problems seen in biotechnology and software patents.