ArticlePDF Available

A History of Yen Exchange Rates

Authors:
  • Fordhan University

Abstract and Figures

The history of Japanese exchange rates, though short by British or American standards, is exceedingly rich, both from the standpoint of variation in the data and in the institutions governing exchange rate arrangements and Japanese monetary conditions. This paper reviews that history and traces the evolution of yen-dollar and yen-sterling exchange rates to indexes of purchasing power parity, and it investigates the links among exchange-rate regimes, exchange rates themselves and other macroeconomic variables. Two conclusions emerge: (1) Purchasing power parity - at least in relative form - held remarkably well for the yen over the longer run. (2) The variability of real yen exchange rates under the current float does not, in fact, differ greatly from the often substantial and largely self-reversing movements observed historically.
Content may be subject to copyright.
A History of Yen Exchange Rates
James R. Lothian*
Fordham University
Graduate School of Business Administration
New York, N.Y. 10023, USA
January 19, 1991
Forthcoming in Japanese Financial Market Research,
William T. Ziemba, Warren Bailey and
Yasushi Hamao, eds., Amsterdam: Elsevier, 1991
Abstract
The history of Japanese exchange rates, though short by British or
American standards, is exceedingly rich, both from the standpoint of
variation in the data and in the institutions governing exchange rate
arrangements and Japanese monetary conditions. This paper reviews that
history and traces the evolution of yen-dollar and yen-sterling exchange
rates from 1874 until the present, comparing their behavior to that of the
dollar-sterling rate. It shows the relationships of all three nominal
exchange rates to indexes of purchasing power parity, and it investigates the
links among exchange-rate regimes, exchange rates themselves and other
macroeconomic variables. Two conclusions emerge: (1) Purchasing power parity
at least in relative form — held remarkably well for the yen over the
longer run. (2) The variability of real yen exchange rates under the current
float does not, in fact, differ greatly from the often substantial and
largely self-reversing movements observed historically.
* I would like to thank Cornelia McCarthy for comments on and assistance in
the preparation of this paper, and Kyung-Won Lee and Dario Werthein for their
computational help. Most important is the debt that I owe to the late John
Metcalf who stimulated my interest in Japanese monetary issues and directed
me to what had then been a largely unexploited body of data. This paper
extends and in several places draws upon my earlier paper "A Century Plus of
Yen Exchange Rate Behavior," written under the sponsorship of the Japan-U.S.
Center for Business and Economic Studies of New York University and published
in Japan and the World Economy.
1
1. INTRODUCTION
The history of Japanese exchange rates, though short by British or
American standards, is exceedingly rich, both from the standpoint of
variation in the data and in the institutions governing exchange rate
arrangements and Japanese monetary conditions. In the approximate century
and a quarter that followed the Meiji restoration of 1867, Japan experienced
three episodes of floating exchange rates, two episodes — one very brief — on
the gold standard, a period of heavily managed floating rates during the
interwar years, the dollar peg of the Bretton Woods era, and the
exceptionally severe inflation and accompanying substantial yen depreciation
of the World War II years.
In this paper I review that history. I trace the evolution of yen-
dollar and yen-sterling exchange rates from 1874 until the present and
compare the behavior of both to that of the dollar-sterling rate. I go on to
analyze the relationship of all three to indexes of purchasing power parity
and to examine the links among exchange-rate regimes and the behavior of
exchange rates themselves and of other important macroeconomic variables.
2. HISTORICAL DESCRIPTION OF EXCHANGE-RATE BEHAVIOR
Following the Meiji restoration, Japanese trade with the rest of the
world increased dramatically. From a base of essentially nil at the time of
Admiral Perry's first visit in 1853, exports rose to approximately 15% of GDP
shortly after the turn of the century and to over 20% of GDP by the 1920s.1
For most of the nineteenth century, however, Japan was not on the gold
standard. From 1867 to 1878, the Japanese monetary system was effectively a
system of fiat currency and floating exchange rates. From 1878 until 1897,
when Japan did finally adopt gold, Japan both de jure and de facto was on a
silver standard. The result was a continuation of floating rates relative to
the gold standard world.2
This flexibility in exchange rates enabled Japan to avoid the deflation
that prevailed in Britain, America, and other countries on gold during these
years. We can see this in Table 1.3 Over the subperiod 1874 to 1887 Japanese
wholesale prices showed virtually no net change, earlier inflation being
offset by later deflation. Over the later subperiod 1888 to 1896, they
actually rose by 35%. In the United States, wholesale prices declined by
slightly over 40% between 1874 and 1887 and by another 21% between 1888 and
1896. In Britain, the deflation followed a largely similar pattern,
cumulative declines in wholesale prices of 41% and 11% in the two subperiods,
respectively.
In the foreign exchange market, the yen depreciated relative to both
the dollar and sterling. For the full period 1874 to 1896, the increase in
the yen-dollar rate averaged 3.15% per year and the increase in the yen-
sterling rate, 3.03% per year. In both instances, the declines were more or
less in line with the cross-country differences in inflation rates, but in
neither case was the offset exact. In real terms, the yen appreciated
somewhat against both currencies, while the dollar fell slightly against
sterling. We can see this in the figures presented in the last three columns
of Table 1 showing the average annual percentage changes in real exchange
rates and in the plot of the real yen-dollar and real pound-dollar rates in
2
Figure 1.4
Purchasing power parity, therefore, held tolerably well as a first
approximation. But for Japan in particular it was only that. One
possibility for the slack in the relationship between changes in nominal
exchange rates and the differential in inflation rates is measurement error
in the Japanese price data, an overstatement of the levels of wholesale
prices in the later relative to the later years of the period. An
alternative is a shift in the equilibrium real exchange rate, resulting
perhaps from increased productivity in the Japanese tradeable goods sector.5
In addition to these trend-like movements, both yen real rates
exhibited fairly sizable year-to-year variability, well in excess of the
variability of dollar-sterling, particularly in the subperiod from 1888 to
1896. This variability, however, had no obviously adverse effects on other
real variables, either real trade flows or real output. Exports and imports
increased substantially as already noted. Rates of growth of Japanese real
income and industrial production were comparable to or higher than the rates
in Britain and America. Between 1885 and 1900, real income in Japan
increased at an average annual rate of 3.1% versus 2.35% in the United
Kingdom and 2.79 in the United States. Over the longer period 1874-1896,
industrial production increased by 4.75% per year in Japan versus 1.96% per
year and 4.44% per year in the United Kingdom and the United States
3
respectively.6
Table 1
Rates of change of wholesale prices, nominal exchange rates and real exchange
rates in Japan, the United States and the United Kingdom, 1875-1989
S)))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))Q
Wholesale prices Nominal rates Real rates
S)))))))))))))))))Q S)))))))))))))))))Q S))))))))))))))))Q
Period Japan U.S. U.K. ¥/$ ¥/£ £/$ ¥/$ ¥/£ £/$
S)))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))Q
1875-1896 1.43 -2.77 -2.30 3.15 3.03 0.12 -1.07 -0.71 -0.36
1875-1887 -0.27 -3.10 -3.03 2.16 2.06 0.10 -0.66 -0.69 0.03
1888-1896 3.91 -2.30 -1.24 4.56 4.41 0.15 -1.65 -0.74
-0.91
1897-1914 2.67 2.15 1.58 0.17 0.34 -0.17 -0.34 -0.74
0.40
1915-1940 3.76 0.54 1.96 2.86 1.62 1.24 -0.36 -0.17 -0.19
1915-1921 10.58 5.10 9.90 0.35 -2.91 3.26 -5.13 -3.59 -1.55
1922-1928 -5.21 -5.81 -9.77 0.51 3.72 -3.21 2.69 1.20 1.49
1929-1940 3.29 -1.76 1.27 5.69 3.03 2.66 0.64 1.01 -0.37
1941-1953 40.24 5.92 6.74 34.13 32.37 1.76 -0.18 -1.13 0.94
1954-1973 1.37 2.16 3.24 -1.42 -2.11 0.69 -0.62 -0.24 -0.38
1974-1989 2.85 5.71 9.74 -4.24 -6.23 1.99 -1.37 0.67 -2.04
S)))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))Q
Source: See endnote 3.
Note: Figures are continuously compounded per cent per annum rates of
change.
The difference between Japanese and U.S. and U.K. price behavior in this
last quarter of the nineteenth century appears to a large extent to mirror
international developments rather than domestic monetary policy actions in
Japan. Throughout these years, countries were continually shifting from
silver to a gold standard. At the same time that this shift in the relative
demands for the two precious metals was taking place, discoveries of silver
in the United States were increasing its supply. The result, as Irving
Fisher (1911) documented, was an upward trend in the price levels of the
countries that remained on silver and a downward trend in the price levels of
countries on gold.
When Japan did make the switch to gold in 1897, price movements in the
gold-standard world had begun to reverse. Gold discoveries, coupled with the
introduction of improved methods of refining, led to a more than doubling of
the world's gold stock from 1890 to 1914. (Friedman and Schwartz, 1963, p.
137). This in turn increased growth in money supplies and thus caused prices
to rise. In Japan, the inflation exceeded that of the rest of the world.
Given the fixed nominal exchange rate, the yen therefore depreciated against
both the dollar and sterling in real terms. Government borrowing abroad and
the drawing down of the gold balances received as an indemnity payment
following the war with China in 1893 and 1894 are the likely reasons for this
disparity in price behavior.7 These enabled Japan to insulate itself from the
operation of international gold-standard forces and thus to pursue
inflationary policies domestically.
In 1914, with the outbreak of war in Europe, the worldwide gold standard
4
broke down, most countries blocking its workings by placing embargoes on gold
exports, some leaving gold completely. Japan took the former route until
1917, at which point it left gold officially. Unlike Britain and America,
Japan remained off the gold standard throughout the 1920s, not returning
until the beginning of 1930, and then only to leave a scant two years later.
The twenties were not, however, years of completely free floating yen
exchange rates. An initial attempt to peg the yen against the dollar (1919
to 1920) was followed by controlled depreciation and then two planned, but
aborted, moves to return to gold. The first attempt failed in the wake of
the Great Kanto Earthquake of 1923 and the large trade deficits that
resulted. The second, after a year of preliminary stabilization of the yen,
was abandoned following the financial panic of March 1927 (Takagi, 1989).
The years 1932 to 1934 were marked by a more or less free yen float, but the
five years that followed by a peg of the yen to sterling.
What stands out during the 1915-1940 period is the volatility of real
exchange rates. Judged in terms of both the subperiod-average rates of
change shown in Table 1 and the yearly standard deviations shown below in
Table 2, it was at record highs, far greater than under the gold standard
and, in the main, even greater than under the post-Bretton Woods float. The
only sense in which this is not the case is for the period viewed as a whole.
The average annual rates of change of all three real rates over the years
1915 to 1940 were in fact less than the respective averages for the years
prior to 1914. In each instance, protracted movements of the real exchange
rate in one direction during WWI and the years immediately thereafter were
very nearly offset by subsequent protracted movements in the opposite
direction. Over the longest period, therefore, purchasing power parity again
appears to have held, despite substantial departures for long periods in
between.
With World War II came the disruption of international transactions,
breaks in the official yen exchange-rate data and substantial increases in
price levels around the world. In Japan, the inflation was severe. Between
1940 and 1949 Japanese wholesale prices increased by a multiple of 127, or at
a continuously compounded average annual rate of increase of 53.8%. Relative
to American and British wholesale prices, this translated into (continuously
compounded) cumulative increases in excess of 400%.
In 1948, when official data for yen exchange rates become available, its
value relative to the dollar had fallen from the 4.35 yen per dollar rate in
place in 1940 to 160 yen per dollar. By 1950, in the face of continued
strong inflation, it reached 361 yen per dollar, roughly the rate maintained
for the remainder of the Bretton Woods era.
Then in 1971, in the face of monetary excesses in the United States, the
reserve-currency country, the Bretton Woods system broke down and the current
float began. Since then the yen has shown a trend-like nominal appreciation
against the dollar and sterling, a similar real appreciation against the
dollar, though somewhat surprisingly, not sterling, and a series of
alternating sharp shorter term real appreciations and depreciations against
both currencies.
The monetary part of the picture during the early years of the float can
be divided into three episodes, all of which show evidence of links to U.S.
policy. In the mid 1970s, Japan in part as a spillover from policy in the
United States, experienced both high money growth and inflation (Darby and
Lothian, 1983b). In its aftermath, however, Japanese policy became
5
considerably tighter than policy in the United States and remained so longer.
Despite renewed expansionary effects emanating from the United States via the
balance of payments, Japan therefore escaped the double-digit inflation that
plagued America and Britain at the start of the last decade.8 In the latter
part of the 1980s, Japan appears to have again been led into expansive policy
as the Bank of Japan, along with the U.S. Federal Reserve, sought to halt the
depreciation of the dollar.
Of particular interest in these episodes is the pattern of volatility of
real exchange rates and of inflation. Over time, fluctuations in inflation
have become more muted in Japan while fluctuations in the real yen- dollar
rate have remained substantial. This, coupled with the longer term downward
trend in the yen-dollar real exchange rate have been a source of increased
skepticism about both purchasing power parity as an equilibrium condition and
the functioning of the floating rate system.
3. PPP, REAL EXCHANGE RATES AND EXCHANGE-RATE REGIMES
The historical overview highlights several sets of important issues. One
has to do with the purchasing power parity relationship. The other centers
around the links between exchange-rate regimes, exchange-rate variability and
the behavior of other macroeconomic variables. The specific question that
arises with regard to PPP is whether the tendency for nominal exchange rates
to move in line with relative price levels that is apparent in the longer
term comparisons presented in Table 1 is a behavioral phenomenon or simply a
statistical quirk, the spurious correlation that can arise between two
trended series.
The theoretical rationale for PPP and modified PPP relationships is as a
macroeconomic equilibrium condition. In the simplest theoretical models,
which ignore the effects of real variables like productivity and differences
in relative prices of traded and non-traded goods, absolute PPP holds. It is
the open-economy analogue of the classical closed-economy neutrality
proposition as in in the monetary-approach models of the type developed in
Frenkel and Johnson (1976). Expressed in log form, the absolute PPP
relationship is

pt - et = pt* , (1)

where p, and p* represent the logarithms of the price levels in the home
country and the foreign country respectively, e represents the logarithm of
the nominal exchange rate (the price in the home country's currency of a unit
of the foreign country's currency), and t is an index of time.
There is now abundant empirical evidence suggesting that to the extent
that purchasing power parity holds, it does so only over longer time periods,
and that even then there may be disturbances to the relationship that are
highly persistent in their effects. Two general classes of models have
evolved to explain this phenomenon. In one, which is an extension of the
monetary-approach model, such deviations are purely transient, the result of
sluggish adjustment of prices to monetary shocks. (See, e.g., Dornbusch,
6
1976). In the other, which assumes instantaneous adjustment of goods prices
and thus the price level, deviations from PPP can be permanent, the result of
real shocks that affect the equilibrium real exchange rate (See Stockman,
1980). Models of this class preserve the long-run neutrality (or super-
neutrality) of money but see absolute PPP as a highly special case that would
only exist in the limit, in situations in which real influences were of no
practical significance. Relative PPP does, however, potentially fare better
in these models. Real shocks have one-time effects on levels. As the time
period lengthens, the effect on rates of change therefore progressively
diminishes.
Extending the concept of neutrality in another direction, Stockman (1983)
demonstrated that within the context of an equilibrium model similar to the
one developed in his earlier (1980) paper, and as intuition might suggest,
the (nominal) exchange-rate regime should have no effect on the equilibrium
behavior of real variables, including that of the real exchange rate.
Like continuous PPP, this insight does not appear to carry over to the
actual data. Real exchange rates, as Stockman went on to show and as
evidence in Mussa (1986) confirms, have been more variable under floating
rates than fixed rates during the post-WWII period. The behavior of other
real variables, however, appears to be invariant across the two regimes
(Baxter and Stockman, 1989; Baxter, 1991).
The major difficulty that arises in interpreting these results is that the
regime is essentially an endogenous variable. The choice of regime very
likely is influenced by factors that, in turn, affect monetary and price-
level behavior, and also by the behavior of real variables, including the
real exchange rate itself.9 How real exchange rates behave under different
regimes, as well as the choice of the regime, may be two aspects of the same
general question.
Below I examine these issues, the time-series behavior of PPP and the
relationships between exchange-rate regimes and the variability of real
exchange-rates. I begin with the analysis of real-exchange rate variability
since it is more heavily descriptive and thus serves as useful introduction
to the time-series analysis of PPP that follows.
3.1 REAL-EXCHANGE-RATE VARIABILITY AND EXCHANGE-RATE REGIMES
The data in Table 2 showing standard deviations of the log real exchange
rates and their first differences for various subperiods appear fully
consistent with the hypothesis of greater variability under floating than
fixed exchange rates. Standard deviations for the current floating rate
period, for the interwar period and the Japanese nineteenth century float are
indeed greater than the standard deviations for the Bretton Woods and gold
standard periods in most instances.10
This, however, does not appear to be the full story. One hint that more
is involved than a simple fixed-floating dichotomy is provided by experience
during the Japanese float in the latter decades of the nineteenth century.
In this episode there is a marked difference in variability — particularly in
the variability of the differenced data — between the subperiods 1875-1887
and 1888-1896. In the first of these subperiods, Japanese real exchange
rates were noticeably less variable than in the second and not appreciably
more variable than the real pound-dollar rate. Quite interestingly, this
7
first subperiod saw much greater stability of Japanese inflation rates than
the second.
Table 2
Standard deviations of real exchange rates, 1875-1989
S)))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))Q
Period Countries
S)))))Q S))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))Q
Levels of logs Differences in logs
S))))))))))))))))))))Q S)))))))))))))))))))))))Q
JA/US JA/UK UK/US JA/US JA/UK UK/US
S)))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))Q
1875-1896 8.80 7.71 4.95 8.77 6.95 4.77
1875-1887 8.31
6.29 5.89 7.90 5.26 5.28
1888-1896 8.22 7.74 3.47 10.38 9.24 4.15
1897-1914 5.50 7.93 6.31 5.52 3.82 3.95
1915-1940 17.67 18.03 12.46 9.14 11.88 10.53
1921-1928 8.72 8.83 4.07 8.83 9.62 5.57
1929-1940 14.38 16.69 13.39 9.31 13.07 14.20
1954-1973 5.43 5.03 3.89 4.37 4.45 3.23
1974-1989 13.64 9.12 13.71 10.15 10.00 10.82
S))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))Q
Note: Figures are multiplied by 100 to convert to per cent terms.
A more serious problem is posed by the interwar years. This was a period
of managed floats alternating with pegs of various sorts, over various time
spans, depending upon the currency. Real exchange rates, however, were even
less stable during the interwar years than under the current float. Hence,
if there is a behavioral-type relationship between the degree of exchange
rate flexibility and the variability of real exchange rates it is certainly
not monotonic. Alternatively, it may be that the relationship is largely
statistical, economic conditions that give rise to variability in real
exchange rates also strongly influencing the choice of regime.
To investigate these issues further, I computed standard deviations of the
changes in the log real exchange rates and of the three countries' inflation
rates for five-year periods. I then used these as the observations in a
series of dummy-variable regressions. These regressions took the general
form:

Fxj = (0 + (1 DFIX + (2 DIW + (3 DWW + ,j , (2)

where Fx is the standard deviation of variable x, DFIX is a dummy taking the
value 1 for fixed-rate periods (the gold-standard years and the years of
greatest stability under Bretton Woods) and 0 otherwise, DIW is a dummy
taking the value 1 for the interwar period and 0 otherwise, DWW is a dummy
taking the value 1 for the two world wars and 0 otherwise, the (s are
8
coefficients to be estimated, , is the error term, and j is an index for the
period. Table 3 contains the results of these regressions.
Under the hypothesis that the regime per se is the determinant of real-
exchange-rate variability, (1, (2 and (3 should all be negative, and (2 and (3
should each be less in absolute value than (1. The data, in general, do not
support these predictions.
Table 3
Regressions to analyze the variability of real exchange rates and inflation
rates across regimes
S)))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))Q
Countries (0 (1 (2 (3
R2SEE
S)))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))Q
Fxj = (0 + (1 DFIX + (2 DIW + (3 DWW + ,j,
)Log real exchange rate
S))))))))))))))))))))))Q
JA/US .081 -.042 .002 .086 .294 .068
(3.517) (-1.311) (0.048) (2.216)
JA/UK .086 -.060 .032 .134 .413 .081
(3.152) (-1.577) (0.665) (2.899)
UK/US .087 -.051 .031 .015 .490 .036
(4.534) (-2.145) (0.886) (.778)
Inflation rate
S)))))))))))))Q
JA .051 -.018 .062 .182 .386 .098
(1.554) (-.395) (1.056) (3.256)
US .052 -.023 .054 .040 .395 .039
(3.917) (1.264) (2.279) (1.798)
UK .043 -.010 .069 .048 .378 .045
(1.840) (-.402) (2.113) (1.631)
S)))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))Q
Source: Observations are standard deviations of annual data for non-
overlapping five-year periods.
Note: Fx is the standard deviation of the variable x, DFIX is a dummy for
fixed-rate periods, DIW is a dummy for the interwar period, DWW is a dummy
taking the value 1 for the two world wars and 0 otherwise. Figures in
parentheses are t statistics.
In all three instances, DFIX has a negative sign, which is consistent with
the view that the variability of real exchange rates is low under fixed
rates. But only in the case of the pound-dollar rate is the difference
statistically significant. For the two yen rates only DWW is significant.
Much more important, in all three cases there appears to be little difference
9
statistically between the interwar period and periods of relatively free
float: DIW is insignificant and slightly positive in all three instances.
Certainly, there is no evidence of lower variability then as would be the
case if the degree of variability of real exchange rates were directly
related to the degree of flexibility of nominal exchange rates.
The inflation-rate regressions provide a partial clue to what underlies
these results. For all three countries, DWW is significantly positive and
for Japan especially so. For the United States and the United Kingdom, so
also is DIW. DFIX is negative in all three instances but in none of the
regressions is it significant.
Both bodies of data, therefore, show somewhat similar temporal patterns.
and, in the case of Japan, a similarity that is particularly pronounced. The
close association observed between movements in nominal and real exchange
rates since the advent of floating exchange rates in the early 1970s is,
therefore, clearly not a general phenomenon. Over the long span of years
covered by these data, variability in inflation rates very often has
accompanied variability in real exchange rates. This continued association
between the two suggests the need for a common explanation.
3.2 PPP: Evidence from tests of cointegration
The implications of the theoretical models of exchange rate determination
reviewed above translate into competing hypotheses about the nature of the
disturbances that affect the PPP relationship.
To illustrate, let us first amend equation (1) to include a disturbance
term and also, since it will be of use empirically, consider an alternate
version written in terms of the real exchange rate.
As the empirical counterpart of equation (1), we get:

pta = a + pt* + ut , (3)

and as the real-exchange-rate equation,

qt = aN + utN , (4)

where pta / pt - et, qt / (et - pt + pt*), p and p* now represent logarithms of
price indexes rather than price levels, a and aN are normalizing constants,
and u and uN are error terms.
Particularly well suited to analyzing the processes governing these errors
are the tests of cointegration developed by Engle and Granger (1987).
According to Engle and Granger, two series which themselves have to be
differenced n times to be stationary, are said to be cointegrated of order n-
1 if some linear combination of their nth differences is stationary.11
Cointegrated variables have the property that even though, for example, the
levels of both may be subject to drift, there is some linear combination of
the two that is not. Tests for cointegration are therefore essentially unit-
root tests applied to the errors in these equations, or to suitably
differenced versions thereof.
10
To see the connection between the tests and the hypotheses about exchange
rate behavior suggested by theory, let us first consider the (instantaneous)
equilibrium model. Since in this model both goods prices and the nominal
exchange rate adjust fully within the period to monetary shocks, deviations
from PPP are solely the result of real shocks. These real shocks both have
permanent effects and provoke full within-period adjustment. Accordingly,
the equilibrium model predicts: non-stationary of the uts (or utNs) and hence
non-cointegration of pta and pt*; the necessity of differencing to achieve
stationarity; and an extremely rapid pattern of adjustment.
In the monetary overshooting model, real shocks play no role. Deviations
from PPP are solely the result of lagged adjustment to monetary shocks. In
the long run, the adjustment of nominal exchange rates and the price level to
such shocks is complete, but in the short run the exchange rate overshoots to
maintain covered interest rate parity, while the price level adjusts slowly.
The overshooting model, therefore, predicts: stationarity of the uts and,
hence, cointegration of the levels of pta and pt*; and a pattern of adjustment
that corresponds to that of the price level.
A third more general class of models admits the possibilities of both real
shocks influencing the equilibrium exchange rate and sluggish adjustments of
prices (see e.g. Mussa, 1982). The predictions of these models are,
therefore, a mixture of those of the other two: stationarity of the errors,
at least after differencing or adjustment for a deterministic trend in the
real exchange rate; and a pattern of adjustment to residual errors that again
mimics that of the price level following a monetary shock.
To test these hypotheses, I followed two related procedures. One was the
two-step method outlined by Engle and Granger (1987); the other was simply to
apply unit-root tests in the context of simple univariate models of the real
exchange rate.
In the two-step procedure, the first step was to estimate the
cointegrating regression based on equation (3):
pta = a + b pt* + ut , (5)
where a and b are the coefficients to be estimated and where the slope
coefficient b, which in theory should be unity, is included as an allowance
for measurement error (Taylor, 1988).12
The second step uses variants of the Dickey-Fuller (1979) test to examine
the stationarity of the uts.13 The equations underlying these tests took the
general form:

K
)ut = $1 ut-1 + E $k-1 )ut-k + vt. (6)
k=1

Here the parameter of interest is $1, the coefficient on the level of the
lagged error term from the cointegrating regression. A negative and
statistically significant value of $1 leads to rejection of the hypothesis of
non-stationarity. This, in turn, implies that pa and p* are cointegrated and
hence is evidence in favor of long-run PPP. In one variant of the test, the
11
coefficients on the lagged differences of the errors were constrained to
zero. This is referred to as the DF (Dickey-Fuller) test. In the other, no
such constraint was imposed. This variant of the test is referred to as ADF
(augmented Dickey-Fuller) test.14
The alternative procedure, in which I examined the stationarity of the
real exchange rate directly, is essentially a test of cointegration subject
to the constraint that b, the slope coefficient in the cointegrating
regression, is unity. Given this constraint, the two steps collapse into one
and the following general equation serves as the basis for our tests:

K
)qt = :0 + :1 qt-1 + E 8k )qt-k + vt . (7)
k=1

Again the focus of the tests is on the coefficient of the lagged level, a
value of :1 significantly less than zero providing evidence in favor of the
hypothesis of stationarity of the real exchange rate. In the DF tests, the
8k again were assumed to be zero; in the ADF tests, the number of such
coefficients to be included in the regression was chosen empirically.
To investigate the influence of real variables and other factors that
might cause the real exchange rate to undergo permanent shifts, I conducted
two further series of tests. In the first, I estimated a variant of (7) that
included a deterministic time trend as an additional regressor. In the
second, I allowed for a stochastic trend by substituting log differences of
the real exchange rate data in place of the log levels used initially. In
both instances, I conducted unit-root tests similar to those used above.
The equations underlying these additional tests took the respective forms:

K
)qt = :0 + :1 qt-1 + :2 t + E 8k )qt-k + vt , (8)
k=1

and

K
)qt - )qt-1 = :0 + :1 )qt-1 + E 8k ()qt-k - )qt-k-1) + vt . (9)
k=1

Table 4 contains the results of the cointegration tests based on the two-
step procedure, both the DF and ADF t-like statistics and the Durbin-Watson
statistic from the cointegrating regression. Table 5 contains the statistics
for the analogous unit root tests for the real exchange rates. In each
instance in Table 4, we are able to reject the hypothesis of no cointegration
between pta and pt*. The same is true for the third test proposed by Engle and
Granger based upon the Durbin-Watson statistic. Correspondingly, we are able
to reject the hypothesis of non-stationarity of the real exchange rate, or
put another way, of no cointegration given the constraint of a unit
coefficient in the cointegrating regression linking pta and pt*.
Estimated speeds of adjustments to equilibrium are rather lengthy in both
instances.15 For the pound-dollar the estimated half lives range from 2.1
12
to 2.3 years based on the results reported in Table 4 and from 2.2 to 2.9
years based on those reported in Table 5. These are not the rapid speeds of
adjustment envisioned in the equilibrium models, but they are not out of line
with the estimated speeds of adjustment of price levels to monetary shocks in
the United States and the United Kingdom.16
Table 4
Tests for cointegration between the logarithms of exchange-rate-adjusted
price levels: 1875-1989
S)))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))Q
Countries b DW 1-$1 DF 1-$1ADF(K) K
sb s$1 s$1
)))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))Q
JA/US 1.164 .540*.714 -4.486*.741 -4.663*2
(.019) (.064) (.077)
JA/UK 1.091 .553*.715 -4.421*.747 -3.392** 2
(.014) (.065) (.075)
US/UK 1.016 .474** .779 -3.495** .723 -3.583** 3
(.014) (.063) (.077)
S)))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))Q
Notes: The slope coefficient in the cointegrating regression is denoted by
b and its standard error by sb. The coefficient in the test regression of
the lagged residual from the cointegrating regression, ut-1, is denoted by $1
and its standard error by s$1. DW is the Durbin-Watson statistic from the
cointegrating regression, DF is the Dickey-Fuller test statistic and ADF(K)
is the augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic from a regression with K lagged
values of the differenced residuals. One, two, and three asterisks denote
significance at the .01, .05 and .10 levels, respectively in this and the
next table.
For the yen rates, the situation is similar when we confine our attention
to Table 4. The estimated half lives range from 2.1 to 2.4 years for the
yen-pound and from 2.1 to 2.3 years for the yen-dollar. The picture changes,
however, when we look at the results reported in the top panel of Table 5.
For the yen-dollar the estimates range from 3.7 to 4.2 years, and for the
yen-pound from 3.0 to 3.7 years.
The difference in the two sets of estimates for the yen exchange rates, I
believe, reflects the imposition of the constraint b=1 that is implicit in
the real-rate formulation. For the pound-dollar the constraint appears to be
reasonable. The estimate of b reported in Table 4 is virtually unity and
reversing the order of the variables in the cointegrating regression does not
alter this result. In the cointegrating regressions for the two yen rates,
in contrast, the estimates of b are both somewhat removed from unity, 1.16
and 1.09 for the yen-dollar and yen-pound, respectively. This, coupled with
the visual impression of a long-term drift in the yen-dollar rate that one
gets from Figure 1, raise questions about the importance of other than
13
transient shocks.
One possibility is outright measurement error, particularly for the price
series, but perhaps also for the early exchange rate data since these were
derived as midpoints of the yearly highs and lows published by the Bank of
Japan. The other obvious possibility is that real variables are affecting
these real exchange rates. As already noted, a number of researchers have
used differences in productivity growth in the United States and Japan to
account for the drift in the yen dollar rate over the post!WWII period (see
Table 5
Unit root tests of real exchange rates: 1875-1989
S)))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))Q
Countries 1-:1 DF 1-:1ADF(K) K
s:1 s:1
S)))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))Q
Levels K
S))))) )qt = :0 + :1 qt-1 + E 8k )qt-k + vt
k=1
JA/US .847 -2.987** .829 -2.887** 2
(.051) (.059)
JA/UK .792 -3.727* .828 -2.789** 2
(.056) (.062)
UK/US .786 -3.364* .729 -3.443*3
(.064) (.073)
Levels with trend
S))))))))))))))))Q K
)qt = :0 + :1 qt-1 + :2 t + E 8k )qt-k + vt
k=1
Countries 1-:1 :3 DF 1-:1 :3 ADF(K) K
s:1 s:3s:1 s:3
S)))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))Q
JA/US .741 -.0009 -4.040* .668 -.0012 -4.308*2
(.064) (.0003) (.077) (.0004)
JA/UK .646 -.0013 -4.903* .663 -.0012 3.847** 2
(.072) (.0004) (.088) (.0005)
UK/US .788 .0000 -3.291*** .733 .0000 3.277*** 3
(.065) (.0002) (.082) (.0002)
Differences
S))))))))))Q K
)qt - )qt-1 = :0 + :1 )qt-1 + E 8k ()qt-k - )qt-k-1) + vt
k=1
Countries DF ADF(K) K
S)))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))Q
14
JA/US -9.808* -7.704*3
JA/UK -10.750* -7.586* 2
UK/US -9.394* -6.026*3
S)))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))))Q
Notes: The symbols s:1 and s:3 represent the standard errors of the
regression coefficients :1 and :3. DF is the Dickey-Fuller test; ADF(K)
is the augmented Dickey-Fuller test based on a regression using n lagged
differences of the dependent variable.
Marston, 1986; and Yoshikawa, 1990). In light of the rapid growth of the
Japanese traded goods sector prior to WWII, it is plausible to believe that
productivity differences may have been important then also. Given the
somewhat low power of unit-root tests, we may therefore be incorrectly
rejecting the hypothesis of non-stationarity.
To investigate this possibility, I ran the additional tests based on
equations (8) and (9). In the middle panel of Table 5, I show the results of
the tests in which a deterministic trend is included in the regression. In
the bottom panel, I show the results for the first differences in q. In
both cases, we can reject non-stationarity, and generally at high levels of
significance. Real yen rates may be subject to permanent influences — either
stochastic shocks or forces that follow a trend-like pattern — but there is
a decided tendency to return to equilibrium otherwise. Over long periods PPP
appears to hold at least for rates of change, and perhaps also for levels,
albeit with the possible need for adjustment for a dterministic trend in the
real exchange rate.17
4. CONCLUSIONS
For the study of exchange-rate behavior, Japanese historical experience
offers a nearly ideal laboratory. Over the 115 years for which data are
available, the yen has floated with much greater frequency than either
sterling or the dollar, while the Japanese price level has been subject to
considerably greater variability than either the British or the American
price level.
Despite this volatility, however, purchasing power parity — at least in
relative form — has held remarkably well for the yen over the longer run.
Using an expanded body of data relative to that in my earlier (1990) study,
I can always reject the hypotheses of non-trend stationarity and non-
difference-stationarity of real yen exchange rates at high levels of
significance. Relaxing the constraint of a unit cointegrating factor between
the exchange-rate-adjusted Japanese price level and the foreign price level,
I can do the same for the hypothesis of non-stationarity of the absolute
levels.
These results stand in sharp contrast both to casual impressions gained
from experience under the current float and to much scholarly evidence
derived from it. The difference, I believe, is due in the main to the
difference in the spans of data. Given the existence of long-lived
deviations of exchange rates from PPP, a long historical series is a virtual
necessity if we are to distinguish persistent, but transient, deviations from
permanent ones.
Viewed from the perspective of this study, the continued emphasis by the
15
Bank of Japan and by business economists on PPP as a macroeconomic
equilibrium condition no longer appears anomalous.18 The fluctuations in the
real yen-dollar rate over the past decade that made it seem such turn out to
not differ much from the often substantial and largely self-reversing
movements observed historically. Relative to the fluctuations in the years
surrounding World War II they are, in fact, rather small.
Not directly identifiable are the factors producing such fluctuations.
For the sterling-dollar rate they appear to have been largely transitory in
their impact. For the two yen rates, both permanent and transitory factors
appear to have mattered. Productivity-related influences may well have been
important over much of the sample period. In addition, the close association
between variability in yen real exchange rates and variability in the
Japanese inflation rate suggests a major role for monetary influences.19
16
REFERENCES
Abuaf, Niso and Phillipe Jorion, 1990, Purchasing power parity in the long
run, Journal of Finance, 45, 157-174.
Baillie, Richard T. and Tim Bollerslev, 1989, Common stochastic trends in a
system of exchange rates, Journal of finance 44, 167-181.
Bank of Japan, Statistics Department, 1966. Hundred year statistics of the
Japanese economy (Bank of Japan, Tokyo).
Baxter, Marianne, 1991, Business cycles, stylized facts and the exchange rate
regime: Evidence from the United States, Journal of international money
and finance 10, forthcoming.
Baxter, Marianne and Alan C. Stockman, 1988, Business cycles and the exchange
rate system: some international evidence, Journal of monetary economics,
23, 377-400.
Darby, Michael R., 1983, Movements in purchasing power parity: The short and
long runs, in Michael R. Darby, James R. Lothian, et al., The inter-
national transmission of inflation (University of Chicago Press for the
NBER, Chicago, IL).
Darby, Michael R. and James R. Lothian, 1983a, British economic policy under
Margaret Thatcher: A midterm examination, Carnegie Rochester conference
series on public policy, 18, 157-208.
Darby, Michael R. and James R. Lothian, 1983b, Conclusions, in Michael R.
Darby, James R. Lothian, et al., The international transmission of
inflation (University of Chicago Press for the NBER, Chicago, IL).
Darby, Michael R. and James R. Lothian, 1989, International transmission
afloat, in Michael D. Bordo, ed., Money, history and international
finance: Essays in honor of Anna J. Schwartz (University of Chicago Press
for the NBER, Chicago, IL).
Dickey, David A. and Wayne A. Fuller, 1979, Distribution of the estimators
for autoregressive time series with a unit root, Journal of the American
statistical association 74, 427-431.
Diebold, Francis X., Stephen Husted and Mark Rush, "Real exchange rates under
the gold standard, unpublished manuscript, 1990.
Dornbusch, Rudiger, 1976, Expectations and exchange rate dynamics, Journal
of political economy 84, 1161-1176.
Enders, Walter, 1988, ARIMA and cointegration tests of purchasing power
parity, Review of economics and statistics 70, 504-508.
Enders, Walter, 1989, Unit roots and the real exchange rate before World
War I: The case of Britain and the United States, Journal of international
money and finance 8, 59-73.
Engle, Robert F. and Clive W.J. Granger, 1987, Cointegration and error
correction: Representation, estimation and testing, Econometrica 55,
251- 287.
Engle, Robert F. and Byung Sam Yoo, 1987, Forecasting and testing in
cointegrated systems, Journal of econometrics 35, 143-159.
Feinstein, C.H., 1972, National income, expenditure and output of the United
Kingdom, 1855-1965 (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge).
Fisher, Irving, The purchasing power of money (Augustus Kelley, New York).
[a reprint of the 1922 second revised edition of the 1911 original]
Frenkel, Jacob A., and Harry G. Johnson, 1976, eds, The monetary approach to
the balance of payments (University of Toronto, Toronto).
17
Friedman, Milton and Anna J. Schwartz, 1963, A monetary history of the United
States: 1867-1960 (Princeton University for the NBER, Princeton, NJ).
Friedman, Milton and Anna J. Schwartz, 1982, Monetary trends in the United
States and the United Kingdom (University of Chicago for the NBER,
Chicago, IL).
Fuller, Wayne A.,1976, Introduction to statistical time series (John Wiley
and Sons, New York, NY).
Gandolfi, Arthur E. and James R. Lothian, 1983, Price behavior and the demand
for money, in Michael R. Darby, James R. Lothian, et al., The inter-
national transmission of inflation (University of Chicago Press for the
NBER, Chicago, IL).
Hakkio, Craig S. and Mark Rush, 1989, Market efficiency and cointegration:
an application to the sterling and deutschemark exchange markets, Journal
of international money and finance 8, 75-88.
International Monetary Fund, International financial statistics, various
issues.
Lockwood, William W., 1954, The economic development of Japan: Growth and
structural change, 1868-1938 (Princeton University, Princeton, NJ).
Lothian, James R., 1986, Real dollar exchange rates under the Bretton-Woods
and floating-rate systems, Journal of international money and finance 5,
429-448.
Lothian, James R., 1990, A century plus of Japanese exchange rate behavior,
Japan and the world economy, 2, 47-70.
Lothian, James R., Michael R. Darby and Michael Tindall, 1990, Buffer stock
models of the demand for money and the conduct of monetary policy, Journal
of policy modeling, 12, 325-345.
Marston, Richard, 1986, real exchange rates and productivity growth in the
United States and Japan, NBER working paper no. 1922.
McNown, Robert and Myles S. Wallace, 1989, National price levels, purchasing
power parity and cointegration: A test of four high inflation economies,
Journal of international money and finance 8, 533-545.
Mitchell, B. R., 1975, European historical statistics, 1750-1970 (Columbia
University Press: New York, NY).
Moulton, Harold G., 1931, Japan: An economic and financial appraisal
(Brookings, Washington, DC).
Mussa, Michael, 1982, A model of exchange rate dynamics, Journal of political
economy 90, 74-104.
Mussa, Michael, 1986, Nominal exchange rate regimes and the behavior of
real exchange rates: Evidence and implications, in Karl Brunner and
Allan H. Meltzer, eds., Carnegie-Rochester conference series on
public policy 26 (North Holland, Amsterdam).
Nakamura, Takafusa, 1983, Economic growth in prewar Japan (Yale University
Press, New Haven). [ a translation by Robert A. Feldman of Senzenki nihon
keizai seicho no bunseki (An analysis of economic growth in prewar Japan)
IWANI SHOTEN publishers, Tokyo 1971].
Ohkawa, Kazushi and Henry Rosovsky, 1973, Japanese economic growth (Stanford
University, Stanford, CA).
Ohta, Takeshi, 1983, Exchange-rate management and the conduct of monetary
policy, in Paul Meek, ed., Central bank views on monetary targetting
(Federal Reserve Bank of New York, New York, NY).
18
Savvides, Andreas, 1991, Real exchange rate variability and the choice of
exchange rate regime, Journal of international money and finance, 9,
forthcoming.
Shinjo, Hiroshi, 1962, History of the yen (Tokyo, Kinokuniya Bookstore Co.,
Ltd. for the Research Institute for Economic and Business Administration
of Kobe University).
Stockman, Alan C., 1980, A theory of exchange rate determination, Journal of
political economy, 88, 673-698.
Stockman, Alan C., 1983, Real exchange rates under alternative monetary
systems, Journal of international money and finance 2, 147-166.
Stockman, Alan C., 1988, Real exchange rate variability under pegged and
floating nominal exchange rate systems: An equilibrium theory, University
of Rochester, Working paper no. 128 .
Sturm, Frederick W., 1990, The yen, the dollar and the pull to parity,
Fuji Securities, Inc., Perspectives, March 30.
Suzuki, Yoshio, 1988, Prospects for the future of the international monetary
system: A Japanese perspective, paper presented at the New York University
conference on international financial markets.
Takagi, Shinji, 1989, Floating exchange rates in interwar Japan, unpublished,
International Monetary Fund.
Taylor, Mark P., 1988, An empirical examination of long-run purchasing power
parity using cointegration techniques, Applied economics 20, 1369-1381.
Taylor, Mark P., and P.C. McMahon, 1988, Long-run purchasing power parity in
the 1920s, European economic review, 32, 179-197.
United States Department of Commerce, 1973, Long term economic trends (United
States Government Printing Office, Washington, DC).
Yoshikawa, Hiroshi, 1990, On the equilibrium yen-dollar rate, American
economic review 3, 576-583.
19
1. Data for Japanese nominal exports and imports came from Ohkawa and
Rosovsky (1973). I divided these figures by the estimates of nominal GDP in
Nakamura (1983) to convert them to ratio form.
2. The silver yen became legal tender in May of 1878. See the discussions
of this period in Moulton (1931) and Shinjo (1962) and the references cited
therein.
3. The exchange rate data for the period ending in 1965 are annual series
for the yen relative to the currencies of the other three countries as
reported in the Bank of Japan's Hundred Year Statistics of the Japanese
Economy. For the years 1880 to 1914, these are midpoints of the range
between the reported yearly high and low exchange rates for each currency;
for 1874 to 1879 and for the years after 1914, they are yearly averaged data.
These series were used directly to compute yen-other country real exchange
rates and to derive the sterling-dollar real exchange rate.
The published figures for 1894 contained what appears to be two errors.
I corrected the yen-dollar rate using the alternative estimate of Nakamura
(1983, p. 34) and derived the yen-sterling rate using that corrected figure
and the estimate of the dollar-pound exchange rate for 1894 in Friedman and
Schwartz (1982).
Observations for yen exchange rates for the years 1941 to 1947 were not
reported by the Bank of Japan. For these years, I used Swiss quotes of yen-
dollar rates from Abuaf and Jorion (1990) that Phillipe Jorion graciously
provided me, and the dollar-sterling figures reported in Friedman and
Schwartz (1982) to fill in the missing observations for the yen-sterling and
pound-dollar rates and to derive the yen-pound rate.
I updated the nominal exchange rate series for the years after 1965
using the basis of the annual average yen-dollar and dollar-pound rates
reported in the International Financial Statistics (IFS) and derived the yen-
pound rate from these figures.
The data for wholesale prices came from a variety of sources: for the
United States,the U.S. Department of Commerce's Long Term Trends for the
years 1873 to 1970, and the IFS thereafter; for the United Kingdom, European
Historical Statistics for the years 1873 to 1975 and IFS thereafter; and for
Japan, the Bank of Japan's Hundred Year Statistics for the years 1873 to 1965
and the IFS thereafter. These subseries were linked either by regression or
by multiplying the earlier series by the ratio of the overlapping
observations. The resultant series were then rebased to 1980.
4. I define the real exchange rate as the ratio of the nominal exchange
rate (the price of a unit of the foreign currency) divided by the ratio of
the home-country price index to the foreign-country price index.
5. This explanation has been widely applied to explain the behavior of the
yen-dollar rate in the post-WWII period. See, for example, Marston (1986)
and Yoshikawa (1990).
6. Japanese real income (GDP) and industrial production data came from
Nakamura (1983); U.S. and U.K. real income (NNP) data from Friedman and
NOTES
20
Schwartz, (1982); U.S. industrial production from U.S. Department of Commerce
(1973); and U.K. industrial production from Feinstein (1972).
7. See the discussion of this episode in Lockwood (1954, pp. 36-37) and the
references cited therein.
8. This short-run spillover of expansive U.S. policies to Japan is evident in
data for Japanese balance of payments and high-powered money growth. Japan's
official settlements surplus increased sharply in 1977 and remained high in
1978 in the face of substantial U.S. official settlements deficits in these
years. Japanese high-powered money growth in this environment rose from 8.1%
per year on average in 1976 and 1977 to 13.9% per year in 1978.
See Darby and Lothian (1989) on the difference between long-run and short-
run price behavior among OECD countries since the advent of floating rates
and Ohta (1983) for a discussion of Japanese policy during the late 1970s and
early 1980s.
9. Stockman (1988) attributes the greater stability of real exchange rates
under fixed rates to government actions in the goods and capital markets that
affect both the price level and the nominal exchange rate. Mussa (1986), in
contrast, attributes the variability under floating exchange rates to the
non-instantaneous adjustment of goods prices.
Savvides (1991) using a simultaneous model estimated for a group of 39
developing countries over the period 1976 to 1984 studies the relationship
between the exchange-rate regime and the behavior of real exchange rates. He
finds no independent effect of the regime on the variability of real exchange
rates.
10. The definition of the gold-standard period varies with the countries
being compared. For Japan it begins in 1897 and for the United States in
1879.
11. See the discussion of cointegration in Engle and Granger, 1987. I apply
this technique to long-term time series data for Japan, the United States,
the United Kingdom and France in my earlier (1990) paper. Unlike the data
used here those data excluded the WWII and immediate postwar years.
Other applications to exchange rate data are contained in Abuaf and Jorion
(1990), Baillie and Bollerslev (1989), Diebold, Husted and Rush (1990),
Enders (1988, 1989), Hakkio and Rush (1989), McNown and Wallace (1989),
Taylor (1988) and Taylor and McMahon (1988).
12. As I point out below, an estimate different from unity may also be an
indication of omitted variables that affect the equilibrium real exchange
rate.
13. Since there is no way a priori to choose the ordering of the variables,
I also ran the reverse set of regressions and conducted the corresponding
tests for cointegration. These resulted in no appreciable change in the
results reported below.
21
14. Significance levels for the t-statistics used in these tests are those
of Engle and Yoo (1987).
15. These estimated adjustment speeds are derived from the coefficients on
the lagged level terms in equations (6) and (7). The estimated half lives
of adjustment are ln(.5)/ln(1-$1) and ln(.5)/ln(1-:1) for the two equations
respectively.
16. For the United States and the United Kingdom, the lag before the effects
of a monetary shock become apparent in prices is often described as being on
the order of two years. Full adjustment — including overshooting — appears
to take longer, however. See Darby and Lothian (1983a) for a discussion of
this issue and for estimates of the adjustment process for the United Kingdom
that takes overshooting into account.
17. A similar phenomenon appears to characterize money-price relationships.
(See Gandolfi and Lothian, 1983; and Lothian, Darby and Tindall, 1990).
18. See Yoshio Suzuki (1988) of the Bank of Japan's research department for
an analysis based on long-run purchasing power parity of movements in the yen
exchange rates under the current float. Frederick W. Sturm (1989) of Fuji
Securities presents a similar analysis of recent movements in the yen-dollar,
DM-dollar, and dollar-pound exchange rates.
19. Evidence suggesting that this is also the case under the current float
is presented in my (1986) study of the real dollar exchange rates of 11 OECD
countries.
... In parallel, real currency exchange rate should be defined as the price of the currency in real terms (Yang and Zeng 2014). The history of Japanese exchange rates, though short by British or American standards, is exceedingly rich, both from the standpoint of variation in the data and in the institutions governing exchange rate arrangements and Japanese monetary conditions (Lothian 1991). ...
... Evidence on the HBS effect is mixed. Lothian (1990Lothian ( , 1991 finds some evidence for several currencies versus the Japanese yen. Lothian and Taylor (2008) find evidence of an HBS effect for the dollar-sterling real exchange rate but not for the French franc-sterling rate. ...
Chapter
Full-text available
This book reflects the new diversity of interest in international finance that summarizes and synthesizes developments in the many and varied areas that are now viewed as having international content. The book attempts to differentiate between what is known, what is believed, and what is still being debated about international finance. The book consists of five major topics: (1) exchange rates and risk management, (2) international financial markets and institutions, (3) international investing, (4) international financial management, and (5) special topics. The chapters cover market integration, financial crises, and the links between financial markets and development in some detail as they relate to these areas.
... Abuaf and Jorion (1990) study a century of dollar-franc-sterling exchange rate data and verify PPP. Lothian (1991) also finds evidence that the yen/sterling and yen/dollar real exchange rates are stationary during the years 1875-1989. Diebold, et al.(1991 explore long time spans (ranging from 74 to 123 years) of nineteenth century data covering the gold standard pre-1913 period for six countries -five European countries and the US. ...
Article
Full-text available
Recent studies on real exchange rates advocate the use of long samples in order to reveal the low frequency properties of the processes. The present paper contributes to this strand of the literature by exploiting recently released time series for the drachma/sterling rate for the period 1833-1939. This is an interesting period as it covers different exchange rate regimes and the effects of important historical events. In the paper, the mean-reverting behaviour of the real drachma/sterling exchange rate is initially examined applying univariate unit root tests and then the validity of Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) is tested using cointegration analysis. The results provide support for a weak PPP relationship, which turns out to be robust across different sub-periods characterised by different exchange rate regimes. Adjustment to PPP is reached at a relatively high speed and occurs via movements of the nominal exchange rate.
Article
This paper constructs nominal and real multilateral effective exchange rates ffor Japan during the period 1879-1938. Existing studies of Japanese quantitative economic history have tended to use the dollar-yen bilateral exchange rate. A comparison of different indices suggests that the new data offer new insights into Japan�s economic history.
Article
This paper reexamines the causality between the dollar and the yen in a multivariate framework with the aid of cointegration and error-correcting modeling for the 1951–94 period. The Phillips-Perron tests and Johansen's tests are performed. While causality from interest rates to exchange rates is found in the short run, no causality between prices and exchange rates is found in the short run. However, causality is found running from relative prices to exchange rates along with interest rates between the U.S. and Japan in the long run, which supports the long-run PPP hypothesis.
Article
Full-text available
Article
Even prior to the extreme volatility just observed, output growth volatility-following protracted decline-was flattening or mildly rising in some countries. More widespread was an increasing tendency from the mid-1990s for shocks in one country to transmit rapidly to other countries, creating the potential for heightened global volatility. The higher sensitivity to foreign shocks, in turn, appears related to stepped-up vertical specialization associated with the integration of emerging markets in international trade. Increased international spillovers call for stronger ex post coordination mechanisms when shocks are large but the best ex ante prevention strategy probably is sensible national policies.
Article
Using over one hundred years of historical data for the UK, Canadian, Japanese, and French-US real exchange rates, we find that real exchange rate volatility is greater for flexible exchange rate periods than for fixed-rate periods.
Article
Full-text available
Examination of over a century's worth of annual data for Japan, the United States, the United Kingdom and France reveals a marked tendency for real exchange rates to return to their (measured) equilibrium values. The hypothesis that exchange-rate-adjusted price levels in these countries are not cointegrated is almost always rejected. Similar unit-root tests much more often than not reject the hypothesis of non-stationary (or non-trend-stationary) of real exchange rates. Analysis of earlier periods of floating yen rates - particularly the latter decades of the nineteenth century - points to an important link between monetary conditions and real exchange rate variability.
Article
Full-text available
Let n observations Y 1, Y 2, ···, Y n be generated by the model Y t = pY t−1 + e t , where Y 0 is a fixed constant and {e t } t-1 n is a sequence of independent normal random variables with mean 0 and variance σ2. Properties of the regression estimator of p are obtained under the assumption that p = ±1. Representations for the limit distributions of the estimator of p and of the regression t test are derived. The estimator of p and the regression t test furnish methods of testing the hypothesis that p = 1.
Article
The rise of Japan from agrarianism to a position as one of the leading industrial powers is one of the most dramatic and meaningful phenomena in economic history. Professor Lockwood, assistant director of the Woodrow Wilson School of Public and International Affairs of Princeton University, lucidly describes this astonishing transformation, analyzes the factors involved (capital, technology, foreign trade, the role of the state, etc.), and discusses the consequences.
Article
The subject of time series is of considerable interest, especially among researchers in econometrics, engineering, and the natural sciences. As part of the prestigious Wiley Series in Probability and Statistics, this book provides a lucid introduction to the field and, in this new Second Edition, covers the important advances of recent years, including nonstationary models, nonlinear estimation, multivariate models, state space representations, and empirical model identification. New sections have also been added on the Wold decomposition, partial autocorrelation, long memory processes, and the Kalman filter. Major topics include: * Moving average and autoregressive processes * Introduction to Fourier analysis * Spectral theory and filtering * Large sample theory * Estimation of the mean and autocorrelations * Estimation of the spectrum * Parameter estimation * Regression, trend, and seasonality * Unit root and explosive time series To accommodate a wide variety of readers, review material, especially on elementary results in Fourier analysis, large sample statistics, and difference equations, has been included.