ArticlePDF Available

Yochai Benkler. The Wealth of Networks: How Social Production Transforms Markets and Freedom.

Authors:
[This is the pre-print version of a book review forthcoming in the journal
‘Prometheus’ in 2007. See the journal webpage:
http://www.tandf.co.uk/journals/titles/08109028.asp ]
The Wealth of Networks: How Social Production
Transforms Markets and Freedom
Yochai Benkler
New Haven and London, Yale University Press, 2006, xii + 515 pp., US$ 40.00, ISBN
0-300-11056-1, cloth.
This is a visionary book written by a man on a mission. It articulates one possible
answer to the question of what might come after the proprietary-based knowledge-
based economy that currently exists in advanced countries. Benkler is professor of
law at Yale Law School and one of the most ardent proponents of the open source
movement and the information commons approach. He argues that a new form of
economy might be emerging, i.e. the “networked information economy”, in which
nonmarket and nonproprietary commons-based peer production (i.e. “social
production”) and exchange of information, knowledge and culture play a central role.
This has become feasible because the capital required for social production and
exchange in the networked information economy is relatively cheap and widely
distributed.
Much of the book argues the perceived advantages of the networked information
economy from a multi-disciplinary and liberal political perspective, and the numerous
threats endangering the realisation of its potential. The incumbents of the existing
proprietary-based “industrial information economy”, in particular Hollywood and the
recording industry, have to loose much and only social practices and political action
can prevent them from strangulating the fledgling networked information economy
through over-regulation. A recurring theme throughout the book is the plea to keep
open access, as much as possible, to information and communication infrastructure, to
existing information, knowledge and culture, and to the creation of new information,
knowledge and culture. In short, information wants to be free, needs to be free, and
the resources necessary to produce and exchange it should be available to everyone.
The book is divided into an introduction and three major parts. Part one consists of
three chapters that describe the technological-economic transformation making the
new production practices of the networked information economy possible. Chapter
two introduces some of the basic economics of information production and
innovation. It covers basic features of information as an economic good, like non-
rivalry, that make it a candidate for nonmarket production, and some basic ideas about
knowledge accumulation (like the ‘standing on the shoulders of giants’ argument) that
indicate the dangers which overly restrictive patent and copyright laws might pose to
future knowledge creation. Most of the material is well-known, but central as building
blocks for the main arguments put forward in the book.
1
Chapter three looks closely at social production and exchange, discussing open source
software production, as well as many non-software related collaborative projects like
Wikipedia, public resource computing projects like SETI@home, peer-to-peer file-
sharing platforms like Napster, KaZaa, the application of sharing-based techniques to
communication, e.g. Skype. They seem to reflect the state of affairs at about the
middle of 2004. Many of these phenomena depend on participants having systematic
excess computing capacity available. Business models that might make such excess
capacity superfluous, such as ‘computing on demand’, or that make widespread
commercial distributed computing feasible, are potentially a major threat to the core
of Benkler’s networked information economy. At best, they are briefly mentioned in
the book. The next chapter provides answers to three puzzling aspects of nonmarket
(especially peer) production from an economic perspective: Why do people
participate? Why now, why here? Is sharing of material and non-material resources
via the Internet (computing power, creativity etc.) ‘efficient’? Benkler introduces the
reader to some of his specific vocabulary associated with ‘sharable goods’, like
modularity, granularity and lumpiness. However, the discussion is not as extensive as
in some of his earlier articles.1
Part two is by far the largest part of the book, containing six chapters that are both
descriptive and normative. They deal mostly with the social and political
opportunities that have arisen due to the transformations described in part one, but the
realisations of which are by no means inevitable. It elaborates why, despite being
enabled by technological changes, the networked information economy is not
determined by them. Chapter five discusses the networked information economy’s
potential to increase individual autonomy, thereby remedying the loss of agency that
was imposed by the industrial economy. Amongst other things, Benkler discusses the
advantages of commons-based wired and wireless infrastructure compared to their
proprietary versions. He sees commons-based wireless systems as the primary legal
form of communications capacity that does not systematically subject its users to
manipulation by infrastructure owners. The networked information economy also
leads to a radical increase in the number of information sources. In this context the
author addresses two critical objections to his vision, i.e. quality concerns and the
issue of information overload (the Babel objection). These are serious and hotly
debated issues, but commons-based peer production itself is beginning to show how
they might be overcome.
The next two chapters focus on the possible contributions of the networked
information economy to an improved public sphere. Benkler’s discussion extents the
well-known debate about the democratising effects of the Internet. Chapter six first
postulates the design characteristics of a communications platform for a liberal public
sphere, before critically reviewing the role of the mass media in the 20th century and
earlier. The focus is mostly on U.S. media history, but some developments in other
countries are also mentioned. The chapter should be a useful item on a media studies
reading list. One shortcoming is the sometimes insufficient referencing. For example,
Harold Innis, Alfred Chandler, James Beniger, Eli Noam are mentioned, but no
references are provided.
Chapter seven discusses how the dominance of the industrial information economy’s
mass media model is being challenged by the emerging networked information
economy, and how these developments have the potential to alleviate the worst
2
weaknesses of the old model. Citizens need no longer be passive consumers and
spectators, but can become active participants. Basic communication tools like email,
mailing lists, the world wide web, and blogs are discussed, as well as interesting case
studies about the 2004 U.S. election. This is followed by an overview of findings
from research on Web typology, small world phenomena etc. Next, the argument is
put forward that peer production also produces the public watchdog function in the
networked public sphere, and examples of distributed political action are given. The
chapter finishes with an interesting discussion of how networked communications can
work around authoritarian control, using examples from former Yugoslavia, Iran,
China and, as extreme outlier or exception to prove the rule, Myanmar.
Benkler also tries to contribute to political theory. He argues in chapter eight that
cultural production and exchange should be seen as legitimate subjects for normative
evaluation within liberal political theory and that in the networked environment they
are attractive development from the perspective of such theory. A large part of the
chapter is descriptive, providing many examples of new forms of cultural production.
The core contributions of the networked environment to increased transparency of
cultural symbols and the openness to alternative views is illustrated by a Google
search for the cultural meaning of the Barbie doll. Many readers fed up with market-
dominated culture will be delighted to know that there exists a Barbie Liberation
Organization! Like in the case of information and knowledge production, there is
danger that freedom of cultural production in the networked information economy
might become severely restricted due to the power of industrial information economy
incumbents in shaping the regulatory environment.
Chapter nine is even more ambitious. The author tries to establish the positive impacts
of social production and exchange on issues of justice, economic development and
human welfare. The topics covered range far and wide, from liberal theories of justice
to information-embedded goods and tools, from Amartya Sen and the Human
Development Index to a variety of commons-based solutions to economic
development, including sector specific analyses and issues like software production,
scientific publication, food security and production of and access to medicines. The
basic claim that the networked information economy provides new paths to improving
human welfare is well argued, but Benkler is no specialist in the vast literature on
economic development, or the more specific one on the role of information, and of
information and communications technologies, in development. Experts in these
fields might fell frustrated by the few aspects of these highly complex issues that are
highlighted by the author.
The next chapter reviews the social science literature on the effects of the Internet on
social relations, i.e. on community and family. Increased individual autonomy is
central to Benkler’s claims about the networked information economy. He therefore
needs to counter the possibility that more Internet use leads to social isolation,
alienation and destruction of social capital. Again, the story he weaves seems
convincing. People use to Internet mostly for strengthen pre-existing relationships and
for establishing some limited-purpose, loose relationships, the later being important
for social production an exchange. However, social capital expert may find the
coverage of the literature somewhat selective, and a non-expert may be annoyed by
Benkler mentioning, for example, seminal authors like James Coleman, Mark
Granovetter and Robert Putnam, without providing references to their work.
3
Part three of the book consists of just two chapters, a long chapter detailing the battles
over the institutional ecology of the digital environment, and a concluding chapter
summarizing the main arguments made in the book. Chapter eleven provides an
overview of how law and policy are being shaped in response to the developments
discussed earlier in the book, and how this affects the production, use and exchange of
information etc. Numerous struggles shape the institutional setup in which the
different production and exchange modes compete. For the potential gains in
autonomy, democracy, critical culture, justice, human development etc. associated
with social production and exchange to be realised, the institutional setup of a society
has to create space for these activities so that they can become more than fringe
practices. Benkler is correct to emphasis the co-evolution of law, technology,
behaviour and social practices, but I was disappointed to see no references to the large
institutional economics literature that exists on this topic. As in many parts of the
book, Benkler uses interesting and sometimes colourful examples to make his points.
For example, he discusses how the law dealt with an artist’s video showing U.S.
president George Bush and British prime minister Tony Blair lip-synching a love
ballad, and the legal treatment of shopbots.
To sum up, the book should be of interest to a wide readership, i.e. anyone concerned
about the future of the knowledge-based economy, and economic, social and political
alternatives to the current market-dominated model. Benkler makes the reader look at
advanced capitalist economies and societies in a new way. The book, although
sometimes repetitive, is full of interesting facts and new perspectives on the
networked information economy and its struggles with the industrial information
economy. Whether social production and exchange of information, knowledge and
culture will be able to secure enough space to warrant the label networked
information economy and society remains an open question.
The breath of topics covered and the multi-disciplinary nature of the book imply that
often only a selective review of the literature is given. This is counter-balanced, if not
more than compensated, by providing the broader picture which would not be visible
from a narrower disciplinary perspective. Somewhat more surprising is the neglect of
some prominent U.S. based researchers who have worked on a number of the major
issues raised in the book. For example, Paul David isn’t mentioned anywhere, despite
his prominent work on open science and open source. Benkler definitely comes across
as a man on a mission who is more concerned with getting his basic message onto a
big canvas rather than providing an academic tome that aims at a representative
coverage of the relevant literature.
The phenomena associated with the networked information economy highlighted by
Benkler, and the hypotheses put forward, deserve further theoretical and empirical
analysis by others based in a variety of disciplines. Some readers might interpret
Benkler’s networked information economy to foreshadow a new form of
(information-based) socialism. However, the industrial information economy and the
networked information economy are just two extreme cases, leaving many in-between
possibilities. For example, an alternative not properly explored in the book is that
social production and exchange, or something similar, might increasingly be taken up
by commercial businesses, producing new synergies between proprietary and non-
proprietary modes. Elastic Compute Cloud, the new venture by Amazon.com which is
4
spearheading that company’s latest transformation, comes to mind, as do many
examples of peer-production within companies. Alternatively, what emerges might
transcend both capitalism and socialism, constituting a shift to a truly new type of
socio-economic system.2 There is need to relate Benkler’s work to the institutional
economics literature on varieties of capitalism etc. to which it contributes. There is
also need for empirical research, for example on the relative economic efficiency of
social production and exchange systems for information, knowledge and culture, over
market-based systems, and for specific studies of the motivational factors underlying
social production and exchange projects.
True to his mission, Benkler has made the book, and many of his other publications,
available for free on the Internet. The interested reader is referred to the Science
Commons reading room of the Creative Commons website at http://sciencecommons.
org/resources/readingroom.html, which links to Benkler’s website at http://www.
benkler.org/. Many of the references used in the book are also available from Science
Commons.
Notes and References
1. I recommend the following publications to anyone interested in Benkler’s
economic methodology: Benkler, Yochai (2002), “Coase’s Penguin, or, Linux and
The Nature of the Firm”, Yale Law Journal, Vol. 112, No. 3, pp. 369-446; and
Benkler, Yochai (2004), “Sharing Nicely: On Shareable Goods and the
Emergence of Sharing as a Modality of Economic Production”, Yale Law Journal,
Vol. 114, No. 2, pp. 273-358.
2. For an example of a search for the latter, see Geoffrey Hodgson, Economics and
Utopia: Why the Learning Economy is not the End of History, Routledge: London,
1999.
Hans-Jürgen Engelbrecht
College of Business, Turitea Campus
Massey University, New Zealand
5
... Given the constraints that exist on the network and the potential of digital technologies to alter the distribution of power, there started to emerge more positive, negative or even neutral views regarding the value and effectiveness of digital activism. If, on the one hand, and in a more optimistic view, Bates (2007) and Kirkpatrick (2008) believe that digital activism can change traditional power hierarchies and empower citizens through the transmission of alternative content and changing the distribution of a top-bottom power for an authority defined by peer-to-peer relationships, other authors, such as Morozov (2010), believe that digital ecosystems provide new methods of antidemocratic control, surveillance and persecution, giving governments the ability to block citizens' access to certain content and monitor their online actions, which undermines activist movements. In addition to these two views, there are still authors who believe that technology will not change existing power structures, nor lead to different activism, but only to potentially improved versions by combining online and offline practices (Shah et al., 2013). ...
Book
Full-text available
The use of the Web on a global scale and based on two-way communication, provided by Web 2.0, enabled the creation and dissemination of social movements and online activist practices, due to the greater ease and reach of the association of individuals in “virtual communities”, characterized by shared interests and common issues. In addition, the access to additional sources of information on the Web and the greater ability of the masses to make their opinions heard, has balanced the distribution of power, allowing an increasingly closer and interactive relationship between audiences and social organisms, like companies. In the field of online communication between brands and consumers, social networks play a prominent role as a stage for this new ability for public influence and participation. The public, increasingly aware of the most varied socio-political problems, quickly began to approach brands on social platforms as a way to pressure companies to adopt a more active role in society and to comment on relevant social and political issues. Some even join in “anti-brand movements” or in “anti-brand communities” when considered that brands reveal an irresponsible position regarding the consequences of their activities and/or a communication that doesn’t suit the values defended by consumers. From this closer communication, brands began to become aware of the need to commit themselves to the demands of consumer-activists and to get involved in the causes of society itself, beginning to take a public position on the most pressing and current social, political, economic and/or environmental issues, initiating the so-called Brand Activism. However, there are several factors influencing adherence of brands to activism and the outcomes of such actions, like the possibility and ease of access of companies and consumers to the Information Age and mainly the authenticity demonstrated by brands when defending a certain cause, complementing online actions with offline activist practices. This gave rise to positive, negative and neutral theories about the impact and effectiveness of digital activism. This theoretical investigation will thus contribute to expose and discuss the factors that made social networks a dual platform, which, on the one hand, presents itself as a lever for the emergence and proliferation of Brand Activism and, on the other hand, is today one of the most important means for brands to develop actions to fight for positive socio-political changes. Based on a bibliographic review and concrete examples of brands that are already involved in activism actions, a current picture of the application of this concept will be presented, as well as the different perspectives that guide the area. In addition, conclusions will be presented on the constraints to the practices of brand activism around the globe, derived from the unequal access and use of technology and the economic, social and political context in which the use of the technology occurs. Finally, the importance of authenticity for obtaining favorable results will be explained, namely in terms of coherence between the communication carried out by brand on its various platforms and its values and offline practices regarding the same subjects.
... It has the capacity to highlight the inequalities and irrationality of the present reality by presenting the model to which humanity can aspire, and show art can have an emancipatory effect. Yet this power emanates from the form, not the content : The way art is produced is more important than what it contains or even its political message (Benjamin, 1968;Groys, 2014). ...
Thesis
Full-text available
The powerful players involved in surveillance are mainly governments and corporations, but the possibility for ordinary citizens to both carry out surveillance on others, as well as to themselves become the objects of observation, has increased greatly. This thesis explores how control over surveillance systems can be allocated to communities; suggests that surveillance technology need not be limited to control, discipline, or profit; and shows how citizens and communities can use surveillance technology in a positive manner for their own needs and benefit. The first phase of the research involved the study of the participation of civilians in surveillance. I mapped different forms of citizen participation in surveillance and discuss the component of participation in several different surveillance situations, paying special attention in each case to how this participation is practiced, supported, managed, or questioned. This mapping led to a field study of the relationship between the authorities and citizens in the case of a mass citywide video surveillance project in Jerusalem. The data collected through field research carried out in public spaces in West Jerusalem reveals mixed reactions and behaviors concerning surveillance, both from the authorities and the residents. These responses range from compliance or even the desire to have the system expanded to uneasiness and distrust towards having citizen-led surveillance activities turn on themselves, their neighbors, park visitors, or park and municipal workers. I particularly studied the use of the social media, smartphones, and other accessible technologies as a tool for community-based surveillance. Through these surveillance practices, I observed actively engaged citizen groups creating a “common space”, as well as commoning practices that accommodate, support, and express the community of which they are members. Based on these findings, a prototype for a citizen-operated surveillance platform named CommunityEyes was designed and developed. With this platform, I researched potential tools and systems for community-based surveillance and sought to explore how “participatory surveillance” can make the public space not only safer and more welcoming but also more open and democratic. The prototype, a web-based application that allows communities to set up participatory video surveillance, connects the power of social media with video surveillance technology, creating a system that allows communities to share in the monitoring of their neighborhood. It enables people to watch, comment, and communicate directly with neighbors, and crowdshare information while fully cognizant of the fact that they are themselves surveilledunder surveillance. Conclusions from the testing of the prototype, performed in the protected environment of an art exhibition, show that CommunityEyes not only has the potential of serving as a participatory community surveillance platform but that it could also serve as a stimulus, and catalyst for public discourse. Such conversations resulted in the development of “surveillance literacy” as a concept and for the need to educate people and communities about surveillance technology and platforms and the benefits and dangers of surveillance practices. While advocating transparency and open smart-city practices, there is simultaneously also the need for promoting closed community platforms that are owned collectively and governed democratically.
... Given the constraints that exist on the network and the potential of digital technologies to alter the distribution of power, there started to emerge more positive, negative or even neutral views regarding the value and effectiveness of digital activism. If, on the one hand, and in a more optimistic view, Bates (2007) and Kirkpatrick (2008) believe that digital activism can change traditional power hierarchies and empower citizens through the transmission of alternative content and changing the distribution of a top-bottom power for an authority defined by peer-to-peer relationships, other authors, such as Morozov (2010), believe that digital ecosystems provide new methods of antidemocratic control, surveillance and persecution, giving governments the ability to block citizens' access to certain content and monitor their online actions, which undermines activist movements. In addition to these two views, there are still authors who believe that technology will not change existing power structures, nor lead to different activism, but only to potentially improved versions by combining online and offline practices (Shah et al., 2013). ...
Chapter
El capítulo presenta el panorama actual e invita a la reflexión sobre aspectos relacionados con la diversidad social y activismo digital ante el poder de los medios, las redes sociales como potenciadoras de la Inclusión social y digital, y, la educación mediática y diversidad en pro de la participación ciudadana con el fin de mostrar el papel que la educación mediática cumple hoy en día como favorecedora del activismo digital de la ciudadanía.
... Given the constraints that exist on the network and the potential of digital technologies to alter the distribution of power, there started to emerge more positive, negative or even neutral views regarding the value and effectiveness of digital activism. If, on the one hand, and in a more optimistic view, Bates (2007) and Kirkpatrick (2008) believe that digital activism can change traditional power hierarchies and empower citizens through the transmission of alternative content and changing the distribution of a top-bottom power for an authority defined by peer-to-peer relationships, other authors, such as Morozov (2010), believe that digital ecosystems provide new methods of antidemocratic control, surveillance and persecution, giving governments the ability to block citizens' access to certain content and monitor their online actions, which undermines activist movements. In addition to these two views, there are still authors who believe that technology will not change existing power structures, nor lead to different activism, but only to potentially improved versions by combining online and offline practices (Shah et al., 2013). ...
Book
Full-text available
Los medios de comunicación ocupan un papel preponderante en la sociedad actual, adquiriendo cada vez más poder, a la par que los gobiernos y aquellos que tienen acceso al podio discursivo social (Aguaded y Romero-Rodríguez, 2016). Su capacidad de influencia en la opinión pública, gracias al uso de las tecnologías de la información y la comunicación, su presencia ubicua y su maximización de alcance por parte de los prosumidores (Civila et ál., 2020), es aprovechada por diferentes agentes, para sus propios fines, como en el caso de los partidos políticos para modificar la intención de voto, las empresas para incidir en el consumo de sus productos, a través de la publici-dad y el marketing, o los influencers a través de las redes sociales, entre otros.
... Given the constraints that exist on the network and the potential of digital technologies to alter the distribution of power, there started to emerge more positive, negative or even neutral views regarding the value and effectiveness of digital activism. If, on the one hand, and in a more optimistic view, Bates (2007) and Kirkpatrick (2008) believe that digital activism can change traditional power hierarchies and empower citizens through the transmission of alternative content and changing the distribution of a top-bottom power for an authority defined by peer-to-peer relationships, other authors, such as Morozov (2010), believe that digital ecosystems provide new methods of antidemocratic control, surveillance and persecution, giving governments the ability to block citizens' access to certain content and monitor their online actions, which undermines activist movements. In addition to these two views, there are still authors who believe that technology will not change existing power structures, nor lead to different activism, but only to potentially improved versions by combining online and offline practices (Shah et al., 2013). ...
... Hitherto, the possible function of the web and social media has been classified into two categories in extant literature (Ceron, 2017). Some studies identify social media as a coercive public realm that allows for a dialogue based on objective interactions between citizens and politicians (Bates, 2007;Coleman & Blumler, 2009). This enables more openness, accountability and the strengthening of the democratic system (Khazaeli & Stockemer, 2013). ...
Article
Full-text available
This inquiry relates to the empirical linkages between educational quality, Facebook penetration and accountability dynamics. The empirical investigation is based on the Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) technique and Quantile regression for the conditional linkages which articulate low, middle, and high initial levels of public accountability. It explores a cross-section of 168 countries. The main finding is that there is an overwhelming positive connection between Facebook penetration and accountability dynamics. The established positive nexus is apparent in all quantiles of public accountability. In addition, tertiary and secondary school enrollment positively influence public accountability. By utilizing a novel dataset in analyzing the established nexuses, this study adds to the existing literature on social media and governance (i.e., educational quality, Facebook penetration and accountability dynamics). Similarly, the posture addresses contemporary policy concerns regarding a lack of documentation on the impacts of social media.
Article
In the era of connectivity, companies find fundamentally new ways of accessing workforce: On the internet a standby labor force is at their disposal allowing to source labor on demand - just like electricity from the socket. It seems as if the masses of people willingly offering their skills, time and energy to crowdsourcing platforms can be considered a state-of-the-art manifestation of standing-reserve as Martin Heidegger described with regard to nature. His concept of standing-reserve denotes the fact that something exists just to be ready for use and functions merely as a source of profit. The fact that companies today have labor available on tap also results in new forms of working, which are determined by peculiarities and specific ways of how the platforms organize working processes and deal with the crowd. To ensure performance and to deliver a consistent service the platforms must incessantly exert force in order to turn a scattered pool of individuals into a purposeful whole. The standby labor force can be seen as an extreme instance of how algorithmically infused processes shape the contours of labor today.
Book
Full-text available
Many technologies and practices that define the Internet today date back to the 1990s – such as user-generated content, participatory platforms and social media. Indeed, many early ideas about the future of the Internet have been implemented, albeit without fulfilling the envisioned political utopias. By tracing back the technotopian vision, Clemens Apprich develops a media genealogical perspecive that helps us to better understand how digital networks have transformed over the last 30 years and therefore to think beyond the current state of our socio-technical reality. This highly original book informs our understanding of new forms of media and social practices, such that have become part of our everyday culture. Apprich revisits a critical time when the Internet was not yet an everyday reality, but when its potential was already understood and fiercely debated. The historical context of net cultures provides the basis from which the author critically engages with current debates about the weal and woe of the Internet and challenges today’s predominant network model.
The Wealth of Networks: How Social Production Transforms Markets and Freedom Code and other laws of cyberspace
  • Copyright
Copyright © 2007, Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Inc. Yochai Benkler. The Wealth of Networks: How Social Production Transforms Markets and Freedom. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 2006, 515 pp. ISBN 0–300–11056–1 (hardcover). $40.00. Reviewed by Benjamin J. Bates REFERENCES Lessig, L. (2000). Code and other laws of cyberspace. New York: Basic Books. Downloaded by [McMaster University] at 12:00 02 December 2014
Coase's Penguin, or, Linux and The Nature of the Firm Sharing Nicely: On Shareable Goods and the Emergence of Sharing as a Modality of Economic Production
I recommend the following publications to anyone interested in Benkler's economic methodology: Benkler, Yochai (2002), " Coase's Penguin, or, Linux and The Nature of the Firm ", Yale Law Journal, Vol. 112, No. 3, pp. 369-446; and Benkler, Yochai (2004), " Sharing Nicely: On Shareable Goods and the Emergence of Sharing as a Modality of Economic Production ", Yale Law Journal, Vol. 114, No. 2, pp. 273-358.