ArticlePDF Available

Abstract

In 1922, Thomas Edison publicly introduced his latest invention—a new type of money, a commodity-backed currency that he believed was the long-term solution to America's monetary woes. “I want to cast the variable out of money. This gold money is not good enough. It's a fiction” he boldly proclaimed ( New York Times 1922).
Thomas Edison’s Monetary Option
David L. Hammes
Department of Economics
University of Hawaii at Hilo
200 W. Kawili Street, Hilo, HI 96720-4091
hammes@hawaii.edu
Douglas T. Wills
Milgard School of Business
University of Washington Tacoma
1900 Commerce St. CB 358420, Tacoma, WA 98402-3100
dtwills@u.washington.edu
We are grateful to John Chant, Robert Ekelund, Thomas Humphrey, Arthur Rolnick,
Zane Spindler, Richard Timberlake, Warren Weber, and participants at the annual
meeting of the History of Economics Society Conference, July 2003, for helpful and
insightful comments. We also thank two anonymous referees for their many insightful
and penetrating questions. We would especially like to thank Leonard DeGraaf of the
Edison Archives for invaluable assistance. The standard caveat applies to all.
1
Thomas Edison’s Monetary Option
Abstract
One of Thomas Edison’s lesser-known ‘inventions’ was a
“commodity reserve” monetary plan proposed in 1922 to guarantee price
stability. Our paper outlines Edison’s plan, provides a modern
interpretation, and summarizes contemporary comments about his idea.
Edison proposed that U.S. currency should be backed by the
agricultural production of American farmers. Money would be injected
into the economy by “interest free” loans to farmers and canceled within
the year. We show that Edison’s plan amounted to farmers selling their
produce to the government in exchange for cash and an American call
option.
JEL classification: B31, E42, E51
2
Introduction
In 1922, Thomas Edison publicly introduced his latest invention – a new type of
money, a commodity-backed currency that he believed was the long-term solution to
America’s monetary woes. “I want to cast the variable out of money. This gold money is
not good enough. It’s a fiction.”, he boldly proclaimed.
1
According to Edison: “…the relative value of the earth’s produce appears to be
constant, a money unit representing basic commodities and nothing else would be equally
constant, that…and further, since the
relative value of the earth’s produce is constant
there is no reason why the farmer should not finance himself, as the gold miner does,
simply by turning his output into money directly.” (New York Times, 1922, emphasis in
original).
While Edison was far from first to propose a commodity-backed currency he did
propose something unique and distinguishable from plans advocated before and after.
2
The purpose of this paper is to ground Edison’s plan in the monetary thinking of the day,
1
See the Special Features section of the July 16 1922 New York Times. The plan was explained in an article
by Garet Garrett followed by an analysis by Mr. Garrett.
2
His plan has some similarities to the “Sub-Treasury” plan proposed in the 1880s by C.W. Macune and
others (Hicks, 1928). The authors thank Steven C. Hammes for making this connection. Commodity
backed currencies became a subject of some academic interest over the next several decades with a series
of articles by Clark (1933), Benjamin Graham (1937), Frank Graham (1940), Beale, Kennedy, and Winn
(1942), Hayek (1943), Friedman (1951), Nash (2001), and Boyle (2002). Few of these authors even
mention, let alone explicitly analyze Edison’s plan, although Benjamin Graham does approvingly cite him
(Graham 1937 p. x). Most of these later works deal with a “composite” commodity currency in which the
monetary unit is backed by a fixed ratio of different commodities.
3
analyze his plan, and present heretofore unseen contemporary comments he received on
his plan.
Monetary Thought in the 1920s
New monetary proposals were not particularly unusual in the early part of the 20
th
Century. Monetary issues had been at the forefront of public debates since the
introduction of greenbacks and even the creation of the Federal Reserve System failed to
put the issue to rest.
3
To the public, given the erratic performance of the post-World War
I U.S. economy, the monetary system seemed as unstable as ever. In addition to dramatic
busts and booms in economic performance, the price level rose by nearly 100% in the
five years prior to 1921, followed by 11% deflation in 1921, and another 7% decline in
prices in 1922.
Solutions to this instability came from all corners. From academe, solutions were
grounded in two long-standing and distinct approaches to monetary issues, the Banking
School and the Currency (or quantity theory) School.
4
J. Laurence Laughlin was the
leading American proponent of the former and it was still the operating philosophy of
most officials in the Federal Reserve.
5
Crucial to this approach are the convertibility of
the medium of exchange into a monetary standard, e.g. a fixed amount of gold, and the
3
See Mehrling, 2002, on the monetary debates that led up to the formation of the Federal Reserve System.
4
See Mehrling 1997 and Laidler 1999. Following Laidler we include adherents to “real bills” in the
Banking School.
5
Of course, one of Laughlin’s students, H. Parker Willis, was instrumental in drafting the House version of
the act creating the Federal Reserve System. In the WWI period, Willis was the Board’s first Secretary, and
he was its first Director of Research.
4
banking system’s passive provision of currency through the extension of credit on goods
in production.
The best known advocate of the quantity theory was Irving Fisher. He argued that
monetary mismanagement created price level instability and price level instability caused
output fluctuations. Hence, a rule assuring price level stability through the changing gold
value of the dollar, determined by the general level of prices, was “…sufficient, for
stabilization of business activity in general” (Laidler, 1999, page 185). Thus, Fisher
argued that the central bank should actively manage the money supply in order to attain
and maintain stability of the general level of prices.
Other proposals came from non-academics. Keynes’ “great Trinity of crankdom”
of Taylor J. Peddie, Arthur Kitson, and Major Clifford H. Douglas (Skidelsky, 1995,
page 416) independently proposed variants of fiat money plans.
6
Carl Strover, a lawyer
from Chicago, published Monetary Reconstruction in 1922 advocating a fiat currency
system. These (and other) advocates of fiat money schemes were sometimes derisively
referred to as “unsound money men” and “inflationists”.
7
6
Kitson was influential in British monetary debates and the work of Major Douglas influenced political
movements in the Canadian and American mid-west.
7
See Irving Fisher, Stable Money: A History of the Movement, 1934, for a thorough exposition of the many
monetary proposals of this time.
5
If there was one distinguishing feature between these individuals and the
academics--of both schools—it was that the latter believed in the gold backing of the
currency.
8
Of all these reformers, no one of that time had the public profile and admiration
accorded Edison. Unaware of recent monetary history or of these academic debates,
Edison barged onto this tri-fissured plane that featured quarrels among and between: (1)
academics and non-academics, (2) proponents of, and those antagonistic to, gold backing
for the currency, and (3) those believing that the Federal Reserve should passively
respond to the ‘needs of business’ or actively manage the money supply in order to attain
a price level target.
9
Edison’s Proposal
Edison claimed his system would help farmers by stabilizing prices and protect
them from opportunistic bankers. In his plan, currency would be backed by specific
commodities, yet it avoided the problem of different and varying exchange rates between
commodities, a common criticism of such plans (e.g. bimetallism; see Reeve 1943, page
361). At its heart was the belief that for money to be “sound” it had to be based on
something of constant value like, in Edison’s opinion, the commodities produced by
American farmers.
8
And, sometimes more than gold. See Mehrling (1997, page 36) who states that Laughlin “went much
farther than the original Banking School…Monetization of any form of real property, he insisted, is
perfectly safe…and is merely a way of transforming disparate goods into mobile form so that they can meet
for exchange in the market.” (emphasis in original).
9
This suggests an extension of the matrix in Mehrling, 2002, page 216.
6
The plan was simple in design but complicated and expensive to put into practice.
Edison first outlined his plan in May 1922 in: “A Proposed Amendment to the Federal
Reserve Banking System” (Edison, 1922). In this 15-point plan, he proposed that the
government issue Federal Reserve currency in the form of interest-free loans to farmers
based on the value of newly produced commodities. To obtain this loan the government
would store the commodities during the term—for up to one year—of the loan. The per
unit price of the commodity determining the amount of the loan would be its average
price over the most recent twenty-five year period.
For example, suppose the current world price of a bushel of wheat is $1.00, the
25-year average price is $1.50 and that a farmer harvests 1,000 bushels of wheat. Under
Edison’s plan this farmer could store the wheat (at no cost to the farmer) in a government
warehouse for up to one year in exchange for (1) a mortgage certificate specifying the
quality and quantity of the wheat and (2) an equity certificate stipulating ownership of the
wheat. Both certificates could be broken into standardized units and were transferable.
The farmer could take the mortgage certificate and exchange it for Federal
Reserve currency of 50% of the historic value (in this example, $750). National Banks
would be required to exchange the mortgage certificate for the specified amount of
currency. The equity certificate would be necessary to reclaim the wheat. Therefore, the
farmer has stored $1,000 worth of wheat with the government in exchange for a $750
‘loan’ and the promise to reclaim the wheat within one year.
10
When the farmer wanted to
sell the wheat, he could reclaim it from the warehouse by producing the equity certificate
10
The government becomes a type of pawn broker but doesn’t have the right to sell the good until after one
year.
7
and $500. Any unclaimed wheat would be sold at the current market price by the
government.
Edison thought he had accomplished his dual goals of stabilizing the currency and
helping the farmer. The currency would be backed by something of value and would not,
in Edison’s opinion, be inflationary because it was self-canceling when the farmer
reclaimed the wheat. He believed this self-limiting feature would restrain note issue and
that the tie to the historical value of commodities would anchor the value of the currency
better than the gold-backed system of the day.
Farmers gained as they were not obligated to sell the wheat immediately upon
harvesting in order to obtain funds. Farmers could let the government store their products
and obtain an interest free loan for up to 50% of the historically determined value until
they chose to sell it. Farmers would therefore not have to sell their product when prices
were low and could still obtain funds without being at the mercy of the bankers. Money
would be injected into the economy when commodities were put into the warehouse and
exactly the same amount of money would be withdrawn when the farmers came to
reclaim their products.
As for the operation of the plan, Edison proposed that twelve warehouses be
constructed throughout the country (six in the “cotton states” and six in the “wheat
states”). He designated thirty-six different commodities that would be eligible for storage
with the requirement that these commodities must be newly produced within the United
States.
11
11
The proposed commodities were cotton, wheat, barley, rye, hay, oats, buckwheat, flaxseed, flax, rice,
American sugar, cloverseed, wool, peanuts, onions, soy and lima beans, cow peas, Porto Rico coffee,
8
Plan Operation
If the plan had been put into practice then it probably would have operated much
as Edison envisioned. However, what would have been created was substantially
different from the simple “interest free loan” mechanism of the original design. To
demonstrate, continue the above example from the point at which the wheat is deposited
in the warehouse – the farmer has exchanged 1,000 bushels of wheat for a mortgage
certificate worth $750 and an equity certificate that entitles him to reclaim 1,000 bushels
at any time over the next year for $750.
The mortgage certificate, a transferable financial instrument that by law must be
redeemed for a specific amount of currency is, in effect, money. The mortgage certificate
is equivalent to currency, in our example $750.
The equity certificate, a transferable financial instrument that gives the owner the
right, but not the obligation, claim a specified amount of a good at a specified price is, in
effect, an American call option.
12
The equity certificate is equivalent to an American call
option with an expiry date of one year and a strike price equal to the value of the
mortgage certificate. In our example, the farmer ‘sells’ his 1,000 bushels to the
linseed, linen, almonds, English walnuts, pecans, cheese, tallow, lard, hams, bacon, rosin, bituminous coal,
prunes, dried apples, dried apricots, raisins, and degerminated corn.
Twelve of the fifteen points dealt with the specification, location, construction, and operation of
the warehouses. Topics Edison seemed more comfortable with.
12
An “American” call option can be exercised at any point up to the expiration date whereas a “European”
option can only be exercised on the expiration date.
9
government in exchange for $500 and a one-year call option to buy 1,000 bushels for
$500.
What Edison intended as a plan to provide free storage and interest free loans to
farmers is a program that is economically equivalent to the farmer selling his product to
the government for cash and a call option – quite ironic for a plan to help “financially
naïve” farmers!
Would farmers have used this plan? That depends on the market value of the call
option (i.e. the Equity Certificate). The owner of the call option has the right to purchase
the specified quantity for the strike price at any point up until the expiration date. On the
expiration date, the call option must be worth the world price less the strike price. In the
example above, if the world price is $1300 on the expiration date then the call option
must be worth $550. If the option sells for less than $550, say $500, then one could buy
1000 bushels of wheat for $1250 and immediately sell it for $1300 locking in a riskless
profit. If the owner of the option tries to sell it for more than $550, say $600, then there
will be no buyers for the option.
Given that the equity certificate could be exercised at any point within one year,
arbitrage would ensure that the combined value of the mortgage certificate and the equity
certificate would never be less than the world price of the commodity. If the combined
value was less, then investors could purchase equity certificates, immediately exercise
them and lock in risk-free profits.
Farmers would ‘sell’ their product to the government because at the time of issue
the combined value of the certificates would always be above the world price. Users of
the product would value the call option because it would lock in a price, allow them to
10
manage risk, and provide free storage. Speculators would also purchase options
depending on their expectations of future prices. The value of the equity certificate would
fluctuate for the same reasons options prices fluctuate today (underlying asset price,
variance of prices, time to expiry, etc.).
Farmers would use this system even if the world price were never expected to rise
above the strike price. Suppose the world price of 1000 bushels of wheat was $200 and
that no one believed the price would rise to $750 over the next year. Then the equity
certificate would be worthless. The farmer would ‘sell’ his wheat to the government for
$500 and the option would never be exercised. In this case, the twenty-five year average
price becomes a price floor.
Edison arbitrarily chose 50% of the 25-year average price. Changing either
variable would not have any impact on whether farmers would use the plan; it would only
change the value of the call option. Furthermore, the relative level of the 25-year average
price to current world price would also have no impact other than changing the value of
the call option. In all cases, cash plus the value of the call option would be greater than or
equal to the world price.
Under this system, regardless of the world price, farmers are always better off
selling their wheat to the government. If a farmer did not want to speculate on future
price movement then he could simply sell his equity certificate and walk away.
Therefore, Edison would have accomplished his goal of helping the farmer, albeit for
very different reasons. Instead of the intended benefit of interest free loans, Edison’s plan
would have provided a price floor and subsidized storage services.
13
13
There is the possibility of another one-time benefit to farmers. When the plan is first introduced all of the
new produced output would go into storage. This would likely cause an increase in the world price as
11
The program would probably have worked something like the following. After
harvest the farmer would take the produce to the government warehouse in exchange for
the mortgage certificate (cash) and the equity certificate (call option). The money supply
increases accordingly. An organized market would have no doubt quickly developed
where the equity certificates could be bought and sold. If the farmer did not want to
speculate on the future price of his product, then the farmer would sell the equity
certificate. At this point the farmer has effectively sold his produce and has no further
obligation to the government.
As mentioned above, one of two groups would buy the certificates. One group
would be speculators who would buy and sell certificates throughout the year based on
their expectations of future prices. The second group would be users of the product.
These users would buy the certificate to lock in a price for when they needed the product.
As such, users would be reclaiming the product for a specified price (in our previous
example, $500) throughout the course of the year when they need it and thus the money
supply would be reduced accordingly.
14
________________________________________________________________
Example of a Transaction
The call option (i.e. Equity Certificate) is created by the warehouse and then
given to the farmer in exchange for the farmer’s agricultural product. The warehouse
does not set the exercise price; the exercise price is determined by 50% of the 25-year
average price of the specific product. The warehouse does not bear any financial liability
by the creation of the call option; it simply stores the product and returns it when the
option is exercised.
current demanders of the good would have to go to world markets (equivalent to a harvest failure caused by
an early frost). As the world price rose the market value of the equity certificate would rise as well.
14
There is the possibility of a third group, the open market committee of the FED. The impact of this rather
intriguing aspect of the plan is, however, beyond the scope of this paper.
12
At expiry the value of the option is MAX (0, P
W
– EX) where P
W
is the current
world price and EX is the exercise price. The current market value of the call is a
function of length of time till expiry, current interest rates, and the volatility of the price
of the product.
15
For example, assume the current price of wheat is $1.00, the 25-year average is
$1.50, and the (one period) interest rate is 7%. The exercise price will be $0.75. Using a
simplified one-period binominal model where P
W
will either be $1.25 or $0.80 at the end
of the period, a call option on one bushel of wheat will be worth $0.30. In other words, a
buyer would be willing to spend $0.30 to obtain the right to buy a bushel of wheat for
$0.75 at any time over the next year.
Suppose a farmer stores 1,000 bushels at the warehouse. Assuming the farmer
immediately converts the mortgage certificate into cash, the following transactions would
be recorded.
16
The monetary base increases by the value of the mortgage certificate. The gain or
loss fro
Suppose at expiry P
W
= $1.25 and the owner exercises the call options. The
transac
Wheat $1,000 $750 M.C. Cash $750 M.C. $750 $750 Cash
$250 E.C. E.C. $250
Inventor
y
-$X
FED
Assets Liabilities
Warehouse
Assets Liabilities
Farmer
Assets Liabilities
m the call option is not recognized until the farmer sells the call option. If the
farmer immediately sells the options for market value then he will realize a gain of $50
and have no further involvement in this transaction.
Farmer
Cash $300
E.C. ($250)
Assets Liabilities
tions would be recorded as follows:
Warehouse Option Owner
Wheat ($1,000) ($250) E.C. Cash ($750)
Cash $750 E.C. ($300)
Wheat $1,250
Assets Liabilities Assets Liabilities
15
The example will ignore storage costs.
16
The Equity Certificate is a contingent liability and how exactly that would be depicted on a balance sheet
is not entirely clear. For illustrative purposes however we will have the warehouse fully disclose the
liability immediately on the books.
13
The option owner realizes a gain of $200. Assuming that the Warehouse is
require
From the warehouse’s perspective after they return the cash to the FED they have
o furt
__________________________________________________________________
Contemporary Comments on the Plan
Far from being the stereotypical inventor working alone, Edison aggressively
sought the opinions of others no matter what the project. As one biographer writes, “As
he invented a system of electric lighting, Edison was simultaneously reinventing the
system of invention.” (Israel 1998, pages 167-8.). Edison’s success depended not only on
his own creativity and cognitive style but in using a research team to thoroughly vet
ideas.
In 1921 and 1922 he thought “on this subject [of money] steadily for several
months” (Garrett 1922), writing to Pierre Jay, Chair of the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York: “I am studying the whole question starting with the first recorded panics in Europe
and to-date, and hope some day to get something out of the Complex which may be of
some value, there appear to be many conflicting opinions.”
He also stated in the
preamble to his “Proposed Amendment” that: “I have approached the matter in the same
d to return cash immediately to the FED the entire transaction is completed with
the following transactions.
n her assets or liabilities. The same is true for the FED. The farmer is gained from
the transaction by $50 and the Option Owner gained by $200. The taxpayers subsidized
the operation of the warehouse.
17
Warehouse FED
Cash ($750) ($750) M.C. M.C. ($750) ($750) Cash
Assets Liabilities Assets Liabilities
17
Notes handwritten by Edison, April 1922, to an assistant for communication to Jay.
14
way that I do with a mechanical or other invention, namely, get all the facts as far as
possible, and then see what can be done to solve the problem.” (Edison 1922)
What Edison fails to mention is the extensive correspondence he undertook with
any o
on
ts of
ison sought the opinion of these, and other, experts he was not always
ally
“The most important single desideratum for sound money…is stability of value, namely
of purchasing power…our
present system would be greatly improved by…a variable
m f the leading academic and financial figures of the day. He met with Irving Fisher
and their on-going correspondence covered everything from Fisher’s latest book on
stabilizing the dollar to mutual health concerns. Edison received extensive comments
his plan from two other academic economists, Princeton’s E.W. Kemmerer, and E.M.
Patterson from the University of Pennsylvania.
18
W.P.G. Harding, Governor (Chairman)
of the Federal Reserve Board and Pierre Jay, Chairman of the New York Federal
Reserve, also privately provided evaluations of the plan as did numerous presiden
national banks.
While Ed
eager to take their advice: “All new things about money and banking, all the great
reforms, come from the outside. I find that in the books.”
19
In fact, when he person
contacted seventeen experts (i.e. his “research team”) with specific questions on his
proposal there wasn’t one who provided support. Kemmerer, provided the following
analysis:
18
Edison’s request for input on his plan was not always warmly received from academics. See Hammes
and Wills (2004) for an account of some responses.
19
New York Times, July 16 1922. The article by Garrett begins with several Edison quotes including this
one.
15
bullion dollar…as…advocated by Irving Fisher…I do not believe that your plan would
provide…for adjusting the supply of currency to the demands of trade necessary for the
maintenance of stability of monetary value…The administrative expenses of the plan
would be heavy…much more expensive than the Fisher plan and more complicated in its
operation.”
Kemmerer also thought that Edison’s plan would be subject to political manipulation:
“Inflation would result…[it would be] politically [im]possible to hold the currency issues
er
Patterson echoes Kemmerer’s concerns:
“The multiple standard…possesses many distinct merits. It does not, however, escape
…Its chief weakness lies in the fact that it proposes
ch
he slightest chance that Edison can
misconstrue their responses as favorable to his proposal. Yet, neither believes that the
gold sta w it
down to the basis of the commodity prices of the selected group of commodities for the
period of 25 years you mention…and that once made, an endless circle of the type so
common in paper money schemes of the kind where money is backed by land, products,
government bonds etc., would follow,---more money leading to higher prices and high
prices with the resulting popular inference of monetary scarcity leading to more money.”
the use of gold as a measure of value
a new and very unsatisfactory way of supplying the community with a medium of
exchange…we shall have a badly adjusted volume of circulating medium…your proposal
has…this weakness….it would perform the money functions very poorly…very mu
more poorly than does our present system.”
Neither Kemmerer nor Patterson leaves t
ndard is some utopian ideal without flaw, rather, given its drawbacks, they sa
as the best standard for the time.
16
Comments from the Federal Reserve officials were no more encouraging. Harding
comments:
tages of the gold standard are (1)…universally accepted.., (2)…large value in small
bulk, and (3) the supply of gold cannot be so greatly increased within a short period of
time as to affect the value of that already produced.”
“…if we built a high wall around this country and had no relations with other countries,
based on goods and with no convertibility
into gold. But the minute such a wall is done away with and we enter into relations with
foreign countries…we must have some acceptable standard of value with which to pay or
receive payment…Gold is now the accepted standard of value throughout the world…”
Four businessmen provided extensive comments to Edison: C.H. Crennan from
the Continental and Commercial Bank of Chicago; J.B. Forgan, Chairman of First
orters
e.
20
“I do not think that currency issued in this way would be sound currency…The
advan
And on convertibility, Pierre Jay wrote:
we might conceivably get along with money
National Bank of Chicago; D.P. Kingsley President of New York Life Insurance; and
C.E. Mitchell, President of National City Bank of New York. Edison found no supp
amongst them. All thought his plan inflationary, destabilizing, and expensive to operat
20
Mitchell’s response was particularly blunt:
“…we would regard this scheme highly impracticable…it would be very expensive…It would lack
elasticity – responsiveness to fluctuating demands…there would be great pressure upon the Congress to
enlarge the list of eligible commodities. Every industry would want to have its products included…No
se method for keeping the currency true to any standard is given…the plan is inferior to the system in u
now…”
17
Garrett’s analysis in the New York Times is respectful, but equally critical.
21
Garrett’s unstated but clearly implied conclusion was that Edison simply didn’t
understand the monetary system. He was particularly critical of Edison’s claim that his
plan could be tried out as an experiment supplementing the current system.
In a reply published by the Times, Edison argued that Garrett did not understand
his system: “What is really wanted is a single currency based entirely on mortgage
loans…To do this it would be necessary to withdraw greenbacks and gold and silver
notes, put these in the vaults and then issue a single currency representing loans on
property of twice the value…We would then have all the sound currency desired.” (New
York Times, July 17 1922).
Ironically Irving Fisher was much more encouraging. He did not think Garrett’s
criticism did Edison’s plan justice and that the concern that it would be inflationary was
premature.
22
He added: “…from Garrett’s description of your plan, it would seem to me
incomplete because of the failure to connect up banking reserves with it, or banking
And this comment from Kingsley summarizes his tone throughout:
“The world has tried many times to drop what you call a “fiction” and substitute so-called ‘values’ as a
basis of money. Such attempts have always failed and always will…Of course the lessons of history mean
little to the men who call all history ‘bunk’. ”
Forgan, while negative over-all, did not think the plan necessarily inflationary.
21
The editor for the Times introduces Garrett as “…a writer of high repute, especially on financial
subjects.” Garrett’s articles were a result of a series of conversations he had with Edison.
22
Correspondence between Fisher and Edison is in Banking 1922, Box 1, folder 21.
18
deposits.”
23
But he concludes, “I rather think that your plan and Merriam’s completely
worked out may ideally be superior to mine…”.
24
Fisher later expressed disappointment that the only copy of Edison’s plan is from
the Garrett article: “I think I understand your plan but what I hoped you would be able to
send me is your own most detailed statement of it….My own book on the subject is 300
pages…I have as yet seen nothing authoritative from you describing your plan.” All the
evidence indicates that Garrett’s description is a complete description of Edison’s plan.
At a meeting of the Academy of Political Science in 1922 William T. Foster
publicly criticized the plan for basing “…the issue of money on total production rather
than on the rate of increase, and on past valuations rather than on volume, and on a few
commodities rather than on all commodities.” (Foster 1922, page 11). He goes on to
argue the plan would be destabilizing and challenged the legitimacy of granting special
privileges to any one group of producers.
25
Evaluation
It is difficult to assess the impact of Edison’s plan because, as Fisher pointed out,
it was incomplete. Edison himself was inconsistent on whether his plan was to supplant
or merely supplement the monetary system. It is beyond the scope of this paper to fully
23
Letter dated July 31, 1922.
24
Fisher was referring to his “compensated dollar” plan and Merriam was a professor at the University of
California. An intriguing suggestion from an anonymous referee is that here Fisher is “reveal[ing] his own
doubts about the gold standard. “
25
Only Arthur Kitson of Great Britain, who was not one of the original experts that Edison contacted, gave
positive comments on his plan. See Hammes and Wills, 2005a.
19
work out all the implications under different assumptions, especially the implications of
using options to control the money supply (Hammes and Wills, 2005b).
Unsurprisingly, it is clear from the comments that no one recognized that the
Equity Certificate was an American Call Option. Edison explicitly asked the bankers and
academics whether it would be eligible for discount at a commercial bank. All the
bankers were emphatic that no bank would discount such paper and that it might actually
be against the law to do so. Forgan equated it to a second mortgage.
Where Edison’s monetary system fits in within the range of monetary thought of
the time is equally challenging to pin down. Edison never refers to different schools of
thought and seems blissfully unaware of, or uninterested in, the academic debates still
smoldering from the early years of the century.
26
While it remains unknown how he
chose the seventeen original recipients of his questionnaire, it is highly unlikely that he
leaned toward any school of thought or they to him.
27
26
As noted by an anonymous referee: “The establishment of the Federal Reserve System…can be
understood as the outcome of a decade long (or longer) monetary debate that in 1922 no [academic] one
was willing to reopen…the central bank (Benjamin Strong) was just starting to think about how to use the
new system for active management domestically while restoring the gold standard internationally. There
was no room for Edison in that discussion.”
27
We found no evidence that Edison sought out members of one ‘school’ or another. That he had a longer
correspondence with Fisher than any of the others no doubt reflects other common interests (e.g. health)
and Fisher’s out-going and zealous style. In fact, Fisher unsuccessfully used this opportunity to try and
persuade Edison to present his plan to Congress’s Goldsborough Committee. So, this short, but intense
communication with Fisher should not be construed as Edison favoring the Quantity Theory. Had a ‘real-
bills man’ like H. Parker Willis (who was one of the seventeen to whom Edison initially wrote) been more
inclined, he, too, could have engaged Edison at more length (see Hammes and Wills, 2004).
20
Despite that, Edison’s plan has a “real bills” flavor to it with respect to the
emphasis on the currency being created by the production of real goods (crops) and then
canceled within a specific time period. However, this similarity is more superficial than
substantive. The rationale for the Real Bills doctrine is that money would be injected into
the economy as the needs of trade expanded which was proxied by the amount of real
bills. Therefore, changes in the money supply are positively correlated with changes in
current (or near future) production (that the real bills were financing) and the central bank
could regulate that growth by the rate at which it discounted real bills.
Under Edison’s plan money would be created on completed (or past) production
as crops come to the government warehouses, but there is no explicit mechanism for
control of the amount of money through a discount rate. Instead, the government must
respond passively and automatically according to the volume of crops brought to the
warehouses and the twenty-five year average price. There is no additional role of
monetary control—which real bills advocates saw as being crucial--for the central bank
through manipulation of the discount rate.
Conclusion
Under the onslaught of criticism of his plan, a lack of popular support in response
to Garrett’s piece in the New York Times, lessening public pressure to “do something”,
and a heavy load of his on-going work, Edison soon gave up the monetary project.
28
28
Dorfman, 1959, Vol.4, page 34, cites “sufficient legislation providing credit for farmers” as the reason
for Ford’s and Edison’s lack of further interest. This legislation was the Agricultural Credit Act, passed in
early 1923, amending section 13 of the Federal Reserve Act allowing agricultural paper of up to nine
21
However, he remained convinced he was correct having an assistant write to Irving
Fisher on August 7, 1922 (Fisher, 1922):
“This [Edison’s commodity-backed money] is the idea that Mr. Edison has so far been
unable to get any bankers or other persons to understand except one. He further thinks
that a great many persons seem to be in a rut and their minds refuse to act…This work
Mr. Edison says he did for Mr. Ford and he is not
highly interested in urging it, but thinks
in years to come people will come around to his views.”
29
While commentators were justifiably harsh in their criticism of his logic and of
his ignoring the public cost of operating this plan, it is less clear that they were correct in
their analysis of its implications. In light of the options interpretation of the plan it is not
clear that the plan would have been either inflationary or destabilizing. And, of course, all
the commentators entirely missed the benefits that would have flowed from the
development of additional financial institutions, deeper markets in existing--and newly
created markets in--standardized options contracts in the 1920s.
months’ maturity to be eligible for rediscount at Federal Reserve Banks. See Harding (1925), page 222;
pps. 238-245.
29
Kitson being the lone exception.
22
REFERENCES
Beale, W.T.M. Jr., Kennedy, M.T., and Winn, W.J. “Commodity Reserve Currency-A
Critique,” Journal of Political Economy 50, no.4 (1942): 579-594.
Boyle, David, (ed.), The Money Changers: Currency Reform from Aristotle to E-cash,
Earthscan, London, 2002.
Clark, J.M. “The Proposal for a Composite Commodity Currency,” in Economic Essays
In Honour of Gustav Cassel, 75-87. London, UK: George Allen & Unwin 1933.
Crennan, C.H. Responses to Questionnaire, February 24, 1922, Banking, Box 7, folder 3,
(1922). Edison National Historic Site Archives, West Orange, New Jersey.
Dorfman, J. The Economic Mind in American Civilization, Viking Press, NY, Vols. 4 and
5, 1959.
Edison, Thomas A. “A Proposed Amendment to the Federal Reserve Banking System”,
West Orange, NJ, Revised May 13, 1922., Banking 1922, Box 4, folder 6, Edison
National Historic Site Archives, West Orange, New Jersey.
Edison, Thomas A., Letter to Irving Fisher, August 7, 1922, Banking 1922, Box 1, folder
21, Edison National Historic Site Archives, West Orange, New Jersey.
Edison, Thomas A., Two letters to Irving Fisher, December 19, 1922, Banking 1922, Box
6, folder 1, Edison National Historic Site Archives, West Orange, New Jersey.
Fisher, Irving, Stable Money A History of the Movement, Adelphi Co., New York, 1934.
Fisher, Irving, Letter to Thomas Edison, July 31, 1922, Banking 1922, Box 1, folder 21,
Edison National Historic Site Archives, West Orange, New Jersey.
Fisher, Irving, Letter to Thomas Edison, August 11, 1922, Banking 1922, Box 1, folder
21, Edison National Historic Site Archives, West Orange, New Jersey.
23
Fisher, Irving, Letter to Thomas Edison, Dec. 12, 1922, Banking 1922, Box 6, folder 1,
Edison National Historic Site Archives, West Orange, New Jersey.
Forgan, J.B. Responses to Questionnaire, February 16, 1922, Banking, Box 7, folder 5,
Edison National Historic Site Archives, West Orange, New Jersey.
Foster, William Trufant. “Edison-Ford Commodity Money”, an address before the annual
meeting of the American Academy of Political Science, November 23, 1922.
Foster, W.T., and Catchings, W. Money 2
nd
Ed., Houghton Mifflin Publishing, Boston
and New York, 1924.
Friedman, Milton. “Commodity-Reserve Currency,” Journal of Political Economy, 59,
(1951): 203-232.
Garrett, Garett. “Staple Money,” July 16, 1922, New York Times.
Graham, Benjamin. Storage and Stability. McGraw-Hill, New York, NY (1937).
Graham, Frank. “The Primary Functions of Money and Their Consummation in
Monetary,” American Economic Review Supplement, (1940):1-16.
Hammes, D., and Wills, D., “Thomas Edison’s ‘Except One’: The Monetary Views of
Arthur Kitson Revisited”, The Journal of Economic Studies, Vol. 32, No.1, 2005a.
Hammes, D.L., and Wills, D.T., 2004, “Edison’s Plan to Reinvent Money”, Financial
History Magazine, Issue 80, Winter 2004., pps. 16-19, 2004.
Hammes, D.L., and Wills, D.T., “Money, Prices, and Output in a Pure ‘Edison’ Monetary
Economy,” working paper, 2005b.
Harding, W.P.G. February 6, 1922, Banking, Box 7, folder 4, Edison National Historic
Site Archives, West Orange, New Jersey.
24
Hayek, F. A. “A Commodity Reserve Currency,” The Economic Journal, 53, (1943):176-
184.
Hazlitt, H., column in The New York Evening Mail, December 9, 1921. Edison’s copy in
Banking 1921 Collection, location: Banking.
Hicks, J.D., “The Sub-Treasury: A Forgotten Plan for the Relief of Agriculture”, The
Mississippi Valley Historical Review, Vol. 15, No.3, December 1928.
Israel, Paul. Edison-A Life of Invention. John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 1998.
Jay, P. Responses to Questionnaire, April 3, 1922, in Banking, Box 2, Folder 4, Edison
National Historic Site Archives, West Orange, New Jersey.
Kemmerer, E.W. Responses to Questionnaire, Banking Collection, box 2, folder 4, 1922,
Edison National Historic Site Archives, West Orange, New Jersey.
Kingsley D.P. Responses to Questionnaire, February 24, 1922, Banking, Box 5, folder
17, 1922, Edison National Historic Site Archives, West Orange, New Jersey.
Laidler, David, Fabricating the Keynesian Revolution, Cambridge University Press,
1999.
Laughlin, J. Laurence, A New Exposition of Money, Credit, and Prices, Vols. 1 and 2,
The University of Chicago Press, 1931.
Mehrling, P.G., “Economists and the Fed: Beginnings,” Journal of Economic
Perspectives
, 16, no.4, (2002): 207-217.
Mehrling, P.G., The Money Interest and the Public Interest, Harvard University Press,
1997.
Mitchell C.E. Responses to Questionnaire, February 23, 1922, Banking, Box 5, folder 16,
1922, Edison National Historic Site Archives, West Orange, New Jersey.
25
Nash, J. “Ideal Money” at:
http://www.syntelos.org/john/nash.html, 2001.
Patterson, E.M. Responses to Questionnaire, Banking, Box 7, folder 3, 1922, Edison
National Historic Site Archives, West Orange, New Jersey.
26
... 2. Bitcoin could become the anchor currency. It could take on a life of a "commodity reserve" monetary plan similar to what Thomas Edison proposed in 1922 [Sauser (2014); Hammes and Wills (2006)] and integrate with mobile banking and microfinance in regions such as Haiti or Africa. However, it does not need to be tied back specifically to agriculture, nor do 'interest free' loans have to be introduced. ...
Article
Full-text available
This article discusses how the sudden shift in policy reform and innovation has the potential to liberate the financial markets. The economic potential of internet finance is beginning to take hold across the capital markets as industries like Peer – to – Peer Lending, Equity and Debt based Crowdfunding and virtual currencies and cryptocurrencies which are types of digital currency are quickly transforming the way businesses are being financed. From borrowing and lending, buying and selling securities, to conducting wire transfers internationally, these innovations are creating a new class and generation of investors will source investments opportunities. Helping institutions and governments assess risks and manage performance in order to determine where to deploy capital; and showing signs of lessening the inequality gap. Following the neolithic agricultural revolution and the industrial revolution, this new revolution will enable more people to access financial services in less traditional ways, especially the unbanked world with its huge potential. These new financial opportunities, such as peer – to - peer (P2P) lending, will be discussed and examined, and we will stress how they can allow people to bypass current barriers in the global economy. We conclude by arguing that all these developments, energized by the efforts of innovators and entrepreneurs, have the potential to radically transform the world in which we live, while promoting the core values of industrialized societies including democracy, capital formation, sustainability, and equality without solely relying on tax increases
... The initial plan was quite simple. He proposed to eliminate excess volatility in commodity prices by having the state maintain 2 The knowledgeable reader will observe that I do not follow Graham's own suggestion that he was building on Thomas Edison's proposal to monetize commodities (discussed in Hammes and Wills 2006) and Irving Fisher's (1920) index stabilization plan. I read both references as the attempt of an amateur to associate himself with experts. ...
Article
Benjamin Graham’s amateur proposal for a commodity reserve currency (1937, 1944) has attracted the attention of professional economists and policy makers, but usually for their own prior purposes and designs. This paper places the proposal in the context of Graham’s own time and the intellectual resources available to him, with a view to elucidating both Graham’s own sense of the proposal and the reasons the proposal earned the reception it did.
Article
Purpose This paper aims to apply the doctrine of siyasah shariyyah to a policy proposal in the area of monetary economics, namely, the Grondona system of conditional currency convertibility, which has been proposed as a practical means of resisting the economic instability caused by the present-day fiat money system. Design/methodology/approach The paper uses library research to review the literature relevant to the Grondona system, and examines the extent to which its operations conform to the principle of siyasah shariyyah, thereby encouraging Maslahah, i.e. the public interest. Findings It has been found that the Grondona system conforms to the philosophy of siyasah shariyyah because it promotes public welfare in a number of ways. First, it is based on the fundamental principle of Prophet Yusuf’s/Joseph (peace be upon him) economic planning, which is accumulating reserves of primary commodities during times of plenty and releasing those reserves of commodities during periods of scarcity. Second, it provides the necessary linkage between the monetary world and the real economy. Third, it could be implemented in parallel with the existing monetary system by using the national currency. Fourth, it would help the least developed countries of the world, which mainly depend on exports of primary commodities (mostly agricultural). Research limitations/implications Because of the chosen research approach, this research study is theoretical in nature. Therefore, researchers are encouraged to evaluate the system from economic perspective based on simulation for the purpose of possible implementation. Practical implications The paper includes important implications for the policymakers in the Organization of Islamic Cooperation countries for the possible implementation of Grondona system. Originality/value This paper fulfils an identified need to apply the philosophy of siyasah shariyyah to the area of monetary economics.
Article
Post-World War I Federal Reserve System policy focused on reducing price levels. Faith in liquidationist ideas led Federal Reserve officials to maintain tight-money policies during the depression of 1920–1921. Farmers suffering through this economic crisis objected to contemporary monetary policy. Organized labor and leading Progressive reformer Robert M. La Follette Sr. seconded their criticism. Postwar challenges to the nation’s financial leadership and its priorities bore tangible results by producing a number of notable reforms, including modifications of Federal Reserve policy and the Agricultural Credits Act of 1923. In the absence of similar political pressure during the Great Depression, the Federal Reserve System adhered to liquidationist ideas and did not pursue monetary expansion.
Article
As usually understood, the significant debate over the founding of the Fed was between advocates of the real bills doctrine and advocates of the quantity theory of money. This understanding however conflates two different distinctions: one between the banking principle and the currency principle, and one between self-regulation and active management. It also fails to take seriously both the context of practical experience with the national banking system and the developing practical experience inside the Fed. I propose a new interpretation focused mainly on the contributions of four economists: J. Laurence Laughlin, Irving Fisher, Paul Warburg and Benjamin Strong.
Data
Source: Walters, S.T., Cahill, M. A., Vader, A. M. (2008). The Officer Responses Questionnaire: A procedure for measuring reflective listening in probation and parole settings. Federal Probation, 72(2), 67-70.
Book
Examining the emergence, in the inter-war years, of what came to be called ‘Keynesian macroeconomics’. This study accepts the novelty of the latter, as represented by the IS-LM model, which in various forms came to dominate the sub-discipline for three decades. It argues, however, that this model did not represent a radical change in economic thinking but rather an extremely selective synthesis of those which had permeated the preceding literature, including Keynes’s own contributions to it, not least the General Theory. Hence the book questions the appropriateness of thinking of this development as the outcome of a ‘Keynesian Revolution’ in economic thought, partly because the most radical aspects of Keynes’s own intended contribution were excluded from it, but mainly because IS-LM is better viewed as the end result of twenty years or more of intellectual development to which many others besides Keynes contributed.
Article
Purpose This paper examines the monetary thought of Arthur Kitson (1861‐1937) as expressed in his published works and in recently discovered answers he submitted in 1922 to a questionnaire from Thomas Edison, the US inventor. Design/methodology/approach Both original source material from the Edison Archive and published sources are used to examine the subject. Findings It is found that Kitson's monetary thought is more orthodox than has previously been claimed by, among others, John Maynard Keynes, and more recently in the economics literature. It is also found that Kitson was the only person to support, without qualification, Edison's plan to reform the US monetary system. Originality/value This paper casts a new light on Kitson's monetary thought, showing the influence of Irving Fisher on Kitson. The paper also presents Edison's questionnaire and Kitson's contributory thoughts on a fiat monetary standard that the questionnaire stimulated.