ArticlePDF Available

Comparing Impacts across Climate Models

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

In this paper we combine a climate-forecasting model, COSMIC, with a global impact model, GIM, to compare the market impacts of climate change projected by 14 general circulation models. Given a specific date (2100), carbon dioxide concentration (612 ppmv), and global temperature sensitivity (2.5C), predicted impacts to economies are calculated using climate-response functions from Experimental and Cross-sectional evidence. The Cross-sectional impact model predicts small global benefits across all climate models, whereas the Experimental impact model predicts a range from small benefits to small damages. High-latitude countries are less sensitive to temperature increases than low-latitude countries because they are currently cool. Uniform global temperature changes overestimate global damages because they underestimate the benefits in polar regions and overestimate the damages in tropical regions compared to the GCM predictions.
Content may be subject to copyright.
Integrated Assessment 1 (2000) 37–48 37
Comparing impacts across climate models
Robert Mendelsohn
a
, Michael Schlesinger
b
and Larry Williams
c
a
Yale University, 360 Prospect Street, New Haven, CT 06511, USA
b
University of Illinois, 105 South Gregory, Urbana, IL 61801, USA
c
Electric Power Research Institute, PO Box 10412, Palo Alto, CA 94303, USA
Received 8 September 1999; revised 19 November 1999
In this paper we combine a climate-forecasting model, COSMIC, with a global impact model, GIM, to compare the market impacts of
climate change projected by 14 general circulation models. Given a specific date (2100), carbon dioxide concentration (612 ppmv), and
global temperature sensitivity (2.5
C), predicted impacts to economies are calculated using climate-response functions from Experimental
and Cross-sectional evidence. The Cross-sectional impact model predicts small global benefits across all climate models, whereas
the Experimental impact model predicts a range from small benefits to small damages. High-latitude countries are less sensitive to
temperature increases than low-latitude countries because they are currently cool. Uniform global temperature changes overestimate
global damages because they underestimate the benefits in polar regions and overestimate the damages in tropical regions compared to
the GCM predictions.
1. Introduction
Two tools have recently been developed to project an-
thropogenically induced climate changes and their impacts.
COSMIC [25] uses the global-mean surface temperature
calculated by a simple climate/ocean model to scale in time
the geographical patterns of changes in surface temperature
and precipitation simulated by any of 14 General Circula-
tion models (GCMs) to generate country-specific climate
projections. GIM [19] combines country-specific climate
projections, market-sector data, and climate-response func-
tions to predict market impacts from warming by sector and
nation. In this paper we combinethese two tools to compare
the projections of the 14 GCMs whose results are included
in COSMIC. This large number of GCMs was selected to
illustrate the variation across models. We thought it im-
portant to show more than one climate-response function
again to illustrate differences. However, it is important that
policy analysts understand that the scenarios do not demon-
strate all possible sources of uncertainty. For example, we
do not explore the effect of alternative baseline emission
scenarios, variations in temperature sensitivity, alternative
time lags due to the ocean, and alternative climate-response
functions. Instead, the scenarios emphasize the new in-
sights from making country-level associations between cli-
mate forecasts and impacts. The integration of GCMs and
country-level impact models provides a new mechanism for
comparing GCM forecasts and for understanding the distri-
bution of impacts across the earth.
There are many links in the chain from carbon dioxide
emissions to climate projections [13]. We know a lot about
each step and yet each step remains a source of uncertainty.
Alternative assumptions about the path of the economy al-
ter emissions over space and time. The carbon cycle de-
termines how these emissions affect concentrations in the
atmosphere. Changes in carbon dioxide and other man-
made greenhouse gases alter the net radiative flux at the
top of the atmosphere, which constitutes a radiative forcing
of the climate system. Changes in temperature at different
heights in the atmosphere will in turn affect clouds and ice,
either compounding or reducing this radiative effect, gen-
erating global temperature sensitivity. Finally, the ocean
will gradually respond to temperature change, warming at
different levels over time, creating a dynamic response that
may take decades to centuries to play out. COSMIC com-
bines a simple climate/ocean model with the geographical
distributions of the changes in surface temperature and pre-
cipitation simulated by 14 GCMs. Assuming that the geo-
graphic climate distributions from each model can be scaled
by the global-mean surface temperature change, COSMIC
predicts country-specific climate projections for each GCM.
GIM ties the country-specific projections of changes in
surface temperature and precipitation to predictions of mar-
ket impacts by sector and country. First, GIM projects what
the future economy will look like at the time of the impact.
Models of each sector must reference baseline projections
of economic activity for that sector in order to calculate fu-
ture climate impacts. For example, agriculture is predicted
to grow more slowly than the rest of the economy, cooling
will grow relative to warming in space conditioning, and the
world economy will be about ten times larger by 2100. Sec-
ond, the climate-response function of each sector must be
predicted. Unfortunately, this is one of the weakest links in
global-warming research. It is very uncertain how the entire
earth will respond to any given climate change. Climate-
response functions have been estimated only for market
effects, that is, impacts to economic sectors [18]. Although
these projections are presented as point estimates, they are
clearly uncertain. We present two projections that come
Baltzer Science Publishers BV
38 R. Mendelsohn et al. / Comparing impacts across climate models
from entirely different empirical approaches to illustrate the
range of uncertainty. Even this is an understatement of the
true level of uncertainty since we have very little empirical
information about the impacts of climate change on devel-
oping countries. Finally, the climate-response functions in
this paper have been calibrated only for the United States.
The climate-response functions for the quality of life such
as ecological changes, human health, and aesthetic impacts,
are still under development; hence, they are not yet included
in GIM. Thus, the market impacts discussed in this paper
cannot be compared directly against estimates of all impacts
such as in [4,22,32].
Since climate itself is changing very slowly, it is ex-
tremely difficult to measure across time the sensitivity of
market sectors to climate change. The literature has conse-
quently resorted to two alternative approaches, Experimen-
tal and Cross-sectional. The Experimental approach con-
structs process-based simulation models from carefully con-
ducted scientific experiments. Using laboratory-controlled
settings, experiments are run on crops, trees, and other sub-
jects to determine their sensitivity to temperature, precip-
itation, and carbon dioxide. Simulation models are con-
structed from the experimental evidence to predict what
will happen in the aggregate. The Cross-sectional ap-
proach uses evidence from alternative locations to make
predictions. By comparing one area with a warmer site,
the Cross-sectional approach is able to discern what would
happen to that place in the long run if it warmed. Both
approaches have strengths and weaknesses. The Experi-
mental approach is able to isolate the impact of each ele-
ment through laboratory controls, while the Cross-sectional
approach is subject to unwanted variation from factors it
fails to control. This advantage of the Experimental ap-
proach leads to a weakness. The controls imposed by the
Experimental approach may eliminate important responses
by subjects, that is, adaptations that limit damages and en-
hance benefits. Since the Cross-sectional approach includes
responses people have already made to where they live,
the Cross-sectional approach captures adaptation. Because
the two methods have different strengths and weaknesses,
and both are highly uncertain, it is prudent to include both
methods in impact analysis.
In this paper we explore a set of future conditions to
compare the impacts calculated for the changes in sur-
face temperature and precipitation simulated by 14 GCMs.
We utilize both Experimental and Cross-sectional climate-
response functions to evaluate the climate projections based
on each of the GCMs. By examining the impacts, we can
gain new insights into which projected climate changes are
important, which are consistent across the GCMs, and how
best to describe these projections for the globe. We focus
on impacts in 2100 to obtain a long-run, but still relevant,
perspective. We assume that humankind commits itself to
a maximum equivalent CO
2
concentration of 750 ppmv,
which implies a carbon dioxide concentration of 612 ppmv
in 2100 [13]. We assume that global population has dou-
bled to 10 billion and that the global gross domestic product
(GDP) is 217 trillion, a ten-fold increase. Finally, we as-
sume that global temperature sensitivity is 2.5
C, that is,
the equilibrium global-mean surface temperature increase
for a CO
2
doubling is 2.5
C.
In the next section we describe various features of
COSMIC and GIM in detail. In section 3 we describe the
aggregate results for each GCM. In section 4 we analyze
these alternative results to explain which features of the
climate projections generate large impacts, which projec-
tions are consistent, and how to aggregate climate forecasts
across the earth from an impacts perspective.
2. COSMIC and GIM
2.1. COSMIC
Analyses of the impacts of anthropogenically induced
climate changes require time-dependent scenarios of the
geographical distributions of these climate changes. If the
anthropogenic emissions of greenhouse gases (GHGs) and
sulfur dioxide (SO
2
) and the sensitivity of the climate
system were known, the best-possible method of con-
structing geographical scenarios of climate change would
be to perform climate-change simulations with coupled
atmosphere–ocean general circulation models (CGCMs),
from pre-industrial time into the future. However, the fu-
ture anthropogenic emissions of GHGs and CO
2
are highly
uncertain (e.g., [30]), as is the radiative forcing due to
sulfate (SO
4
) aerosol created in the atmosphere from the
emitted SO
2
[13]. Thus it is computationally impossible
to perform with a CGCM the multitude of climate-change
simulations required to span the ranges of possible emis-
sion scenarios, climate sensitivities and sulfate radiative
forcing (F
SO
4
(1990)). Accordingly a simpler, computa-
tionally practicable method of constructing these numerous
geographical scenarios of climate change is needed.
The method of scenario construction we employ in the
Country Specific Model for Intertemporal Climate (COS-
MIC) was developed by [23] and further refined at the
Climatic Research Unit, University of East Anglia, Nor-
wich, UK [14], and used in the scenario generation code,
SCENGEN [15]. The method has also been used else-
where [24,25,29,30]. An atmospheric GCM with a mixed-
layer ocean (AGC/MLO) model is used to simulate a con-
trol (con) equilibrium climate and the equilibrium experi-
ment (exp) climate for an enhanced CO
2
concentration. The
geographical distribution of CO
2
-induced equilibrium cli-
mate change for any climatic quantity, Q(λ, ϕ,m), where λ
and ϕ are the longitude and latitude of the AGC/MLO
model’s grid cells and m is the calendar month, is then
calculated and normalized by the corresponding change in
annual global-mean surface-air temperature, T
exp
T
con
,
Q
N
(λ,ϕ,m) =
Q
exp
(λ,ϕ, m) Q
con
(λ,ϕ, m)
T
exp
T
con
. (1)
R. Mendelsohn et al. / Comparing impacts across climate models 39
The change in annual global-mean surface-air temperature,
T (y) = T (y) T (y
0
), (2)
from some pre-industrial time, y
0
(1765), to the present
is calculated with our energy-balance–climate/upwelling–
diffusion–ocean model [28] using the historical radia-
tive forcing of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate
Change [13] and then into the future for a prescribed
climate-change scenario and a prescribed climate sensitiv-
ity, G. The changes in annual global-mean surface-air tem-
perature relative to a reference year, y
ref
(= 1990), are then
calculated from
δT (y) = T (y) T (y
ref
) = T (y) T (y
ref
). (3)
The time-dependent geographical distributions of monthly
climate change in year y relative to y
ref
for each climate-
change scenario of equivalent CO
2
concentration
1
and pre-
scribed climate sensitivity are then determined from
δQ(λ,ϕ, y,m) = δT (y)Q
N
(λ,ϕ, m), (4)
the normalized pattern of greenhouse-gas-induced climate
change being taken to be the same as the pattern of
CO
2
-induced climate change, Q
N
(λ,ϕ, m). Finally, the
monthly climatic quantities in year y are obtained from
Q(λ,ϕ, y,m) = Q
obs
(λ,ϕ, y
ref
,m) + δQ(λ,ϕ,y,m), (5)
where Q
obs
(λ,ϕ, y
ref
,m) are the observed climatic quanti-
ties for month m of the reference year or period containing
the reference year.
In COSMIC the geographical distributions of the nor-
malized changes in monthly mean surface-air temperature
and precipitation, Q
N
(λ,ϕ, m), can be chosen for any of
the 14 GCMs listed in table 1. The changes in annual
global-mean surface-air temperature, δT (y), can be cal-
culated by COSMIC for any of 7 main scenarios of fu-
ture concentrations of greenhouse gases [39], each for low,
medium and high sulfate aerosol emission rates
2
[39], as
well as for two ways (proposed by [13] and [37]) of stabi-
lizing the CO
2
concentration at either 350, 450, 550, 650
or 750 ppmv. Each calculation can be performed for a
wide range of values of G and F
SO
4
(1990). COSMIC
calculates the country-specific annual cycles of surface-air
temperature and precipitation rate for 177 countries, as well
as the global-mean sea-level rise, and is available gratis on
compact disk.
3
1
The amount of CO
2
required to give the same radiative forcing as all
the greenhouse gases together.
2
In Version 1 of COSMIC, the sulfate aerosol burden influences only
δT (y), that is, no account is taken of the geographical distribution of
climate change due to the sulfate aerosol. The latter will be included in
Version 2 of COSMIC.
3
To request a no-cost license contact: Larry J. Williams; Electric Power
Research Institute; 3412 Hillview Avenue; E-mail: ljwillia@epri.com;
fax: (650) 855-2950.
2.2. GIM
GIM is a spreadsheet model that begins with a country-
specific set of climate changes and then predicts market
impacts. A separate model is designed for each sensi-
tive market sector: agriculture, forestry, energy, water, and
coastal structures. A separate calculation is made for each
sector and country that combines the change in climate,
sector data, and a climate-response function. This leads
to calculations of damages or benefits by sector and coun-
try. Quality-of-life effects such as changes in ecosystems,
health, and aesthetic losses are not included in this version
of the model as climate-response functions for these effects
are not yet available.
The current version of GIM responds to annual temper-
ature and precipitation. Future versions of the model will
move to seasonal climate variables to gain more detailed
insight into climate impacts. Annual climate by country
is one of the inputs to the model. These projections are
obtained from COSMIC for each GCM.
For each country, key parameters of each sector are col-
lected. For example, area of cropland, area of forestland,
and length of coastline provide important insights into agri-
culture, forestry, and coastal structures, respectively. Gross
Domestic Product (GDP) by country is also a key in several
sectors. As GIM becomes more sophisticated, additional
parameters will be collected for each country.
The heart of GIM is its climate-response functions. Ear-
lier impact research predicted impacts from a limited set
of climate scenarios. Examining individual scenarios be-
comes cumbersome when it is important to evaluate a large
number of scenarios and when one evaluates a path of cli-
mate change. Consequently, the literature had begun to
develop climate-response functions, descriptions of how
impacts change within a sector as climate changes [18].
Many integrated assessment models have climate-response
functions to measure damages, given a path of climate
change [12,16,21,22]. Unfortunately, many of these re-
sponse functions were invented by the authors or were fit
to very limited observations (for example, current condi-
tions and doubling of greenhouse gases). In this paper, we
rely upon climate-response functions based on empirical
research [20]. In that study, over a dozen of the lead-
ing impact researchers did empirical studies of each of the
climate-sensitive sectors of the US economy. There were
four key elements in this new research: inclusion of effi-
cient adaptation, broad sectoral estimates, dynamic analysis
when appropriate, and use of future economic conditions.
The research relied upon the two major alternative meth-
ods of measuring the response to climate. Several studies
relied upon the Experimental method, which begins with
carefully controlled laboratory studies and uses these to
construct simulation models. The remainder of the studies
relied on Cross-sectional evidence. By comparing farms
and households in cool versus warm locations, one can es-
timate how people have adapted to their resident climates
and how they may react as these climates change in the
40 R. Mendelsohn et al. / Comparing impacts across climate models
Table 1
GCM model simulations: global annual averages for doubling the pre-industrial carbon dioxide concentration.
Acronym Institution T P Reference
(
C) (%)
BMRC Bureau of Meteorology Research Center 2.11 2.38 [10]
CCC Canadian Climate Centre 3.50 4.00 [2,3,17]
GF30 Geophysical Fluid Dynamics Laboratory
(R30 run)
4.00 8.3 [35,36]
GFDL Geophysical Fluid Dynamics Laboratory
(first run)
4.00 8.3 [35,36]
GFQF Geophysical Fluid Dynamics Laboratory
(Q-flux run)
4.00 8.30 [35,36]
GISS Goddard Institute for Space Studies 4.20 11.00 [7–9]
HEND Henderson-Sellers using CCM1 at NCAR 2.50 5.60 [11]
OSU Schlesinger and Zhao at Oregon State
University
2.40 7.80 [26]
POLD Pollard and Thompson-GENESIS with
dynamic sea-ice
2.27 3.13 [31]
POLS Pollard and Thompson-GENESIS with
static sea-ice
2.27 3.13 [31]
UIUC Schlesinger at University of Illinois at
Urbana-Champaign
3.37 5.53 [28]
UKMO United Kingdom Meteorological Office 5.20 15.00 [38]
WANG Wang et al. at State University of New
York at Albany and NCAR
a
3.90 6.90 [33]
WASH Washington and Meehl using CCM1
at NCAR
4.82 4.75 [34]
a
NCAR is the National Center for Atmospheric Research.
Table 2
Aggregate impacts in 2100 by GCM model experimental responses (billions of 1990 $/year).
GCM Continent
a
Total Africa Asia LatAm WEur Comm NAm Ocean
BMRC 54 112 31 67 1 224 48 9
CCC 28 139 52 87 9 250 62 13
GF30 210 79 9 30 14 245 83 16
GFDL 203 100 8 37 12 267 81 12
GFQF 134 113 1 49 13 224 78 17
GISS 45 103 86 59 15 217 73 13
HEND 69 163 103 73 9 216 66 21
OSU 33 111 157 45 13 209 68 10
POLS 147 134 40 92 10 230 114 22
POLD 163 103 77 44 20 270 112 14
UIUC 139 186 161 97 10 223 85 12
UKMO 27 139 97 62 14 245 82 17
WANG 29 143 145 72 18 239 90 17
WASH 25 123 90 55 12 219 79 18
AVERAGE 55 125 70 62 12 234 80 15
a
The continents above are Africa, Asia, Latin America, Western Europe, the former Soviet Union
and Eastern bloc, North America, and Oceania.
long run. The strength of the Experimental method is that
it can isolate climate effects from other factors in the en-
vironment. Further, it can explore the effect of factors that
are not yet evident in the environment, such as higher levels
of carbon dioxide. The weakness of the approach is that
experiments are designed to control responses, both en-
vironmental and human. Adaptations that ecological sys-
tems and people make to climate change are suppressed,
thereby exaggerating the damages and reducing the bene-
fits from warming. The Cross-sectional approach is able
to capture efficient adaptations because the method com-
pares systems currently adapted to different climates. For
example, the farm in a cool place is compared to a farm in
a warm place, given all the adaptations that farmers have
made to where they live. This advantage of Cross-sectional
evidence comes at a cost. Cross-sectional studies are vul-
nerable to unmeasured factors that may be correlated with
climate. If these factors are not taken into account, they
R. Mendelsohn et al. / Comparing impacts across climate models 41
Table 3
Aggregate impacts in 2100 by GCM model Cross-sectional responses (billions of 1990 $/year).
GCM Continent
a
Total Africa Asia LatAm WEur Comm NAm Ocean
BMRC 150 10 32 3 2 100 29 1
CCC 152 18 31 6 5 108 33 2
GF30 185 5 35 3 6 106 41 2
GFDL 184 9 31 2 5 114 42 1
GFQF 165 12 35 0 6 98 41 3
GISS 131 15 17 7 7 94 38 2
HEND 97 28 8 10 5 95 32 4
OSU 116 15 0 3 6 93 37 1
POLS 173 16 39 7 6 101 53 4
POLD 175 10 21 2 8 112 48 2
UIUC 98 31 1 14 5 99 42 2
UKMO 136 21 16 5 6 104 39 3
WANG 119 22 1 9 7 102 43 3
WASH 143 13 22 2 5 96 38 3
AVERAGE 145 16 21 5 6 102 40 2
a
The continents above are Africa, Asia, Latin America, Western Europe, the former Soviet Union
and Eastern bloc, North America, and Oceania.
can be confused with climate effects, thereby leading to
misleading results. This is not a problem for the carefully
controlled experimental studies. Consequently, the Experi-
mental and Cross-sectional methods complement each other
well, and we rely upon both of them in this study.
The climate-response functions in these studies were
quadratic in temperature. That is, the response function
indicated a hill-shaped relationship between impacts and
temperature. This is an essential feature of the model and
explains many of the results in this paper. Countries that
are currently cooler than optimal are predicted to benefit
from warming. Countries that happen to be warmer than
optimal are predicted to be harmed by warming. Although
the quantitative measures shown in the paper remain highly
uncertain, these qualitative insights are likely to be robust.
3. Results
Combining the projections of COSMIC and GIM, one
can examine the impacts from a wide set of climate mod-
els. COSMIC provides a consistent set of conditions so that
the scenario, global temperature sensitivity, and ocean dy-
namics are the same. Given these identical conditions, one
can then study the alternative distributional patterns pre-
dicted by each GCM and examine their effect on impacts.
Although there have been a number of GCM comparisons
conducted by atmospheric scientists, these studies focused
on climate projections, not the resulting impacts [6]. Previ-
ous comparisons have consequently not been able to iden-
tify which aspects of these projections are important, what
impacts do these GCMs consistently agree upon, which as-
pects lead to a wide range of impacts, and how best to
aggregate climate projections across the earth.
To compare the 14 GCMs using a consistent set of start-
ing conditions, we make a number of assumptions. First,
we assume that carbon emissions are on a global path con-
sistent with reaching a maximum of 750 ppmv [13]. Sec-
ond, we examine the impacts in 2100. Given the IPCC path
specified above, carbon dioxide will reach 612 ppmv
by 2100. Third, we specify a global temperature sensitivity
of 2.5
C. The model predicts a global-average temperature
of 2.21
C by 2100. Fourth, we assume that the economy
grows according to medium projections so that global GDP
is $217 trillion by 2100. Given these assumptions, we cal-
culate the country-specific climate outcomes according to
each of the 14 GCMs in COSMIC. These climate changes
are then used to predict impacts by market sector for each
country.
In tables 2 and 3 we present continental estimates of
aggregate market impacts for each of the 14 GCMs us-
ing the Experimental and Cross-sectional climate-response
functions, respectively. Compared to the size of the econ-
omy in 2100 ($217 trillion), the market effects are small.
Global net impacts have a broad range across GCMs us-
ing the Experimental climate-response functions: from
$139 billion of damages to $210 billion of benefits, with
an average of $55 billion of benefits. The Cross-sectional
climate-response functions imply a narrower range of im-
pacts across GCMs: from $97 to $185 billion of benefits,
with an average of $145 billion of benefits a year. The
Experimental climate-response functions are more steeply
hill-shaped and thus they respond more sharply to tem-
perature increases in the polar and tropical regions. This
explains why the Experimental results are more sensitive
to the variety of GCM projections.
The results are also quite different across countries.
First, the GCMs generally agree that temperature change
increases with latitude. The GCMs also agree that pre-
42 R. Mendelsohn et al. / Comparing impacts across climate models
cipitation changes will not be uniform, although the pre-
cipitation projections are not consistent across the GCMs.
However, the impact models suggest that the magnitude of
impacts will depend not only on the changes in temperature
and precipitation, but also on the base conditions in each
country. Countries that are already hot or dry will be more
vulnerable to warming. Countries that are cold, in contrast,
are likely to benefit from warming. These initial conditions
lead to different outcomes across countries.
The results indicate that there will be large benefits from
warming in the Former Communist bloc (the former So-
viet Union and Eastern Bloc countries). The benefits in
this region almost offset losses throughout the tropics in
the Experimental results. The Soviet benefits account for
two-thirds of the net global benefits in the Cross-sectional
results. The results also suggest that there will be large ben-
efits in North America and small benefits in Western Eu-
rope. The critical factor that these benefiting countries have
in common is that they are currently cool so that warming
is helpful. The Experimental model predicts sizeable dam-
ages from warming in Africa, Latin America, Oceania, and
often Asia because these areas are currently already hot.
In contrast, the Cross-sectional model predicts that Africa,
Oceania, and Latin America will suffer only modest dam-
ages because of the compensating effects of carbon fertil-
ization and adaptation, and that Asia will likely benefit.
It is interesting to compare this geographic pattern
against the predictions of other authors. Tol predicts ben-
efits for more polar countries and damages for low lat-
itude countries as in this analysis [32]. However, both
Fankhauser and Nordhaus predict more uniform damages
across the entire world [4,22]. It appears that both of these
latter studies fail to fully account for initial climate condi-
tions in predicting warming impacts in a country. Because
it is important, future integrated assessment models will
need to do a better job of integrating geographically spe-
cific climate predictions and impacts.
The most important market impact from warming is agri-
cultural. According to the Experimental results, agriculture
was responsible for average global benefits of $88 billion,
compared to total net benefits of only $55 billion. The
Cross-sectional results were similar; agriculture would pro-
vide average benefits of $163 billion compared to total net
market benefits of $145 billion. Forestry was also per-
ceived as being beneficial, contributing an additional $20
and $29 billion in the Experimental and Cross-sectional re-
sults, respectively. The remaining sectors were expected
to generate net damages. Water damages were expected to
average $32 billion, energy damages were expected to be
about $9 billion, and coastal impacts were anticipated to be
$6 billion.
In addition to generating the largest expected effect, agri-
culture also explains most of the variation both across coun-
tries and across the GCMs. The standard error of aggre-
gate market impacts across the 14 GCMs is $101 billion
in the Experimental results and $54 billion in the Cross-
sectional results. The standard error for agriculturalimpacts
is $94 billion in the Experimental results and $52 billion
in the Cross-sectional results. Agriculture is the source of
most of the variation across models. In comparison, wa-
ter has a standard error of only $9 billion and energy only
$4 billion.
The three GCMs that predict the largest benefits in ta-
bles 2 and 3; GF30, GFDL, and POLD, all predict large in-
creases in temperature at high latitudes and small increases
at low latitudes. The benefits in the Communist bloc coun-
tries and North America are consequently higher and the
damages in Latin America and Africa are lower. In con-
trast, the three GCMs that predict the greatest damages or
smallest benefits in tables 2 and 3; HEND, OSU, and UIUC,
predict more uniform temperature changes; relatively high
values for low latitudes and relatively modest increases at
high latitudes. The benefits to the polar countries are con-
sequently smaller and the damages in the tropical countries
are higher.
The variability of estimated global impacts that result
from differences in the GCM climate forecasts can be seen
in more detail with the maps shown in figures 1 and 2. Fig-
ure 1 shows annual percentage changes in GDP as calcu-
lated by the Experimentalclimate-response functions driven
by different climate-change projections. The GCMs used
to prepare the three maps were chosen to represent the
maximum, average, and minimum impacts. There are sev-
eral ways in which the maximum and minimum impact
maps could be chosen. Total global market welfare losses
(shown in tables 2 and 3) could be used. This would result
in a measure mainly dependent on the countries with the
largest GDPs. An alternative would be to compare area- or
population-weighted percent GDP changes. In some sense
this would result in maps with the most/least red, and would
place the most weight on countries with the largest areas
or populations. Instead, we chose a method that weights
each country equally, independent of GDP, area, or popula-
tion. This method ranks 14 possible maps according to the
sum of percentage changes in GDP across all 177 countries
included in the GIM model.
The maximum-impact map in both figures 1 and 2 re-
sulted from using the UIUC GCM climate simulation. This
GCM generated larger impacts because it predicts relatively
more warming in the tropics than the other models. The
minimum-impactmap (again for both figures) was produced
with the POLD simulation. This GCM predicts more ben-
efits because it predicts relatively more warming for more
polar countries and less warming in the tropics. The top
map in figure 1 and 2 is the minimum impact map and the
maximum map is at the bottom of the figures. The middle
map shows the average impact, calculated by averaging the
impacts estimated by each of the 14 climate models used
in this analysis.
The most striking feature of figures 1 and 2 is the simi-
larity between maps going from top (minimum impact) to
bottom (maximum impact). Of course, the choice of “bins”
shown in the legend strongly affects the main features of
the maps. Nevertheless, these maps support the points
R. Mendelsohn et al. / Comparing impacts across climate models 43
Figure 1. Range of impacts calculated using Experimental climate-response functions. The POLD model produced smaller impacts than most other Gcms.
The UIUC model led the high impact end of the group.
44 R. Mendelsohn et al. / Comparing impacts across climate models
Figure 2. Range of impacts calculated using Cross-sectional climate-response functions. The POLD model produced smaller impacts than most
other Gcms. The UIUC model led the high impact end of the group.
R. Mendelsohn et al. / Comparing impacts across climate models 45
Table 4
Regressions of aggregate impacts on average global climate
change.
a
Impact
Experimental
= 720 341 T
Pop
+ 1711 P
Pop
186 77 687
Impact
Experimental
= 809 317 T
Area
+ 639 P
Area
423 163 917
Impact
Cross-sectional
= 375 109 T
Pop
+ 206 P
Pop
62 26 228
Impact
Cross-sectional
= 381 94 T
Area
29 P
Area
126 49 274
a
Dependent variable is net global market effects for 2100 in
billions of 1990$. Climate variables measure the aggregate
change in temperature and precipitation weighted by either
population or area. The standard errors are below the regres-
sion equation.
evident in tables 2 and 3. Developing countries in the trop-
ics are likely to be harmed by expected climate change,
while the developed countries, and transition economies, in
temperate and northern climates will see a net improvement
in the market sectors that are most responsive to climate
changes.
Although it has become customary to average tem-
perature increases across the entire globe when reporting
global changes, global impacts are more sensitive to the
population-weighted average change. We compare two
alternative aggregations of temperature and precipitation
across nations. The area measure weights climate in coun-
tries by total area. The population measure weights all
climate changes by the number of people in each coun-
try. Countries with more people get more weight. Ta-
ble 4 reports regressions of global net impacts across the
14 models on aggregate temperature and precipitation us-
ing the two alternative weights. The population-weighted
measure of both temperature and precipitation is statisti-
cally more significant and can explain a greater fraction of
the variance of global impacts across the climate models.
Population-weighted temperature and precipitation changes
are better predictors of impacts than land-weighted aver-
ages. This insight is likely to apply to national averages
as well. Weighting grids by population can give a better
estimate of the average temperature change than weighting
grids by area.
Table 4 provides another key insight. The coefficient
on temperature change is negative and significant in all the
models. Although the net impacts of climate change are
beneficial relative to an unchanged state, the models imply
that higher temperatures are harmful. There are two expla-
nations of this result. First, the climate-response function
for temperature is hill-shaped, not linear. Starting from
a cool climate, warming is beneficial at first. However,
as warming continues, more countries exceed the optimum
and warming becomes increasingly harmful. By 2100, all
the GCMs predict that the unweighted global temperature
change will exceed 2
C at which point further warming
is harmful. Second, changes in precipitation and carbon
dioxide are beneficial. Thus the overall net impact of all
Table 5
Regressions of regional impacts on regional climate
change (Experimental).
a
Impact
Africa
= 44 86 T
Pop
+ 287 P
Pop
63 14
Impact
Asia
= 214 157 T
Pop
+ 994 P
Pop
103 42 332
Impact
LatAmer
= 42 59 T
Pop
+ 357 P
Pop
15 8 34
Impact
WEur
= 9 1T
Pop
+ 93 P
Pop
52 11
Impact
Soviet
= 99 + 39 T
Pop
+ 235 P
Pop
41 13 76
Impact
NAmer
= 84 7T
Pop
+ 216 P
Pop
28 7 42
Impact
Oceania
= 6 11 T
Pop
+ 28 P
Pop
11 6 17
a
Dependent variable is regional impacts in 2100 in bil-
lions of 1990$. Regional climate change is average
change in region.
Table 6
Regressions of regional impacts on regional climate
change (Cross-sectional).
a
Impact
Africa
= 37 26 T
Pop
+ 38 P
Pop
11 3
Impact
Asia
= 110 44 T
Pop
+ 103 P
Pop
27 11 85
Impact
LatAmer
= 34 21 T
Pop
+ 44 P
Pop
32 7
Impact
WEur
= 8 1T
Pop
+ 25 P
Pop
21 4
Impact
Soviet
= 56 + 14 T
Pop
+ 60 P
Pop
16 5 29
Impact
NAmer
= 51 5T
Pop
+ 54 P
Pop
10 3 20
Impact
Oceania
= 5 4T
Pop
+ 7P
Pop
31 4
a
Dependent variable is regional impacts in 2100 meas-
ured in billions of 1990$. Regional climate change
is average change in region.
the changes is beneficial, even though the marginal effect
of additional temperature is harmful by 2100.
The sensitivity of each sector to climate is not uni-
form across all regions. Tables 5 and 6 display the re-
gional sensitivity. These sensitivities were calculated by
regressing the Experimental and Cross-sectional impacts
on the population-weighted climate measures for each re-
gion. North America, Western Europe, and the Soviet bloc
all have positive or small negative temperature coefficients
because they are currently cool. In contrast, Africa, Asia,
and Latin America have large negative temperature coeffi-
cients because they are currently hot. The resources each
continent possesses determine the size of the coefficients.
Asia has large coefficients because it has the most people,
whereas Oceania has few people and thus small coefficients
throughout. Tables 5 and 6 also reveal that the temperature
sensitivity of the Experimental results is greater in magni-
46 R. Mendelsohn et al. / Comparing impacts across climate models
Table 7
Market impacts from uniform climate change.
a
Measure Continent
b
Total Africa Asia LatAm WEur Comm NAm Ocean
Experimental
Average GCM 59 125 69 60 14 234 80 15
Area 130 145 154 82 15 187 67 19
Population 72 123 120 67 15 172 65 15
Cross-sectional
Average GCM 146 16 21 4 6 102 40 2
Area 95 21 2 12 7 87 36 3
Population 114 15 12 7 7 81 36 2
a
Impacts are measured in billions of 1990 $/year. The area-weighted uniform temperature change is 2.49
C with
a precipitation increase of 5.5% and the population-weighted uniform temperature change is 2.21
C, with a
precipitation increase of 5.2%.
b
The continents are Africa, Asia, Latin America, Western Europe, the former Soviet Union and Eastern bloc, North
America, and Oceania.
tude than that of the Cross-sectional results. As mentioned
earlier, this heightened sensitivity is due to the more steeply
shaped Experimental climate-response functions.
In order to shed more light on these results, we compare
the GCM results to the impacts from a uniform climate
change. We examine the impacts predicted by GIM using
two uniform climate predictions: the area and population-
weighted average temperature and precipitation change.
The results are displayed in table 7. Even though uni-
formity implies the same change in temperature and pre-
cipitation in every country, the impacts vary widely. Coun-
tries that begin cool benefit whereas countries that begin
warm are harmed. Comparing the uniform results to the
impacts generated by the GCMs reveals significant differ-
ences. The average uniform scenarios predict large dam-
ages in low-latitude countries in Africa, Asia, and Latin
America, and smaller benefits in high-latitude countries.
The uniform climate changes overestimate global damages.
The population-weighted results are better than the area-
weighted estimates, but they suffer from the same prob-
lems. The uniform scenarios miss the important variation
in temperature across latitudes.
This paper aggregates market effects across continents
without making any adjustments for the incomes of the im-
pacted countries. Some authors have argued that such ad-
justments should be made [5]. Unfortunately, the world has
yet to agree on a social-welfare function that could generate
such weights. Further, one would also have to weigh costs.
As costs become more evenly distributed across countries,
the importance of such weights diminishes [1]. Figures 1
and 2 both present impacts as a fraction of GDP. The results
indicate that impacts will be small relative to GDP. Because
the low-income countries tend to be clustered in the low lat-
itudes, the maps also indicate that any weighting scheme
that placed higher weights on low-income countries would
tend to emphasize the damages in the more tropical coun-
tries relative to the benefits in the more temperate countries.
Thus, the more weight one gave to low-income countries,
the more the resulting index would lean towards damages.
4. Conclusion
This paper combines COSMIC, a climate-projection
tool, and GIM, an impact-projection tool, to examine the
country-specific market impacts predicted by 14 GCMs
for 2100. Although there is considerable uncertainty about
the exact magnitude of country-specific impacts, there are
a number of insights from this research. First, the mod-
est climate-change scenarios expected by 2100 are likely to
have only a small effect on the world economy. The mar-
ket impacts predicted in this analysis do not exceed 0.1%
of global GDP and are likely to be smaller. Second, the
market impacts will vary from country to country across the
globe. High-latitude countries are expected to gain and low-
latitude countries are expected to be harmed by warming.
Third, although the overall effects of warming and carbon
fertilization on the globe in 2100 are near zero, the mar-
ginal effect of higher temperature is expected to be harmful.
Temperature changes beyond 2
C are expected to reduce
benefits and increase damages. Fourth, the GCMs pre-
dict greater warming near the poles and less warming near
the equator relative to a uniform climate change scenario.
These consistent deviations reduce damages (increase ben-
efits) relative to a uniform climate change and should be
taken into account. This research is intended to illustrate
the power of COSMIC and GIM as forecasting tools. The
research is also intended to reveal weaknesses or problems
with these forecasts. For example, the current use of coun-
trywide estimates of climate change is problematic for large
countries because climates vary sufficiently within national
borders that more localized estimates would be preferable.
Another weakness in these forecasts is the reliance on an-
nual temperature changes. Future models should attempt
to model seasonal changes. A third prominent weakness
involves the reliance on United States evidence to cali-
brate the responses to climate change. Clearly it would
be preferable to have estimates of regional responses to
climate change from around the world. Finally, in many
sectors, it would be attractive to get more detailed infor-
mation about each country. For example, there is no soil
R. Mendelsohn et al. / Comparing impacts across climate models 47
data in the current agriculture or forestry models, little in-
formation about space heating and cooling in the energy
model, and little data about runoff in the water models.
Prudent policy-makers should understand that the country-
specific estimates of impacts are consequently preliminary
and are likely to change as the models become more so-
phisticated.
Finally, we have measured only market effects from pre-
dicted climate changes. Preliminary research indicates that
climate change is also likely to impact the quality of life.
Effects on ecosystems, health, and aesthetics have not been
taken into account in this analysis. Impacts from changes
in extreme events or catastrophes should also be measured.
As research in these areas develops, the model can be
revised to include these more complete measures of im-
pacts.
Acknowledgements
This research was funded by the Electric Power Research
Institute and the US National Science Foundation (Grant
No ATM-9522681).
References
[1] C. Azar, Weight factors in cost-benefit analysis of climate change,
Env. and Res. Econ. 13 (1999) 249–268.
[2] G.J. Boer, N. McFarlane and M. Lazare, Greenhouse gas induced
climate change simulated with the Canadian Climate Centre second
generation general circulation model, J. Clim. 5 (1992) 1045–1077.
[3] S.J. Cohen, G.J. Boer, N. McFarlane, J.P. Blanchet, M. Lazare, N.E.
Sargent, F.G. Majaess, D.P. Phillips, M. Webb and T. Cutler, Ap-
plication of the Canadian Climate Center general circulation model
output for regional climate impact studies, Canadian Climate Centre,
Downsview, Ontario, Canada (1990).
[4] S. Fankhauser, Valuing Climate Change, The Economics of the
Greenhouse (Earthscan, London, 1995).
[5] S. Fankhauser, R. Tol and D. Pearce, The aggregation of climate
change damages: A welfare theoretic approach, Env. and Res. Econ.
10 (1997) 249–266.
[6] W.L. Gates, A. Henderson-Sellers, C. Boer, A. Folland, B. Kitoh, F.
McAvaney, N. Semazzi, A. Smith, Q. Weaver and C. Zeng, Climate
models evaluation, in: Climate Change 1995: The Science of
Climate Change, eds. J.T. Houghton et al. (Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge, 1996).
[7] J. Hansen, G. Russell, D. Rind, P. Stone, A. Lacis, S. Lebedeff,
R. Ruedy and L. Travis, Efficient three-dimensional global models
for climate studies: Models I and II, Mon. Wea. Rev. 111 (1983)
609–662.
[8] J. Hansen, A. Lacis, D. Rind, L. Russell, P. Stone, I. Fung, R. Ruedy
and J. Lerner, Climate sensitivity: Analysis of feedback mechanisms,
in: Climate Processes and Climate Sensitivity, Geophys. Monogr.
Vol. 29, eds. J. Hansen and T. Takahashi (American Geophysical
Union, Washington, DC, 1984) pp. 130–163.
[9] J. Hansen, I. Fung, A. Lacis, D. Rind, S. Lebedeff, R. Ruedy, L.
Russell and P. Stone, Global climate changes as forecast by Goddard
Institute for Space Studies three-dimensional model, J. Geophys.
Res. 93 (1988) 9341–9364.
[10] T.L. Hart, W. Bourke, B.J. McAvaney, B.W. Forgan and J.L.
McGregor, Atmospheric general circulation simulations with the
BMRC global spectral model: The impact of revised physical para-
meterizations, J. Clim. 3 (1990) 436–459.
[11] A. Henderson-Sellers, R.E. Dickinson, T.B. Durbidge, P.J. Kennedy,
K. McGuffie and A.J. Pitman, Tropical deforestation: Modelling
local to regional-scale climate change, J. Geophys. Res. 98 (1993)
7289–7315.
[12] C. Hope, J. Anderson and P. Wenman, Policy analysis of the green-
house effect: An application of the PAGE model, Energy Policy 21
(1993) 327–338.
[13] J.T. Houghton, L.G. Meira Filho, B.A. Callander, N. Harris, A. Kat-
tenberg and K. Maskell, eds., Climate Change 1995: The Science of
Climate Change (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1996).
[14] M. Hulme, S.C. Raper and T.M. Wigley, An integrated framework
to address climate change (ESCAPE) and further developments of
the global and regional climate modules (MAGICC), Energy Policy
23 (1995a) 347–355.
[15] M. Hulme, T. Jiang and T.M. Wigley, SCENGEN, a climate change
scenario generator, a user manual, Climatic Research Unit, Univer-
sity of East Anglia, Norwich, UK (1995b).
[16] A. Manne, R. Mendelsohn and R. Richels, MERGE: A model for
evaluating regional and global effects of GHG reduction policies,
Energy Policy 23 (1993) 17–34.
[17] N.A. McFarlane, G.J. Boer, J.P. Blanchet and M. Lazare, The Cana-
dian Climate Centre second generation general circulation model and
its equilibrium climate, J. Clim. 5 (1992) 1013–1044.
[18] R. Mendelsohn and M.E. Schlesinger, Climate-response functions,
Ambio 28 (1999) 362–366.
[19] R. Mendelsohn, W. Morrison, M.E. Schlesinger and N.G.
Andronova, Country-specific market impacts of climate change, Cli-
matic Change (1999), in press.
[20] R. Mendelsohn and J. Neumann, eds., The Economic Impact of Cli-
mate Change on the United States Economy (Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge, 1998).
[21] W.D. Nordhaus, To slow or not to slow, Econ. J. 5 (1991) 920–937.
[22] W.D. Nordhaus, Managing the Global Commons: The Economics of
Climate Change (The MIT Press, Cambridge, 1994).
[23] B.D. Santer, T.M. Wigley, M.E. Schlesinger and J.F. Mitchell, De-
veloping climate scenarios from equilibrium GCM results, Report
No. 47, Max-Planck-Institut f
¨
ur Meteorologie, Hamburg, Germany,
1990.
[24] M.E. Schlesinger and N. Andronova, Regional climate-change sce-
narios based on 2 × CO
2
and 4 × CO
2
equilibrium climate-changes
simulated by the UIUC atmospheric general circulation/mixed-layer
ocean model, Report to EPRI, Urbana, IL, 1994.
[25] M.E. Schlesinger and L.J. Williams, COSMIC Country Spe-
cific Model for Intertemporal Climate, Computer Software, Electric
Power Research Institute, Palo Alto, 1997.
[26] M.E. Schlesinger and Z.C. Zhao, Seasonal climate changes induced
by doubled CO
2
as simulated by the OSU atmospheric GCM/mixed-
layer ocean model, J. Clim. 2 (1989) 459–495.
[27] M.E. Schlesinger, N. Andronova, A. Ghanem, S. Malyshev, T.
Reichler, E. Rozanov, W. Wang and F. Yang, Geographical scenar-
ios of greenhouse gas and anthropogenic-sulfate aerosol induced cli-
mate changes, Climate Research Group, Department of Atmospheric
Sciences, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, Urbana, IL,
1997a.
[28] M.E. Schlesinger, N. Andronova, B. Entwistle, A. Ghanem, N.
Ramankutty, W. Wang and F. Yang, Modeling and simulation of
climate and climate change, in: Past and Present Variability of the
Solar-Terrestrial System: Measurement, Data Analysis and Theo-
retical Models. Proceedings of the International School of Physics
“Enrico Fermi” CXXXIII, eds. G. Castagnoli and A. Provenzale (IOS
Press, Amsterdam, 1997b).
[29] M.E. Schlesinger, N. Andronova, A. Ghanem, S. Malyshev, E.
Rozanov, W. Wang and F. Yang, Geographical scenarios of green-
house gas and anthropogenic-sulfate aerosol induced climate change,
Do We Understand Global Climate Change? (Norwegian Academy
of Technological Sciences, Oslo, 1998).
[30] M.E. Schlesinger, S. Malyshev, E.V. Rozanov, F. Yang and N.G.
Andronova, Geographical Distributions of Temperature Change for
48 R. Mendelsohn et al. / Comparing impacts across climate models
the SRES Scenarios of Greenhouse Gas and Sulfur Dioxide Emis-
sions. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 1999, submit-
ted.
[31] S.L. Thompson and D. Pollard, A global climate model (GENESIS)
with a land surface transfer scheme (LSX) Part 1. Present climate
simulation, J. Clim. 8 (1995) 732–761.
[32] R. Tol, The damage costs of climate change: Towards more com-
prehensive calculations, Env. and Res. Econ. 5 (1995) 353–374.
[33] W.C. Wang, M.P. Dudek and X. Liang, Inadequacy of effective CO
2
as a proxy to assess the greenhouse effect of other radiative gases,
Geophys. Res. Lett. 19 (1992) 1375–1378.
[34] W. Washington and G. Meehl, Greenhouse sensitivity experiments
with penetrative cumulus convection and tropical cirrus albedo ef-
fects, Clim. Dyn. 8 (1992) 211–233.
[35] R.T. Wetherald and S. Manabe, An investigation of cloud cover
change in response to thermal forcing, Climatic Change 8 (1986)
5–23.
[36] R.T. Wetherald and S. Manabe, Cloud feedback processes in a gen-
eral circulation model, J. Atmos. Sci. 45 (1988) 1397–1415.
[37] T.M. Wigley, R. Richels and J.A. Edmonds, Alternative emissions
pathways for stabilizing CO
2
concentrations, Nature 379 (1996) 240–
243.
[38] C.A. Wilson and J.F. Mitchell, A doubled CO
2
climate sensitivity
experiment with a global climate model including a simple ocean,
J. Geophys. Res. 92 (1987) 13,315–13,343.
[39] G.W. Yohe and M.E. Schlesinger, Sea level change: The expected
economic cost of protection or abandonment in the United States,
Climatic Change 38 (1998) 447–472.
... This growing concern has heightened research into the future socioeconomic impacts of climate change [27][28][29]. However, existing studies vary significantly in scope and rarely analyze these impacts simultaneously, complicating policy coordination [28][29][30][31][32]. ...
... Studies have shown a nonlinear concave effect of climate change on economic growth, indicating that while additional global warming may stimulate growth in cooler areas, it will reduce growth in hotter regions. Research by Mendelsohn, Morrison et al. [27]; Mendelsohn, Schlesinger, and Williams [44]; Stern [45]; and the IPCC [7] has demonstrated that the impact of climate change on economic output varies across world economies. Developing economies are at the highest risk, while developed economies are more likely to experience gains. ...
... At the global level, major studies quantifying the future impacts of climate change include Mendelsohn, Morrison et al. [27]; ...
Article
Full-text available
Extreme weather events, rising temperatures, and shifting rainfall patterns pose significant threats to developing countries with fragile social, economic, and political structures. While research has intensified on socioeconomic impacts of climate change, existing survey studies exhibit substantial scope variations and seldom concurrently analyze these impacts, hindering policy coordination. This study reviews literature on the broad spectrum of socioeconomic impacts of climate change to discern trends and underscore areas requiring additional attention. The survey unveils that, across various socioeconomic indicators, the most vulnerable groups bear a disproportionate burden of climate change, with long-term impacts forecasted to surpass medium-term effects. Adaptation and mitigation options are feasible but must be tailored to local contexts.
... Studies made using the assumption that "climate differences between locations are valid analogs for climate changes over time" (Tol 2024, p. 2) cannot be used to estimate the economic impact of global warming. From Table 1 in (Tol 2024), these papers are (Mendelsohn, Schlesinger, and Williams 2000;Maddison 2003;Rehdanz and Maddison 2005;Hope 2006;Horowitz and Lange 2014;Maddison and Rehdanz 2011;Ng and Zhao 2011;Desmet and Rossi-Hansberg 2015b;Kalkuhl and Wenz 2020;Conte et al. 2021;Cruz and Rossi-Hansberg 2021;Newell, Prest, and Sexton 2021), and subsequent papers (Kotz, Levermann, andWenz 2024b, 2022) considering precipitation but in which "tipping points … are not considered" (Kotz, Levermann, and Wenz 2024b, p. 556). ...
Conference Paper
Full-text available
This paper explains why estimates by economists of future economic damage from climate change have been sanguine, when compared to warnings by scientists, and why these economic projections, widely disseminated throughout the financial sector, are wrong. Economic analysis of climate change has been dominated by damage functions, which map expected levels of global warming to expected future levels of GWP (Gross World Product) and GDP. We critically review the methods used to calibrate these damage functions. In chronological order of development, these are: • The "enumerative approach", which assumes that global warming will primarily damage industries that are exposed to the weather, while having negligible impact on industries that take place in "carefully controlled environments" (Nordhaus 1991); • "Expert elicitations", which report the average outcomes of surveys of opinions of the impact of global warming on GDP (Nordhaus 1994a); • The "traditional Ricardian analysis" (D. Prakash et al. 2023, p. 12) or "statistical approach", which assumes that temperature and income data across space at a point in time can be used as a proxy for the impact of global warming on income over time (Mendelsohn, Nordhaus, and Shaw 1994); and; • The prevalent approach today, of using data on GDP and changes in temperature in the recent past to predict future GDP using expected temperature increases from global warming (Kalkuhl and Wenz 2020). All of these methods misunderstand what global warming and climate change mean, and all of them produce underestimates of the level of economic damages from global warming. We demonstrate how these flawed economic methods have dominated the advice of investment consultants to pension fund trustees, resulting in a significant underestimation of the financial impact of climate change. Correcting for this underestimation greatly magnifies the feasible severity of the impact of global warming on the economy and brings forward the onset of economic damages to the acknowledge assistance from Ole Peters and Emilie Soysal of the London Mathematical Laboratory on the topic of ergodicity. 2 present rather than the distant future. This increases the likelihood that a "Climate Minsky Moment" will occur in financial markets during the lives of beneficiaries alive today.
... Using the Ricardian model, they predict much smaller losses and gains than the reduced-form model, predicting a cumulative effect of a loss of 0.3% to 2060 GDP levels from 2.0°C warming. In a similar study, Mendelsohn, Schlesinger and Williams (2000) cumulative market impact costs do not exceed 0.1% of GDP in 2100 assuming 2.5°C rise of global temperature. In a very extreme scenario, Stern (2005) assuming global warming of between 2.4°C and 5.8° costs of extreme weather alone could reach 0.5 -1% of world GDP per annum by the middle of the century and an average loss of 5% of global GDP per annum over the next two centuries. ...
Article
Climate change is a global problem that challenges humanity. Global warming, which is expected to bring extreme weather events, exposes human health, ecological systems, and ultimately the economy to great risks. Although the economy affects climate change, climate change also affects the economy. The effects of climate change on the economy in the short term can be positive or negative, but in the long term there is a consensus that global GDP will on average experience a significant reduction depending on the intensity of global warming. In addition to the small direct impact through disruption of economic inputs, the indirect impact through the transmission mechanism of productivity and investments on GDP is complex.However, climate impacts are not expected to have an equal negative impact on all economies in the world, and the Republic of North Macedonia is in the group of counties less vulnerable to climate change. In this paper, we will apply the SECAP methodology for assessment of climate risks and vulnerability of the local economy of the City of Skopje. For this purpose, we will do an in-depth analysis of the local economy through the sectoral approach. The City of Skopje is an administrative city, and the sectors that are most vulnerable to climate change, such as agriculture, forestry, fishing and construction, are marginal. An increase in the intensity of the extreme weather is expected, especially the increase in temperatures in all seasons with increased precipitation and flash floods. Therefore, an increase in climatic risks is expected in the local economy in the City of Skopje in relation to the current vulnerability. Аlthough some sectors would be negatively affected by climatic change, the general assessment is that the economy of the City of Skopje will remain moderately vulnerable to future climate risks. It is because of the expectations for strong adaptability of local businesses and change of business models according to the new economic conditions.
... Moreover, statistical methods often treat cross-sectional variation, and some aspects of climate change, such as carbon dioxide fertilization and the direct effects of sea level rise, as not exhibiting significant spatial variation. Mendelsohn, Schlesinger, and Williams (2000), in contrast, predicted cumulative damage of not greater than 0.1 percent of GDP by 2100 at 2.5°C. They also forecast that high-latitude countries will gain while low-latitude countries will lose. ...
Technical Report
Full-text available
The Socioeconomic Impact of Climate Change in Developing Countries in the Next Decades: A Review provides a discussion of future trends as established in the literature on the interaction between socioeconomic indicators and projected future climate change scenarios. It enhances our understanding of future predicted patterns of climate change effects in the coming decades and the need for climate-resilient interventions. There is a significant body of literature on climate impacts on GDP per capita and crop yield in developing countries. However, impacts on farmland value, water resources, and energy security have received much less attention. Across sectors, countries, and regions, the most vulnerable groups were found to be disproportionately affected, and the impact is predicted to be larger in the long term than in the medium term. There are feasible adaptation and mitigation options, but these need to be developed and designed to reflect local peculiarities or contexts. Generally, the review report indicates the need for urgent actions to be undertaken, especially in the most vulnerable countries, if we are to stand a chance of averting or minimizing the menace of climate change in the future.
Article
Full-text available
Climate change is a pressing global issue with far-reaching consequences, extending beyond environmental concerns to profoundly impact the world economy. This paper provides a comprehensive analysis of the economic ramifications of climate change on a global scale. Drawing on a diverse range of economic indicators, case studies, and predictive models, we explore the multifaceted dimensions of climate-induced economic challenges. Our examination begins with an overview of the direct economic costs associated with climate change, including damages to infrastructure, changes in agricultural productivity, and increased frequency and severity of extreme weather events. We delve into the intricate interplay between climate change and various sectors, such as agriculture, energy, and insurance, elucidating how shifts in climate patterns disrupt established economic systems. Furthermore, we scrutinize the indirect economic consequences, focusing on the repercussions for human health, migration patterns, and geopolitical stability. The paper addresses the disproportionate impact of climate change on vulnerable populations, exacerbating existing social and economic inequalities both within and between nations. The study employs a forward-looking approach, incorporating climate projections to estimate future economic scenarios under different climate change mitigation and adaptation strategies. By assessing the potential costs and benefits of various interventions, we aim to guide policymakers, businesses, and communities toward informed decision-making that mitigates economic risks and maximizes opportunities in the face of climate change. In conclusion, this paper contributes to the ongoing discourse on the economic implications of climate change by offering a global perspective that integrates insights from diverse disciplines. As nations grapple with the urgent need for climate action, understanding the economic dimensions of this challenge becomes paramount for fostering sustainable development and resilience in an increasingly interconnected world.
Article
Full-text available
The article aims to provide evidence of the link between income inequality and climate change in both developed and low-income economies. This study uses a descriptive analysis method along with panel data analysis to assess the impact of climate changes on income inequality in 42 advanced economies and 68 developing countries between 1995 and 2020. The results of empirical research confirm that climate change is an important factor responsible for growing income inequality. The impact of a country’s vulnerability is positively associated with increasing income inequality in low-income economies. In turn, climate resilience has a statistically significant effect on income distribution in both groups, although the ability to mitigate climate change and adapt is considerably weaker in developing countries. This research raises our awareness of the links between the economy and climate change, including their implications for income inequality, and signals possible changes in the redistributive system to mitigate climate change and combat income inequality. The added value of this article is the results of research on the negative consequences of climate change on income inequality in over 100 countries. Particular attention was paid to the ethical issue of unequal responsibility for causing climate change between rich and poor countries.
Article
Full-text available
The Conference of the Parties (COPs) resulted in the development of the Kyoto Protocol and the Paris Agreement to reduce global warming by reducing greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions and deforestation by 2030. Over 25 years of COPs, coherent information is scanty on the status of the GHG emissions and deforestation within the period of the COP meetings especially after the ushering in of the Kyoto Protocol. With less than a decade to reach 2030, there is need for a review to gauge if the 2030 GHG reduction target is on course. This has a bearing on the attainment of the Sustainable Development Goals 1, 13, 14 and 15. A literature-based review was conducted on the status of GHG emissions (prior and during COP meetings) and deforestation covering the COP period. The review reveals that from 1976 to 1995 (prior to COP meetings), the annual GHG emissions were lower (32.44 ± 7 million kiloton) than during the decades (1999–2018) of the COP meetings (38.4 ± 9 million kiloton) (p = 0.0001). Forest loss and tree cover loss (deforestation) increased by an average of 3.4 and 20.6 million ha per year, respectively. The COPs have resulted in the establishment of the Green Climate Fund, the Adaptation Fund and revamping of the Global Environment Facility on funding and response to proposals, although faced with inconsistent provision of climate finance. As major emitters, developed countries (G20) hold the key to achieving the GHG reduction. Policies that either promote sustainable forestry or reduce the reliance on trees/forests should be implemented.
Article
Full-text available
This paper develops climate-response functions for sensitive market sectors in the United States' economy using two empirical methods. The experimental approach constructs a process-based impact model from the results of controlled experiments. Reduced-form equations can be estimated from the model responses to multiple climate scenarios. The cross-sectional approach estimates response functions directly from empirical evidence in the field. Both methods indicate that agriculture, forestry, and energy have a hill-shaped relationship to temperature. Precipitation, sea-level rise, and carbon dioxide are also important.
Article
Full-text available
The model used is a general circulation model of the atmosphere coupled with a mixed layer model of the oceans. The sensitivity of each version of the model is inferred from the equilibrium response of the model to a doubling of the atmospheric concentration of carbon dioxide. In response to the increase of atmospheric carbon dioxide, cloudiness increases around the tropopause and is reduced in the upper troposphere, thereby raising the height of the cloud layer in the upper troposphere. This implies a reduction of the temperature of the cloud top and, accordingly, of the upward terrestrial radiation from the top of the model atmosphere. On the other hand, the increase of low cloudiness in high latitudes raises the planetary albedo and thus decreases the CO2 induced warming of climate. However, the contribution of this negative feedback process is much smaller than the effect of the positive feedbakc process involving the change of high cloud. -from Authors
Article
Three distinct models from earlier work are combined to: (1) produce probabilistically weighted scenarios of greenhouse-gas-induced sea-level rise; (2) support estimates of the expected discounted value of the cost of sea-level rise to the developed coastline of the United States, and (3) develop reduced-form estimates of the functional relationship between those costs to anticipated sea-level rise, the cost of protection, and the anticipated rate of property-value appreciation. Four alternative representations of future sulfate emissions, each tied consistently to the forces that drive the initial trajectories of the greenhouse gases, are considered. Sea-level rise has a nonlinear effect on expected cost in all cases, but the estimated sensitivity falls short of being quadratic. The mean estimate for the expected discounted cost across the United States is approximately 2billion(witha32 billion (with a 3% real discount rate), but the range of uncertainty around that estimate is enormous; indeed, the 10th and 90th percentile estimates run from less than 0.2 billion up to more than $4.6 billion. In addition, the mean estimate is very sensitive to associated sulfate emissions; it is, specifically, diminished by nearly 25% when base-case sulfate emission trajectories are considered and by more than 55% when high-sulfate trajectories are allowed.
Article
Climate Change 1995--The Science of Climate Change is the most comprehensive assessment available of current scientific understanding of human influences on past, present and future climate. Prepared under the auspices of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC), each chapter is written by teams of lead authors and contributors recognized internationally as leading experts in their field. Climate Change 1995 is the first full sequel to the original 1990 IPCC scientific assessment, bringing us completely up to date on the full range of scientific aspects of climate change. This assessment forms the standard scientific reference for all those concerned with climate change and its consequences, including policy makers in governments and industry worldwide, and researchers and senior-level students in environmental science, meteorology, climatology, biology, ecology and atmospheric chemistry.
Article
Introduction Energy balance models Formulation Governing equations Calibration: simulation of the present-day seasonal cycle Simulation of 2 × CO2-induced temperature and sea-level - changes Radiative-convective models Formulation Governing equations Surface convection Convective adjustment Model specification and initialization Simulation of the present-day temperature Simulation of the temperature change induced by doubling the CO2 - concentration General circulation models Formulation of atmospheric GCMs Formulation of ocean/sea-ice models Model validation: simulation of the present climate Simulation of 2 × CO2-induced climate change
Article
The sensitivity of a global climate model to increased atmospheric CO2 concentrations is presented, assessed, and compared with earlier studies. The ocean is represented by a 50-m slab in which the heat convergence due to oceanic dynamics is prescribed, producing an accurate simulation of sea surface temperatures, sea-ice extents, and associated features in the control simulation. Changes in surface temperature are qualitatively similar to those found in earlier studies using models with similar or lower horizontal resolution, although the global warming is slightly larger. The simulated changes in hydrology agree broadly with those in studies made with higher horizontal resolution and prescribed changes in sea surface temperatures and include a drying over the northern mid-latitude continents. Many of the discrepancies in the responses of different models can be traced to differences in the simulations of present-day climate. The choice of convective parametrization appears to influence the senstivity of the simulated response in the tropics.
Article
The present-day climatology of a global climate model (GENESIS Version 1.02) is described. The model includes a land-surface transfer component (LSX) that accounts for the physical effects of vegetation. The atmospheric general circulation model is derived from the NCAR CCM1 and modified to include semi-Lagrangian transport of water vapor, subgrid plume convection, PBL mixing, a more complex cloud scheme, and a diurnal cycle. The surface models consist of LSX; multilayer models of soil, snow, and sea ice; sea ice dynamics; and a slab mixed layer ocean. Brief descriptions of the current model components are included in an appendix. GENESIS is an ongoing project to develop an earth system model prototype for global change research. The Version 1.02 climate model has already proved useful in paleoclimate studies.Results of present-day simulations are described using an atmospheric spectral resolution of RIS (4.5° lat×7.5° long) and a surface-model resolution of 2°×2°. In general the quality of the simulations is comparable to that of previous coarse-grid models with predicted sea-surface temperatures. Most of the errors are attributed to coarse atmospheric resolution, inaccurate cloud parameterization, large ocean roughness length, and lack of ocean dynamics.The results are compared with those using a simplified bucket-soil model and crude parameterizations of surface albedo and roughness. Although quite similar results are obtained on global scales, significant regional differences including surface warming and drying occur in some regions of Amazonia and northern midlatitude continental interiors.
Article
The authors report results from a model study using the National Center for Atmospheric Research Community Climate Model (Version 1) general circulation model to assess the impact of regional scale deforestation on climate change. In the model a large parcel in the Amazon basin is changed from tropical rain forest to scrub grassland. Impacts can include adding CO[sub 2] to the atmosphere by biomass burning, increasing surface albedo, changing precipitation and evaporation rates, impacting soil moisture, and general weather patterns. They compare their model results with earlier work which has looked at this same problem.