Content uploaded by Peter Nigel Smith
Author content
All content in this area was uploaded by Peter Nigel Smith on Jan 16, 2014
Content may be subject to copyright.
Discussion of The Fisher Effect Puzzle: A Case of Non-Linear Relationship
Peter N Smith (University of York)
1. Assessing the Fisher equation
Analysis of the Fisher equation or, equivalently, of the determination of the real interest rate
has been the subject of many studies over the years. It provides a significant challenge because
the two key variables to be modelled both appear in expectation and so the impact of how
expectations are modelled has to be allowed for along with the other aspects of the problem.
The Fisher equation is usually understood to connect the ex-ante real interest rate e
t
r to ex-ante
(or expected) inflation e
t
π
and the observed nominal interest rate it(which many authors regard
as fixed in advance of the determination of inflation), so ee
ttt
ri
π
=
−. The difference between
the ex-ante and ex-post real interest rate t
r is the (assumed to be) random inflation
expectational error:
()
ee e
tt t t t tt t
rr r i
π
πεπ
=+ − =+=− (1)
where the expectational error is e
ttt
πε
π
=−. The Fisher equation is therefore an accounting
identity which defines the ex-post real interest rate. The approach of Hall et al is to focus on
the relationship between the nominal interest rate and ex-post inflation i a b u
ttt
π
=+ + where
the hypothesis of interest is b=1 and the real interest rate is a constant a. As the authors say,
analysis of this particular equation, either through cointegration analysis or otherwise has often
returned estimates of b substantially (and often significantly) below one. It is impressive that
the method of estimation employed in this paper returns a (time varying average) value of b
close to one. There is, however, a serious limitation to the approach that the authors adopt in
that they assume that the real interest rate is constant, so:
()
e
tt t t t t t
ri ab uaw
πππ
=− =+ − + =+ (2)
As is demonstrated below, it is unlikely in most modelling situations that this will be true. Put
differently, the error term t
u is likely to be predictable. An alternative approach is to test for
cointegration between t
i and t
π
based on the finding that they are integrated I(1), non-
stationary, variables. This approach has the appeal that it allows the equilibrium (or long-run)
real interest rate to be time varying and stationary and which could be a function of long-run
stationary features of the macro economy such as technology growth.
Having said this, Hall et al use a result in Swamy at al (2008) which shows that their
estimation method is robust to mispecification of various types. Their estimate of b is therefore
reliable and it is interesting that they obtain estimates of b which are close to unity on average
over time. The time-varying nature of the estimates of a and b must depend in part on the
elements of the determination of the real interest rate which have been omitted. It would have
been interesting to see the impact of introducing some of these variables on the estimates of a
and b. The authors offer the possibility of asymmetry in the behaviour of inflation in the
parameters after 1983 and more could be learnt about this by further structural analysis.
2. Evaluating the persistence and stationarity of the elements of the real interest rate
The time-series properties of inflation and the nominal and real interest rates have occupied
numbers of researchers. Representative is the work of Rose (1988) who found that the nominal
interest rate and prices appear to both be I(1) implying that inflation is stationary whilst the
nominal interest rate is non-stationary. He then goes on to show how this prime facia evidence
of non-stationarity in the ex-ante real interest rate is inconsistent with the implications of the
consumption-based capital asset pricing model (CCAPM) given the stationarity of
consumption growth and the real returns of a number of other financial assets. Subsequently,
evidence has been presented that price inflation maybe be non-stationary (see Ball and
Cecchetti (1990), for example). This, however, has not resolved the problems because further
analysis, supported by the results in Table 1 of Hall et al, show no evidence in favour of
cointegration between inflation and the nominal interest rate and therefore stationarity of the
ex- ante real interest rate.
Further evidence, mirroring developments in the modelling of persistence in time series
processes, has supported the argument that inflation and the nominal interest rate are not best
described as integrated I(1) or stationary I(0) processes but rather as persistent fractionally
integrated I(d) processes where 0<d<1. Whether they are fractionally stationary or not depends
on estimates of the parameter d. Sun and Phillips (2004) initiated much of this work and found
estimates of d≈0.9 for t
i, t
π
and t
r for a sample of quarterly data from 1934-1999 implying
fractional non-stationarity for all three variables. Their conclusion then followed that the real
interest rate or Fisher equation is not a cointegrating long-run relationship. This analysis,
however, does not take into account the potential structural breaks and non-linearity in the
behaviour of the variables concerned. Recent research suggests that, having accounted for one
or more of these factors, the evidence might be that the three variables concerned are, in fact,
fractionally stationary. That would mean that they are stationary but persistent which would
lead to behaviour of the real interest rate which is more consistent with the implications of
economic theory. Charfeddine and Guegan (2007), for example, find breaks in inflation in the
US in April 1967, January 1973 and July 1981 using Bai and Perron (1998) sequential testing.
Their estimates of d for untransformed inflation are between 0.408 (standard error = 0.05) and
0.89 (0.10). When they remove the structural breaks in inflation from the series and re-estimate
d they obtain estimates between 0.046 (0.039) and 0.228 (0.074) which are clearly significantly
smaller than 0.5 and border on failing to reject I(0) stationarity against a more persistent
alternative. Baillie and Morana (2009) allow for non-linearity in estimation of d. They estimate
an adaptive ARFIMA model which allows the constant term to be time varying (they choose a
flexible fourier form which can approximate a range of non-linear functions). Their results are
that estimation of d produces an estimate of between 0.42 (0.042) and 0.69 (0.067) for
unadjusted US CPI inflation from January 1948 to October 2006. The estimate of d for a
generalisation of the ARFIMA model which allows for non-linearity is 0.346 (0.04). Therefore
allowing for non-linearity and structural breaks reduces the estimated persistence of the
inflation rate significantly. If similar results can be found for the nominal interest rate series
there would then be the prospect of the three series t
i, t
π
and t
r being regarded as mildly
persistent stationary series. Whilst further analysis is required, similar results for consumption
growth and other asset returns would re-establish the consistency of the time-series behaviour
of key variables and the equilibrium properties of standard macroeconomic models such as the
CCAPM.
3. The macroeconomic determinants of the real interest rate
In parallel to the investigation of the time series properties of the real interest rate there has
been development in analysis of the macroeconomic equilibrium determinants. In a standard
monetary model (eg Gali (2008), Ch 2) the ex-ante real interest rate is given by:
{
}
1
ra
tyatt
E
ρσψ
+
=+ ∆ (3)
where ρ=-lnβ the discount rate of utility, σ the coefficient of relative risk aversion (CRRA),
ya
ψ
is the reduced-form parameter relating equilibrium output to technology and 1
at+
∆ is the
technology shock. In this equation the real interest rate is determined by the real side of the
economy in equilibrium and is stationary for a stationary growth rate in technology. In a
stochastic model, Canzoneri and Dellas (1998) show that monetary factors can also play a role
in the equilibrium real interest rate. They show that when decomposed into a risk-free rate and
a risk premium, the determination of the ex-ante real interest rate can be affected by central
bank operating procedures such as the choice between interest rate, money and nominal
income targeting. In particular, they show that real interest rates should be lower under money
than interest rate targetting for a given set of shocks.
What have we learned about the determination and behaviour of the real interest rate? Many
studies have contributed to finding that the real interest rate is a function of a number of,
probably stationary, variables including technology growth. In addition, changes in monetary
policy regimes are likely to be important source of variation in the real interest rate. These
effects might appear as structural change and parameter variation in estimates of the Fisher
equation. Hall et al show us that, armed with an estimation method which is robust to these
developments, we can obtain an estimate of the slope of the Fisher equation which is much
closer to our expectations than when we employ more limited methods.
4. References
Bai, J. and P. Perron (1998), "Estimating and testing linear models with multiple structural
changes", Econometrica, 66, pp 47-78.
Baillie, R.T and C. Morana (2009), "Investigating inflation dynamics and structural change
with an adaptive ARFIMA approach", mimeo Queen Mary University London.
Ball, L. and S.G. Cecchetti (1990), "Inflation and uncertainty at short and long horizons",
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, pp 215-254.
Canzoneri, M.B. and H. Dellas (1998), "Real interest rates and central bank operating
procedures", Journal of Monetary Economics, 42, pp 471-494.
Charfeddine, L. and D. Guegan (2007), "Which is the best model for the US inflation rate: A
structural changes models or a long memory process?", CES Working Paper No. 2007.61,
Universite Paris.
Gali, J.(2008), Monetary Policy, Inflation and the Business Cycle: An Introduction to the New
Keynesian Framework, Princeton University Press, Princeton NJ.
Rose, A. (1988), "Is the real interest rate stable", Journal of Finance, 43, pp 1095-1112.
Sun, Y. and P.C.B. Phillips (2004), "Understanding the Fisher equation", Journal of Applied
Econometrics, 19, pp 869-886.
Swamy, P.A.V.B., Tavlas, G., Hall, S.G. and G. Hondroyannis (2008), "Estimation of
parameters in the presence of model mispecification and measurement error", mimeo,
University of Leicester.