ArticlePDF Available

A future for small business? Prospective scenarios for the development of the economy based on current policy thinking and counterfactual reasoning

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

Scenarios represent future possibilities or descriptions of ‘what might be’. This paper generates a series of possible futures based on an identified policy priority, namely the encouragement of increased levels of small business activity. Counterfactual thinking is used to challenge this policy objective and to formulate alternative possibilities. Specific consideration is made of the nature of the future economy in terms of business linkages and market integration, as are the likely strategic responses of businesses and government. Eight scenarios are developed based on these drivers of change in economic structure and business activity. Data on the world economy are then applied to 19 developed and developing economies to test the scenarios. How these ‘externally generated’ scenarios can be applied to and made relevant to businesses, and in particular smaller enterprises, is examined, as are the broader implications for the future nature and structure of economic activity.
Content may be subject to copyright.
A future for small business? Prospective scenarios
for the development of the economy based on current
policy thinking and counterfactual reasoning
Andrew Atherton
Enterprise Research and Development Unit, Lincoln Business School, University of Lincoln,
Brayford Pool, Lincoln LN6 7TS, UK
Available online 19 March 2005
Abstract
Scenarios represent future possibilities or descriptions of ‘what might be’. This paper generates a
series of possible futures based on an identified policy priority, namely the encouragement of
increased levels of small business activity. Counterfactual thinking is used to challenge this policy
objective and to formulate alternative possibilities. Specific consideration is made of the nature of
the future economy in terms of business linkages and market integration, as are the likely strategic
responses of businesses and government. Eight scenarios are developed based on these drivers of
change in economic structure and business activity. Data on the world economy are then applied to
19 developed and developing economies to test the scenarios. How these ‘externally generated’
scenarios can be applied to and made relevant to businesses, and in particular smaller enterprises, is
examined, as are the broader implications for the future nature and structure of economic activity.
q2005 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
1. Why consider small business futures?
Scenarios provide an established and validated means of considering the future and its
distinctive possibilities. Proponents of scenarios development indicate that it is ‘an
invaluable tool’ and that it provides ‘a capacity to manage the unknown challenges of the
future’[60]. They argue that scenario building is ‘an essential element for working on, and
creating, alternative futures’ and ‘an important part of socio-economic analysis’[63]. Such
approaches to futures thinking are well established in practitioner and policy communities
[61] and have been used with reference to a broad range of issues and phenomena,
0016-3287/$ - see front matter q2005 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.futures.2005.01.002
Futures 37 (2005) 777–794
www.elsevier.com/locate/futures
E-mail address: aatherton@lincoln.ac.uk.
including: the global economy [64]; community development [4]; urban planning [3];
technology forecasting [6]; the development of information and communication
technology [69] economic sectors [49,14]; and geopolitical issues [28]. The potential
value of futures thinking has been recognised by policy-makers and can be seen in aspects
of policy-making [18]. There appears, therefore, to be public as well as private sector
familiarity and engagement with future scenarios development as a tool for policy
formulation and consideration. Indeed, it has been noted that ‘scenario planning is
enjoying a boom period’ [62].
Smaller businesses, i.e. enterprises with fewer than 251 employees, account for almost
all businesses in developed and mature economies and generate the majority of private
sector employment and output [43]. In most newly industrialized and developing
countries, smaller enterprises account for a majority of enterprises and for a significant
share of private sector economic activity [70] or are recognised as central to the future
development of the economy [37]. Successive studies, starting from the work of Birch [5],
have attributed the majority of new jobs created in many developed economies to small
businesses and new ventures [7,25,29,31,35,53,13]. Smaller enterprises have also been
associated with high levels of economic adaptability and flexibility, and are seen as
creating economic opportunity through innovation [43].
In spite of the importance ascribed to small businesses by governments and analysts
[21], there has been little consideration of their future development and the potential
implications for policy. Indeed, in a review of a recent special edition on small business
futures, Fuller [24] notes that what is lacking in the recent literature is the identification
and consideration of future scenarios focused on small businesses and their development.
The extent to which scenarios thinking has been applied to small businesses and their
future development is limited (the work of Fuller is an exception [24,58,23]) and there are
few examples of the application of futures thinking to the development of small businesses
within a policy framework [54].
2. Policy aspirations and counterfactual thinking as a means of developing scenarios
Many established scenarios development methods use groups, typically of peers or
experts, to identify future possibilities and their drivers and to generate and assess scenarios
[60,63,61,4,3,30]. Such methodologies bring together and synthesise multiple views and
perspectives based on the personal, and hence subjective, opinions and judgements of those
involved [42]. Scenario planning based on active consultation [50], brainstorming [30] and
engagement of actors [60,63], therefore, embraces multiple ethical, philosophical and
conceptual stances and values. Such approaches raise a hermeneutic challenge, if we define
hermeneutics as the understanding of understanding (as Geertz [26] did so), in that they
incorporate multiple subjectivities based on disparate and potentially non-commensurable
belief and value systems. As Tilley and Fuller [58] have noted: “.there is little by way of
explicit futures epistemology. Where rigorous principles are identifiable in the literature,
they represent a wide range of epistemological positions.”
Scenarios, in consequence, can be seen as shared constructs that emerge from a synthesis
of different positions and stances; in large part reflecting their emergence and use as a means
A. Atherton / Futures 37 (2005) 777–794778
of generating shared views about possible futures and hence as a collective or organisational
learning dynamic [64]. They operate, in other words, as ‘sensemaking’ strategies [66],
rather than as factual or deterministic accounts of actual futures. The non-predictable,
sensemaking nature of scenarios appears to be accepted in broad terms, although Slaughter
[50]
14
notes: “There are basically two views about [prediction] in the field. One, held most
strongly by Bell (1997), is that all forward-looking references involve prediction in some
form. I take a different view, which I believe is held by a majority, that prediction in social
systems is neither possible nor desirable.” Indeed, Slaughter noted that scenario
development embraces the ‘irreducible uncertainty’ of the future.
2.1. The pursuit of policy goals as a means of selecting a preferred future scenario
From a policy-making perspective, however, the future, in terms of aspirations and
preferences for particular outcomes, is not irreducible. Government decision can be seen
as the pursuit of a desired future [38], and hence the prioritisation of a specific scenario as
the basis for public allocation of resource and intervention in the economy and society.
From this perspective, the focus shifts from questions asking what the future might look
like as a planning or sensemaking exercise to specific considerations of how particular
priorities and interventions will ‘play out’. It contextualises thinking about the future in
stated policy objectives and intentions and in doing so points to likely, possible and
preferred outcomes. This paper starts from the premise that desired policy goals and
outcomes offer an opportunity to generate possible future scenarios that consider
and hence evaluate specific government concerns and strategies. This approach to
scenarios formation recognises the possibility that there is a preferred future, at least for
part of the policy-making and implementation community. It is this preferred future, in
terms of the implications of current policy statements and plans, that provides an initial
consideration of future possibilities for the economy and businesses.
2.2. Counterfactual thinking as a means of considering alternative futures
Counterfactual thinking has been developed to gain insight into mental models and
cognitive processes, including: mental norms [47]; alternative schematic representations
[34]; and strategies for formulating and considering alternative scenarios [41]. Analyses of
counterfactuals within the cognition literature have focused especially on hindsight, or
post hoc, rationalisations of previous decisions and actions [40,48]. They have been used,
in other words, to consider ‘what might have been’ [10].
Applications of counterfactual thinking can be seen in many aspects of economic,
political and social analysis, including: project assessment and consideration [15,39,65];
evaluations of economic reform and restructuring [11,17]; macro-economic modelling
[16,44]. The technique has been used in several academic disciplines, in particular history
[55,8]. Counterfactual approaches have generated distinctly different scenarios to test
project impact and outcomes and to consider alternative approaches to planning [2].
Counterfactual reasoning has also been used in considerations of the future [56,45].
Counterfactual thinking is used in this paper to establish a series of polarised future
possibilities, as distinctive and markedly different ‘hypothetical states of affairs’.
A. Atherton / Futures 37 (2005) 777–794 779
The technique is deployed, as such, to generate a collection of distinctive future scenarios
that are binary in nature, in that each possible future is linked with a diametrically opposed
possibility. A focus on polarisation and the generation of opposite, and hence opposing,
future possibilities represents one way in which counterfactual thinking can be used. The
approach has been used extensively in many fields (as noted above) to identify alternative
paths and outcomes that are not necessarily polarised, but that represent other possibilities.
Counterfactual thinking seeks out alternative paths and outcomes. The application of
counterfactuals to futures thinking, therefore, can generate multiple alternatives, many of
which may be subtle and nuanced and only some of which are diametrically opposed.
The public policy context for the generation of small business scenarios suggests a
benefit of futures thinking is to construct and imagine the most disparate and different
possible outcomes. By identifying extremely variant futures, via polarisation, decisions by
policy-makers on where and how to intervene can account for the possibility, or risk, that
the outcomes from government action and expenditure may be antithetical to the desired
outcomes. The use of polarised approaches to counterfactual thinking is particularly
evident in economic analysis of public intervention, via techniques such as cost-benefit
analysis and game theory.
This approach to counterfactual thinking as polarisation recognises that policy
development and implementation is unpredictable in impact and result [46] and, as such,
future economic structures and dynamics are presently unknown and uncertain. The broad
definition of the polarised approach to counterfactual thinking adopted in this paper
(adapted from [9]) is that it is: ‘a statement concerned with an hypothetical future state of
affairs that runs counter to established views and objectives.’
3. Two future possibilities for the UK business population as a starting point
The future development of the economy and of the dynamics of business activity can be
considered from multiple perspectives and using different approaches. In this section of
the paper, a particular focus is placed on the structure of a future economy and in particular
on the relative importance of small and large businesses. Such a distinction between small
and large is used to reflect the distinctive natures of different sizes of businesses [67],in
terms of management and operation as well as in terms of the implications for the
underpinning nature of competition and economic behaviour that is likely to emerge. As
has been noted, smaller business are associated with high degrees of adaptability and
responsiveness, which in turn points to a different basis for business activity to an
economy in which large companies dominate and compete on the basis of economies of
scale (c.f. [27] for considerations of the limitations of securing economies of scale by
increasing market share).
3.1. The emergence of a ‘small business economy’
Many governments, in developed and developing nations, view the growth and
development of small businesses as integral to economic development and prosperity. In
the UK, for example, the Small Business Service has as its objective that the UK becomes
A. Atherton / Futures 37 (2005) 777–794780
the ‘best place in the world to start and run a business’ [52] by increasing the number and
quality of business starts, as well as encouraging greater rates of survival amongst new
ventures and growth by established small and medium enterprises. In similar terms, the EU
Green Paper on Entrepreneurship proposes that Europe should become ‘more
entrepreneurial’ by encouraging more people to start businesses and by enabling and
supporting the growth of existing smaller enterprises. Similar policy statements supporting
the expansion of the small business sector can be seen in many other countries
(e.g. Australia [33]; China [51], and Japan [68].
Integral to government promotion of smaller businesses and laws and policies to
promote business start-up and SME growth and expansion is a desire to increase the
significance of these enterprises within an economy. A likely outcome from successful
achievement of these policy goals will be an absolute increase in the number and economic
importance of smaller businesses. A growth in the importance and relative share of
economic activity by small businesses, therefore, is a starting point for future scenarios of
economic development. It represents a preferred future for government agencies and other
entities that support small businesses (a broad outline of such a ‘small business economy’
is included in Table 1).
3.2. The counter-factual future scenario: emergence of a ‘large business economy’
The counter-factual state to a future economy dominated by small businesses is a
growth in the importance and significance of large companies. Larger businesses account
for the majority of private sector employment and turnover in this scenario, and as a result
become the basis for economic activity and growth. As large companies increase their
share of economic activity, a probable outcome will be that competition is based
increasingly on securing advantages from size, in particular gaining and exploiting
economies of scale. A likely result will be that smaller businesses will be less able to
compete and will be pushed out of markets and activities by larger companies seeking
greater influence and control over customers and suppliers. The number of SMEs will
decline, and those that remain will become dependent upon larger businesses or will
become isolated within localised economies and marginalised in smaller and less
attractive markets that are not of interest to large companies. These changes may lead to
new forms of economic flexibility, for example in contractual obligations and supplier
prices, as has been seen to some extent in the case of the zaibatsu in Japan [59]. Producer
power may concentrate in the hands of a few, leading to oligopolistic conditions and near-
monopoly market dynamics.
4. Integrated or isolated? Connectivity as a critical driver of business futures
Integration within a local economy and with other economies has been identified as a
critical aspect of the development and emergence of ‘well founded’ regions and local
economies and business groupings [12,20]. Related to this, assessments and analyses of
globalisation have focused on the integration of markets, and on the implications of
increased economic ‘connectivity’ for business strategy. Part of this debate has focused on
A. Atherton / Futures 37 (2005) 777–794 781
whether the geography of competition and market concentration is genuinely international
or whether levels of cross-border market integration vary [36]. Such considerations
suggest a ‘mixed’ model of market integration, in which global and local businesses
co-exist and compete. Different levels of international engagement amongst businesses
also indicate a need to look in more detail at interactions where the ‘localization of
competitive advantage’ is a result of the ‘globalization of competition’ [20]. The patterns
and dynamics of market integration, therefore, promise to be complex, variable and
difficult to predict in generalised terms.
4.1. The emergence of a highly connected future economy
The thesis that there will be high levels of future economic integration rests on the
growth and expansion of extensive linkages and inter-dependencies within markets as well
as between industries, sectors and business groupings. In an integrated economy,
businesses will be involved in multiple networks, of differing geographical scope from
Table 1
Outline comparison of small business and large business futures
Small business economy Large business economy
Summary data 4Cmillion small businesses !3.8 million small businesses
Accounting for 2/3 or more of private
sector employment
Large companies account for 2%C
of all businesses
Generating more than 60% of private
sector GDP
Accounting for 2/3 of private
employment
And O60% of GDP
Nature of the small
business sector
Highly diversified
Local economic actors and global
players
Dominating most aspects of
economic activity
Dependence upon larger OEMs and
supply chains
Small businesses more focused on
local economies
Nature of the economy
overall
Less concentration of ‘seller power’
Restructuring away from industries
with significant economies of scale
Greater importance of a small
number of large businesses
Increased ‘seller power’
Competition between ‘giants’ to win
market share
Sources of competitive
advantage
Highly adaptable and flexible
High levels of competition and
innovation
Reduced dominance of markets by
a small number of businesses
Economies of scale
Ability to access resources
Greater geographical scope
Emergence of ‘giants’
Issues and developmental
challenges
Greater ‘churn’, due to more start-ups
and greater competition
Risks of reduced competition leading
to lower levels of innovation
Need for new forms of resource
provision to fund and enable growth
Increased focus on renewal and
entrepreneurship in large companies
Interactions between businesses,
government and society fragmented
Larger companies seeking out
protection and special privileges
from government
A. Atherton / Futures 37 (2005) 777–794782
local through to international and global. Interactions between large companies and
smaller businesses will be commonplace, incorporating a broad range of different
relationships and transactions.
One probable result from the emergence of an integrated economy will be wider
sensitivity to economic events and fluctuations that are distributed through, and hence
amplified by, the extensive networks and linkages that enable and underpin integration and
connectivity. Indeed, the internationalisation of transactions and interactions that will
occur within an integrated economy is likely to lead to rapid ‘knock-on’ effects from
events and occurrences in particular locations or situations. The overall result, therefore, is
likely to be cyclical fluctuations in economic and business prosperity and wealth, with
highly networked and interactive businesses being sensitive to external events.
4.2. Business isolation and dis-connection as an alternative condition
The counterfactual outcome to an integrated economy is one that will be more isolated
and less connected. This thesis will lead to a future world economy in which there are
many local economies and markets, with little linkage between each other and localised
rather than cross-border business-to-business networks. Such an atomisation of economic
exchange and interaction is characterised as negative and has been identified as a
constraint on economic growth in less wealthy nations: ‘Developed markets, more global,
inclusive, and integrated, offer more opportunity and choice. Underdeveloped markets,
more likely in poor countries, are more likely to be local and segmented’ [70].
The fragmented economy scenario need not be a negative future possibility for all
businesses, however. Within a developed economy and in particular in prosperous regions
and localities, strong local networks combined with local economic opportunities may
provide an endogenous growth framework that can sustain the development of businesses.
Indeed, such a fragmented economy may offer high levels of protection against entry into
such a market by non-local competitors. A prerequisite for this positive interpretation of a
future economy that is less connected is that the local economic condition and endowment
is healthy and wealth resides within the local economy. This type of fragmented economy,
therefore, may only be relevant in certain localities and, in itself, implies that the exclusion
of less developed and less prosperous nations, regions and localities will continue and may
increase. This derivation of a fragmented, less connected, economic future can be
conceived of as ‘gated’ prosperous local economies dispersed amongst poorer, subsistence
economies.
4.3. ‘Defensive’ and ‘embracing’ approaches to connectivity: incorporating business
and government policy stances and strategies into the framework
Responses by government as well as businesses to different levels of connectivity may
vary, depending upon the perceived benefits and advantages to enterprises. Alternative
futures may lead to conclusions that connectivity is either a positive or negative condition
for business activity. Positive conceptions will lead business decision-makers and policy-
makers to embrace future conditions and levels of connectivity. Alternatively, negative
perceptions of particular forms of connectivity will result in more defensive responses to
A. Atherton / Futures 37 (2005) 777–794 783
future conditions. A third, and key factor, therefore, in developing future scenarios of the
economy—and applying these constructs to small businesses—is to consider the responses
by the key economic and political actors and influencers to levels of integration and dis-
connection. In particular, the scenarios developed in this paper will examine the extent to
which responses to possible futures are either ‘embracing’, i.e. engaging positively, or
‘defensive’, i.e. seeing a particular scenario as a threat or negative condition.
5. A typology of alternative futures for small business
The framework constructed so far in this paper has identified three key drivers of future
economic and business activity that are of particular relevance: (I) the share of economic
activity between large and small enterprises; (II) the extent or lack of connectivity in the
economy, both nationally and globally; (III) whether responses to connectivity by
economic and political actors will be embracing or defensive. Combining these three
drivers of future economic structure and business activity generates eight distinctive
permutations or ‘possible futures’ (Fig. 1 below). Each scenario is based on the following
conditions [19]:
1. The future distribution of economic activity between large and small businesses: (i) a
‘small business’ economy in which economies of scale in production and competition
are neutralised or counteracted by the adaptability of smaller businesses; (ii) a ‘large
business’ economy in which larger companies dominate markets and secure greater
market share through economies of scale, marketing, and political linkages.
2. The extent of economic connectivity and integration, within and across national
economies: (i) high levels of economic integration and business connectivity at all
Fig. 1. Map of possible future scenarios for business in the UK.
A. Atherton / Futures 37 (2005) 777–794784
geographical scales; (ii) economic fragmentation and isolation combined with a lack of
connectivity between businesses.
3. The response, by government and business, to economic integration or dis-connection,
in terms of: (i) embracing approaches, i.e. positive engagement with emergent patterns
of connectivity; (ii) defensive reaction to future forms of connectivity.
The eight scenarios represent alternative, and in most cases, significantly different
possible economic futures. Each, however, does not represent a desirable, or undesirable,
future per se. Instead, the scenarios can be considered possible outcomes or conditions that
will have both positive and negative effects, implications and outcomes. They represent a
range of possible contexts and environments within which businesses may find
themselves. Each scenario is summarised below:
5.1. Global flexible specialisation
A future economy dominated by small businesses, and hence by small business ‘ways
of doing business’, where markets are connected and small businesses trade without regard
to administrative, political or market boundaries. This connected and highly networked
future is embraced by businesses, leading to the identification and seeking out of
competitive advantage based on comparative advantage and hence to high levels of firm
specialisation within dense and multiple networks. Such a scenario is likely to be based on
the emergence of clusters of international and global competitiveness that deploy local and
embedded relations and trust to gain advantage. It will also result in high levels of product
and service differentiation, and hence high levels of consumer choice and purchasing
power (due to ‘seller power’ being dispersed amongst many businesses, mainly small, in
many locations). Global flexible specialisation is also likely to lead to high levels of
investment, by businesses and probably also by governments and multi-lateral institutions,
in communications and mobility infrastructure in order to reduce transaction costs and so
take advantage of the internationalised nature of business interaction and the diversity of
choice, location and activity.
5.2. Local ‘boosterism’
A more defensive approach to a future small business economy where markets are
highly integrated will result in low or minimal levels of business propensity to collaborate
This future is predicated on economic conditions within which levels of competition are
high and ‘cut-throat’ as businesses adopt defensive responses to integration, leading to
vulnerability for individual firms and confrontational business strategies. Price wars,
customer incentives and tie-ins and supplier ‘lock-in’ will be likely dominant features
within this scenario. Politicians, particularly in elected systems, are likely to respond to
high levels of competitive turbulence and business uncertainty by seeking to support and
protect businesses, both in order to ensure that employment levels are maintained within
local constituencies and to avoid the adverse economic impacts of lower profitability
(as a result of price cuts) and higher levels of firm closure (due to more confrontational
business competition).
A. Atherton / Futures 37 (2005) 777–794 785
5.3. Diverse small economies
Should the future see the emergence of an economy within which small businesses
dominate, but markets are less connected and business interactions more localised than
globalised, then a likely outcome will be the emergence of many local economies.
Embracing this future could lead to local attempts, by businesses and government, to
encourage greater levels of economic activity within each economic unit. Under such
circumstances, a local regime of taxation re-distribution may emerge that penalises
consumers and privileges businesses. Re-distributive mechanisms are likely to be
egalitarian, in that preference for one or some businesses over others risks creating unfair
advantage within the local economy. The constraints of operating within localised and
fixed economic areas and environments may lead to efforts to encourage co-operation and
interventions to punish or minimise high levels of competition, particularly those seeking
to gain short-term or non-sustainable competitive advantage over other businesses. This
scenario may also lead to greater awareness of the need for sustainability of resources.
5.4. ‘Niche ecology’ economy
In a future in which small businesses dominate and low levels of economic integration
result in defensive responses, local economies are likely to break down into smaller, less
connected units as local communities seek to ‘look after their own’. Within this scenario,
businesses would manifest defensiveness in terms of a lower tendency and willingness to
co-operate and by attempting to protect local markets and customers. Localised Darwinian
(i.e. ‘survival of the fittest’) competition is likely to emerge, creating multiple un-
connected niches. An additional likely outcome from the emergence of many localised
economic units is disparity between these entities, leading to regional divergence within
countries and increasing disparity of income between rich and poor areas. Local
economies with low levels of economic activity, competitiveness and endowments would
likely become ‘locked-in’ [1] to slow rates of growth or even decline and to forms of
autarky. This could lead to social unrest and turbulence.
5.5. Global corporate economy
A future economy that is dominated by large companies that operate across nations, and
that is supported and encouraged by government and embraced by businesses, will
generate global or at least globalised markets. Such a scenario will lead to the
concentration of producer power in a relatively small number of large companies that will
adopt multiple strategies in order to gain competitive advantage. These may include an
increased focus on innovation in order to generate improved products and services and
enhanced choice for customers, should competition be high. It may also lead companies to
seek economies of scale through greater market share. Government’s role is likely to focus
on attempts to improve interaction and exchange across borders and to seek to regulate
adverse impacts of business activity or mitigate negative externalities. Small businesses
are likely to become of declining importance as larger companies expand into markets that
previously would have been considered of marginal interest and return. Those small
A. Atherton / Futures 37 (2005) 777–794786
businesses that survive and succeed in this scenario are likely to be highly dependent upon
larger companies.
5.6. ‘Strategic’ state support
Defensive responses to the domination of future economic activity by large
businesses operating across connected and integrated markets will lead to attempts to
secure advantage by gaining additional resources and protection. Government is more
likely to support individual large businesses, and possibly key sectors (especially if they
are seen as under competitive threat). In developing and industrialising economies,
defensiveness may take the form of strategic support for and allocation of resources to
large companies closely connected to the state, as was seen in Japan and Korea in the
second half of the twentieth century. In both developed and developing countries, the
likely outcome will be the seeking out of forms of protection of the domestic market,
based on legislative measures, exploitation of tacit socio-cultural differences, and
collusion between domestic companies. It will also lead in certain cases to the
promotion of exports of goods and services and to support for entry into other markets.
Strategic state support is likely to lead to a growing focus on comparative advantage
(i.e. to exploit all forms of trading advantage) and to protecting major domestic
enterprises. In small and relatively under-developed economies, this will lead to lower
levels of competitiveness and efficiency. In larger domestic markets with competitive
internal markets and a diversified economic structure, this may lead to the emergence of
national ‘champion’ businesses that can sustain themselves in their home market, and
may be able to compete in other markets.
5.7. Corporate ‘states and fiefdoms’
Embracing a future economy that is dominated by larger businesses, but that is less
connected in terms of markets, will lead to the emergence of companies that dominate
particular markets and localised economies. These ‘fiefdoms’ will emerge as a result of
a lack of connection, resulting in and perhaps emerging from the formation of barriers
to market entry for firms that wish to enter new markets. Increased costs of business
expansion, whether into new geographical or consumer markets, will allow locally
dominant large companies to influence and ultimately control local economies and, in
doing so, create local monopolies or oligopolies. Government response may be to
support these local and niche ‘giants’ and to seek to minimise adverse externality costs,
such as environmental damage or social problems. Public intervention may also attempt
to counteract reduced domestic market connectivity by seeking means and strategies to
encourage and support trade and business activity. This will, however, lead to debates as
to how to target and allocate such funding, as it will be finite and so subject to rationing.
5.8. State protectionism
A more defensive response to a less connected economy that is dominated by larger
companies is likely to lead to government intervention to protect domestic markets and
A. Atherton / Futures 37 (2005) 777–794 787
domestic businesses. This will result in further fragmentation of particular markets into a
series of protected national ‘sub’-national markets. It may also lead to localisation and
regionalisation within nations, particularly if regional and local government is strong or
independent. In both instances, the reduction of market scope may mean that large
companies that dominate particular markets may not be able to sustain profits and so will
either reduce in size or wind up. The net result may be a declining economy that comes to
resemble the niche ecology economy scenario, albeit with some continued dominance by
larger companies that adapt (for example, through diversification or horizontal integration,
or via innovations in client relationship management and marketing).
6. Extending the analysis to the current world economy
Although the scenarios and underpinning analysis have focused on the future,
international comparisons of economic structure and activity based on existing data
provide a means of assessing national difference, as well as an opportunity to test the
conceptual framework. Using World Bank data [7] on trade balances [22] and levels of
foreign direct investment (FDI) [71], an indicative picture of business integration and
economic integration can be developed. These two indicators were used because they
provide an overview of overall trade performance, i.e. commercial interactions across
markets, and the perceived attractiveness of an economy for external investors, i.e. the
amount of external money being committed to an economy by others.
The two data sets were compared with the relative distribution of small and medium
enterprises in relation to large businesses (in this case companies employing 500 or more
staff), using data developed by the OECD [43]. The results are summarised in Fig. 2, using
a three-variable plotting format. Levels of FDI are reflected in the size of the ‘bubble’ for
each of the countries, and trade balance was plotted on the y-axis. The graph uses available
data relating to the two primary criteria used to develop the future scenarios, namely: the
relative proportions of large and small businesses in an economy, and the extent of
business and trade integration [57].
This graph was then analysed in terms of the framework developed for future scenarios
for businesses (Fig. 1). Fig. 3 re-frames the international comparison based on the key
parameters used to develop the scenarios, and hence relates the data to the eight identified
futures. This was achieved by comparing individual country figures with the mean for all
three variables, namely: percentage of businesses (employing fewer than 500 staff in this
case); trade balance (export payments less import payments) as a percentage of GDP; and
foreign direct investment in millions of dollars. A qualitative assessment approach was
adopted in order to integrate the economic integration indicators (trade balance, FDI
flows), with each country assessed in terms of the size of the trade balance (both positive
and negative) and levels of FDI (with reference to GDP as well as via comparison with
other countries). Overall, countries were rated on the following scale across both
indicators: very high, high, above average, average, below average, low and very low.
Countries were deemed ‘more integrated’ when rated very high for both trade balance and
FDI flows. Conversely, countries were considered ‘less connected’ when both figures were
A. Atherton / Futures 37 (2005) 777–794788
low (although overall levels of trade were also considered in cases where the trade balance
was in balance).
Distribution across the framework was relatively dispersed, with countries demonstrat-
ing a broad range of positions, albeit with few placed in the bottom left quadrant (i.e. large
Fig. 2. International comparisons of SME populations, National Trade Balances and Foreign Direct Investment.
Sources: OECD SME Outlook 2002; World Bank World Development Report 2002.
Fig. 3. Multi-national mapping of selected countries against the scenarios framework.
A. Atherton / Futures 37 (2005) 777–794 789
business-less connected economies). The U.S. appears, based on these indicators, to be
both dominated by large businesses, in comparison with other countries, and highly
integrated with other economies (in most part due to high levels of FDI). In broad terms,
four general groupings could be identified amongst the other businesses:
1. Countries with relatively large small business populations and high trade balances and
levels of foreign direct investment (Belgium, Sweden).
2. Countries with above average figures for all three indicators, i.e. more small businesses
and higher levels of integration (Finland, France, Italy, Switzerland).
3. Countries with low levels of connection, as measured (Australia, Austria, Czech
Republic, Mexico, Poland, Spain, Turkey).
4. Countries with relatively high levels of integration, as measured by the two selected
indicators, and a proportionately bigger large business population (Germany, Norway,
UK and to some extent Denmark).
Countries with above average figures in terms of small business population, trade
balance and foreign direct investment flows appeared to possess the characteristics and
features of ‘Global Flexible Specialisation’, i.e. they competed internationally and had
high levels of small business involvement in the economy (groups 1 and 2 from the list
above [32]. Economies with low levels of international investment and trading
performance and relatively high or average small business populations reflected the
‘Diverse Small Economies’ scenario, in that they tended to be smaller economies that were
less integrated into the international economy than other nations (group 3). And countries
with a higher proportion of large companies and high foreign direct investment can be
associated with the ‘Global Corporate Economy’ scenario (group 4).
7. Scenarios as a ‘starting point’: embedding futures thinking in smaller businesses
Two broad approaches to futures thinking via the development of scenarios can be
discerned in the practitioner and research literature. The first focuses on scenarios as a
planning and organisational learning ‘tool’ or method. Organisationally-specific
approaches embrace the shared considerations and concerns of individuals and groups
working within or involved in the same organisation or community [60,63]. The technique,
as such, has tended to be used as a developmental process of formulating views on the future
by individuals who are both participants in the exercise and recipients of the outcome.
An alternative approach is to develop scenarios that relate to a specific issue or
condition rather than to a particular organisation [49,14,17,16,44]. Scenarios developed in
this way provide a future context for actors and organisations, as can be seen in this paper.
In part, this approach reflects the use of a publicly stated policy objective as a starting point
for the scenarios. However, there are two additional reasons for this concern with
developing a broad characterisation of possible futures. The first is that small businesses
often lack the resources and time to engage in structured futures planning via scenarios
development (in part due to a tendency not to formalise management and planning
activities). This paper, as such, builds on the small number of previous attempts to map
A. Atherton / Futures 37 (2005) 777–794790
a possible future from the perspective of and with the intention of informing management
and decision in the smaller business [23].
A second reason for this distinction, or separation, is the focus on broader notions of
economic structure and its development and change within the paper itself. The scenarios
explore the future nature of the economy rather than the particular concerns, prospects and
conditions of a particular business, either large or small. There is, as a result, a need to
consider how the scenarios can be related to and made sense of in terms of the particular
circumstances of a business. The specific conditions and context within which a business
will find itself in relation to a scenario cannot be established, in detail at least, from
consideration of a scenario in its current form. Instead, the scenarios developed in this
paper represent a starting point for future thinking within businesses, in that they will only
be useful and useable if made relevant by assessment of their specific significance and
implications for a business and its staff. The scenarios point to the need for businesses to
consider not only which scenarios are possible or even likely, but also to consider the
strategic implications for the business. This, in turn, supports views that scenarios
development as a form of futures planning leads to and requires organisational learning
[63,61], whether ‘internally generated’ or externally sourced.
References
[1] B. Arthur, Competing technologies, increasing returns and lock-in by historical events, Economic Journal
99 (1989) 116–131.
[2] C.-H. Bae, M.-J. Jun, Counterfactual planning: what if there had been no Greenbelt in Seoul?, Journal of
Planning, Education and Research 22 (4) (2003) 374–383.
[3] A. Barbanente, M. Khakee, M. Puglisi, Scenario building for Metropolitan Tunis, Futures 34 (7) (2002)
583–596.
[4] C. Bezold, Alternative futures for communities, Futures 31 (5) (1999) 465–473.
[5] D. Birch, Job Creation in America: How Our Smallest Companies Put the Most People to Work, Free Press,
New York, 1987.
[6] H. Bouwman, P. van der Buin, Technological forecasting and scenarios matter: research into the use of
information and communication technology in the home environment in 2010, Foresight 5 (4) (2003) 8–19.
[7] L. Broesma, P. Gautier, Job creation and job destruction by small firms: an empirical investigation for the
Dutch manufacturing sector, Small Business Economics 9 (3) (1997) 211–224.
[8] J. Bulhof, What if? Modality and history, History and Theory 38 (2) (1999) 145–168.
[9] A. Bullock, S. Trombley, The New Fontana Dictionary of Modern Thought, Harper Collins, London, 1999.
[10] R. Byrne, Mental models and counterfactual thoughts about what might have been, Trends in Cognitive
Sciences 6 (10) (2002) 426–431.
[11] G. Clarke, C. Menard, A. Zuluaga, Measuring the welfare effects of reform: urban water supply in Guinea,
World Development 30 (9) (2002) 1517–1537.
[12] P. Cooke, K. Morgan, The Associational Economy, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1998.
[13] I. Dale, A. Morgan, Job Creation—The Role of New and Small Firms, Small Business Service, Sheffield,
2001.
[14] R. Darton, Scenarios and metrics as guides to a sustainable future: the case of energy supply, Process Safety
and Environmental Protection 81 (5) (2003) 295–302.
[15] J. Dixon, R. Carpenter, L. Fallon, P. Sherman, S. Manopimoke, Economic Analysis of Environmental
Impacts of Development Projects, Earthscan Publications, London, 1986.
[16] M. Doi, P. Tiwari, T. Kawakami, Trade and factor market reforms in China, Labour 16 (3) (2002) 537–555.
A. Atherton / Futures 37 (2005) 777–794 791
[17] P. Domah, M. Pollitt, The restructuring and privatization of the electricity distribution and supply businesses
in england and wales: a social cost-benefit analysis, Fiscal Studies 22 (1) (2001) 107–146.
[18] DTI Manufacturing 2020 Foresight Panel, UK Manufacturing: We Can Make It Better, www.foresight.gov.
uk, 2000.
[19] Each scenario, therefore, is based on the following combination: Future ScenarioZf1(small business or
large business)Cf2(integrated or less connected)Cf3(embracing or defensive). The result is the following
permutations of the three drivers of future economic structure: (1) small business-more integrated-
embracing; (2) small business-more integrated-defensive; (3) small business-less connected-embracing; (4)
small business-less connected-defensive; (5) large business-more integrated-embracing; (6) large business-
more integrated-defensive; (7) large business-less connected-embracing; (8) large business-less connected-
defensive.
[20] M. Enright, in: N. Hood, S. Young (Eds.), The globalization of competition and the localization of
competitive advantage: policies towards regional clustering, St Martin’s Press, New York, 2000, p. 2000.
[21] Enterprise Directorate, European Commission, Green Paper on Entrepreneurship in Europe, www.europa.
eu.int/comm/enterprise/entrepreneurship, 2003.
[22] ‘External balance of goods and services’, i.e. the net different between exports and imports, as an overall
percentage of GDP provides a broad indication of international trade performance. Data were assessed to
identify both a positive ‘trade balance’ and the overall scale of the balance, as both indicate high levels of
performance and activity within a global economy.
[23] E. Fuller, Responding to the Future for Small Business, Foresight Project, Durham University Business
School, Durham, 1997.
[24] E. Fuller, Small business futures in society, Futures 35 (4) (2003) 297–304.
[25] C. Gallagher, M. Daly, J. Thompson, The growth of UK companies and their contribution to job creation,
Small Business Economics 3 (4) (1991) 269–286.
[26] C. Geertz, Local Knowledge, Fontana, London 1973.
[27] P. Ghemawat, F. Ghadar, The dubious logic of global mega-mergers, Harvard Business Review July–
August (2000) 65–72.
[28] J. Glenn, T. Gordon, Constructing peace scenarios for the Middle East, Foresight 5 (4) (2003) 36–40.
[29] A. Heshmati, On the growth of micro and small firms: evidence from Sweden, Small Business Economics
17 (3) (2001) 213–228.
[30] A. Hines, The future of futures: a scenario salon, Foresight 5 (4) (2003) 28–35.
[31] S. Hohti, Job flows and job quality by establishment size in the finnish manufacturing sector, 1980–1994,
Small Business Economics 15 (4) (2000) 265–294.
[32] In the cases of Finland and France, and to some degree Belgium and Sweden, there exists a well-established
cadre of large and very large companies, many of which trade internationally. It is important, as such, to note
that large businesses can and do play an important role in economies which have comparatively large small
business populations (as measured by share of the total business population).
[33] Industry Task Force on Leadership and Management Skills (The Karpin Report), Enterprising Nation:
Renewing Australia’s Managers to Meet the Challenge of the Asia-Pacific Century, Australian Federal
Government.
[34] D. Kahneman, D. Miller, Norm theory: comparing reality to its alternatives, Psychological Review 93 (2)
(1986) 136–153.
[35] J. Konings, Gross job flows and the evolution of size in UK establishments, Small Business Economics 7 (3)
(1995) 213–220.
[36] H. Leknes, C. Carr, Globalisation, international configurations and the strategic implications: the case of
retailing, Long Range Planning 37 (2004) 29–49.
[37] S. Li, I. Vertinsky, Z. Dongshou, The emergence of private ownership in China, Journal of Business
Research 5882 (2003) 1–8.
[38] C. Lindblom, The Policy-making Process, Prentice-Hall, New York, 1980.
[39] L. Manski, J. Newman, J. Pepper, Using performance standards to evaluate social programmes with
incomplete outcome data: general issues and application to a higher education block grant program,
Evaluation Review 26 (4) (2002) 355–381.
A. Atherton / Futures 37 (2005) 777–794792
[40] K. Markman, P. Tetlock, ‘I couldn’t have known’; accountability, foreseeability and close call
counterfactual denials of responsibility, British Journal of Social Psychology 39 (3) (2000) 313–325.
[41] K. Markman, I. Gavanski, S. Sherman, M. McMullen, The mental simulation of better and worst possible
worlds, Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 29 (1993) 87–109.
[42] R. Mitchell, I. Tydeman, R. Gurnow, Scenario generation: limitations and developments in cross-impact
analysis, Futures 9 (3) (1977) 202–215.
[43] Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, OECD SME Outlook, 2002.
[44] P. Osakwe, L. Schembri, Real effects of collapsing exchange rate regimes: an application to Mexico, Journal
of International Economics 57 (2) (2002) 299–325.
[45] J. Pearl, Probabilities of causation: three counterfactual interpretations and their identification, Synthese 121
(1) (1999) 93–149.
[46] E. Pestel, Modellers and politicians, Futures 14 (2) (1982) 122–128.
[47] N. Roese, Counterfactual thinking, Psychological Bulletin 121 (1) (1977) 133–148.
[48] N. Roese, J. Olson, Counterfactuals, causal attributions and the hindsight bias: a conceptual integration,
Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 32 (1996) 197–227.
[49] P. Schwab, F. Cerutti, U. von Reibnitz, Foresight—using scenarios to shape the future of agricultural
research, Foresight 5 (1) (2003) 55–61.
[50] R. Slaughter, From forecasting and scenarios to social construction: changing methodological paradigms in
futures studies, Foresight 4 (3) (2002) 26–31.
[51] Small and Medium-sized Enterprises (SMEs) Promotion Law of the People’s Republic of China, www.sme.
gov.cn/, under the policies banner, 2002.
[52] Small Business Service, A Government Action Plan for Small Business, www.sbs.gov.uk/action, 2004.
[53] D. Storey, S. Johnson, Job generation in britain: a review of recent studies, International Small Business
Journal 4 (4) (1986) 29–46.
[54] Strategy Unit, Cabinet Office, Strategic Opportunities for Small Business in the UK, www.strategy.gov.uk,
2001.
[55] F. Sylvan, S. Majeski, A methodology for the study of historical counterfactuals, International Studies
Quarterly 42 (1) (1998) 79–108.
[56] P. Tetlock, D. Visser. Thinking about Russia: plausible acts and probable futures. British Journal of Social
Psychology 39 (2) (2000) 173–196.
[57] The relative distribution between small and large is based on the actual percentage of businesses with fewer
than 500 employees, as per the OECD data. Levels of integration were based on a qualitative assessment of
‘trade balance’ and foreign direct investment figures from the World Bank 2002 report. Countries were rated
on a sliding scale, with countries such as Belgium that had positive high figures in both figures being rated as
very integrated and countries with low and negative trade balances and FDI figures as less integrated. The
graph is indicative, in any case, as it is based on two calculations that serve as very general proxies of actual
levels of business connectivity and economic integration.
[58] F. Tilley, E. Fuller, Foresighting methods and their role in researching small firms and sustainability,
Futures 32 (2000) 149–161.
[59] S. Tsuru, Japan’s Capitalism, Canto, Cambridge Economic Policies and Institutions, Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge, 1993.
[60] K. van der Heijden, Scenarios: The Art of Strategic Conversation, Wiley, Chichester, UK, 1996.
[61] K. van der Heijden, Can internally generated futures accelerate organizational learning?, Futures 36 (2004)
145–159.
[62] K. van der Heijden, Can internally generated futures accelerate organizational learning?, Futures 36 (2004)
145.
[63] K. van der Heijden, R. Bradfield, G. Burt, G. Cairns, G. Wright, The Sixth Sense: Accelerating
Organizational Learning with Scenarios, Wiley, Chichester, UK, 2002.
[64] P. van Notten, J. Rotmans, M. van Anselt, D. Rothman, An updated scenario typology, Futures 35 (5) (2003)
423–443.
[65] A. Vawda, P. Moock, J. Price Gittinger, H. Patrinos, Economic analysis of world bank education projects
and project outcomes, International Journal of Educational Development 23 (6) (2003) 645–660.
[66] K. Weick, Sensemaking in Organizations, Sage, New York, 1984.
A. Atherton / Futures 37 (2005) 777–794 793
[67] J. White, A small business is not a little big business, Harvard Business Review July/August (1981) 18–23.
[68] White Paper on Small and Medium Enterprises in Japan, www.meti.go.jp/english/report/, 2002.
[69] E. Wilson, Investing in the global information future, Futures 30 (1) (1998) 23–42.
[70] World Bank, World Development Report 2002: Building Institutions for Markets, Oxford University Press,
Oxford, 2002, p. 57.
[71] World Bank data on foreign direct investment (FDI), in millions of dollars, were used to assess levels of
external business interest in an economy. FDI is a useful broad indicator of openness of an economy because
it highlights international business interest in a particular country, and because it is a net flow of investment
into a country, i.e. actual money invested in businesses.
A. Atherton / Futures 37 (2005) 777–794794
... Chartered Professional Accountants of Canada (Axson, 2018) distinguished 3 different types of scenario building methods (see Table 1): Spectrum method, Matrix method, Binary method. If the Spectrum method along one axis and the Two-axes method along two axes are not sufficient to cover the scenarios, the three-dimensional scenario construction method (see Table 1) can be applied (Atherton, 2005;Bradbrook et al., 2013;Gratton and Truss, 2003). The advantage of this method is its disadvantage in the same time as using many dimensions makes the whole scenario planning complicated, and it may not be possible to have all eight scenarios. ...
... -striving for simplicity -very limited cases, and is not suitable for elaborating complex scenarios -provides insufficient information -suitable for yes/no decisions -employment of driving forces of key importance Three -dimensional (Atherton, 2005;Bradbrook et al., 2013;Gratton and Truss, 2003) In this method, each scenario occurring along the three axes is located in eight cells. In this case a higher number of driving forces might be used. ...
Article
The purpose of this article is to present an online scenario building platform developed by the author. With the help of this platform scenarios can be created using arbitrary online scenario building methods in a way that a high number of individual participants could join the process. Using the elaborated online method, the entire scenario building process can be accomplished ranging from the development of driving forces, through the analysis of data and scenarios created and to their feedback. The platform enables the development of not only targeted methods, but the entirely general ones as well. This article provides a detailed presentation of the Two-axes method scenario created by use of this platform and constantly tested on several scenario building tasks. Individuals of various competencies participated in the testing over the past years, covering university students, experts, and representatives of various stakeholder groups. The platform comes with a text mining package with the help of which the resulting scenarios can be analysed logically and textually. This package enables the mapping out of the extent to which the scenarios, the driving forces and the intermediate stages are logically related.
... Given this objective, our aim is to propose a novel critical counterfactuals method of futures research, validated through exploring conjectures about a fictional future of entrepreneurship. We therefore also include a contribution to the literature on futures studies in Entrepreneurship (for example : Atherton, 2005;García-Olivares & Solé, 2015). The CCF (Critical Counterfactual Futures) method was developed at X University and is presently being used to systematically consider critical perspectives in International Business, Business Schools and the Future of Work. ...
... Here, amid the pains of slowing economic growth, we witness the paradoxical rise of the unicorn venture (Henrekson & Sanandaji, 2017). In the futures mould, we follow, for example, Atherton (2005) and García-Olivares & Solé (2015). ...
Preprint
Full-text available
This conceptual paper is inspired by a critical and counterfactual application of science fiction. Although both science fiction and counterfactuals in futures studies are not uncommon, this paper sets out a theoretical position for a critical perspective on their use. A critical counterfactuals method is proposed, in which a device of fictional news headlines provides a set of counterfactual vignettes-small scenes from the future-used to explore the emergence of an extant concept of entrepreneurship. In order to assign relative truth values to science fiction vignettes, a truth-table is used to examine coherence between the counterfactuals and a range of projected future moments, based on three dimensions of an uncertain future history. This approach is argued as overcoming several limitations of fictional scenarios/vignettes in counterfactual analysis, including the indeterminacy intuition: the accepted wisdom that impossible or wholly implausible scenarios are unfeasible. In reporting on an initial study, the paper draws conjectures about a future entrepreneurship, highlighting the method's potential in delivering new insights into how future education and support policies might better develop entrepreneurship for a sustainable economy.
... Take, for example, the business arena where a corporate leadership team might rigorously analyze the potential ripple effects had they opted for an alternative investment strategy (Baron, * The majority of the work was completed during Wenhao's internship at the Allen Institute for AI. 2000; Atherton, 2005). Counterfactual reasoning has long been considered a necessary part of a complete system for AI. ...
... According to the Small and Medium Enterprises Development Agency of Nigeria and National Bureau of Statistics report (SMEDAN & NBS, 2013, p. 3), small firms are business ventures that have total assets (land and building excluded) above 10 million naira, but not more than 100 million naira, and whose total workforce is between 10 and 49 em-| 69 ployees. They have global recognition as engines of socio-economic transformation, because they provide jobs and wealth-creation opportunities and assist in income redistribution in both developing and developed economies (Atherton, 2005;OECD, 2017). However, small firms in Nigeria are bedevilled with an immeasurable number of challenges including the lack of financial access, dilapidated infrastructures, irregularities in government laws, the lack of support for business development services, insufficient access to markets, multiple taxations, and obsolete technology (SMEDAN & NBS, 2013). ...
... Lastly, considering the past can be used to augment and improve other futuring techniques by simply adding new possibilities to the scenario development process. Atherton (2005) uses counterfactual narratives to add "polarised", unpredictable possibilities to future scenarios that explore policy for small businesses, as does Todorova (2015), but in the context of global geopolitical events. For Gordon and Todorova (2019), counterfactual narratives provide additional inputs into a Real Time Delphi exercise -"not so much to forecast what may come to pass, but to stimulate imaginations by framing an unlimited set of what if questions that can test and expand our assumptions about reality" (p. ...
Article
Full-text available
While the past is present in all futuring activities it tends to remain implicit and has not received adequate attention by futures scholars and practitioners. In response, this conceptual paper offers a novel framework with which the past can be brought into futures studies in a structured and comprehensive way. We begin by providing a brief account of how the past already figures in futures studies as part of efforts to understand the lingering effects of the past on the future; as part of a drive for ontological pluralization; and as a way to augment more mainstream futuring exercises. We then introduce two past-facing approaches to futuring, recasting and pastcasting, and illustrate their symmetry with the more familiar future-facing approaches, forecasting and backcasting. The symmetry, we argue, is based on shared aims and a shared style of inquiry. We then compare the different approaches and illustrate the landscape of futuring as an interplay of two dimensions: the focus of the activity on outcomes or pathways, and the stakes involved in it.
... It became important considering the social and political potential of small industry strategically due to its great ability to absorb manpower by utilizing domestic resources (Kuncoro, 2003). Atherton (2005) describes the important role of small industry in encouraging all business activities in all phases of the economy. Small industries play an important role in supporting the increasing economic productivity of a country. ...
Article
Full-text available
Small industries are life-sustaining for communities because of their political and strategic position in terms of creating job opportunities and increasing revenue. One small industrial sector that has the potential to be developed is the food industry. Small food industries are widely scattered in every area, including in the city of Palembang. A small industrial group of food that became one of the culinary icons in Palembang is the cracker industry. This type of industry is a culinary icon that has been famous for foreign countries. Nevertheless, the cracker industry is still experiencing obstacles in terms of capital and marketing. The cost of raw materials is relatively expensive to technically trigger the industry inefficiencies. Therefore, it is necessary to review the technical efficiency of this small industry. The variables used in this study were capital, labor, and output. The data used is secondary data that is analyzed by using the Stochastic Frontier Analysis (SFA) approach. The results showed that the technical efficiency achievement of small industrial crackers in South Sumatera is still categorized as low. The use of labor input is more effective than capital use as a result of the utilization of technology and local resources. Therefore, the development of small industrial crackers through an efficiency approach cannot be separated from the application of technology, human resource management, marketing, and business climate.
... After the scenario development process in the narrow sense is completed, the determined scenarios feed into the further scenario use phase [134], i.e., the organization's strategy process, namely strategy development and, later, execution [110]. Apart from employing scenario techniques, organizations can also consider externally given scenarios such as those offered by Atherton for small businesses [6]. ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper challenges the solely rational view of the scenario technique as a strategy and foresight tool designed to cope with uncertainty by considering multiple possible future states. The paper employs an affordance-based view that allows for the identification and structuring of hidden, emergent attributes of the scenario technique beyond the intended ones. The suggested framework distinguishes between affordances (1) that are intended by the organization and relate to its goals, (2) that emergently generate organizational benefits, and (3) that do not relate to organizational but individual interests. Also, constraints in the use of scenarios are discussed. Affordance theory’s specific lens shows that the emergence of such attributes depends on the users’ specific intentions.
... After the scenario development process in the narrow sense is completed, the determined scenarios feed into the further scenario use phase [134], i.e., the organization's strategy process, namely strategy development and, later, execution [110]. Apart from employing scenario techniques, organizations can also consider externally given scenarios such as those offered by Atherton for small businesses [6]. ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper challenges the solely rational view of the scenario technique as a strategy and foresight tool designed to cope with uncertainty by considering multiple possible future states. The paper employs an affordance-based view that allows for the identification and structuring of hidden, emergent attributes of the scenario technique beyond the intended ones. The suggested framework distinguishes between affordances (1) that are intended by the organization and relate to its goals, (2) that emergently generate organizational benefits, and (3) that do not relate to organizational but individual interests. Also, constraints in the use of scenarios are discussed. Affordance theory’s specific lens shows that the emergence of such attributes depends on the users’ specific intentions.
Book
Full-text available
Az Ökológia Kutatóközpont Tanulmányai a kutatóközpontban folyó tudományos kutatásokba enged betekintést kutatóknak, gyakorlati szakembereknek, döntéshozóknak és a széles olvasóközönségnek. E sorozat keretében magyar nyelvű összefoglaló tanulmányokat jelentetünk meg a kutatóközpont szakemberei által koordinált tudományos kutatásokról, amelyek az ökológia változatos szakterületeit érintik, beleértve az interdiszciplinárisan kapcsolódó tudományterületeket is. A magyarországi természeti és környezeti állapotának változása számos kihívást tartogat számunkra a következő évtizedekben. A jövő lehetséges változásainak feltérképezése segít abban, hogy hatékonyabban fel tudjunk készülni az előttünk álló kihívásokra célzott kutatások indításával. E cél érdekében indult a „Környezeti jövőkutatás: Magyarország 2050” című program 2016-ban, melynek záró tanulmányát tartja kezében az olvasó. Munkánk fő célkitűzése, hogy a jövőbeli lehetőségek és veszélyek feltárásával javaslatot tegyünk olyan kutatási irányokra, témakörökre, amelyek hatékonyan és célzottan segíthetik a természetmegőrzést a következő évtizedekben. A jövőkutatási folyamatban multidiszciplináris kutatócsoportunk a Horizon Scanning, azaz a jövőfürkésző eljárást alkalmazta. Az eljárás a jövőkutatás egyik formájának, az előretekintésnek az első fázisa, amely a lehetséges jövők tartományának feltérképezésére irányul. A szakirodalmi feltárás után szakértők bevonásával egy ötletbörzét, majd egy kollektív információrendszerező és -értékelő workshopot tartottunk. A részvételi folyamat eredményeként kapott jövőállításokhoz kapcsolódóan fogalmazódtak meg azok az ökológiai kérdésköröket középpontba állító komplex problémák, amelyek a 2050-es jövő alakulása/alakítása szempontjából potenciálisan fontos kutatási irányokat határozhatnak meg Magyarország számára.
Article
Full-text available
Penelitian ini bertujuan untuk membuat pengukuran modal manusia pengusaha kecil melalui penyusunan suatu indeks modal manusia (IMM). Modal manusia merupakan konsep yang tersusun dari berbagai aspek sumberdaya manusia. Aspek-aspek yang dimasukkan dalam indeks modal manusia ini terdiri dari aspek pendidikan, latihan, pengalaman, ketrampilan, dan kewirusahaan. Indeks yang disusun merupakan pengukuran akumulasi pencapaian kualitas sumberdaya manusia pengusaha. Dalam penyusunan indeks setiap aspeknya sudah dipastikan memiliki peranan terhadap kinerja usaha. Penelitian ini diharapkan memberikan pemahaman tentang bagaimana mengukur kemanfaatan investasi dalam peningkatan kualitas SDM sebagai suatu modal manusia yang akan bermanfaat dalam peningkatan kinerja usaha.
Article
Full-text available
Presents a theory of norms and normality and applies the theory to phenomena of emotional responses, social judgment, and conversations about causes. Norms are assumed to be constructed ad hoc by recruiting specific representations. Category norms are derived by recruiting exemplars. Specific objects or events generate their own norms by retrieval of similar experiences stored in memory or by construction of counterfactual alternatives. The normality of a stimulus is evaluated by comparing it with the norms that it evokes after the fact, rather than to precomputed expectations. Norm theory is applied in analyses of the enhanced emotional response to events that have abnormal causes, of the generation of predictions and inferences from observations of behavior, and of the role of norms in causal questions and answers. (3 p ref) (PsycINFO Database Record (c) 2012 APA, all rights reserved)
Chapter
Two seemingly competing tendencies, the globalization of economic activity and the localization of industries, have captured the interest of scholars, economic development professionals, and policy-makers in recent years. While trends towards globalization of industries and companies appear to reduce the importance and distinctiveness of (subnational) regions, a tendency towards localization of certain industries and economic activities appears to do exactly the opposite. The simultaneous globalization and localization tendencies have created policy challenges for national and local governments. One response to these challenges has been a dramatic proliferation of regional development policies based on regional clusters of firms and industries.
Article
The almost universal belief among executives today is that bigger is better: companies are entering into huge, pricey cross-border mergers at an unprecedented rate. Common wisdom is that industries will become more concentrated as they become more global. This idea has persistently dominated business-from Karl Marx's "one capitalist kills many" theory to the more recent "one, two, or three shall dominate" logic put forth by business practitioners. In this article, the authors debunk the myth of increased concentration; the perceived links between the globalization of an industry and the concentration of that industry are weak. Empirical research shows that global- or globalizing - industries have actually been marked by steady decreases in concentration since World War II . The authors present the biases that managers often have about consolidation and offer alternative strategies to pursuing the big M&A deal. There are better, more profitable ways of dealing with globalization than relentless expansion, they say. Those strategies include buying up cast-off assets from merging rivals; focusing more on domestic or regional growth rather than on global expansion; taking advantage of merging rivals' weakened market position during integration and launching an aggressive marketing campaign; and building alliances with other companies rather than buying them up. In an era that is witnessing technological discontinuities, managers shouldn't focus on size as a goal; instead, they should focus on the development of new business models that help them compete.
Article
Scenario building is an essential element for working on, and creating, alternative futures. This paper, based on the work at the Institute of Alternative Futures, discusses the use of scenarios in the context of community development and explores three basic types of scenarios—`the official future', `hard times' and paradigm shift or visionary scenarios. With examples from Washington and elsewhere, the paper tries to show how communities can reinvent themselves and meet the challenges of the future with the aid of scenarios.