ArticlePDF Available

The Swedish ICT miracle - Myth or reality?

Authors:

Abstract and Figures

This article investigates the productivity development in Sweden in the 1990s. The results show that much of the recorded Swedish surge in labor productivity was due to the spectacular growth of the Radio, television and communication equipment (RTC) industry. However, this article shows that the productivity growth of the RTC industry is very sensitive to value added price deflators. Unlike Sweden, the US uses hedonic price indexes for semiconductors and microprocessors which are important intermediate inputs in the RTC industry. Estimates based on the US intermediate input price deflators for semiconductors and microprocessors suggest that the productivity growth of the Swedish RTC industry during the 1990s is an artefact. This implies that the productivity growth of total manufacturing has also been overestimated. The results for Sweden are also interesting for other countries such as Finland, Ireland and South Korea where ICT producing industries have contributed substantially to labor productivity growth.
Content may be subject to copyright.
SSE/EFI Working Paper Series in Economics and Finance
No. 556
February 2004
The Swedish ICT Miracle – Myth or Reality*
By
Harald Edquist
Abstract: This paper investigates the relative labor productivity level for total manufacturing in Germany,
Sweden and the US for the period 1980–2001. The paper also presents estimates of labor productivity
levels for 18 different manufacturing industries for the period 1993–2000. The results show that the
Swedish manufacturing productivity caught up with German and US productivity in the 1990s, overtaking
the German level in 1995 and coming very close to the US level by the end of the 1990s. It has been argued
that much of the Swedish surge in labor productivity during the second half of the 1990s was due to the
spectacular growth of the Radio, television and communication equipment (RTC) (ISIC 32) industry.
However, this paper shows that since 1998 Swedish RTC productivity has been declining relative to the
corresponding industry in Germany and the US. Moreover, it is shown that the productivity growth of the
ICT-producing industries is very sensitive to the value added price deflators that areused to calculate real
value added growth rates. Unlike Sweden, the US uses hedonic price indexes for semiconductors and
microprocessors. These electronic components are important intermediate inputs in the RTC industry.
Therefore estimates based on the US intermediate input price deflators for semiconductors and
microprocessors suggest that the productivity growth of the Swedish RTC industry during the 1990s is
partly a statistical artefact. This implies that the productivity growth of total manufacturing also has been
overestimated.
JEL-codes: O10; O30; O47; O57
Keywords: Information and communication technology (ICT), Productivity, Technological change,
Value added deflators
* I am especially grateful to Robert Inklaar, without whose help this paper never would have been written. I
would also like to thank Bart van Ark, Edwin Stuivenwold, Marcel Timmer and Gerard Ypma at the
Groningen Growth and Development Centre and Magnus Henrekson at the Stockholm School of
Economics for providing valuable comments and data for this paper. Moreover, I am grateful to Göran
Svensson, Bertil Klang and Per Ericson at Statistics Sweden and Arvid Wallgren and other participants at
the seminar at the Swedish Central Bank for insightful comments. Financial support from the Jan
Wallander and Tom Hedelius Foundation and the Carl Silvén Foundation is also gratefully acknowledged.
Department of Economics, Stockholm School of Economics, PO Box 6501, SE-113 83 Stockholm,
Sweden. Phone: +46 8 736 92 59, Fax: +46 8 31 32 07, E-mail: Harald.Edquist@hhs.se
1
Table of Contents
1. INTRODUCTION .................................................................................................................................... 2
2. LABOR PRODUCTIVITY LEVELS IN MANUFACTURING .......................................................... 4
2.1 Currency conversion....................................................................................................................... 4
2.2 Unit value ratio data....................................................................................................................... 7
2.3 Productivity level results................................................................................................................. 8
2.3.1 Unit value ratio results ............................................................................................................................. 8
2.3.2 Productivity level benchmark results for 1997......................................................................................... 9
3. EXTENDING LABOR PRODUCTIVITY LEVELS BY GROWTH RATES ................................. 10
3.1 Time series data ............................................................................................................................ 10
3.1.1 Data description ..................................................................................................................................... 10
3.1.2 Price deflators ........................................................................................................................................ 11
3.2 Productivity level results for the manufacturing industry............................................................. 12
3.2.1 Total manufacturing ............................................................................................................................... 12
3.2.2 Industry level.......................................................................................................................................... 13
4. ICT DEFLATORS AND RELATIVE LABOR PRODUCTIVITY ................................................... 15
4.1 ICT deflators ................................................................................................................................. 15
4.2 A detailed investigation of the Radio television and communication equipment industry ............ 17
5. CONCLUSIONS..................................................................................................................................... 25
6. REFERENCES ....................................................................................................................................... 27
7. APPENDIX ............................................................................................................................................. 48
7.1 Appendix 1: Unit value ratios ....................................................................................................... 48
7.2 Appendix 2: ICT deflators............................................................................................................. 50
2
1. Introduction
During the 1990s productivity research increasingly came into focus. Comparisons of
productivity across countries and industries are important for evaluating economic
performance. Moreover, particular attention has been paid to productivity comparisons in
industries with rapid technological change and falling prices such as the Information and
Communication Technology (ICT) producing industry.
Comparing productivity in industries producing homogenous products is an easy task.
For example, in the crude oil industry, output is arrived at by a mere counting of barrels
of oil produced. However, measuring productivity in industries where technology
changes rapidly is a totally different matter. According to “Moore’s law” microprocessors
are halved in price and double in capacity every 18 months. A computer based on the
latest technology might be obsolete within a year or two. Is it then reasonable to compare
productivity in industries with rapidly changing technology and prices across countries?
Nordhaus (1997) argues that capturing the impact of new technologies on living
standards is beyond the practical capability of official Statistical Agencies. The essential
difficulty is that high-tech goods and services consumed today may not even have existed
a decade ago. Moreover, if they did, the quality of the goods that we consume today is
much higher compared to the quality of “the same” good a decade ago.
The increase in productivity growth in the US economy since 1995 (see Council of
Economic Advisers 2003) has resulted in an intense debate on the impact of ICT
technology on productivity in different countries. In Sweden, ICT technology created an
economic boom at the end of the 1990s. In 2000 Stockholm was named the Internet
capital of Europe by the Newsweek Magazine. According to Newsweek the Stockholm
phenomenon could be explained by “the looming marriage of the Internet and the third-
generation mobile telephony in Europe” (Newsweek 2000). Figures from Statistics
Sweden also supported the spectacular development of the Swedish Radio, television and
communication equipment (RTC) (ISIC 32) industry. For the period 1996–2000 the labor
productivity growth in RTC was approximately 35 percent per year.
3
Four years later, it is evident that much of the Swedish Internet era of the late 1990s was
a transient hype, partly created by media. However, it has been very difficult to explain
the fundamental fact that productivity growth in Swedish manufacturing and particularly
in the RTC industry increased so rapidly during the last years of the 1990s. Did the
increased productivity growth in manufacturing and RTC of the late 1990s reflect some
fundamental changes in the economy or was it largely a statistical artefact?
There have been a number of studies examining productivity development in Sweden
during the 1990s. Most of them investigate productivity growth in Sweden compared to
other countries (see Lundgren and Wiberg (2000), Edquist and Henrekson (2001, 2002),
Lind (2002, 2003) and Apel and Lindström (2003)). So far much of this research has
been focused on Swedish productivity growth, often in comparisons with productivity
growth in other countries. The results have emphasized the spectacular growth and the
increasing importance of the Swedish RTC industry. A common claim is that without the
spectacular growth of the RTC industry the productivity growth in total manufacturing
during the second half of the 1990s would have been much lower (Lind 2003). Moreover,
the productivity performance of the total manufacturing industry during the 1990s has
often been described as the “ICT miracle”.
Much research has been carried out about Swedish productivity growth. However, the
research on comparative productivity levels has been limited. Moreover, it has not been
clarified to what extent the use of country specific value added price deflators have
affected the growth in the RTC industry. The following questions have remained
unanswered: How big is the gap in productivity level for different manufacturing
industries between Sweden and other countries? Which industries have been catching up
during the 1990s? What impact does the use of different value added price deflators and
quality adjustments have on productivity growth and relative productivity levels in the
ICT-producing industries?1
1 For a definition of the ICT producing industries see OECD (2002).
4
The purpose of this paper is to answer the questions stated above. In sections 2 and 3 I
present estimates of labor productivity levels for Swedish manufacturing relative to the
corresponding levels in Germany and the US in 1980–2001. Moreover, I also provide
estimates of labor productivity levels for 18 manufacturing industries at the 2-digit ISIC2
level for the period 1993–2000. The method used for comparing productivity levels is
based on the industry-of-origin approach.3 In short, the industry-of-origin approach
converts output by industry to a common currency with a producer price-based and
industry specific Purchasing Power Parity, which is called Unit Value Ratio (UVR).4 In
section 4, the impact of value added price deflators for the ICT-producing industry is
investigated. Section 4 also compares the intermediate input and gross output price
deflators for ISIC 32 in Sweden and the US. Section 5 concludes.
2. Labor productivity levels in manufacturing
2.1 Currency conversion
In order to compare labor productivity levels between countries with different currencies,
it is necessary to convert the value added of different countries into a common currency.
Since price levels in different industries can vary substantially across countries, it is also
necessary to find a conversion method that is industry specific (Scarpetta et al. 2000).
The conversion can be made in a number of ways. One possibility is simply to use the
existing exchange rate between the two countries. However, this implies several
disadvantages. For example, the exchange rate is only based on traded goods, it is not
industry specific, it is affected by exchange rate policies and currency market fluctuations
and it does not adjust for international price differences (Monnikhof and van Ark 2002).
An alternative to the exchange rate is to use Purchasing Power Parities (PPPs). PPPs are
obtained from the expenditure side and reflect the relative price levels for private
2 ISIC stands for International Standard for Industry Classification and it is an UN based classification
standard (see United Nations Statistics Division (2000))
3 The industry-of-origin approach has been developed by the ICOP (International Comparisons of Output
and Productivity) group at the University of Groningen since 1983 (see van Ark and Pilat 1993).
4 The methodology of unit value ratios is discussed in more detail in section 2.1.
5
consumption, investment and government expenditure (van Ark and Timmer 2002). PPPs
are constructed by gathering expenditure prices for a large sample of products in each
country. The ratio between the expenditure prices for the same products in the two
countries are then used to construct the PPPs. Finally, the ratios of expenditure prices for
each product group are aggregated to a country specific PPP.
While PPPs are successfully used for comparisons of GDP and labor productivity at the
aggregate level, there are a number of problems associated with the use of PPPs for
industry level comparisons. One problem is that expenditure PPPs only apply to final
output, so that intermediate output is not covered by PPPs. According to Monnikhof and
van Ark (2002) intermediate products account for around one third of the value in
manufacturing. Another drawback with using the expenditure PPPs for comparisons on
the industry level is that they include margins, indirect taxes and subsidies. They also
include import prices, while export prices are excluded (van Ark and Pilat 1993).
According to van Ark and Timmer (2002) there are two alternatives to construct reliable
industry level PPPs. The first approach is to transform expenditure PPPs to industry
groups by “peeling off” indirect taxes and transport and distribution margins and thereby
create producer price level PPPs.5 The second approach is the industry-of-origin approach
that will be used in this paper. The industry-of-origin approach converts the currency by
using output data instead of expenditure data. The conversion is made by calculating unit
value ratios (UVRs).
Unit values (UV) are computed by dividing the ex factory value of output for a product
category by the produced quantities. The information is most often based on production
censuses or industrial surveys. In practice, products or product groups that are similar in
both countries are matched against each other. Unit values for the two countries are then
divided in order to obtain a product unit value ratio (UVR). Each product UVR indicates
the relative producer price of the matched product in the two countries. Product UVRs
5 This method was pioneered by Jorgenson and associates. For a more detailed description of the method
see van Ark and Timmer (2002).
6
are aggregated step by step to higher levels; from the product level to the industry level
and finally to the total manufacturing level.6
The industry-of-origin methodology also has some drawbacks. According to van Ark
(1996) there are three major problems7 with the UVR-method that affect the
comparability of the estimates across countries:
In many sectors and industries UVRs are based on a limited sample of items. For
example, in manufacturing where the average percentage of output covered by
unit value ratios is between 15 and 45 percent, it is usually assumed that UVRs
for matched items within a manufacturing industry are representative for non-
matched items.
Comparisons of unit values are affected by differences in product mix. Often
output values are only calculated for product groups instead of specific products.
This leads to problems on a disaggregated level because of the lack of harmonized
product coding systems between different countries.
The unit value ratios also have to be adjusted to differences in product quality
across countries. However, it is even more serious in international comparisons
since the frequency of “unique products” that are only available in one country, is
higher than for comparisons over time.
Despite these caveats the industry-of-origin methodology appears to be the preferred
method for comparing productivity levels across countries. Nonetheless, it is important to
keep in mind that the industry-of-origin methodology has limitations and that results for
industries with low coverage ratios must be interpreted with caution.
6 For a detailed and more formal explanation of the industry-of-origin approach see appendix 1.
7 Another problem that is not discussed by van Ark (1996) is that UVRs are often used in a single deflation
procedure, which means that intermediate products are not included in the estimation of UVRs.
7
2.2 Unit value ratio data
The unit value ratios presented in this paper are based on two bilateral investigations for
the year 1997. The first investigation compares the unit value ratios between Germany
and Sweden and the second compares the unit value ratios between Germany and the US.
This allows for comparisons of Sweden and the US by using Germany as a link. The unit
value ratios between Sweden and Germany are based on data from the Eurostat Prodcom-
database (Europroms 2001). The unit value ratios between Germany and the US have
been calculated by Inklaar et al. (2003a) and are based on the Eurostat Prodcom-database
and the US manufacturing census for 1997.
Before aggregating the UVRs, outliers were removed from the Prodcom-database.8 For
the comparison between Germany and Sweden products with deviation more then 200%
and less than 75% of the EU average9 were removed. For the comparisons between
Germany and the US products with deviations more that 100 percent and less than 50%
of the EU average were removed. The reason for allowing a larger boundary for Germany
and Sweden is that Sweden is a smaller country with an economy characterized by a high
degree of specialization.10 Moreover, some product groups were deleted since it was
obvious that the product groups were not comparable across countries.11
The quantity of the Swedish product group Radio transmission apparatus with reception
apparatus (Prodcom 32201170) is missing. Since this product group has significant
importance for the RTC industry (ISIC 32) an estimation of the quantity has been made.
Table 1 shows the values of gross output and quantity for the Radio transmission
apparatus with reception apparatus (Prodcom12 32201170) divided into three different
subgroups. Quantity data only exists for the subgroup Transmission apparatus,
8 To remove outliers is a standard procedure in calculations of unit value ratios.
9 The average of the EU is based on at least four EU countries.
10 If a larger boundary is not used for Sweden and Germany, a very large number of product groups would
be removed since Sweden has a very specialized economy compared to the EU average.
11 For example, the product group Other machines and appliances for testing materials (Prodcom
33206259) was dropped since it was obvious that it contained different products that were not comparable
between Sweden and Germany.
12 Prodcom is a classification code for industry products at the 8-digit industry level.
8
incorporating reception apparatus, for cellular networks "mobile telephones" (CN13
85252091). It is therefore assumed that the Radio transmission apparatus with reception
apparatus (Prodcom 32201170) has the same gross output/quantity ratio as this subgroup.
This assumption appears to suggest that apples should be compared with oranges.
However, the intuition behind this assumption is that the production value for Radio
transmission apparatus with reception apparatus does not differ very much whether it is
used for radio-telephony, radio-broadcasting, television or cellular networks. This view is
supported by officials at the Swedish company Ericsson that is the largest supplier of
Radio, transmission apparatus with reception apparatus (Prodcom 32201170). According
to specialists14 at Ericsson the prices and technical specifications are approximately the
same for the two largest subgroups15 in table 1 (i.e. CN 85252091 and CN 85252099).
2.3 Productivity level results
2.3.1 Unit value ratio results
Table 2 and 3 present the results for the calculations of the unit value ratios. The unit
value ratios for 18 manufacturing industries in Sweden and Germany are shown in table
2. In total there were 802 matches between product groups in manufacturing. Food
products (ISIC 15–16), Wood and products of wood and cork (ISIC 20), Paper products
(ISIC 21) and Radio, television and communication equipment (ISIC 32) are the
industries with the highest coverage ratios. Office accounting and computing machinery
(ISIC 30), Medical, precision and optical instrument (ISIC 33) and Other transport
equipment (ISIC 35) have low coverage ratios. Medical precision and optical instrument
(ISIC 33) has the highest UVR with 15.83 SEK/EUR, while Office accounting and
computing machinery has the lowest with 5.83 SEK/EUR. For manufacturing the Fisher16
13 CN stands for Combined Nomenclature and is a classification code for industry products that is used by
Statistics Sweden. The CN code is compatible with the Prodcom classification code.
14 Interview with Olle Zimmerman 2004-01-13.
15 The radio, transmission apparatus with reception apparatus for civil aircrafts is such a small part of the
total production value of the industry that the assumed price has a very small effect on the total gross
output/quantity ratio for the total Radio, transmission with reception apparatus (Prodcom 32301170).
16 The Fisher exchange rate is derived by taking the square root of the product of the Paasche exchange rate
and the Laspeyres exchange rate.
9
exchange rate is 9.41 SEK/EUR which is higher than the average exchange rate of 8.65
SEK/EUR in 1997.
Inklaar et al. (2003a) also provide estimates of unit value ratios for manufacturing in
Sweden and Germany. Their results are based on 250 matches compared to 802 for the
study presented here. Moreover, the coverage ratios for Sweden are higher for all
industries except Chemicals (ISIC 22).17 The unit value ratios estimates for different
industries do not differ much between the results in this article and those by Inklaar et al.
However, there is a large difference for Medical precision and optical instrument (ISIC
33). In table 2 the UVR is 15.83 SEK/EUR for Medical precision and optical instrument,
while it is only 7.18 SEK/EUR in Inklaar et al. One reason for the difference is that
Inklaar et al’s UVR estimates are based on 3 matches, while the results in table 2 are
based on 16 matches.
Table 3 presents the estimates of the unit value ratios for Germany and the US. Food
products (ISIC 15–16), Textile, clothing, leather and footwear (ISIC 17–19), Paper
products (ISIC 21) and Basic metals (ISIC 27) have high coverage ratios. The lowest
coverage ratios are found for Printing and publishing (ISIC 22), Fabricated metal
products (ISIC 28) and Other transport equipment (ISIC 35). Printing and publishing
(ISIC 22) has the highest UVR with 2.12 Dollar/EUR and Textile clothing, leather and
footwear (ISIC 17–19) has the lowest with 0.66 Dollar/EUR. The Fisher exchange rate
for the whole manufacturing industry is 1.11 Dollar/EUR.
2.3.2 Productivity level benchmark results for 1997
Table 4 reports the labor productivity levels18 for the benchmark year 1997. The
differences in labor productivity level among industries within the same country depend
heavily on the capital intensity among industries. Therefore the interesting results are the
differences in relative productivity in the same industry across countries. According to
table 4 the Swedish Chemicals (ISIC 24) industry had the highest labor productivity level
17 For Chemicals the difference in coverage ratio is 5 percentage points between the result in table 2 and
Inklaar et al (2003a).
18 In this paper labor productivity is defined as value added per number of persons engaged.
10
relative to Germany and the US. Paper products (ISIC 21) also had very high levels of
labor productivity relative to Germany and the US. The Swedish manufacturing recycling
(ISIC 36–37) industry had the lowest labor productivity level relative to Germany, while
manufacturing recycling (ISIC 36–37) and RTC (ISIC 32) had the lowest productivity
level relative to the US. The highest labor productivity level for Germany relative to the
US was found for Printing and publishing (ISIC 22). The highest labor productivity level
in the US relative to Germany was found for RTC.
3. Extending labor productivity levels by growth rates
3.1 Time series data
3.1.1 Data description
The results of the relative productivity level for the benchmark year (1997) can be
extended to other years by using labor productivity growth rates (based on value added in
fixed prices). Labor productivity growth rates are calculated by using time series with
value added, value added deflators19 and employment. The labor productivity growth
rates are then used to calculate the change in relative productivity performance based on
the benchmark year. The Swedish time series data has been taken from the Swedish
National Accounts (Statistics Sweden 2003b). Due to changes in industrial classification
and the introduction of the new 1993 system of National Accounts (SNA), the Swedish
data only covers the period 1993–2001. This limits the estimation of the relative labor
productivity levels at a detailed industry level20 to the period 1993–2000. However, for
total manufacturing it has been possible to link time series of value added, value added
deflators and employment of the Swedish National Accounts with industry data from the
STAN database for 1980–1992 (OECD 2001b). This makes it possible to present
estimates of the productivity level in Swedish manufacturing for the period 1980–2001.
The data for Germany and the US are based on the 60-industry database (GGDC 2003).
19 A definition of value added deflators and how they are calculated can be found in section 4.2.
20 This paper presents estimates for most manufacturing industries at the 2-digit ISIC industry level.
11
Furthermore, all aggregation for the US and Germany have been based on Törnqvist
weights.21
3.1.2 Price deflators
One of the major problems with comparing productivity growth and levels across
countries is to construct similar and reliable deflators. All three countries use double
deflation22 in order to calculate the value added in fixed prices for the production side of
the economy. Double deflation means that the production value (gross output) is deflated
with an output price index23, while intermediate inputs are deflated with an input price
index. Since double deflation is used in all three countries there should not be a major
problem to compare the value added growth rates across countries. However, the value
added in fixed prices for Sweden is based on a Laspeyres volume index with moving
average based on year t–1, while value added in fixed prices for Germany and the US are
based on the Törnqvist index with moving averages based on the average of the year t–1
and t. The way these indexes are weighted influences the value added deflator. This is
further discussed in appendix 2. Appendix 2 also shows how the Swedish data is
approximated to provide estimates that closely approximate estimations based on
Törnqvist weights.
Another major problem when comparing productivity levels for different industries is the
different policies used by Statistical Offices to account for quality changes. In the US
hedonic price indexes are used extensively to account for the quality changes for the ICT-
producing industries. Sweden only uses hedonic price indexes for imports of computers,
while Germany does not use any hedonic measures (Scarpetta et al. 2000). Due to the
differences of price deflation in the ICT-producing industries I will use the US ICT-
deflators for the ICT-producing industries in Sweden and Germany. By applying the US
ICT-deflators also on Sweden and Germany one implicitly assumes that the industry
structure and price changes for the ICT-producing industry would be identical across
21 See appendix 2.
22 A thorough description of how value added price deflators are calculated and its implications for
productivity growth is made in section 4.2.
23 In this article gross output price deflators are based on producer price indexes.
12
countries. The empirical validity of these assumptions is questionable. In section 4, I
therefore analyze the effects of relaxing these assumptions on the productivity
development in RTC.
3.2 Productivity level results for the manufacturing industry
3.2.1 Total manufacturing
The labor productivity level estimates24 for total manufacturing for Germany, Sweden
and the US are presented in figure 1. The results in figure 1 indicate that the productivity
level in Swedish manufacturing was well below that of Germany and the US at the
beginning of the 1980s. During the 1980s Sweden caught up slightly with Germany,
while the productivity gap between Sweden and the US increased. During the late 1980s
and the beginning of the 1990s relative productivity levels remained unchanged.
However, from 1993 to 2001 Sweden was catching up with Germany and the US. In
1995 Sweden overtook Germany in terms of labor productivity and the productivity gap
between the two countries was increasing during the period 1995–2000. Moreover, labor
productivity gap between Sweden and the US was only 5 percent in 2001 compared to 33
percent in 1993.
The results for total manufacturing seem to correspond well with the growth patterns of
total manufacturing presented by Lind (2003). However, Inklaar et al. (2003b) present
estimates of labor productivity levels in manufacturing for EU countries and the US.
According to the results by Inklaar et al. the labor productivity level in manufacturing in
Sweden increased from 93.5 percent of the US level in 1979–81 to 99.3 percent in 1994–
1996. However, labor productivity fell to 86.6 percent for 1999–01. The fall in Swedish
labor productivity for manufacturing in the late 1990s is not supported by the results
presented here. One possible explanation is that Inklaar et al. use harmonized US
24 The labor productivity level results for total manufacturing are based on domestic deflators.
13
deflators for ICT producing industries,25 while the results in figure 1 are based on
national deflators.
3.2.2 Industry level
Estimates of labor productivity levels at the industry level (2-digit ISIC level) are less
certain than those of total manufacturing. It is important to keep in mind that the results
presented for the industry level are based on the assumption that the unit value ratios also
apply for unmatched product groups. This implies that the result for industries with low
coverage ratios must be interpreted with caution (see table 2 and 3). Nevertheless, labor
productivity level estimates for different manufacturing industries at the more
disaggregated level are important in order to understand the dynamics of productivity
changes in manufacturing. Table 5 and 6 present labor productivity estimates at the
industry level for Germany, Sweden and the US for the years 1993 and 2000. These
estimates were calculated by extending the benchmark estimates for 1997 with labor
productivity growth rates (in fixed prices).
The results in table 5 show that in 1993 Sweden had its highest labor productivity level
relative to Germany and the US in Chemicals (ISIC 24). Labor productivity in this
industry was approximately 80 percent higher than in the US and Germany. Paper
products (ISIC 21), Fabricated metal products (ISIC 28) and Office, accounting and
computing machinery (ISIC 30) were other industries where relative productivity was
high in Sweden. Electric machinery and computing (ISIC 31), Radio, television and
communication equipment (ISIC 32), Motor vehicles, trailers and semi-trailers (ISIC 34)
and Manufacturing recycling (ISIC 36–37) were industries where Swedish relative
productivity was low compared to Germany and the US.26
In 2000, Chemicals (ISIC 24) and Paper products (ISIC 21) still had the highest labor
productivity relative to Germany and the US. Radio, television and communication
equipment (ISIC 32), Motor vehicles, trailers and semi-trailers (ISIC 34) and
25 The use of different value added deflators will be discussed in detail in section 4.2.
26 It is important to keep in mind that labor productivity level results for industries with low coverage ratios
must be interpreted with caution.
14
Manufacturing recycling (ISIC 36–37) had the lowest labor productivity levels relative to
the US, while Electrical machinery and computing (ISIC 31), Medical, precision and
optical instrument (ISIC 33) and Other transport equipment (ISIC 36–37) had the lowest
productivity level relative to Germany.
Tables 4–6 show that the relative labor productivity level for Swedish manufacturing
industries throughout the period 1993–2000 was high for Chemicals (ISIC 21) and Paper
products (ISIC 21). However, it was not these industries that had the highest growth
rates throughout the period. As documented by Edquist and Henrekson (2001) it was the
ICT-producing industries that experienced the highest growth during the latter part of the
1990s in Germany, Sweden and the US.
Tables 4–6 also indicate that there was a relative increase in the labor productivity level
of the Swedish RTC industry relative to Germany and the US for the period 1993–1997.
However, from 1997 to 2000 the German RTC industry caught up with and forged ahead
of its Swedish counterpart in terms of labor productivity level. The same pattern can be
found for the US RTC industry, even though relative labor productivity was higher in the
US throughout the period 1993–2000. Lind (2003) argues that RTC has been crucial for
economic growth in Swedish manufacturing. The results in table 4–6 do not imply that
the growth rate was low in the Swedish RTC industry for the period 1997–2000. Instead
the results indicate that for the period 1997–2000 labor productivity growth for this
industry was higher in both Germany and the US compared to Sweden. From 1997–2000
Sweden lost much of its labor productivity edge in RTC compared to Germany and the
US.
There is a well known hypothesis that productivity growth rates vary inversely with
productivity level. This has to do with the level of technology embodied in a country’s
capital stock. When a leader in technology invests in new capital the accompanying
productivity increase is limited by the advance of knowledge between the time when the
old capital was installed and the time it is replaced (Abramovitz 1986). However, a
lagging country has the opportunity to embark on a catching-up process by borrowing
superior techniques from the more advanced economies. This implies that the larger the
15
gap between leader and follower the greater the follower’s potential for productivity
growth.
This catching-up hypothesis can also be applied to industries. Figures 2 and 3 show the
correlation of the difference in the Swedish productivity level relative to Germany and
the US in 1993 and the average Swedish labor productivity growth rate for industries at
the 2-digit ISIC level. The results in figures 2 and 3 indicate a negative correlation.
However, the correlation evidence is not very strong. One possible reason to that there is
no strong correlation is that the period investigated is very short. Many articles that
investigate the catching up hypothesis use time periods of at least 25 years. There are also
several other reasons why there is no catching up at the industry level. According to
Gerschenkron (1962) different countries have different productive and organizational
structures of industry. For example, Hansson and Henrekson (1994) found that
competition could explain that the Swedish tradadables sector was catching up 1970–85,
but not the nontradables sector.
4. ICT deflators and relative labor productivity
4.1 ICT deflators
The results for the ICT-producing industries presented in tables 4–6 are based on the US
ICT deflators (see section 3.1.2). Applying the US deflators for all three countries
automatically assumes that the industry structure of the Swedish and German ICT-
producing industries are identical to the US and that the price decline for all products
would be the same in all three countries. These assumptions are not empirically valid. In
this section, I will therefore try to relax these assumptions by comparing deflators for the
three countries. An interesting question then is what effect the use of different value
added deflators has on measured productivity?
16
Table 7 shows the deflators based on the calculations from each country’s statistical
office.27 The approximation of the Swedish deflators to the German and US deflators are
described in appendix 2. Table 7 shows that the US deflators for Office, accounting and
computing machinery (ISIC 30) are m7uch more negative than those for Sweden and
Germany. Interestingly, the German deflators are more negative than the Swedish ones
for Office, accounting and computing machinery. One reason to this could be that the
structure of the industry is very different in the two countries. For example, the US
Office, accounting and computing machinery industry could be producing more
semiconductors and microprocessors, while the corresponding industry in Sweden
produces other types of computer equipment. For RTC (ISIC 32) the Swedish deflators
are more negative than both the US and German deflators for all years except for 1998
when the US deflator is slightly more negative than the Swedish one. The deflators for
Electric machinery and computing (ISIC 31) and for Medical, precision and optical
instruments (ISIC 33) do not differ as much as the other two ICT-producing industries in
the three countries.
What effects does the use of different deflators have for the estimates of relative labor
productivity? Table 8 presents the result for relative labor productivity for Sweden and
Germany when different ICT-deflators are used. The results indicate that the use of
different deflators have large impacts on labor productivity levels for Office, accounting
and computing machinery (ISIC 30) and for Radio, television and communication
equipment (ISIC 32). If the US deflators are used for the German Office, accounting and
computing machinery industry, while the Swedish deflators are applied to the same
industry in Sweden, this results in a substantial decline in the relative labor productivity
level for the Swedish Office, accounting and computing machinery industry. According
to table 8 the labor productivity level for Office, accounting and computing machinery
went from being 18 times higher than the German level in 1993 to becoming only one
half of the German labor productivity level in 2000. There is no empirical evidence that
can justify these results. Nevertheless, the results clearly show how sensitive productivity
calculations are to large differences in value added deflators over a longer time period. In
the other two cases (see table 8), the productivity level in the Swedish Office, accounting
27 An exact description of how value added price deflators are calculated is presented in section 4.2.
17
and computing machinery industry remains higher relative to the same industry in
Germany for the period 1993–2000.
For RTC the Swedish labor productivity level increases throughout the period 1993–2000
relative to Germany when country specific deflators are used. When the US deflators are
applied for Germany and the country-specific ones for Sweden, the result shows that
Swedish relative labor productivity increased for the period 1993–1997. After 1998 there
is a decline in the Swedish relative labor productivity level and in 2000 the higher
productivity level in Sweden has almost disappeared. When the US deflators are applied
on both countries, there is a similar decline in the Swedish relative labor productivity
level after 1998. For the year 2000 the relative labor productivity level is only 93 percent
of the German labor productivity level. On the other hand, if country specific deflators
are used for both countries the productivity level increases throughout the period 1993–
2000.28
The results presented in table 8 show that the use of different deflators for the ICT-
producing industries has a large influence on the relative labor productivity level between
Sweden and Germany. Nonetheless, the results in table 8 strongly suggest that the labor
productivity level for the Swedish RTC (ISIC 32) industry relative to Germany has
decreased since 1998. This does not imply that the productivity growth rate for this
industry has been slow in Sweden since 1998, but rather that the Swedish RTC industry
has lagged in labor productivity relative to Germany since 1998.
4.2 A detailed investigation of the Radio television and
communication equipment industry
During the period 1993–2000 labor productivity growth in the Swedish RTC industry
was 47 percent per year. Figures 4–6 illustrate the development of the RTC industry in
Germany, Sweden and the US. Figure 4 shows that gross output in the Swedish RTC
industry as a share of gross output in manufacturing, increased from 4 percent in 1993 to
28 To compare labor productivity growth rates for Germany and Sweden with country specific value added
deflators is very problematic, since Sweden uses other types of quality adjustments than Germany (see
section 3.1.2).
18
12 percent in 2000. The corresponding figures for Germany and the US were
approximately 2 and 6 percent 1993–2001. As illustrated by figure 5 the value added in
the Swedish RTC industry as a share of value added in manufacturing also increased
considerably during the 1990s. However, the corresponding share for the US RTC
industry was higher in 1993–2000. Figure 6 shows that the number of persons engaged in
the Swedish RTC industry as a share of total manufacturing increased from around 4
percent in 1993 to 6 percent in 2000. The number of persons engaged in RTC related
service industries such as data-consulting and data-services also increased considerably
during the 1990s (Johansson 2004).
Figures 4–6 show that the Swedish RTC industry became increasingly important for the
Swedish economy during the 1990s. It is therefore crucial that the productivity
development in the Swedish RTC industry is correctly measured. Table 8 showed that the
use of different deflators for the RTC industry can have enormous effects on productivity
growth measures. By using US deflators also for the German and Swedish ICT-producing
industries one implicitly assumes that the structure of the ICT-producing industries is the
same in all three countries and that the price fluctuations of output and intermediate input
prices are identical. In this section, I investigate what happens with the deflators for the
Swedish and the US RTC industry when these assumptions are relaxed.
When comparing ICT deflators across countries it is crucial to understand how the value
added in different countries is deflated. Both the Swedish and the US National Accounts
are based on double deflation to arrive at a value added in fixed prices (see section 3.1.2).
Double deflation implies that the values of gross output and intermediate input are
deflated separately with an output price index and an intermediate input price index,
respectively. These two series are then used to arrive at value added in fixed prices. More
specifically, value added in fixed prices can be defined as an average of the price change
in gross output )
ln
ln
(t
P
Output
and the price change of intermediate inputs )
ln
ln
(t
P
Input
. The
price change of intermediate inputs is weighted by the share of intermediate inputs in
gross outputs )( QP
MP
Output
Input and the entire expression is multiplied by the inverted share of
19
value-added in gross output )( VAP
QP
VA
Output (OECD 2001a). The exact relation for the value
added price deflator and intermediate input and output prices is shown in the following
expression:
=
dt
Pd
QP
MP
dt
Pd
VAP
QP
dt
Pd Input
Output
InputOutput
VA
Output
VA lnln
ln (4.1)
Equation 4.1 shows that the price change in intermediate inputs has a large influence on
the value added price deflator if the proportion of intermediate input as a share of total
output is high.
Figure 7 shows the gross output and intermediate input price deflators for RTC in
Sweden and the US. According to figure 7 the US gross output and the intermediate input
prices decreased more rapidly than the corresponding gross output and input prices for
Sweden. The average price deflator for the Swedish intermediate inputs was zero, while
the average price deflator for the US intermediate inputs was –0.05 for the period 1994–
2001. For the output prices the average price deflator for Sweden was –0.10 and for the
US –0.18. For which products have the price deflator for the intermediate input prices
and for the output prices decreased more in the US compared to Sweden?
To answer this question I investigate the price deflators for RTC at a more disaggregated
industry level. At the 3-digit ISIC industry level, RTC consists of the following three
industries: Electronic valves and tubes29 (ISIC 321), Telecommunication equipment
(ISIC 322), Radio and television receivers (ISIC 323). Figures 8–10 compare the gross
output price deflator for these three industries in Sweden and the US for the period 1994–
2001. For Sweden there exists two price indexes for the three industries. One price index
is published by the Department of Prices and Consumption and the other is based on the
National Accounts.30 The difference between the two price indexes is that the price index
29 By and large, Electronic valves and tubes (ISIC 321) consists of the production of semiconductors and
microprocessors.
30 The Department of Prices and Consumptions and the National Accounts are both Departments at
Statistics Sweden.
20
published by the Department of Prices and Consumption is based on a product mix that is
lagged two years, while the price index in the National Accounts is not.31 Moreover, the
output price index in the National Accounts is an industry index, which means that it
includes both goods and services, while the index published by the Department of Prices
and Consumption is a product index which only represents goods.
Figure 8 shows that the US gross output price deflator for Electronic valves and tubes
(ISIC 321) was much more negative than the corresponding Swedish deflator throughout
the period 1994–2001. Figure 9 shows that the Swedish gross output price deflator for
Telecommunication equipment (ISIC 322) differs considerably for the years 1997–2001
depending on which price index that is used. For the years 1997–2000 the difference is
approximately 10 percent per year. According to the Department of National Accounts
these differences are due to the fact that the Department of Prices and Consumption uses
a product mix that is lagged two years. However, it is difficult to accept that this would
explain the whole difference of approximately 10 percentage points per year 1997–2000
between the two output price indexes.32 According to the price index published by the
Department of Prices and Consumption the Swedish gross output prices for
Telecommunication equipment (ISIC 322) has declined less than the corresponding US
deflator 1997–2000. However, the price index in the National Accounts suggests that the
Swedish price deflator has been approximately the same as the US deflator. Figure 10
indicates that for the period 1994–2001 the Swedish gross output price deflator for Radio
and television receivers (ISIC 323) has been more negative than the corresponding US
deflator.
Intermediate input price deflators for Sweden are not available at the 3-digit ISIC
industry level.33 Figure 11 shows the US intermediate input price deflators for Electronic
valves and tubes (ISIC 321), Telecommunication equipment (ISIC 322) and Radio and
31 On February 9th 2004 the Department of National Accounts at Statistics Sweden decided to release their
output price indexes for the RTC industry at the 3-digit level. The output price indexes published by the
Department of National Accounts had not been public at the 3-digit level and they were released after a
close investigation of an earlier draft of this paper by officials at Statistics Sweden.
32 One explanation to the large difference between the two indexes could be that the Swedish
telecommunication company Ericsson decided to outsource the manufacturing of cell phones abroad during
this period.
33 Statistics Sweden does not publish input price deflators for the 3-digit ISIC level.
21
television receivers (ISIC 323) 1991–2001. For the period 1991–1995 the intermediate
input price deflators for all three industries were close to zero. However, for the period
1996–2001 the price deflators have become more negative in all three industries. The
decrease has been more rapid for Electronic valves and tubes (ISIC 321) and
Telecommunication equipment (ISIC 322) compared to Radio and television receivers
(ISIC 323).
One possible explanation to the larger decrease in the intermediate input and output price
deflators in the US (see figure 7) is that the US systematically uses hedonic adjustments
for semiconductors and microprocessors. This implies that the improved quality in
semiconductors and microprocessors is considered when the price changes are estimated.
Since the invention of the transistor in 1948 there has been an extraordinary increase in
the capacity of semiconductors. According to “Moore’s” law microprocessors are halved
in price and double in capacity every 18 months. In Sweden hedonic price adjustments
are not used to take the quality improvements of semiconductors and microprocessors
into account. This could be the reason why the gross output Swedish price deflators for
Electronic valves and tubes have not decreased as much as in the US (see figure 8).
Since semiconductors are important intermediate inputs in Telecommunication
equipment (ISIC 322) and Radio and television receivers (ISIC 323), it is likely that the
use of hedonic price adjustments for semiconductors also influences the input deflators
for these industries. The fact that Sweden is not using hedonic adjustments for
semiconductors and the lack of Swedish price data for intermediate inputs at the 3-digit
ISIC level for RTC cause problems for accurately comparing price deflators between
Sweden and the US.
Triplett (1996) has shown that if the output price decline in the semiconductor producing
industry is underestimated this means that the intermediate input price decline in
computers is also underestimated. Thus, if the output price decline in the semiconductor
producing industry is overestimated, the intermediate input price decline in computers
would be overestimated. This means that if all intermediate inputs where produced
domestically, the measured productivity for the computer industry would be correct
22
despite the incorrect measurement of prices in the semiconductor producing industry.
Though, the measured productivity would be incorrect for less aggregated industries
within the computer industry such as the semiconductor industry. If the findings by
Triplett are applied on the RTC industry this means that if all semiconductors that are
used in the RTC industry also were produced domestically by the RTC industry the
productivity for the whole RTC industry would be unaffected if the price decline of
semiconductors were underestimated. However, the reasoning by Triplett is only correct
as long as all semiconductors are produced domestically.
Figure 12 shows the value of imports of Electronic valves and tubes as a share of the
total value of production and imports. According to figure 12 approximately 75 percent
of the Electronic components that were used in Swedish RTC industry were imported in
1995–2001. Hence, Triplett’s results do not hold for the Swedish RTC industry. If the
estimated prices of semiconductors are incorrect, the effect on intermediate inputs is
much larger since approximately 75 percent of the electronic components that are used as
intermediate inputs in the RTC industry are imported. How would the Swedish value
added price deflators change if hedonic price adjustments were made also for
semiconductors in Sweden? In order to give an accurate answer to this question it would
be necessary to have price data at a very detailed product level for Sweden and the US.
This data is not available for Sweden due to secrecy. Nevertheless, table 9 and 10 provide
estimates of how value added deflators would change if hedonic price indexes also were
used for semiconductors in Sweden.
Table 9 and 10 shows the recalculation of the Swedish value added deflators under the
assumption that the Swedish intermediate input prices for Electronic valves and tubes
(ISIC 321), Telecommunication equipment (ISIC 322) and Radio and television receivers
(ISIC 323) are the same as for the corresponding industries in the US. The intuition
behind this assumption is that price changes of all intermediate inputs except
semiconductors would be the same in the US and Sweden. It is true that prices vary
between different markets, however a large part of the intermediate inputs in the RTC
industry is purchased globally at world market prices. Moreover, it is also assumed that
the Swedish gross output price deflators for Electronic valves and tubes (ISIC 321) are
23
equal to the corresponding industry in the US. The intuition behind this assumption is
that if hedonic prices were implemented in Sweden for semiconductors and
microprocessors the price decline in the semiconductor producing industry would equal
that in the US. This is a plausible assumption since semiconductors are often priced and
purchased at world market prices (Triplett 1996).
Neither Sweden nor the US use hedonic price indexes for estimating gross output price
deflators for Telecommunication equipment (ISIC 322) and Radio and television
receivers (ISIC 323). Therefore, the calculations in table 9 and 10 for these industries are
based on domestic price indexes for Sweden. Gross output price deflators for
Telecommunication equipment (ISIC 322) and Radio and television receivers (ISIC 323)
in table 9 are based on the price indexes by the Department of Prices and Consumption,
while the price deflators in table 10 are based on the price indexes in the National
Accounts. Finally, the prices are weighted by the specific industry structure of the
Swedish RTC industry (measured as shares of production in gross output and
intermediate inputs at factor costs).
Not surprisingly, the results of the recalculated deflators presented in table 9 and 10
differ widely from the results of the official value added deflators presented in table 7.
The largest difference can be noticed for the period 1997–2000. The recalculated value
added price deflators in table 9 are even positive for the years 1997, 1998 and 2000. The
recalculated value added deflators in table 10 are all negative, but less negative than the
value added deflators in table 7. The reason for the large difference between the deflators
in table 7, 9 and 10 is that the method to calculate the value added price deflator is very
sensitive to the development of the intermediate input34 price deflators. The reason why
Sweden is much more sensitive to price changes in intermediate inputs than the US is
because the intermediate input/gross output ratio for the Swedish RTC industry is much
larger compared to the US.
Figure 13 shows the intermediate input/gross output ratio for the Swedish and the US
RTC industry 1993–2001. During the period investigated the Swedish intermediate
34 Semiconductors and microprocessors are important intermediate inputs in RTC.
24
input/gross output ratio has been constantly higher than the US. Since 1998 the Swedish
ratio has increased dramatically and in 2001 intermediate inputs exceeded the total gross
outputs. Hence, value added in current prices was negative. This development is due to
the increased outsourcing by the Swedish telecommunication company Ericsson. In
Sweden a very large part of the total output of RTC is produced by Ericsson. This implies
that the bulk of intermediate input prices that are reported to Statistics Sweden are
determined by the pricing of one single firm. Semiconductors are often purchased and
priced on the world market. However, if semiconductors or other intermediate inputs are
produced by Ericsson abroad and then imported and used in the Swedish RTC industry,
there is a risk that the internal pricing by Ericsson would not reflect world market prices
of semiconductors and other inputs. It is unclear to what extent Ericsson produces its own
intermediate inputs abroad. However, if a large share of Ericsson’s inputs are produced
abroad by Ericsson and imported, there is a possibility that price changes of
semiconductors and other inputs would be measured incorrectly. This would result in
incorrect productivity estimates for RTC in Sweden.
The value added deflators presented in table 9 and 10 have a great impact on how the
productivity growth in the Swedish RTC industry is measured. Figure 14 shows the labor
productivity growth in the RTC industry 1994–2000 with the official value added price
deflators (see table 7) and the recalculated deflators (see table 9 and 10). The results
show that the productivity growth differs widely depending on which deflators that are
being used. The price deflators based on the price indexes published by the Department
for Prices and Consumption (see table 10) give the largest difference in productivity
growth compared to the official deflators. However, the difference in productivity growth
is also large when the deflators based on the price indexes in the National Accounts are
used instead of the official deflators. The annual productivity growth becomes 20 percent
instead of 35 percent 1997–2000 if the recalculated deflators based on the price indexes
in the National Accounts are used instead of the official deflators.
The use of different deflators also has implications for the growth in total manufacturing.
Figure 15 shows the growth rate of total manufacturing with official and recalculated
deflators. For the period 1997–2000 the growth rates of total manufacturing would be
25
considerably smaller if the recalculated deflators are used. The effect on productivity
growth in manufacturing is smaller if the recalculated deflators based on the price
indexes in the National Accounts are used instead of the deflators based on the price
indexes published by the Department of Prices and Consumption. However, in 1998 the
productivity growth in manufacturing would be about one third lower with the
recalculated value added deflators based on the price indexes in the National Accounts.
The relative productivity development in Sweden is also affected by the use of different
value added deflators. Figure 16 shows the relative productivity with the recalculated
deflators based on the price indexes published by the Department of Prices and
Consumption for the period 1993–2000. The conclusion is that Sweden has only been
growing at the same rate as in the US. The catching up effect in the end of the 1990s (see
table 1) has been eroded.
5. Conclusions
I have used the industry-of-origin methodology to investigate the development of labor
productivity levels in Swedish manufacturing relative to manufacturing in Germany and
the US. The results show that Swedish manufacturing productivity caught up with levels
in Germany and the US during the 1990s. In 1995 Sweden overtook Germany in terms of
labor productivity level and continued to catch up with the US throughout the period
1995–2000. Moreover, Chemicals (ISIC 24) and Paper products (ISIC 21) had the
highest relative labor productivity compared to Germany and the US in 1993–2000.
Evidence of the increasing importance of the RTC industry for total manufacturing in
Sweden during the 1990s was also presented. For RTC, labor productivity increased
substantially in Sweden relative to Germany and the US in 1993–1998. However, for the
period 1998–2000 labor productivity of the Swedish RTC industry declined relative to
Germany and the US. This suggests that the productivity growth of RTC was slower in
Sweden than in the US and Germany 1998–2000.
The results of the labor productivity levels for Office accounting and computing
machinery and RTC turn out to be very sensitive to the choice of value added price
26
deflators. Value added price deflators are used by Statistical Offices to take price and
quality changes into account. Moreover, value added price deflators differ widely among
industries and countries. The Swedish value added price deflators for RTC was
considerably more negative compared to the German and US deflators throughout the
period 1993–2000.35
One explanation to why value added price deflators are more negative in Sweden than in
the US is that the US Statistical Agencies systematically use hedonic adjustments for
semiconductors and microprocessors, while Statistics Sweden is not. Hedonic price
indexes take the improved quality in semiconductors and microprocessors into
consideration when the price changes are estimated. Moreover, semiconductors and
microprocessors are important inputs in the Swedish RTC industry. Calculations of the
Swedish value added deflators based on the US price development for semiconductors
and microprocessors, show that the productivity growth in the RTC industry becomes
considerably lower. This suggest that the spectacular labor productivity growth exceeding
35 percent per year in 1996–2000 for the Swedish RTC industry is partly an artefact.
Moreover, the results show that it is dangerous to draw conclusions from international
productivity comparisons in industries characterized by rapidly changing technology.
The overestimation of labor productivity growth for Swedish RTC also has important
effects for productivity growth in total manufacturing. If the recalculated value added
deflators for RTC are used in order to calculate labor productivity growth rates for total
manufacturing, the productivity performance is less impressive than what is suggested by
official data. Using the revised estimates Sweden caught up with German and US labor
productivity levels during the first half of the 1990s. However, for the period 1997–2000
the labor productivity level was lower than suggested by official data. From a policy
perspective this is an important result, because it shows that the productivity growth
miracle in Swedish manufacturing during the late 1990s is partly an artefact.
35 Except for the year 1998.
27
6. References
Abramovitz, Moses (1986), “Catching Up, Forging Ahead, and Falling Behind”, Journal
of Economic History, Vol. 46, No. 2, pp. 385–406.
Apel, Mikael and Lindström, Tomas (2003), “Informationsteknologins betydelse för den
svenska produktivtetsutvecklingen – ännu en pusselbit”, Ekonomisk Debatt, Vol. 31, No.
5, pp. 29–37.
van Ark, Bart and Pilat, Dirk (1993), “Productivity Levels in Germany, Japan, and the
United States: Differences and Causes”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity:
Microeconomics 2, Washington D.C.
van Ark, Bart (1996), “Issues in Measuring and International Comparison Issues of
Productivity – An Overview”, OECD Expert Workshop on Productivity: International
Comparison and Measurement Issues, OECD, Paris.
van Ark, Bart and Timmer, Marcel (2002), “Measuring Productivity Levels – A reader”,
OECD Working Paper, Paris.
Council of Economic Advisers (2003), Economic Report of the President, United States
Government Printing Office, Washington D.C.
Edquist, Harald and Henrekson, Magnus (2001), “Solowparadoxen och den nya
ekonomin”, Ekonomisk Debatt, Vol. 29, No. 6, pp. 409-419.
Edquist, Harald and Henrekson, Magnus (2002), “Kommer IKT-revolutionen även att att
lyfta europas ekonomier?” in Litan, Robert E. and Rivlin, Alice M. (2002), Bortom
dot.com-företagen, SNS Förlag, Stockholm.
Europroms (2001), European production and market statistics: EU-15
Prodcom/Combined Nomenclature, Eurostat, Luxemburg.
Gerschenkron, Alexander (1962), Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective,
Harvard University Press, Cambridge (Massachusetts).
Groningen Growth and Development Centre (GGDC) (2003), 60-industry database,
Groningen. Available online: http://www.ggdc.net
IMF (2003), PPI Manual, Washington DC. Available online: http://www.imf.org
Hansson, Pär and Henrekson, Magnus (1994), “Catching up in industrialized countries: a
disaggregated study”, Journal of International Trade & Economic Development, Vol. 3,
No.2, pp. 129–145.
Inklaar, Robert, Stokes, Lucy, Stuivenwold, Edwin, Timmer, Marcel and Ypma, Gerard
(2003a), “Chapter VII Data Sources and Methodology” in O’Mahony, Mary and van Ark,
28
Bart (eds), EU Productivity and Competitiveness: A Sectoral Perspective. Can Europe
Resume the Catching-up Process? European Commission, Luxemburg.
Inklaar, Robert, O’Mahony, Mary, Robinson, Catherine and Timmer, Marcel (2003b),
“Chapter III Productivity and Competitiveness in the EU and the US” in O’Mahony,
Mary and van Ark, Bart (eds), EU Productivity and Competitiveness: A Sectoral
Perspective. Can Europe Resume the Catching-up Process? European Commission,
Luxemburg.
Johansson, Dan (2004), “Is small beautiful? The case of Swedish IT industry”
Entrepreneurship & Regional Development, forthcoming.
Lind, Daniel (2002), “Tillväxtens drivkrafter – Produktion och användande av
informationsteknologi i svensk ekonomi”, Ekonomisk Debatt, Vol. 30, No. 7, pp. 611-
619.
Lind, Daniel (2003), ”Svensk industriproduktivitet i ett internationellt perspektiv under
fyra decennier – vad kan vi lära oss av 1990-talet?”, Ekonomisk Debatt, Vol. 31, No. 5,
pp. 39–48.
Lundgren, Kurt and Wiberg, Anders (2000), “Solowparadoxen eller den nya ekonomin?”,
Ekonomisk Debatt, Vol. 28, No. 8, pp. 747-757.
MathWorld (2004), ”MathWorld – A Wolfram Web Resource”, Wolfram Research.
Available online: http://mathworld.wolfram.com
Monnikhof, Erik and van Ark, Bart (2002), “New Estimates of Labor productivity in the
Manufacturing Sectors of Czech Republic, Hungary and Poland”. Research
Memorandum GD-50, Groningen Growth and Development Centre.
Newsweek (2000), “Shining Stockholm”, February 7.
Nordhaus, William D. (1997) “Do Real-Output and Real-Wage Measures Capture
Reality? The History of Lighting Suggests Not,” in Bresnahan, Timothy F. and Gordon,
Robert J. (eds), The Economics of New Goods, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
OECD (2001a), OECD Productivity Manual: A Guide to the Measurement of Industry-
Level and Aggregate Productivity Growth, Directorate for Science, Technology and
Industry, Paris.
OECD (2001b), STAN Database, Paris
OECD (2002), ”Measuring the Information Economy”, OECD Working Paper, Paris.
OECD (2003), Structural Statistics for industry and Services Database, SourceOECD,
Paris.
29
Scarpetta, Stefano, Bassanini, Andrea, Pilat, Dirk and Schreyer, Paul (2000), “Economic
Growth in the OECD Area: Recent Trends at the Aggregate and Sectoral Level,”
Economics Depatement, Working Paper No. 248, OECD, Paris.
Statistics Sweden (2003a), Industrins varuproduktion (IVP), Stockholm. Available
online: http://www.scb.se
Statistics Sweden (2003b), National accounts 1993–2001, Stockholm. Available online:
http://www.scb.se
Statistics Sweden (2003c), Swedish Statistical Database; prices and consumption,
Stockholm. Available online: http://www.scb.se
Triplett (1996), “High-Tech Industry and Hedonic Price Indices”, in OECD, Industry
Productivity; International Comparisons and Measurement Issues, OECD, Paris.
United Nations Statistics Division (2000), International Standard Industrial Classification
of All Economic Activities, Third Revision, (ISIC, Rev.3). Available [online]:
http://esa.un.org/unsd/cr/family2.asp?Cl=2
30
Table 1 Values of gross output (in thousands of SEK) and quantity (number of
radio transmission apparatus) for the Swedish Radio transmission
apparatus with reception apparatus product group in 1997
Code Gross output Quantity
Radio-telegraphic and radio-telephonic
transmission apparatus, incorporating reception
apparatus, for civil aircraft
CN 85252010 1307438 n.a.
Transmission apparatus, incorporating reception
apparatus, for cellular networks “mobile
telephones”
CN 85252091 31779377 1270537
6
Transmission apparatus for radio-telephony,
radio-telegraphy, radio-broadcasting or television,
incorporating reception apparatus
CN 85252099 48538126 n.a.
Radio transmission apparatus with reception
apparatus
Prodcom 32301170 81624940 n.a.
Sources: Europroms (2001) and Statistics Sweden (2003a).
Notes: n.a. = not available. CN stands for combined nomenclature and is a classification code for industry
products that is used by Statistics Sweden. The CN code is compatible with the Prodcom classification
code.
31
Table 2 Number of matches, coverage ratios and unit value ratios for the
manufacturing industry in Sweden and Germany in 1997
Industry ISIC Number
of
matches
Percentage of output
matched
Unit value ratios SEK/EUR
Sweden Germany Laspeyres Paasche Fisher
Food products 15–16 188 79 64 10.19 9.38 9.78
Textile, clothing, leather and
footwear
17–19 91 29 2 11.10 6.99 8.81
Wood and products of wood
and cork
20 26 71 36 7.97 7.97 7.97
Paper products 21 49 54 48 9.34 7.23 8.22
Printing and publishing 22 14 39 37 12.58 10.16 11.31
Chemicals 24 78 14 16 10.89 6.20 9.59
Rubber and plastic products 25 24 23 11 9.28 9.92 9.59
Non-metallic mineral products 26 40 35 42 10.49 6.02 7.95
Basic metals 27 62 29 27 13.17 9.57 11.22
Fabricated metal products 28 33 11 10 7.76 5.30 6.41
Machinery and equipment 29 88 18 12 11.42 5.02 7.57
Office, accounting and
computing machinery
30 4 14 6 7.22 4.71 5.83
Electrical machinery and
computing
31 34 34 13 17.38 7.00 11.03
Radio, television and
communication equipment
32 10 74 23 10.06 9.33 9.69
Medical precision and optical
instruments
33 16 8 10 18.67 13.41 15.83
Motor vehicles, trailers and
semi-trailers
34 15 15 17 10.49 11.80 11.12
Other transport equipment 35 6 12 8 12.76 10.37 11.50
Manufacturing, recycling n.e.c 36 24 28 37 7.67 6.70 7.16
Total Manufacturing 802 37 25 10.75 8.24 9.41
Source: Europroms (2001) and own calculations.
Note: For an exact definition of the Laspeyres, Paasche and Fisher index see MathWorld (2004).
32
Table 3 Number of matches, coverage ratios and unit value ratios for the
manufacturing industry in Germany and the US in 1997
Industry ISIC Number
of
matches
Percentage of output
matched
Unit value ratios Dollar/EUR
US Germany Laspeyres Paasche Fisher
Food products 15–16 132 65 62 1.09 1.36 1.22
Textile, clothing, leather and
footwear
17–19 76 44 62 0.62 0.71 0.66
Wood and products of wood
and cork
20 13 52 31 0.93 1.08 1.00
Paper products 21 18 61 48 1.14 1.22 1.18
Printing and publishing 22 1 0.2 1 2.12 2.12 2.12
Chemicals 24 59 13 18 1.10 1.04 1.07
Rubber and plastic products 25 4 7 23 0.98 1.11 1.04
Non-metallic mineral products 26 23 22 29 1.26 1.42 1.34
Basic metals 27 43 71 70 1.12 1.25 1.18
Fabricated metal product 28 11 7 4 1.24 1.35 1.30
Machinery and equipment 29 53 14 15 0.95 1.04 0.99
Office, accounting and
computing machinery
30 6 38 44 1.09 1.24 1.16
Electrical machinery and
computing
31 18 15 42 0.78 1.22 0.98
Radio, television and
communication equipment
32 17 17 9 0.84 0.96 0.90
Medical precision and optical
instruments
33 16 14 3 1.52 1.72 1.62
Motor vehicles, trailers and
semi-trailers
34 5 39 29 0.87 0.90 0.88
Other transport equipment 35 1 6 3 1.88 1.88 1.88
Manufacturing, recycling n.e.c 36 20 24 16 1.01 1.14 1.08
Total Manufacturing 516 28 28 1.09 1.13 1.11
Source: Inklaar et al. (2003a).
Note: For an exact definition of the Laspeyres, Paasche and Fisher index see MathWorld (2004).
33
Table 4 Labor productivity and relative labor productivity levels (value added
in thousands of EUR per person engaged) for manufacturing in
Germany, Sweden and the US 1997 (Germany = 100)
Industry ISIC Germany Sweden US
Levels
Relative
levels
Levels Relative
levels
Levels Relative
levels
Food products 15–16 36.6 100 52.3 143 56.5 154
Textile, clothing, leather and
footwear
17–19 33.8 100 36.2 107 51.3 152
Wood and products of wood
and cork
20 41.6 100 55.6 134 41.6 100
Paper products 21 53.8 100 79.8 148 45.6 85
Printing and publishing 22 46.0 100 43.0 94 21.7 47
Chemicals 24 71.3 100 112.9 158 66.6 93
Rubber and plastic products 25 48.3 100 46.6 97 46.4 96
Non-metallic mineral products 26 51.2 100 57.7 113 38.2 75
Basic metals 27 52.1 100 55.7 107 44.1 85
Fabricated metal products 28 41.9 100 61.8 147 32.2 77
Machinery and equipment 29 49.5 100 65.4 132 50.0 101
Office, accounting and
computing machinery
30 68.4 100 98.7 144 59.0 86
Electrical machinery and
computing
31 51.5 100 38.6 75 65.5 127
Radio, television and
communication equipment
32 50.3 100 68.3 136 120.8 240
Medical precision and optical
instruments
33 38.9 100 34.7 89 36.8 95
Motor vehicles, trailers and
semi-trailers
34 59.9 100 48.3 81 109.2 182
Other transport equipment 35 50.5 100 37.9 75 33.4 66
Manufacturing, recycling n.e.c 36-37 37.0 100 25.7 69 64.1 173
Total manufacturing 15-37 48.5 100 53.8 111 62.4 129
Sources: GGDC (2003), Europroms (2001), Statistics Sweden (2003b) and own calculations.
34
Table 5 Labor productivity and relative labor productivity levels (value added
in thousands of EUR per person engaged) for manufacturing in
Germany, Sweden and the US 1993 (Germany = 100)
Industry ISIC Germany Sweden US
Levels Relative
levels
Levels Relative
levels
Levels Relative
levels
Food products 15–16 33.8 100 41.6 123 51.9 153
Textile, clothing, leather
and footwear
17–19 31.5 100 32.0 102 48.4 154
Wood and products of wood
and cork
20 33.8 100 41,7 123 35.4 105
Paper products 21 44.9 100 77.4 173 45.5 101
Printing and publishing 22 42.8 100 32.8 77 21.1 49
Chemicals 24 54.3 100 97.2 179 55.7 102
Rubber and plastic products 25 40.6 100 35.5 87 39.4 97
Non-metallic mineral
products
26 45.5 100 53.7 118 38.2 84
Basic metals 27 35.1 100 40.2 114 33.8 96
Fabricated metal products 28 37.8 100 53.5 141 29.8 79
Machinery and equipment 29 39.8 100 51.4 129 40.4 102
Office, accounting and
computing machinery
30 4.2 100 5.6 136 3.6 86
Electrical machinery and
computing
31 53.3 100 34.8 65 69.6 131
Radio, television and
communication equipment
32 8.3 100 5.9 70 18.6 223
Medical precision and
optical instruments
33 43.5 100 35.1 81 44.5 102
Motor vehicles, trailers and
semi-trailers
34 50.0 100 30.5 61 110.6 221
Other transport equipment 35 35.4 100 40.3 114 35.0 99
Manufacturing, recycling
n.e.c
36-37 38.9 100 17.5 45 58.5 150
Total manufacturing 15-37 41.4 100 38.4 93 51.1 121
Sources: GGDC (2003), Europroms (2001), Statistics Sweden (2003b) and own calculations.
Note: Calculations for the ICT producing industries are based on the US ICT deflators.
35
Table 6 Labor productivity and relative labor productivity levels (value added
in thousands of Euros per person engaged) for manufacturing in
Germany, Sweden and the US 2000 (Germany = 100)
Industry ISIC Germany Sweden US
Levels Relative
levels
Levels Relative
levels
Levels Relative
levels
Food products 15–16 37.8 100 54.4 144 48.3 128
Textile, clothing, leather and
footwear
17–19 36.4 100 39.5 108 55.1 151
Wood and products of wood
and cork
20 41.8 100 66.3 160 43.8 105
Paper products 21 56.9 100 90.8 159 40.6 71
Printing and publishing 22 50.7 100 44.0 87 23.4 46
Chemicals 24 75.8 100 139.9 185 70.1 93
Rubber and plastic products 25 47.9 100 50.7 106 46.6 97
Non-metallic mineral
products
26 53.0 100 65.4 123 35.8 68
Basic metals 27 52.7 100 59.4 113 54.2 103
Fabricated metal products 28 43.5 100 68.0 156 31.8 73
Machinery and equipment 29 50.0 100 72.6 145 50.3 100
Office, accounting and
computing machinery
30 219.1 100 319.8 146 188.9 86
Electrical machinery and
computing
31 56.1 100 44.7 80 66.7 119
Radio, television and
communication equipment
32 160.5 100 150.0 93 355.8 222
Medical precision and
optical instruments
33 37.4 100 27.5 74 35.0 94
Motor vehicles, trailers and
semi-trailers
34 48.5 100 72.8 150 126.0 260
Other transport equipment 35 52.8 100 39.8 75 35.8 68
Manufacturing, recycling
n.e.c
36-37 38.2 100 32.4 85 68.7 180
Total manufacturing 15-37 50.4 100 67.5 136 72.6 147
Sources: GGDC (2003), Europroms (2001), Statistics Sweden (2003b) and own calculations.
Note: Calculations for the ICT producing industries are based on the US ICT deflators.
36
Table 7 Value added deflators for the ICT producing industries (ISIC 30–33)
1994–2001
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
Germany
Office, accounting and
computing machinery
–0.17 -0.05 –0.01 –0.06 –0.06 –0.09 –0.13
Electric machinery and
computing
–0.002 –0.001 0.02 –0.01 0.004 0.01 –0.02
Radio, television and
communication equipment
–0.02 –0.01 –0.004 –0.003 –0.04 –0.04 –0.07
Medical, precision and
optical instruments
0.01 0.02 0.03 0.03 0.01 0.03 –0.008
Sweden
Office, accounting and
computing machinery
0.04 0.02 0.06 –0.01 0.02 0.01 –0.004 0.21
Electric machinery and
computing
0.05 0.07 0.12 0.008 –0.03 –0.07 –0.05 0.021
Radio, television and
communication equipment
–0.41 –0.51 –0.40 –0.30 –0.39 –0.39 –0.51
Medical, precision and
optical instruments
0.06 0.02 0.05 0.007 –0.03 –0.03 –0.09 0.06
US
Office, accounting and
computing machinery
–0.23 –0.29 –0.50 –0.56 –0.56 –0.51 –0.23 –0.31
Electric machinery and
computing
0.006 0.01 0.03 0.02 0.03 0.01 –0.01 0.02
Radio, television and
communication equipment
–0.14 –0.41 –0.35 –0.26 –0.41 –0.35 –0.41 –0.35
Medical, precision and
optical instruments
0.04 0.07 0.14 0.08 0.13 0.07 0.06 0.11
Sources: GGDC (2003), Statistics Sweden (2003b) and own calculations.
Note: n.a. = not available.
37
Table 8 Relative productivity level in Sweden and Germany with different
ICT deflators (Germany=100) 1993–2000
Sweden = Swedish deflators
Germany = German deflators
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
Office, accounting and
computing machinery
207 166 160 173 144 149 130 110
Electric machinery and
computing
83 84 88 82 75 87 86 91
Radio, television and
communication equipment
7 14 35 78 136 182 219 228
Medical, precision and optical
instruments
86 84 85 79 89 100 99 84
Sweden = Swedish deflators
Germany = US deflators
Office, accounting and
computing machinery
1842 1370 954 533 144 106 67 52
Electric machinery and
computing
78 80 84 80 75 89 88 94
Radio, television and
communication equipment
29 49 79 113 136 136 129 104
Medical, precision and optical
instruments
67 68 72 74 89 112 115 110
Sweden = US deflators
Germany = US deflators
Office, accounting and
computing machinery
136 137 144 200 144 155 151 146
Electric machinery and
computing
65 69 78 81 75 84 77 80
Radio, television and
communication equipment
70 73 95 121 136 137 126 93
Medical, precision and optical
instruments
81 84 85 81 89 97 90 74
Sources: GGDC (2003), Europroms (2001), Statistics Sweden (2003b) and own calculations.
38
Table 9 Recalculation of the Swedish value added price deflators for the
Radio, television and communication industry (ISIC 32)
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
Gross output price deflator (1)
Electronic valves and tubes (US) –0.12 –0.33 –0.33 –0.23 –0.39 –0.28 –0.32
Telecommunication equipment (SWE)‡ –0.06 –0.10 –0.12 –0.00 –0.01 –0.05 –0.01
Radio and television receivers (SWE) ‡ –0.03 –0.06 –0.12 –0.04 –0.09 –0.13 –0.15
Shares of gross output, measured as
production at factor costs (2)
Electronic valves and tubes 0.07 0.05 0.04 0.04 0.07 0.05 0.05†
Telecommunication equipment 0.89 0.91 0.90 0.92 0.89 0.90 0.90†
Radio and television receivers 0.04 0.04 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.05 0.05†
Gross output price deflator
(3) = (1)*(2)
Radio, television and communication
equipment industry (ISIC 32)
–0.06 –0.11 –0.13 –0.01 –0.03 –0.06 –0.03
Intermediate input price deflator (4)
Electronic valves and tubes (US) 0.01 0.01 –0.07 –0.06 –0.10 –0.05 –0.03
Telecommunication equipment (US) 0.00 0.00 –0.08 –0.07 –0.12 –0.05 –0.05
Radio and television receivers (US) 0.02 0.02 –0.02 –0.02 –0.03 –0.01 –0.00
Shares of intermediate input, measured
as production at factor costs (5)
Electronic valves and tubes 0.05 0.03 0.02 0.04 0.05 0.05 0.05†
Telecommunication equipment 0.90 0.93 0.92 0.90 0.91 0.91 0.91†
Radio and television receivers 0.04 0.04 0.06 0.06 0.04 0.04 0.04†
Intermediate input price deflator
(6) = (4)*(5)
Radio, television and communication
industry equipment (ISIC 32)
–0.002 0.001 –0.08 –0.07 –0.11 –0.05 –0.04
Gross output/value added (7) ‡‡ 3.51 3.90 4.04 3.93 3.92 4.38 5.98
Intermediate input/gross output (8) ‡‡ 0.71 0.74 0.75 0.75 0.74 0.77 0.83
New value added deflators ††
(9) = (7)*[(3)–(8)*(6)]
–0.21 –0.44 –0.30 0.15 0.19 –0.11 0.02
Sources: GGDC unpublished data, Statistics Sweden (2003b), Statistics Sweden (2003c) and OECD
(2003).
Notes: ‡Gross output deflators for Telecommunication equipment and Radio and television receivers are
based on producer price indexes published by the Department of Prices and Consumption. ‡‡Results for
gross output/value added and intermediate input/gross output are average for period t and t–1. †Shares of
gross outputs and intermediate inputs for the year 2000 are assumed to be the same as for 1999. This is due
to the lack of data for the year 2000. ††The new value added deflators is derived from the formula in
equation 4.1.
39
Table 10 Recalculation of the Swedish value added price deflators for the
Radio, television and communication industry (ISIC 32)
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
Gross output price deflator (1)
Electronic valves and tubes (US) –0.12 –0.33 –0.33 –0.23 –0.39 –0.28 –0.32
Telecommunication equipment (SWE)‡ –0.10 –0.13 –0.15 –0.08 –0.09 –0.09 –0.08
Radio and television receivers (SWE)‡ –0.02 –0.05 –0.11 –0.04 –0.09 –0.12 –0.14
Shares of gross output, measured as
production at factor costs (2)
Electronic valves and tubes 0.07 0.05 0.04 0.04 0.07 0.05 0.05†
Telecommunication equipment 0.89 0.91 0.90 0.92 0.89 0.90 0.90†
Radio and television receivers 0.04 0.04 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.05 0.05†
Gross output price deflator
(3) = (1)*(2)
Radio, television and communication
equipment industry (ISIC 32)
–0.10 –0.14 –0.16 –0.08 –0.11 –0.11 –0.10
Intermediate input price deflator (4)
Electronic valves and tubes (US) 0.01 0.01 –0.07 –0.06 –0.10 –0.05 –0.03
Telecommunication equipment (US) 0.00 0.00 –0.08 –0.07 –0.12 –0.05 –0.05
Radio and television receivers (US) 0.02 0.02 –0.02 –0.02 –0.03 –0.01 –0.00
Shares of intermediate input, measured
as production at factor costs (5)
Electronic valves and tubes 0.05 0.03 0.02 0.04 0.05 0.05 0.05†
Telecommunication equipment 0.90 0.93 0.92 0.90 0.91 0.91 0.91†
Radio and television receivers 0.04 0.04 0.06 0.06 0.04 0.04 0.04†
Intermediate input price deflator
(6) = (4)*(5)
Radio, television and communication
equipment industry (ISIC 32)
–0.002 0.001 –0.08 –0.07 –0.11 –0.05 –0.04
Gross output/value added (7)‡‡ 3.51 3.90 4.04 3.93 3.92 4.38 5.98
Intermediate input/gross output (8)‡‡ 0.71 0.74 0.75 0.75 0.74 0.77 0.83
New value added deflators††
(9) = (7)*[(3)–(8)*(6)]
–0.34 –0.53 –0.41 –0.12 –0.10 –0.29 –0.38
Sources: GGDC unpublished data, Statistics Sweden (2003b), Statistics Sweden (2003c) and OECD
(2003).
Notes: ‡Gross output deflators for Telecommunication equipment and Radio and television receivers are
based on producer price indexes in the National Accounts. ‡‡Results for gross output/value added and
intermediate input/gross output are average for period t and t–1. †Shares of gross outputs and intermediate
inputs for the year 2000 are assumed to be the same as for 1999. This is due to the lack of data for the year
2000. ††The new value added deflators is derived from the formula in equation 4.1.
40
Figure 1 Labor productivity levels in manufacturing, value added (in
thousands of Euros) per person engaged in Germany, Sweden and the
US 1980-2001
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000
US
Sweden
Germany
Sources: GGDC (2003), Europroms (2001), OECD (2001b), Statistics Sweden (2003b) and own
calculations.
Note: Calculations are based on official value added deflators. The calculations for Germany before 1991
are based on figures for West Germany.
Figure 2 Scatter diagram of the difference in productivity level between
Sweden and the US in 1993 and the average Swedish labor
productivity growth rate 1993–2000
-200
-150
-100
-50
0
50
100
-0,10 0,00 0,10 0,20 0,30 0,40 0,50
Differe n ce in p roductivity level 1993
Average growth rate
Correlation coefficient: -0.61
Sources: GGDC (2003), Europroms (2001), Statistics Sweden (2003b) and own calculations.
41
Figure 3 Scatter diagram of the difference in productivity level between
Sweden and Germany in 1993 and the average Swedish labor
productivity growth rate 1993–2000
-80
-60
-40
-20
0
20
40
60
80
100
-0,10 0,00 0,10 0,20 0,30 0,40 0,50
Difference in productivity level 1993
Average growth rate
Correlation coefficient: -0.34
Sources: GGDC (2003), Europroms (2001), Statistics Sweden (2003b) and own calculations.
Figure 4 Gross output in the Radio, television and communication equipment
as a share of gross output in total manufacturing (current prices)
1993–2001
0,00
0,02
0,04
0,06
0,08
0,10
0,12
0,14
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
Sweden
Germany
US
Sources: OECD (2001b) and Statistics Sweden (2003b).
42
Figure 5 Value added in Radio, television and communication equipment as a
share of the value added in total manufacturing (current prices) 1993–
2001
0,00
0,01
0,02
0,03
0,04
0,05
0,06
0,07
0,08
0,09
0,10
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
German
y
US
Sweden
Sources: GGDC (2003) and Statistics Sweden (2003b).
Figure 6 Persons engaged in Radio, television and communication equipment
as a share of the persons engaged in total manufacturing (current
prices) 1993–2001
0,00
0,01
0,02
0,03
0,04
0,05
0,06
0,07
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
Germany
US
Sweden
Sources: GGDC (2003) and Statistics Sweden (2003b).
43
Figure 7 Gross output and input price deflators for the Radio, television and
communication equipment industry (ISIC 32) 1994–2001
-0,30
-0,25
-0,20
-0,15
-0,10
-0,05
0,00
0,05
0,10
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
Gross output price deflator SWE
Intermediate input deflator SWE
Gross output price deflator US
Intermediate input deflator US
Sources: GGDC unpublished data and Statistics Sweden (2003b).
Figure 8 Gross output price deflators for the Electronic valves and tubes (ISIC
321) industry 1994–2001 (percent)
-0,50
-0,40
-0,30
-0,20
-0,10
0,00
0,10
0,20
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
Sweden, price index publis hed by the
Department of Prices and Consumption
US
Sweden, price index in the
National Accounts
Sources: GGDC unpublished data and Statistics Sweden (2003c).
44
Figure 9 Gross output price deflators for the Telecommunication equipment
(ISIC 322) industry 1994–2001 (percent)
-0,30
-0,25
-0,20
-0,15
-0,10
-0,05
0,00
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
S we den , pr i ce i nde x publ i s he d by th e
Department of Prices and Consumption
US
Sweden, price index in the
National Ac counts
Sources: GGDC unpublished data and Statistics Sweden (2003c).
Figure 10 Gross output price deflators for the Radio and television receivers
(ISIC 323) industry 1994–2001 (percent)
-0,16
-0,12
-0,08
-0,04
0,00
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
Sweden, price index published by the
Department of Prices and Consumption
US Sweden, price index in the
National Accounts
Sources: GGDC unpublished data and Statistics Sweden (2003c).
45
Figure 11 Input price deflators for Electronic valves and tubes (ISIC 321),
Telecommunication equipment (ISIC 322) and Radio and television
receivers (ISIC 323) in the US 1991–2001
-0,14
-0,12
-0,10
-0,08
-0,06
-0,04
-0,02
0,00
0,02
0,04
1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
Electronic v alves and
tubes (321) US
Telecommunication
equipment (322) US
Radio and television
receivers (323) US
Source: GGDC unpublished data.
Figure 12 Imports of Electronic valves and tubes (ISIC 321) as a share of total
production and imports of Electronic valves and tubes in Sweden
1995–2001 (in current prices)
0,69
0,7
0,71
0,72
0,73
0,74
0,75
0,76
1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
Source: Statistic Sweden (2003b)
46
Figure 13 Intermediate input/gross output ratio for the Swedish and US Radio,
television and communication equipment industry 1993–2001 (in
current prices)
0,00
0,20
0,40
0,60
0,80
1,00
1,20
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001
Sweden
US
Sources: Statistics Sweden (2003b) and OECD (2003).
Figure 14 Labor productivity growth rates in the Radio television and
communication equipment industry with official and recalculated
deflators
-0,400
-0,200
0,000
0,200
0,400
0,600
0,800
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
Official deflators
Recalculat ed deflators based on price indexes by the Depart ment of P rices and Consumption
Recalculat ed deflators based on output price indexes in National Accounts
Sources: GGDC unpublished data and OECD (2003), Statistics Sweden (2003b) and Statistics Sweden
(2003c).
47
Figure 15 Labor productivity growth rates in the total manufacturing industry
with official and recalculated deflators
0,000
0,020
0,040
0,060
0,080
0,100
0,120
0,140
0,160
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
Official deflato rs
Recalculated deflators based on price indexes by th e Depar tm ent of Prices and Consumption
Recalculated deflators based on output price indexes in National Accounts
Sources: GGDC unpublished data and OECD (2003), Statistics Sweden (2003b) and Statistics Sweden
(2003c).
Figure 16 Labor productivity levels in the manufacturing industry, value added
(in thousands of EUR) per person engaged in Germany, Sweden and
the US 1980-2000
0,00
20,00
40,00
60,00
80,00
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000
US
Sweden, official deflators
Sweden, recalculated deflators based on
price indexes by the Department of Prices
and Consumpti on
Germany
Sources: GGDC (2003), Europroms (2001), OECD (2001b), Statistics Sweden (2003b) and own
calculations.
Note: Recalculated deflators are used for the period 1994–2000.
48
Figure 17 Value added price deflators for the Swedish Radio, television and
communication equipment industry (ISIC 32) for different types of
index formulas
-0,80
-0,70
-0,60
-0,50
-0,40
-0,30
-0,20
-0,10
0,00
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
Chained Laspeyres, arithmetic c hange
Chained Laspeyres, log change
Törnqvist aggregation, log change
Sources: Statistics Sweden (2003b) and own calculations.
Note: See Appendix 2 for further details.
7. Appendix
7.1 Appendix 1: Unit value ratios
The UVR-based method was first introduced in the late 1950s, but has been further
refined by the ICOP (International Comparisons of Output and Productivity) group at the
University of Groningen under the direction of Angus Maddison and Bart van Ark (van
Ark and Timmer 2002).
Industry UVRs are based on two alternative indexes: the Laspeyres index that is using the
quantity weights of the base country and the Paasche index that uses the quantity weight
of the other country. As a first step, unit values (uv) are derived by dividing ex-factory
output values (o) by produced quantities (q) for each product i in each economy:
49
i
i
i
q
o
uv = (7.1)
The unit value can be thought of as an average price, averaged throughout the year for all
producers and across a group of nearly similar products. In a bilateral comparison broadly
defined products with similar characteristics are matched. For each matched product, the
ratio of the unit values in both countries is taken. This unit value ratio (UVR) is given by:
B
i
A
i
xu
iuv
uv
UVR = (7.2)
where, A and B are the countries being compared, B being the base country. The product
UVR indicates the relative producer price of the matched product in the two countries.
The product UVRs are used to derive an aggregate UVR for manufacturing branches and
total manufacturing. The most simple aggregation method is to weight each product UVR
by its share in total manufacturing gross output.
BA
ij
I
i
ij
BA
jUVRwUVR
j
=
=
1
(7.3)
with i= 1,…, Ij the matched products in industry j; wij = oij / oj the output share of the ith
commodity in industry j; and oj = =
j
I
iij
o
1the total matched value of output in industry j.
In bilateral comparisons the weights of the base country (B) or the other country (A) can
be used, which provide a Laspeyres and a Paasche type UVR respectively.36 As the
quantity weights are consistent with those that are used to derive the unit values, the
weights and units are consistent. The same procedure is repeated for the final aggregation
step from industry level to the level of total manufacturing.
36 In this paper, calculations are based on the average of the Laspeyres and Paasche indexes, i.e. the Fisher
index.
50
In a comparison between two different countries, it is not possible to match all products
in an industry. This is due to missing data of gross output value and quantity, difficulties
in finding corresponding products and the existence of country specific products. The
composition of production tends to differ much more across countries than the
composition of expenditure (van Ark and Timmer 2002).
7.2 Appendix 2: ICT deflators
Even though the Swedish and the US National Accounts are based on double deflation
there are still differences in the way value added is measured. One important difference is
that the US uses a Törnqvist price index to derive a Törnqvist value added volume index
while Sweden uses a chained Paasche price index to derive a chained Laspeyres volume
index, where the year t–1 is used as the base year.
A Törnqvist volume index is a weighted geometric average of the quantity relatives using
arithmetic averages of the value shares in the two periods as weights.
2
)(
1
0
0
)/(
i
t
iss
n
i
i
t
iT qqQ
+
=
= (7.5)
where 0
i
s denotes the share of the value of product i in the total output of goods and
services in period 0: that is, 0000 /iiii qpqp .
A Laspeyres volume index is a weighted arithmetic average of quantity relatives using
the values of the earlier period as weights.
0
1
1
00
1
0
)/( i
o
i
n
i
t
i
n
i
ii
n
i
t
ii
Lsqq
qp
qp
Q
=
=
=
= (7.6)
where 0
i
s denotes the share of the value of product i in the total output of goods and
services in period 0: that is, 0000 /iiii qpqp .
51
The rational for using a certain index formula is based on theoretical arguments that will
not be discussed in this paper.37 However, from the definitions above there appear to be
two major differences between the chained Laspeyres index and the Törnqvist index. One
difference is that the Laspeyres index is based on the arithmetic average, while the
Törnqvist index is based on the geometric average. Moreover, the Törnqvist price index
uses the average of the two periods t and t–1 as weights while the Laspeyres index only
uses the period t–1 as weights.
The logarithm of the Törnqvist index can be expressed in the following way:
+=
=
0
0
1
ln)(
2
1
ln
i
t
i
i
t
i
n
i
Tq
q
ssQ (7.8)
In order to approximate the Swedish data based on the Laspeyres index to the Törnqvist
index, I use the logarithmic change of the values derived by the Laspeyres volume index.
This gives the log change between two years instead of the arithmetic change. Moreover,
I also use the average of the Swedish value added and intermediate input weights for the
period t–1 and t. Since I do not have access to the weights of every product for the
intermediate input and output it is not possible to change the weights for each product.
Nonetheless, for the total gross output/value added ratio as well as for the intermediate
input/gross output ratio it is possible to use the average weights of the two years t-1 and t
(see section 4.2).
Figure 17 shows the different results from calculating the value added deflator for the
Radio, television and communication equipment by using arithmetic mean and weights
with year t–1 as the base year, log change and weights with the year t–1 as a base, and
log change with the average of the years t and t–1 as base years. Since the latter is the
closest approximation to the Törnqvist price index it will be used for all calculations of
value added price deflators. Moreover, one of the reasons that the value added price
deflators based on arithmetic mean differs widely from those based on logarithmic
37 For a thorough discussion of the theoretical reasons to use certain index formula, see IMF (2003).
52
change is that there are extremely high growth rates of production value and intermediate
input 1993–2000. If the growth rates had been lower than 10 percent per year the
difference would have been negligible.
... The concept of entrepreneurial ecosystems (EEs) emerged to clarify the continuum of regions with high-growth entrepreneurship [1,2]. A view widely used in academia to designate an entrepreneurial ecosystem refers to a community with numerous stakeholders that provides a favourable environment for creating and developing new ventures inside a region [3,4]. ...
... Despite the similarities in proximity and territorial delimitation focusing on the entrepreneurial process' social and economic context, the entrepreneurial ecosystem concept positions the individual entrepreneur as the leading actor [25]. The definition of entrepreneurial ecosystems appears with Spilling [1]. The current description found so far is Riaz [26], who understands entrepreneurial and business ecosystems as linked subsets of a regional economic ecosystem with the commercial exploitation of ideas as complements to organisational assets. ...
Article
Full-text available
Entrepreneurial ecosystems remain under-theorised and conceptually fragmented, making it challenging to comprehend their disposition and performance in the business process. Accordingly, in this research, we explored how knowledge sharing flows through entrepreneurial ecosystems to make analyses and trials to assess new ventures' creation, continuity, and development opportunities. We carried out a systematic literature review on the Web of Science database. The analysis was carried out in two stages: (i) content analysis using NVivo software and (ii) statistical processing and clustering with the support of VOSviewer and Bibliometrix software. Moreover, we reviewed entrepreneurial literature and proposed conceptual model mapping relations through all main actors and knowledge flow in ecosystems. Our findings suggest the knowledge path in the near field sharing mechanisms resulting in a new conception of traditional structures and relations used to judge and decide how to assess opportunities for new ventures' opening, maintenance, and growth. This study contributes to entrepreneurial literature, demonstrating knowledge sharing flow through entrepreneurial ecosystems, considering an embracing, dynamic, and multilevel approach. Furthermore, it highlights political and social contributions to include new emergent perspectives: resource scarcity and structural and institutional gaps. This representation is the first knowledge management model applied to different economies and areas, respecting their singularities.
... Their results reveal a significant outcome in developed/newly industrialised countries, but not in developing countries. This is in line with the results of Edquist (2005), who concludes that there is no clear impact of ICT on the economic growth of developing countries due to the delay in introducing information and communications technology in these kinds of countries. Internet use in these countries only began in the late 1990s and was not always fully available or able to cover large areas. ...
... The results of various studies have shown that ICT investment has a significant impact on economic growth (Edquist 2005;Falk and Biagi 2015;Hanclova et al. 2015). They find that countries investing heavily in ICT in the long run experienced higher growth rates than ICTimporting countries. ...
Thesis
Full-text available
Information and Communications Technology (ICT) is considered an important component in improving the efficiency of various economic activities. However, this is often interrelated with a country’s quality of governance, particularly in developing countries, such as the Middle East and North Africa (MENA). The MENA countries have relatively well-developed ICT coverage, but they suffer from poor quality of governance. Therefore, this region provides a setting to examine new research questions, such as ‘Do ICT investment and usage affect economic growth in MENA countries?’ and ‘Does the impact of ICT investment and usage on economic growth depend on governance quality?’. The main objective of this study is to investigate the long- and short-run impact of ICT investment and usage on economic growth on the one hand, and the moderating role of the quality of governance on the association between these variables on the other hand. The theoretical foundations of this study can be found in endogenous growth theory as proposed by Barro (1996b) and Romer (1990). This study contributes to the ICT literature by emphasising the countries’ quality of governance in the association between technology and economic growth. More importantly, this study is the first to use all the Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI) developed by the World Bank as moderator variables in the association between ICT investment, usage, and economic growth. This study applies the panel ARDL method and uses data for 16 MENA countries between 1995 and 2018. The results suggest that ICT usage alone does play a significant role in contributing to better economic growth, whereas ICT investment has an insignificant impact on economic growth in MENA region. Interestingly, improvements in quality of governance increase the effectiveness of ICT investment and usage in the economic growth of the MENA countries. The results are of importance for policymakers interested in improving the effectiveness of ICT’s contribution to economic growth, by exposing the potential impacts of the MENA region’s governance indicators on ICT investment and usage. It is important to mention that the MENA countries’ policymakers face the challenge of slow economic growth, and they need to formulate policies aimed at increasing ICT investment and usage. Thus, they also need to develop policies that enhance governance quality, as without effective governance, no significant improvements in economic growth can be expected from ICT investment and usage in the MENA region. The MENA countries’ policymakers should guide ICT investment and usage to achieve greater labour productivity to increase and accelerate economic growth.
... In 2005, research papers appeared that argue that with the Internet access and the spread of information and communication technologies, new industrialized economies are showing higher rates of economic growth [50]. Among the reasons for the lag of developing countries in terms of effective use of information and communication technologies Edquist [51] notes the delay in the introduction of the information technology in the activities of enterprises in these countries. Instead, Antonelli [52] predicted the like hood that developing countries would benefit more from information and communication technologies because, unlike developed countries, they could quickly choose the ICT-oriented paradigm and achieve high economic performance quickly. ...
Article
Full-text available
The purpose of the article is to study the impact of the ICT sector on economic development of countries based on the comparative analysis of this sector development in some Eastern European countries. Within the article, economic development of the outlined countries in 2010-2019 was studied and analyzed. The analysis of the impact of the ICT sector on the GDP formation allowed to single out certain groups of countries under this indicator and to identify the characteristics that are inherent to them. Using the correlation-regression analysis made it possible to analyze the ICT impact on economies development and the Czech Republic. Authors paid a special attention to the study of the influence of various factors on the ICT sector development. Accordingly, an analytical study of the dependence of the ICT sector weight in the GDP of the countries on the following parameters: enterprises that employ ICT specialists; enterprises that provided training to develop/upgrade ICT skills of their personnel; percentage of the ICT personnel in total employment; using Internet for Internet banking, % of individuals; enterprises who have ERP software package to share information between different functional areas; enterprises selling online (at least 1% of turnover), % of enterprises; online purchase in the last 12 months, % of individuals; enterprises having received orders via computer mediated networks, % of enterprises. Within the article, the features of the ICT sector development in the COVID-19 context are examined, and it is analyzed how the pandemic has affected the development of this sector in long and short terms. The study showed that the ICT sector today already plays a key role in the development of the national economies. Countries where the sector is developing faster show better performance and economic development.
... Los sistemas de educación y los mercados laborales están nacionalmente y regionalmente constituidos y juegan ________________________Revista Venezolana de Gerencia, Año 21, No. 74, 2016 265 un papel clave en la creación de competencias y en la conformación de las bases de los procesos de innovación. Por ello, Edquist (2005) sugiere que el enfoque SI debería añadir una tercera dimensión, el citado sistema de educación y formación, especialmente a través de la noción de construcción de habilidades o competencias. ...
Article
Respecto al modelo formativo que debe acompañar las apremiantes transformaciones que requiere el actual modelo económico se señala el fomento de la innovación, si bien constriñéndola a la relación entre universidad/empresa. Una combinación ineludible, sin duda, pero que obvia otra relación, la que se establece entre Centros de Formación Profesional y pymes. El objetivo de este artículo es explicar esta última relación apoyándose en la teoría de los sistemas regionales de innovación. La metodología que se ha utilizado ha sido el análisis comparado de las propuestas y perspectivas sobre sistemas, modos de innovación y formación profesional a través del análisis e interpretación de textos. En este artículo, como conclusión, se resalta que los procesos de innovación que impactan positivamente en el nivel de competitividad y en la tasa de crecimiento no son generados exclusivamente por instituciones de innovación y desarrollo sino que también los Centros de formación profesional pueden realizar una importante contribución a la innovación en las pymes.
Chapter
O livro “As novas perspectivas das ciências sociais vol.01”, publicado pela Reflexão Acadêmica Editora, coletânea que une vinte e um capítulos, apresenta trabalhos relacionados com temas diversos da área de ciências sociais. Assim, o livro apresenta seguintes temáticas que envolvem, por exemplo, como as organizações sociais nos dias de hoje, por meio de trabalhos voluntários, conseguem acrescentar algo à sociedade, e como os colaboradores se sentem ao fazer parte de um movimento organizacional. Então, é apresentado um estudo sobre as principais abordagens e formas de manutenção da água, fonte importante para a vida de tantas espécies. Nos entrecruzamentos entre sociedade, sustentabilidade e gestão de negócios, será apresentado um estudo sobre a implantação de mudanças e culturas em uma empresa localizada em Palmas-TO, afim de que sejam adotadas políticas empresariais, governamentais, práticas de sustentabilidades, responsabilidade socioambiental, tendências e demandas globais e que sejam possíveis de serem acompanhadas, mas sem perder a competitividade nos negócios. Temas como os padrões de beleza impostos pela sociedade hoje em dia também são abordados, assim como o impacto que causam na vida de mulheres de meia-idade, e como são necessários buscar caminhos que possam ser alternativas e se encaixar harmoniosamente, entre o ideal de beleza atualmente e como pode ser levado no decorrer da vida. Os trabalhos apresentados nesta coletânea permitem, assim, analisarmos sobre questões sociais enfrentadas atualmente, e como podemos lidar com os desafios encontrados. Dessa forma agradecemos todos os autores pelo esforço e dedicação colocados em seus trabalhos e esperamos poder contribuir com a comunidade científica que se interessa por temas relacionados com as ciências sociais e que o livro auxilie nas temáticas discutidas.
Article
This article aims to estimate the effects of ICT intensity on labor productivity, employment and output of agro-processing industries. To achieve this, the ICT intensity index is applied to rank industries into ‘more ICT-intensive’ and ‘less ICT-intensive’ groups. Thereafter, the annual growth rates of labor productivity, employment and output were calculated. Ultimately, the effects of ICT intensity were examined using Pooled Mean Group estimation, the Toda and Yamamoto Granger Non-Causality Test, and the Impulse Response Function and Variance Decomposition analyses. The findings suggest that ICT intensity yields higher positive and significant effects on the growth of the more ICT-intensive industries. Evidence of a causal relationship was detected for the more ICT-intensive industries. The findings further proved that ICT intensity contributed more to the forecast error variance in the growth of the more ICT-intensive industries. Overall, this article provides evidence of ICT-led growth for industries that use ICT most intensively.
Article
This paper serves to examine whether the growth in labour productivity (LP) in South Africa’s manufacturing sector, following policy reforms after 1994, can be attributed to ICT use. To achieve this, we examine the link between ICT intensity and LP growth of 23 manufacturing industries for the period 1970–2016 and sub-periods 1970–1995 and 1996–2016. The industries are disaggregated into two groups, which are ‘more ICT-intensive’ and ‘less ICT-intensive’, using the ICT intensity index. Four dummy variable regression models are applied to test for the relationship between ICT intensity of industries and LP growth. The findings suggest that LP of the more ICT-intensive industries accelerated more than that of their counterparts. The results underscore the need for policy measures to increase ICT use with the aim of improving LP performance of industries.
Article
Full-text available
The article proposes a solution to one of the key problems – the use of information technology in the management of territorial processes based on the development of tools for digitalization of economic processes on the basis of the software product to identify the structural elements of the economic potential of the regions of Russia, including the features of such regions as the Arctic. As a tool for the implementation of this approach, the VBA programming language built into the Excel spreadsheet is used, which allows flexible use of a standard software product for solving problems at the macroeconomic level. The aim of the study is to develop tools for digitalization of economic processes on the basis of a computer program to determine the extreme structural elements of the growth of the economic potential of the regions to support management decision-making. The systematic approach, methods of statistical and economic analysis, including horizontal and vertical analysis, allowed the authors to assess the dynamics of extreme values of the level of development of economic sectors in the regions of Russia and to develop recommendations for the development of the Federal districts and regions. The directions of further researches consist in application of multidimensional modeling of data for collecting and automatic processing of statistical information on a condition of subjects of the Arctic region.
Article
Full-text available
This article discusses the productivity of the Information and Communication Technology (ICT) sector using cross-sectional data from 793 service firms in Palestine. The authors have examined the impact of ICT growth on service sector productivity in Palestine using a set of indicators for ICT including internet usage, e-commerce, networks, websites, and use of “smart” phones. They find that using ICT (mainly Internet) in commerce (e-commerce) is one of the most important levers of labor productivity among service firms. Service firms that are less ICT-intensive are less productive than more ICT-intensive firms; moreover, the use of mobile phones for services other than send-and-receive calls, highly improves the labor productivity of service firms. Conversely, using a website and computer network does not positively affect the labor productivity. Regarding geographical differences in labor productivity, the analysis shows that firms in Jerusalem are characterized by higher productivity than firms in the West Bank, while firms in Gaza have a lower productivity compared to firms in the West Bank.
Article
Full-text available
This article is the original version of a chapter for the UNESCO-History of Humanity published slightly modified in 2008. Different views on the concept and spread of the industrial revolution, which took place from the late 18th century onwards, are dealt with. By way of example the revolutionary character of technological change and the search for new sources of energy is described and analysed for some major innovations and industries, namely the steam engine, the iron and steel industry and the use of electricity. Furthermore the question is discussed as to what extent sciences were related to technical progress. In this context the emergence of higher technical education at universities is put forward. Some brief remarks on the role of agriculture and the increasing economic ties among countries during the 19th century conclude this paper.
Article
Full-text available
In this study we test whether catching up, the hypothesis that there is technological spillover from leaders to followers, is still important among industrialized countries. Since the USA is no longer the technological leader in many industries and since catching up, if it still exists, may not operate uniformly across different industries, a disaggregated study is more appropriate. A testable model is developed and a number of tests for the existence of catching up are performed. A major improvement on previous tests is that the level of technology is measured in terms of total factor productivity. The two major conclusions, which are quite robust, are that after 1970 there is no catching-up effect left in the tradables sector, while catching up is found for industries in the nontradables sector.
Chapter
This paper examines the roles of the ICT-producing sector and of key ICT-using industries in overall productivity growth in OECD countries. The ICT manufacturing sector, in particular, has been characterised by very high rates of productivity growth in many countries and provides a large contribution to labour productivity growth in Finland, Ireland and Korea. In a few countries, notably the United States and Australia, certain ICT-using services have also experienced an aboveaverage pick-up in productivity growth in the second half of the 1990s. Differences in the measurement of productivity in ICT-producing and -using industries across countries complicate the cross-country analysis.
Article
The growth of U.S. labor productivity rebounded in the second half of the 1990s, after nearly a quarter century of sluggish gains. We assess the contribution of information technology to this rebound, using the same neoclassical framework as in our earlier work. We find that a surge in the use of information technology capital and faster efficiency gains in the production of computers account for about two-thirds of the speed-up in productivity growth between the first and second halves of the 1990s. Thus, to answer the question posed in the title of the paper, information technology largely is the story.