Conference PaperPDF Available

Strategies for Digital Music Markets: Pricing and the Effectiveness of Measures against Pirate Copies - Results of an Empirical Study.

Authors:
  • NOWEDA Apothekergenossenschaft eG

Abstract and Figures

The recording industry is currently faced with a remarkable decline in revenues and record sales. Paid music services have failed to deliver on their promise of a full-catalog, easy-to-use shopping experience so far, and file sharing platforms are still widely used for obtaining online music. In this context we conducted an empirical study via the Internet with 2.260 participants. The main results are: Neither the installation of copy protection measures nor legal actions taken against users of file sharing platforms seem to be appropriate means to increase sales of CDs and on-line music. Potential consumers' willingness to pay is distinctly lower than the prices currently set by the available paid music services. Our study's results suggest that a price cut for music downloads would lead to increased sales, thus creating benefits for both suppliers and consumers.
Content may be subject to copyright.
STRATEGIES FOR DIGITAL MUSIC MARKETS: PRICING AND
THE EFFECTIVENESS OF MEASURES AGAINST PIRATE
COPIES – RESULTS OF AN EMPIRICAL STUDY
Buxmann, Peter, Darmstadt University of Technology, Department of Business
Administration, Economics and Law, Chair of Information Systems, Hochschulstr. 1,
64289 Darmstadt, Germany, buxmann@is.tu-darmstadt.de
Pohl, Gerrit, Rolling Stone Germany, Editor, Head of Online and New Media, and Darmstadt
University of Technology, Department of Business Administration, Economics and Law,
Chair of Information Systems, Hochschulstr. 1, 64289 Darmstadt, Germany, pohl@is.tu-
darmstadt.de
Johnscher, Patrick, Darmstadt University of Technology, Department of Business
Administration, Economics and Law, Chair of Information Systems, Hochschulstr. 1,
64289 Darmstadt, Germany, johnscher@is.tu-darmstadt.de
Strube, Jochen, Darmstadt University of Technology, Department of Business
Administration, Economics and Law, Chair of Information Systems, Hochschulstr. 1,
64289 Darmstadt, Germany, strube@is.tu-darmstadt.de
Groffmann, Hans-Dieter, Freiberg University of Technology, Chair of Information Systems,
Lessingstr. 45, 09599 Freiberg, Germany, hans-dieter.groffmann@bwl.tu-freiberg.de
Abstract
The recording industry is still facing a global decline in revenues and record sales. Paid music
services have failed to deliver on their promise of a full-catalog shopping experience so far, and file-
sharing platforms are still widely used for obtaining online music. In this context we conducted an
empirical study via the Internet with 2.260 participants. The main results are:
Neither the installation of copy protection measures nor legal actions against users of file-sharing
platforms seem to be appropriate means to increase sales of CDs and online music.
Potential consumers’ willingness to pay is distinctly lower than the prices currently set by the
available paid music services.
Our study's results suggest that a price cut for music downloads would lead to increased sales, thus
creating benefits for both suppliers and consumers.
Keywords: File-sharing platforms, paid music services, online music, copy protection, willingness to
pay, empirical study.
1 INTRODUCTION
Since the year 2000, the music industry has suffered from a global loss of 20% in sales in nearly all
major markets. Even though this decrease has turned out to be lower in 2004, the crisis is still not
overcome. Representatives of the music industry often name the combined effect of digital and
physical piracy as one of the main reasons for the loss. According to a study of the International
Federation of the Phonographic Industry (IFPI), the global pirate market for recorded music totaled 1.7
billion units in 2003, while disc piracy increased by 45 million units compared to 2002 - a rise of 4%
(IFPI 2004a, p. 2).
The critical situation of the music industry is particularly shown by the recent massive reduction in
jobs. In 2004, Warner Music Group dismissed one fifth of its global staff and consolidated the
business divisions of its Elektra and Atlantic Group labels. EMI UK laid off 20% of its employees and
as a response to shrinking sales, the artist roster has been trimmed down by the same percentage.
However, evidence suggests that the music market faces a slow process of recovery. The DVD as a
medium for both music and video shows a remarkable growth. Moreover, the business model of legal
digital music downloads has gained in importance. In the U.S., music downloads outsold physical
singles by three to one in the second half of 2003 (IFPI 2004b, p. 3). A growing number of both major
and independent-labels license their catalogs to various online-services for music downloads. A
rapidly expanding online music market can also be observed in Europe, where services like iTunes or
MSN Music have entered the market. Apart from this, many enterprises use online music as a
marketing tool, such as Coca-Cola, which gave away 100,000 downloads for advertising purposes.
With regard to the assessment of the digital music revolution on the Internet, no consistent opinion
exists among the artists. David Bowie provided several albums for free downloading, while in 1999,
Peter Gabriel founded OD2 (On Demand Distribution), one of the first service providers for digital
music. In contrast to this, Klaus Meine, front man of the German rock band “The Scorpions”,
complains about the serious financial damage due to copyright violations, and the Irish musician
Andrea Corr feels deprived of the result of her creative work.
The music industry has reacted with delay to the digital challenge and is now applying a twofold
strategy. On the one hand, users should be kept from file-sharing by restrictive measures like legal
complaints or technological protection of copyrighted music. On the other hand, the music industry
has developed numerous legal alternatives of its own and licenses digital music to intermediaries, such
as Apple or Real Networks. The IFPI (2004a, p. 8) interprets the slight recovery of the music market
in the first half of 2004 as a confirmation of this strategy.
There are a number of publications dealing with online music and file-sharing. Peitz and Waelbroeck
(2004) examine how the music industry could use peer-to-peer (P2P) networks as information
channels for their commercial purposes. Kwok, Lang and Tam (2002) show the chances and risks of a
business model based on P2P technology in a three layer model. They conclude that P2P is only
suitable for the sale of information goods if the adherence to copyrights can be monitored by the
suppliers. Naghavi and Schulze (2001) compare the consequences of bootlegging and piracy,
concluding that bootlegging did neither harm the music industry nor the artists at the time of their
study. Bootlegging only represents an addition to the product range for a restricted user group.
In this article we examine to what extent legal actions against users and operators of file-sharing
platforms as well as the implementation of copy protection technologies are promising strategies to
overcome the current crisis. Moreover, alternative pricing strategies for music download platforms
will be analyzed. The article is based on an empirical study which was conducted among 2,260
Internet users between December 2003 and January 2004.
In the second section, we will introduce the basic data of our empirical study. The effectiveness of the
restrictive measures taken by the music industry will be discussed in the third section. The fourth
section deals with both the willingness to pay for digital music and pricing strategies. The article
closes with a summary of the main results and some future prospects.
2 OVERVIEW OF THE EMPIRICAL STUDY
Our explorative survey was conducted over the Internet from December 8th, 2003 until January 19th,
2004. Next to questions about the purchase of physical sound storage media and online music, the
main emphases of the evaluation were the download behavior of the participants, the assessment of
restrictive measures, as well as differentiated willingness to pay for digital music. The complete
processing of the questionnaire took about 15 minutes.
In total, we received 2,260 usable questionnaires. The age distribution within the sample is given in
table 1.
15 years
and below 16 to 19
years 20 to 24
years 25 to 29
years 30 to 39
years 40 to 49
years 50 years
and older
1.7% 14.7% 26.6% 18.7% 23.1% 11.9% 3.2%
Table 1. Age distribution within the sample
86.4% of the participants were male and 13.6% female.
In the interpretation of the results, it should be noted that studies which are conducted exclusively over
the Internet are not representative for the total population, since only those who are connected to the
Internet can participate. This even more applies to passive recruitments.
For that reason and since the survey was conducted in German, we have no evidence that the sample is
representative for the international music community. Nevertheless, we hope that the results can
provide some insights for the evaluation of particular strategies in the digital music market. In our
survey, we targeted those people who are both familiar with the Internet and show a strong affinity to
music. However, we assume that within this group, attitudes towards issues like restrictive measures
of the music industry or willingness to pay are likely to be similar. Therefore, the problem that our
data reflect predominantly the opinions of German Internet users is put into perspective.
To reach as many participants of the target group as possible, the survey was announced in both online
and offline media. Various web pages published editorial contributions, such as the computer
magazine CHIP, the music magazine Rolling Stone, and the industry-specific specialist journal
Musikwoche. Furthermore the survey was announced in the print version of the Musikwoche, the
German newspaper Freie Presse as well as the teletext of the music TV channels Viva and Viva Plus.
The server log files show that most of the participants were recruited through these channels.
Survey period December 8th, 2003 – January 19th, 2004
Survey language German
Number of participants 2260
Gender ratio 86.4% male, 13.6% female
Table 2. Overview of the study
3 RESTRICTIVE MEASURES BY THE MUSIC INDUSTRY
The music industry is not only facing the challenge posed by file-sharing networks by creating
commercial download-platforms as a legal alternative, but also by implementing restrictive measures.
Many CDs are equipped with copy protection mechanisms to aggravate the production of
unauthorized copies. Furthermore, recording associations around the world are suing operators and
users of file-sharing platforms alike. Thus, according to Varian (2004) the cost of illegal copies are
increased so far that they become more and more unattractive to the consumer. In the following
section we will examine to which extent these measures are promising.
3.1 Copy protection as a measure to increase sales of physical sound storage media
According to the music industry, in addition to file-sharing platforms the illegal copying of sound
storage media is one of the main reasons for the decrease in sales (IFPI 2004a, p. 15). Therefore, the
industry’s efforts are intensive to develop measures against the unauthorized reproduction of
copyrighted music and to enforce property rights. This in particular includes the utilization of copy
protection mechanisms. However, consumers’ acceptance of restrictions in the usability of CDs is
rather low and subject to discussions between industry representatives and consumers. For instance,
consumers often want to play the purchased recordings on other audio devices, like a computer’s CD-
ROM. If at all, this is mostly only possible after installing some additional software provided along
with the CD, meaning an extra effort. But even with conventional audio devices there are often
problems regarding playback. This, obviously, is one of the reasons why copy-protected CDs are rated
inferior compared to those without such restrictive measures (Sundararajan 2004).
Shapiro and Varian (1998) show by means of plain demand functions that the application of liberal
conditions (e. g. the abdication of a copy protection mechanism) increases a product’s value for the
customers, but reduces sales in turn. However, in our opinion it is by no means ensured though that the
reverse case leads to an increase in sales.
Figure 1. Do you refrain from buying copy protected recordings?
On the one hand, our data analysis shows that nearly half of the respondents (46.4%) do not buy copy-
protected recordings (see figure 1). On the other hand, we have 53.6% of the respondents who claim
that copy protection in principle does not stop them from purchasing a recording. This of course does
not imply that the majority of our respondents will buy more music than before - thus affecting a net
increase in sales - if the production of illegal copies is aggravated. Therefore, we cannot give a
definitive statement based on the survey concerning the extent of changes in sales resulting from copy
protection. The consumers’ desire for unrestricted usability of purchased recordings, especially
regarding the burning of CDs, is also mirrored by the demanded features of commercial download
platforms: 72.7% of the respondents rate this as very important, an additional 20.5% as important.
Taking this into account, it appears questionable that copy protection actually increases record sales.
Against this background a lot of smaller labels, but also majors such as Universal Music Germany and
Sony Music Japan, have re-thought their strategies and went back to selling their records without copy
protection.
Sundararajan (2004) argues in this context that it can be expedient to fully utilize the technologically
feasible copy protection, depending on the possibility of price discrimination. Even a partial
implementation of copy protection measures can help to increase the value of a legal product for
customers with a general willingness to pay. Shapiro and Varian (1998, p. 55; see also Alvisi &
Argentesi & Carbonara 2003) discuss a similar idea using the term “versioning”. They suggest
examining digital goods in respect to such properties which might be important to different potential
consumers. Properties influencing the perceived value of online music can be sound quality, the
transferability to other media or audio devices, and the extent to which restrictive measures are
enforced by digital rights management (Becker & Buhse & Günnewig & Rump 2003, Rosenblatt &
Trippe & Mooney 2002).
3.2 Legal actions against operators and users of file-sharing platforms as a measure to
increase sales of physical sound storage media
Another strategy pursued by the music industry contains legal actions against operators and users of
file-sharing networks. A leading role was played by the Recording Industry Association of America
(RIAA), initiating the respective lawsuits as early as 1999. In the meantime there have also been
similar lawsuits in other countries around the world; e. g. the German National Group of IFPI
successfully sued some 400 file-sharers. It is subject to critical discussion though whether prosecution
actually reduces illegal downloading activity: A survey among 1,371 Internet users conducted by the
Pew Internet Project shows that 14% who previously downloaded music files have turned away from
downloading because of the suits brought against music file-sharers by the industry (Rainie & Madden
2004, p. 1). Furthermore, 60% of those Internet users who have never tried music downloading, say
the RIAA lawsuits would keep them from downloading music files (Rainie & Madden 2004, p. 2).
These results imply that the threat of possible legal action could be a successful means to deter users
from file-sharing. However, we have no evidence that these consumers will now purchase more
records instead of using file-sharing platforms.
How do those legal actions affect the number of people using file-sharing platforms? Although the
user base of the popular file-sharing client KaZaA dropped notably during the survey period between
February and March 2004 (Rainie & Madden 2004, p. 2), alternative peer-to-peer networks like
BitTorrent, iMesh and eMule gained popularity as well as users (Rainie & Madden 2004, p. 4).
According to this report, the number of people who download and swap music files online increased
by 27% since December 2003, even though the Recording Industry Association of America had
already brought several lawsuits against music file-sharers.
Looking at the impact of the novel German copyright legislation, our survey shows differentiated
results as well: While 32.9% of the respondents plan to keep on using file-sharing networks, 25.1%
claim to abandon illegal downloading in the future. Another 23.0% are still undecided, with an
additional 19.0% giving no answer whatsoever.
Another aspect which has to be taken into account when discussing the effectiveness of legal actions
against file-sharing users is the implementation of anonymization functionality in coming file-sharing
applications. Furthermore, there are already several software vendors offering programs which prevent
tracking a user’s Internet or file-sharing behavior, e. g. “Secure Filesharing” by Steganos. This could
also serve as an explanation why the vast majority (84.5%) believes that prosecution will hardly be
able to totally prevent the existence of file-sharing networks.
Our results suggest that the restrictive measures currently taken by the music industry are not
necessarily promising means against the decline in sales. Chen and Png (2003) show that it is welfare
superior to manage piracy through lower prices rather than enforcement. Against this background we
analyze the pricing of online music.
4 PRICING FOR ONLINE MUSIC
4.1 Willingness to pay for online music
Regarding the pricing of digital goods, it generally is assumed that cost orientation plays a subordinate
role. On the one hand, the production leads to high fixed costs, which are “sunk costs” (Shapiro &
Varian 1998, p. 21). On the other hand, digital goods can be reproduced with variable costs close to
zero. Hence, even a low price contributes to the coverage of the fixed costs. A strategy for providers of
digital goods therefore can be to create turnover by selling large quantities at relatively low prices
(Shapiro & Varian 1998, p. 21).
Which pricing models could be considered reasonable from the provider’s perspective? An optimal
strategy would be first-degree price discrimination. In this case the products are sold to every customer
at a price which corresponds to his or her maximum willingness to pay. However, the application of
such a price model is unrealistic for the music industry, since it is hardly possible to detect the
willingness to pay for every single (potential) customer. Furthermore, other alternatives for price
discrimination exist, such as different prices charged for certain customer groups or product features
(Shapiro & Varian 1998). In our study we have examined how far the willingness to pay varies for
different kinds of music. We distinguish between four categories of songs, taking into account the
criteria “novelty” and “availability”. These categories are “Current Hits” (songs currently ranked in
the charts), “Older Titles” (songs which are no longer in the charts but have a high availability),
“Rarities” (unpublished so far or being of low availability) and “Newcomer” (releases by new or still
unknown artists).
When interpreting our results, it has to be taken into account that a direct query of a hypothetical
willingness to pay might lead to the appearance of a hypothetical bias. This means that consumers tend
to assess their willingness to pay higher than it would be the case, if a financial obligation was
imposed (Nape & Frykblom & Harrison & Lesley 2002).
Figure 2. Willingness to pay for different categories of music
As shown in figure 2, most of the survey’s participants would not pay more than 99 Cents per music
download. The only exceptions are rarities, for which 25.6% of respondents claim that their
willingness to pay exceeds 1 €. Furthermore, 28.5% of the people questioned are willing to pay a price
for current hits between 50 and 99 Cents, while only 12.3% and 14.6% would pay the same price for
older titles respectively newcomers. Hence, price discrimination dependent on level of publicity and
availability of recordings can be regarded as an interesting pricing strategy for providers of online
music.
4.2 Estimating optimal prices
To further examine pricing strategies for online music, we analyze which price maximizes the
provider’s revenue based on the results presented in figure 2. By applying a regression analysis, we
derive a demand function DF(p) for each category.
The assumption of an exponential function
(1)
p
bbpDF
10
)( =
leads to the parameter values represented in table 2. Our results were calculated based on the
respective mid-points of class (e. g. 74.5 Cents in the class from 50 to 99 Cents). The resulting demand
functions indicate the demand in percent of the maximum demand. For example, at a price of 99 Cents
10.96% of the potential buyers would buy a current hit (DF(99) = 1.48906 * 0.974099 = 0.1096).
b0 b1 R-Square
DF for category “Current Hit“ 1.48906 0.9740 0.98486
DF for category “Older Title“ 0.93626 0.9738 0.95924
DF for category “Rarity“ 1.17375 0.9874 0.98667
DF for category “Newcomer“ 1.24575 0.9714 0.99401
Table 3. Parameters and stability indexes of demand functions for different categories of music
From the demand function (1) we now derive a sales function S(p) for an arbitrary number of
consumers N:
(2)
NbbppS
p
10
)( =
The sales functions for the individual categories are represented in figure 3. We exemplarily assume
that N=10,000 consumers are interested in buying a download; other values for N lead to similar
graphs with varying ordinate values.
Figure 3. Sales function for music downloads of different categories (N=10,000)
We can now determine which price popt maximizes the turnover by differentiating (2) with respect to p
and satisfying S'(p)=0:
(3)
)ln(
1
1
b
p
opt
=
Hence, the optimal price for the category “Newcomer” is 35 Cents, 38 Cents for a current hit and
39 Cents for an older title (values rounded). The optimal price for rarities, however, is 79 Cents. In
contrast to our results, current prices charged by online music stores often exceed the consumers’
willingness to pay.
So far our analysis was based on the assumption that we can neglect variable costs for digital goods.
However, this assumption proves not to be correct in many practical cases, such as the music industry.
To clarify this, let us take a look at an online store for digital music. This store has to bear costs for
both technology and financial service providers. In the following, we denote these turnover dependent
costs as
[]
1,0
β
. Moreover, variable costs c per download arise, e. g. for collecting societies.
Including these costs into the sales function (2) we derive the following profit function (4):
(4)
cNbbNbbppY
pp 1010
)1()( =
β
The fist part of the profit function consists of the remaining sales after deduction of turnover
dependent costs. From this value we subtract the second part, composed of the number of copies sold
and variable costs per download.
We can now determine the profit-optimal price by differentiating (4) with respect to p and satisfying
Y'(p)=0:
(5)
)1)(ln( )1()ln(
1
1
β
β
=b
cb
p
opt
In the following, let us now examine to what extent arising costs can have an effect on the profit-
maximizing price. We assume a hypothetical setting where a provider of music downloads directly
pays the artists, and thus acts as an intermediary between musicians and consumers. In our example,
the artists receive a share of 20% of the turnover. Furthermore, costs occur for a payment service
provider proportional to the turnover. Conditions for these payment services vary; we assume an
average 8% of the gross price. These costs add up to a β of 0.28. In our example, collecting societies
demand 10 Cents per download. We estimate the additional costs per download charged by the
technology service provider at 5 Cents. The variable costs c per download therefore sum up to a total
of 15 Cents. By inserting these parameter values into (5), we determine the profit-maximizing prices
for the supplier as shown in table 3.
Current Hit Older Title Rarity Newcomer
Optimal price 58.78 Cents 60.08 Cents 99.94 Cents 55.34 Cents
Table 4. Profit-maximizing prices for β=0.28 ; c=15
Even though we now obtain higher optimal values, these are still below the prices usually charged by
most online platforms.
4.3 Implications for the music industry
As our results illustrate, a price cut would probably lead to increased revenues. However, such a low
price strategy is currently not applicable for online shops due to the high variable costs. If, to give an
example, an online shop offers downloads priced at 1.39 €, it currently has to pay approximately
75 Cents per download to the respective label.
A prerequisite for the implementation of such a low price strategy is cooperation between the parties
involved in the digital music supply chain, i. e. musicians/composers, labels, collecting societies,
distributors as well as technological and financial service providers. If these parties considered
themselves a cooperation network, this network could earn more money with a low price strategy than
with the policy pursued until now.
The following simple example based on our survey data is meant to serve as an illustration: If an
online music store offered a current hit at a price of 1.39 €, 86 consumers of the 2,260 survey
respondents would buy the song, thus creating a turnover of 119.54 €. Offered at the profit-
maximizing price of 38 Cents, 1,236 of the respondents would buy the song. As a result, the turnover
would increase to 469.68 €, which corresponds to almost a quadruplication of the turnover. With an
equivalent split of this enlarged turnover, all participants of the cooperation network could profit from
a price reduction.
This result is still valid if arising variable costs are included. Thereby, only those variable costs have
to be examined which have to be carried by the cooperation network, i. e. we only consider costs
actually occurring. These include the expenses the service provider has to pay for each download and
the expenses for the financial service provider per transaction. It is important to note that we do not
include royalties charged by labels or collecting societies in our considerations, since they do not
directly result in variable costs for the players. Let us assume that costs of 15 Cents per download
actually arise for payment and technical processing of one single download. At a price of 1.39 € this
would lead to a profit of 98.69 €, which is divided between the partners of the cooperation network.
According to our model, though, in the context of the same costs, an optimal price would be 53 Cents.
At this price an amount of 833 downloads would be sold, which would result in a turnover of
441.49 €. In this case, a total of 124.95 € would occur as variable costs, which would lead to a profit of
316.54 € for the entire cooperation network.
These results show that the various players in the music industry would most likely profit from a
reasonable price reduction. It is, however, a prerequisite that the parties involved act as a cooperation
network, as established in the automobile supply chain for many years. Furthermore, a solution for
splitting up the revenues is necessary which assures a fair share for the players involved.
5 SUMMARY
Our results suggest that neither the implementation of copy protection mechanisms nor legal actions
taken against users and operators of file-sharing platforms seem to be effective means to overcome the
still existing crisis of the music industry.
Furthermore, it becomes clear that a differentiated willingness to pay for digital music indeed does
exist. It turns out that a price cut for music downloads would lead to increased sales, thus creating
benefits for both suppliers and consumers. This result is supported by an experiment Real Networks
conducted on their Rhapsody platform. Thereby, the service sold three times as many music
downloads for 49 Cents as for 99 Cents (Anderson 2004).
Furthermore, a promising measure for music suppliers could consist in building up attractive online
offers for the consumers. Though file-sharing platforms allow the more or less comfortable free
download of music, a specific support for the users is, however, time and capital-intensive and for a
service like KaZaA hardly feasible. In the digital music shop of the future, a customer ideally finds a
choice of products tailored especially to his or her needs. This can include recommendations for songs
and bands fitting the customers’ taste as well as additional information about artists, concerts in the
surrounding region or special offers, such as a “Happy Hour” with reduced prices, etc. Free music
downloads, an online community or a discount system are other means which can make such a
platform more interesting.
Price cuts as well as an improved customer orientation seem to be more promising strategies than
restrictive measures like copy protection or lawsuits.
References
Alvisi, M., Argentesi, E. and Carbonara, E. (2003). Piracy and Quality Choice in Monopolistic
Markets. http://www.bepress.com/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1061&context=gwp
Anderson, C. (2004). The Long Tail. http://www.wired.com/wired/archive/12.10/tail.html
Becker, E., Buhse, W., Günnewig, D. and Rump, N. (2003). Digital Rights Management:
Technological, Economic, Legal and Political Aspects. Springer, Berlin.
Chen, Y. and Png, I. (2003). Information Goods Pricing and Copyright Enforcement: Welfare
Analysis. Information Systems Research 14 (1), 107-123.
IFPI (2004a). Commercial Piracy Report 04. http://www.ifpi.com/site-content/library/piracy2004.pdf
IFPI (2004b). Online Music Report 04. http://www.ifpi.com/site-content/library/online-music-report-
2004.pdf
Kwok, S. H., Lang, K. R. and Tam, K. Y. (2002). Peer-to-Peer Technology Business and Service
Models: Risks and Opportunities. Electronic Markets 12 (3), 175-183.
Naghavi, A. J. and Schulze, G. G. (2001). Bootlegging in the Music Industry, A Note. European
Journal of Law and Economics 12 (1), 57-72.
Nape, S., Frykblom, P., Harrison, G. W. and Lesley, J. C. (2002). Hypothetical Bias and Willingness
to Accept,
http://www.bus.ucf.edu/gharrison/papers/Hypothetical_Bias_and_Willingness_to_Accept.pdf
Peitz, M. and Waelbroeck, P. (2004). Making Use of File-Sharing in Music Distribution.
http://homepages.ulb.ac.be/~pwaelbro/mp3advert.pdf
Rainie, H. and Madden, M. (2004). The state of music downloading and file-sharing online.
http://www.pewinternet.org/pdfs/PIP_Filesharing_April_04.pdf
Rosenblatt, B., Trippe, B. and Mooney, S. (2002). Digital Rights Management: Business and
Technology. M&T Books, New York.
Shapiro, C. and Varian, H. R. (1998). Information Rules: A Strategic Guide to the Network Economy.
Harvard, Cambridge.
Sundararajan, A. (2004). Managing Digital Piracy: Pricing and Protection. Information Systems
Research, Vol. 15 No. 3, 287-308.
Varian, H. R. (2004). Copying and Copyright.
http://www.pub.utdallas.edu/~liebowit/knowledge_goods/varian.pdf
... Second, there are the reasons related to the willingness of consumers to use the channels, which often refers to their willingness to pay (WTP) for the content sold in digital music stores and services. In several prior studies (e.g., Bauxmann et al., 2005), this WTP has been found to be relatively low, especially when compared to the current prices of the content. The causes for this may relate to the positive pull factors of alternate acquisition channels or to the negative push factors of the stores and services themselves. ...
... Unfortunately, relatively few academic studies have analytically examined the WTP for digital music. Some exceptions include the studies by Bhattacharjee, Gopal, and Sanders (2003), Walsh et al. (2003), Bauxmann et al. (2005, Amberg and Schröder (2007), Breidert and Hahsler (2007), Fetscherin and Lattemann (2007), Sandulli and Martín-Barbero (2007), Styvén (2007), Sinha and Mandel (2008), Chiang and Assane (2009), Doerr et al. (2010), and Sinha, Machado, and Sellman (2010). However, these studies have several shortcomings. ...
... All in all, the findings suggest two very important implications for the business models of music download stores. First, as also concluded by Bauxmann et al. (2005), the current prices of the albums and tracks sold in music download stores seem to be too high for most consumers. In Finland, for example, the prices typically vary from 9.49 € to 12.99 € per album and from 0.99 € to 1.69 € per track, which clearly exceeds the WTP expressed by most of the examined consumer segments, especially in the case of albums. ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper examines the effects of gender, age, and income on the willingness to pay (WTP) for music downloads. The examination is based on an online survey of 1 330 Finnish consumers conducted in June 2010. The analysis of the survey data follows a two-phase strategy. In the first phase, the effects of the explanatory variables on the consumers' unwillingness to pay (UWTP) for album and track downloads are examined by using contingency tables and the Pearson's χ 2 tests of independence. In the second phase, the effects of the explanatory variables on the consumers' actual WTP for album and track downloads are examined by using one-way analysis of variance (1-ANOVA) and post-hoc multiple comparisons. The results of the analysis suggest that there are several statistically significant differences in the WTP for albums and tracks between the examined consumer segments. These findings and their implications should be taken into consideration in the future business models of music download stores.
... Using a conjoint measurement of music downloads, Bamert et al. argue that the price is the most important attribute for the purchase decision of consumers (Bamert, Meier-Bickel and Rüdt 2005). The study of Buxmann et al. shows that the willingness to pay for current hits, older songs, rarities and newcomer differs (Buxmann et al. 2005). Also based on a conjoint measurement Breidert and Hahsler investigate the WTP for different product configurations of music downloads. ...
... The attributes and exact specifications defined for this study are: a 1 Price (2.00/6.00/10.00 Euro), a 2 Contract duration (1/6/12 Month), a 3 Music quality (128/256/320 kbit/s), a 4 Distribution channel (Software/Browser), a 5 Offline access (Yes/No), a 6 Mobile application (Yes/No), a 7 Personalization (Yes/No) and a 8 Community features (Yes/No). ...
Conference Paper
Full-text available
In the last years new concepts of digital music distribution have been developed. One of them is Music as a Service, which provides music streaming over the internet as a service - without transferring ownership for the content. This differentiates Music as a Service from Download to Own, which is used by music download platforms predominantly and is the most widely studied concept in academic research. The aim of this paper is to receive first research implications about customers’ attitudes towards MaaS. Based on an empirical survey of 132 Music as a Service users, this research explores the effects of product configurations on consumers’ utility and their willingness to pay (WTP) for premium offers. We can show that next to price, contract duration and music quality as the most important product attributes, there is a high WTP for overcoming insufficient mobile internet coverage.
... We coded all articles to identi- fy the research articles that relate to the emergence and dis- semination of sharing and servitization business models. We excluded research papers that (1) focus on the technological underpinnings of such business models (e.g., optimizing algo- rithms for enhancing online p2p sharing network capabilities; Jeon and Nahrstedt 2003;Sasabe et al. 2003), (2) are devoted to operations research topics (e.g., the allocation of material as- sets in sharing networks; Fan et al. 2008;Kek et al. 2009), and (3) focus on non-commercial contexts (e.g., illegal file sharing; Buxmann et al. 2005;McKenzie 2009). Although these papers provide valuable contributions to improving operational effi- ciency in commercial sharing consumption contexts, their contribution to understanding the transition of goods to ser- vices consumption is limited. ...
Article
Full-text available
The transition from consuming goods to consuming services is a topic of great interest for service researchers and has been examined from various perspectives. We provide an overview of how this field of research has been approached by systematically analyzing the current state of the academic literature. We report the results of a social network analysis of the sharing economy and servitization literature, which reveals the structure of the knowledge networks that have been formed as a result of the collaborative works of researchers, institutions, and journals that shape, generate, distribute, and preserve the domains’ intellectual knowledge. We shed light on the cohesion and fragmentation of knowledge and highlight the emerging and fading topics within the field. The results present a detailed analysis of the research field and suggest a research agenda on the transition of goods to services consumption.
... They lowered the price from 99 Cents to 49 Cents causing a threefold increase in music sales(Anderson 2004). Another empirical study advocates a price differentiation strategy whereas the optimal price for current hits should be 59 cents, older titles 60 cents, newcomers 55 cents and rarities $1(Buxmann et al. 2005). 2 Interestingly, all new music distribution start-ups emerged from outside of the recording industry's environment -a pattern well known in the history of the music industry. ...
Article
Digital distribution has surpassed physical distribution in key markets and will soon be the dominant music distribution model in Australia. Four different business models (free, ad-funded, pay-per-use and subscription-based) and two different music delivery methods (downloading and streaming) currently compete in the market place. The author analyses each distribution model available in Australia and evaluates advantages and disadvantages from the content provider's perspective. The most striking development is the blurring line between promotion and distribution. Content providers can either lower the barriers to access music in order to facilitate rapid music circulation and create a strong promotional effect to support various revenue streams; or heighten the barriers to access music in order to install an artificial scarcity through excludability, which is essential to implement a business model based on selling musical recordings. In this regard, the variety of different digital distribution models provides a flexible toolbox for content providers to coordinate their overall marketing strategy. © Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2013. All rights are reserved.
... By gender, there were 107 women in the film sample and 102 in the music sample. While low, this is typical for investigations that recruit participants online for studies on film and music (e.g., Buxman et al. 2005 By recruiting participants through Danish film and music websites and relying on self-selection, our data may be prone to non-response bias. In order to prevent this issue, we used a number of response facilitation approaches, as identified by Rogelberg and Stanton (2007), including publicizing the survey, designing it carefully to make nagivation intuitive, providing incentives for responding, and managing survey length by using short item measures. ...
Conference Paper
Full-text available
Technologies enabling digital piracy have expanded the variety of modes available to users when deciding how to access film and music. We examine user decisions in context, investigating which factors influence the decision to use traditional or new legal options over piracy. Our study contributes to the literature by reporting on an extension of an integrated model about user decisions which explores the impact of available technologies, socio-economic characteristics, and differences in user preferences on the legality of users' access behavior. The study uses a sample of Danish internet users recruited from the general population. Findings indicate that the economic considerations of price perception and perceived legal availability are the most consistent factors in influencing the access-mode decisions across the various legal options. We close with a discussion of the implications for research and practice.
Conference Paper
Full-text available
Finding the right pricing for music downloads is of ample importance to the recording industry and music download service providers. For the recently introduced music downloads, reference prices are still developing and to find a revenue maximizing pricing scheme is a challenging task. The most commonly used approach is to employ linear pricing (e.g., iTunes, musicload). Lately, subscription models have emerged, offering their customers unlimited access to streaming music for a monthly fee (e.g., Napster, RealNetworks). However, other pricing strategies could also be used, such as quantity rebates starting at certain download volumes. Research has been done in this field and Buxmann et al. (2005) have shown that price cuts can improve revenue. In this paper we apply different approaches to estimate consumer’s willingness to pay (WTP) for music downloads and compare our findings with the pricing strategies currently used in the market. To make informed decisions about pricing, knowledge about the consumer’s WTP is essential. Three approaches based on adaptive conjoint analysis to estimate the WTP for bundles of music downloads are compared. Two of the approaches are based on a status-quo product (at market price and alternatively at an individually self-stated price), the third approach uses a linear model assuming a fixed utility per title. All three methods seem to be robust and deliver reasonable estimations of the respondent’s WTPs. However, all but the linear model need an externally set price for the status-quo product which can introduce a bias.
Article
Purpose The purpose of this paper is to aim to evaluate to what extent present e‐business models for digital audio distribution meet the consumer's expectations. Design/methodology/approach The research method in this paper is particularly based on two empirical studies. In the first study, the supplier side was examined. In this context, 15 e‐business models in the German music market were identified, classified according to two criteria (type of compensation and dependency on the supplier or its technology) and analysed with regard to four aspects “type and volume of content”, “price of content”, “rights of use”, and “additional services”. To evaluate the identified e‐business models, the consumer expectations for digital audio distribution were analysed in a second study. Finally, the results of both studies were compared. Findings The paper finds that most of the identified e‐business models do not meet all of the fundamental consumer expectations. Either the identified category of e‐business models and its characteristics (e.g. dependency on technology) lead to a conflict with regard to the expectations of the consumers, or the implemented e‐business models reveal discrepancies between the concrete offer and the demand. Research limitations/implications The results in the paper are limited to e‐business models for digital audio distribution in the German music market. Practical implications The paper shows that, in order to reach more consumers, most of the existing e‐business models have to be modified. Originality/value Based on two empirical studies, this paper presents the state‐of‐the‐art of the digital audio distribution in Germany and systematically identifies gaps between the demand and the supply side of digital audio content.
Article
Full-text available
The use of file-sharing technologies, so-called Peer-to-Peer (P2P) net-works, to copy music files has become common since the arrival of Napster. P2P networks may actually improve the matching between products and buyers — we call this the matching effect. For a label the downside of P2P networks is that consumers receive a copy which, although it is an imper-fect substitute to the original, may reduce their willingness-to-pay — we call this the competition effect. We show that the matching effect may dominate so that a label's profits are higher with P2P networks than with-out. Furthermore, we show that the existence of P2P networks may alter the standard business model: sampling may replace costly marketing and promotion. This may allow labels to increase profits in spite of lower sales.
Article
Full-text available
This paper analyzes bootlegging of music, i.e. the unauthorized recording and distribution of previously unreleased music (e.g. a live concert). In particular, we investigate whether, and if so, how this illegal activity may hurt bands and record companies. Bootlegging is different from pirating, where legal releases are illegally copied and sold, because it adds to the product variety. It turns out that welfare implications of bootlegging are decisively different from those of pirating—bootlegged music does not crowd out legal sales.
Article
Full-text available
The sharing and downloading of information goods over peer-to-peer (P2P) networks has become a common way for millions of Internet users worldwide to find and trade music, software and other digital media files. In order for P2P networks to evolve into efficient economic marketplaces several issues need to be addressed. Peers may act in different roles, they can be contributors or consumers of the traded goods. Intermediaries may or may not emerge to better facilitate the trade. This paper discusses supplier risks and business opportunities arising from P2P service models. We propose some participation incentive mechanisms to mitigate free riding risk and improve the overall economic efficiency of P2P trading services and briefly outline how these could be implemented as software features in P2P application systems. This paper also examines the roles of P2P agents and concludes with a three-layer model that describes P2P services at the technology application level, the community application level, and the business application level.
Article
Full-text available
This paper analyzes the effects of three bundling strategies – unbundling, mixed bundling, and pure bundling – on profit and sales, using a simulation study based on a model by Schmalensee (1984). The analysis shows under what conditions which strategy is the most profitable, how large the profit and sales differentials are for each strategy, and what characteristics the corresponding price structures have. Based on our results, we explain the differences observed in the study and derive a set of implications for practical price structuring.
Article
Full-text available
This paper analyzes bootlegging of music, i.e. the unauthorized recording and distribution of previously Ž. unreleased music e.g. a live concert . In particular, we investigate whether, and if so, how this illegal activity may hurt bands and record companies. Bootlegging is different from pirating, where legal releases are illegally copied and sold, because it adds to the product variety. It turns out that welfare implications of bootlegging are decisively different from those of piratingbootlegged music does not crowd out legal sales.
Article
The article analyses empirically four methods of measuring willingness to pay (WTP), i.e., directly stated WTP, indirectly stated WTP (employing conjoint analysis), first price auction and Vickrey auction. The sample consists of 1,089 respondents and more than 3,000 individually measured WTP regarding 100 phone minutes for sale. As one result we found that the measured WTP differs significantly and also substantially between different methods. Furthermore, interviews without purchase obligation, i.e., hypothetic questions, have a clear hypothetical bias. The theoretical advantageousness of Vickrey auctions cannot be confirmed.
Article
Music filesharing systems based on peer-to-peer technology are increasingly menacing the entire music industry. After neglecting the issue in the beginning, the major music labels are now struggling to enforce their property rights in the Internet in order to maintain their profits - up to now without substantial impact. The iTunes Music Store, presented by Apple Inc. in April 2003 is the first commercial service able to persuade a considerable number of internet users to pay for digital music they down-load. This article discusses the major factors which contribute to iTunes' success and analyses the service from different perspectives. From a technological point of view, the digital rights management systems stand out as they are quite liberal and even include peer-to-peer elements. The business perspective suggests that its success lies in the integration of the music industry's need for compensation with the customers' requirements to exchange music files and to write them to CD. Taking a new institutional economics approach, the service pays attention to the fact that in the Internet age some (intellectual) property rights can not be enforced in a way the music industry was used to in pre-lnternet times. Leaving some property rights not allocated the remaining property rights can be enforced more efficiently by presenting an innovative and easy-to-use service.
Article
This paper analyzes the optimal choice of pricing schedules and technological deterrence levels in a market with digital piracy where sellers can influence the degree of piracy by implementing digital rights management (DRM) systems. It is shown that a monopolist's optimal pricing schedule can be characterized as a simple combination of the zero-piracy pricing schedule, and a piracy-indifferent pricing schedule that makes all customers indifferent between legal usage and piracy. An increase in the quality of pirated goods, while lowering prices and profits, increases total surplus by expanding both the fraction of legal users and the volume of legal usage. In the absence of price-discrimination, a seller's optimal level of technology-based protection against piracy is shown to be at the technologically maximal level, which maximizes the difference between the quality of the legal and pirated goods. However, when a seller can price-discriminate, its optimal choice is always a strictly lower level of technology-based protection. These results are based on the following digital rights conjecture: that granting digital rights increases the incidence of digital piracy, and that managing digital rights therefore involves restricting the rights of usage that contribute to customer value. Moreover, if a digital rights management system weakens over time due to the underlying technology being progressively hacked, a seller's optimal strategic response may involve either increasing or decreasing its level of technology-based protection. This direction of change is related to whether the DRM technology implementing each marginal reduction in piracy is increasingly less or more vulnerable to hacking. Pricing and technology choice guidelines are presented, and some welfare implications are discussed.
Article
e consider how the government should set the fine for copying, tax on copying medium, and subsidy on legitimate purchases, whereas a monopoly publisher sets price and spending on detection. There are two segments of potential software users—ethical users who will not copy, and unethical users who would copy if the benefit outweighs the cost. In de- ciding on policy, the government must consider how the publisher adjusts price and detection to changes in the fine, tax, and subsidy. Our key welfare result is that increases in detection affect welfare more negatively than price cuts. We also show that the tax is welfare superior to the fine, and that a subsidy is optimal. Generally, government policies that focus on penalties alone will miss the social welfare optimum. (Copyright; Pricing; Enforcement)