ArticlePDF AvailableLiterature Review

Abstract

Hardly a week goes by without a front-page newspaper article on rising health care costs and the uninsured. In this article, I focus mainly on costs, arguing that the issue has been somewhat misconceived: while the level of medical care spending in the U.S. is a cause for concern, the welfare losses associated with rises in that level of spending may not be as large as the public rhetoric can make them seem. In fact, cost containment may not be as urgent as is widely supposed, and some proposed "cost containment" policies may result in welfare losses for the insured and even increase the number of uninsured
Journal of
Economic Perspectives
Volume
6, Number 3
Summer
1992
Pages
3–21
Medical Care Costs: How Much
Welfare Loss?
Joseph P. Newhouse
H
ardly a week goes by without a front-page newspaper article on rising
health care costs and the uninsured. In this article, I focus mainly on
costs,
arguing that the issue has been somewhat misconceived: while
the level of medical care spending in the U.S. is a cause for concern, the welfare
losses associated with rises in that level of spending may not be as large as the
public rhetoric can make them seem. In fact, cost containment may not be as
urgent as is widely supposed, and some proposed "cost containment" policies
may result in welfare losses for the insured, and even increase the number of
uninsured.
The Magnitude of the Medical Expenditure Increase
As both newspapers and pay stubs remind us, the health care sector is a
large part of the economy; spending on health care, $666 billion in 1990,
exceeded 12 percent of GNP. At the federal level, Medicare (for the elderly)
and Medicaid (for the poor) represent 15 percent of outlays. Medicare is the
second largest domestic program of the federal government. At the state level,
Medicaid is 11 percent of total expenditures (1991 Economic Report of the
President, Tables B-76, B-82).
Despite these magnitudes, I think the crux of public concern over health
care costs comes from the data in Table 1; real medical care expenditures per
capita have been growing at around 4 percent per year for five
decades,
except
Joseph P. Newhouse is John D. MacArthur Professor of Health Policy and Manage-
ment, Harvard University, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
4 Journal of Economic Perspectives
Table 1
Growth in Real Health Care Expenditure and GNP, by Decade
(% per year)
in the 1960s when growth was even more rapid. At these rates of growth, the
share of GNP devoted to medical care has also been steadily growing.
Neither citizens nor economists, of course, are especially concerned about
rapid growth in most sectors of the economy, like the personal computer
industry, the fax machine industry, or the cellular phone industry. The conven-
tional explanation of why growth in medical costs is different emphasizes the
moral hazard from health insurance and particularly the tax treatment of
health insurance.
Traditional health insurance reimburses as a function of expenditure or
use.
Because insurance drives the marginal price of medical care at the point of
use to near zero, so the usual view goes, consumers—or physicians acting as
their agents—demand care until the marginal product of additional care is
nearly zero. To use Alain Enthoven's (1980) phrase, we engage in "flat-of-the-
curve" medicine, where spending on medical care increases even though the
additional gains from such spending are very low or nonexistent.
1
Moreover,
the argument continues, the exclusion of employer-paid premiums from tax-
able income exacerbates this situation by leading to excessive health insurance
(Feldstein and Allison, 1974). Pauly (1986) offers a review of this literature; a
1
This view is buttressed by studies showing a reasonably high percentage of procedures—a sixth to
a third, among three procedures studied—that upon clinical review were deemed to be "medically
inappropriate" (Chassin et al., 1987).
Joseph P. Newhouse 5
more recent example of this line of argument is the 1991
Economic
Report of
the
President (p. 142).
However, I will contend that economists have been too preoccupied with a
one-period model of health care services that takes technology as given, and
that we need to pay more attention to technological change.
2
In particular, the
literature has focused on the tradeoff between moral hazard and risk sharing in
the context of the one-period model. The cocktail party story of excessive
medical spending built around that model has some validity, of course. The
price elasticity of demand for medical care services is not zero. Far from it; a
fully insured population spends about 40 to 50 percent more than a population
with a large deductible, and their health status is not measurably improved by
the additional services (Manning et al., 1987).
In this essay I wish to distinguish the welfare losses at a point in time from
those that may occur because of the increases in expenditure over time. My
initial focus, then, is why medical expenditure is increasing, as opposed to
merely "high." To explain increasing expenditure, one needs to point to
something that is changing, indeed to factors that have been changing for 50
years.
Accounting for the Medical Expenditure Increase
In accounting for the expenditure increase, my methods will be similar to
those in the literature accounting for economic growth; identify a series of
factors, determine how much of the change they might account for, and
attribute the residual to technological change. In particular, I consider three
factors known to affect demand for medical services—aging, the spread of
insurance, and the growth of income—as well as two factors that are said to
affect the supply of services—supplier-induced demand and differential pro-
ductivity growth. By deferring consideration of technological change, I want to
establish that the one-period model, with constant technology, cannot give us
much help in explaining the expenditure increase.
Aging
The proportion of elderly has been growing steadily for 50 years, which
might be expected to raise expenditures on medical care. But by how much?
One way to tackle this question would be to calculate by how much spending
would increase solely as a result of the changing proportion by age group, if
spending per person in each age group were fixed over time. For example, the
proportion of the population between the ages of 19 and 64 stayed nearly
constant between 1950 and 1987, rising from 59 to 60 percent. However, the
2
Goddeeris (1984a, 1984b) is a notable exception, as is Weisbrod's (1991) survey article of a year
ago.
6 Journal of Economic Perspectives
population of those over 65 increased from 8 percent of the population in 1950
to 12 percent in 1987, while the proportion of those below age 19 fell from 33
percent to 28 percent. Using the weights given by the average expenditures per
person in each age group in 1987, this swing can account for an increase of 15
percent in total spending.
3
However, the data in Table 1 imply that real
expenditure per capita grew over this period by more than a factor of 5. Thus,
aging can only account directly for a tiny fraction of the increase in expendi-
ture.
Victor Fuchs (1990) has questioned this type of calculation, pointing out
that other effects may be associated with aging. He notes that spending rises
rapidly in the period shortly before death and that as age-specific mortality
rates fall, fewer people at each age are close to death. This would cause the
method just described to understate the effect of aging on costs, essentially
because deaths are concentrated among the elderly, so spending on the elderly
relative to the non-elderly is temporarily depressed while mortality rates are
falling. To get some sense of the quantitative importance of this argument, I
calculated the effect of aging using elderly to non-elderly spending rates from
1977 rather than 1987.
4
The 1977 values give virtually the same result as those
from
1987.
Thus, this criticism does not seem quantitatively important.
Fuchs also speculates that falling age-specific mortality rates may increase
the propensity to intervene medically at any age, which provides an alternate
reason why an aging population may consume ever more medical care. It is
more difficult to assess this argument quantitatively, in part because causation
could run the other way; an increased propensity to intervene could lower the
age-specific mortality rate. However, whichever way the causation runs, the
magnitude of the negative correlation between mortality and spending may not
be large. In the four previous decades, age-adjusted death rates fell least in the
1960s and most in the 1970s, but the rate of expenditure increase was greatest
in the 1960s and next to least in the 1970s. Unfortunately, the 1960s also saw
the introduction of Medicare and Medicaid, which makes any inference from
these data about Fuchs' argument problematic. On balance, however, neither
the direct nor indirect effects of aging on expenditure appear to account for
much of the sustained rise in medical expenditure.
Increased Insurance
This explanation is probably closest to the conventional wisdom among
economists; the spread of insurance has steadily reduced price to the consumer
3
I used the 1987 data for this calculation because I have data on medical spending by five-year age
group for the over-65 for that year and thus can better adjust for aging within the over 65 group.
The data are from Waldo et al. (1989) with corrections supplied by Daniel Waldo. Also, I use the
period beginning in 1950 because I could not readily locate 1940 data on age, but there can be
little doubt that the conclusion would be the same.
4
The calculation for 1977 is somewhat cruder. I only have data on medical spending per person for
the under 19, 19–64, and over 65 age groups for 1977, so I could not use the five-year age cohorts
as described in the previous note. In comparing 1977 and 1987 results, I have used the spending
comparisons for these three age groups in both cases.
Medical Care Costs: How Much Welfare Loss? 7
and driven up demand for medical services, thereby resulting in a steady
expenditure increase. Like the aging argument, this argument has an element
of truth, but it also leaves the great bulk of the increase unaccounted for.
The data from Manning et al. (1987) already referred to show that the
effect of moving from an average coinsurance rate of 33 percent to a coinsur-
ance rate of zero at a point in time is roughly a 40 to 50 percent increase in
demand.
5
The change in the average coinsurance rate from 1950 to 1980 was
from 67 percent to 27 percent. Thus, if a function relating demand to the
average coinsurance rate were linear and if there were no technological change,
the 40 percentage point drop in coinsurance should have caused about a 50
percent increase in demand from 1950 to 1980.
6
Thus, the factor-of-five
increase in real expenditure per person over this period is perhaps eight times
as large as one could account for solely from the effect of increased insurance
on demand in the context of the one-period model.
Another fact that is not consistent with the importance of increased de-
mand from the spread of insurance is that the largest single component of the
increase in real medical expenditure per person has been in the hospital sector.
Yet the average coinsurance rate for hospital services was essentially constant at
about 5 percent in the 1980s (Levit et al., 1991) while real hospital expenditure
rose over 50 percent during the decade.
Increased Income
Medical care is a normal good, so growth in income can also account for an
increase in expenditure. Estimates of the income elasticity of demand for
medical care within the United States (done with cross-section observations
across households, holding insurance constant) are around 0.2–0.4. From 1940
to 1990, real GNP per capita increased by 180 percent. Using an estimate of
income elasticity of 0.2 to 0.4, income growth (given technology) could account
for around a 35 to 70 percent increase in expenditure, obviously a small
portion of the 780 percent actual increase.
In international cross sections of developed countries, with the country as
the unit of observation, however, income elasticities of demand for medical care
are around 1.0 or even more (Newhouse, 1977; Parkin, McGuire, and Yule,
1987;
Gerdtham et al., 1992). Using aggregate relationships can lead to well-
known problems (Parkin, McGuire, and Yule, 1987). Nonetheless, one might
5
Estimated price elasticities are in the range of 0.1 to 0.2. See Manning et al. (1987) for three
different methods of calculating price elasticities.
6
There are serious conceptual problems in relating demand to an average coinsurance rate; for
example, an average coinsurance rate that comes from a deductible followed by full coverage is
likely to have different effects than from a constant coinsurance rate. Thus, one should not expect
the function relating an average coinsurance rate to medical expenditure to be unique. Nonethe-
less,
I am only trying to get a rough feel for the importance of various factors, and for that purpose
ignoring the conceptual problems associated with this function seems permissible. Moreover, it is
worth noting that if the relevant function was constant elasticity rather than linear, there would be
a smaller increase in demand than that estimated in the text. For a discussion of these problems
and their implications for estimation of demand, see Newhouse, Phelps, and Marquis (1980).
8 Journal of Economic Perspectives
prefer this estimate of the income elasticity because the within-country income
elasticities may be distorted by the endogeneity of income at the household
level; sickness may simultaneously depress income and raise medical spending.
Using 1.0 as an income elasticity rather than 0.2 to 0.4, one could account for a
little under a quarter of the overall increase.
7
Supplier-Induced Demand
A substantial literature in health economics has been concerned with
supplier- or physician-induced demand (Cromwell and Mitchell, 1986; Rice,
1983).
This literature has not reached consensus on the magnitude of supplier-
induced demand, but even granting its importance at a point in time, one can
ask about its importance over time. That is, if physicians have considerable
discretion in treating ignorant consumers, to what degree might they have
induced more and more demand?
Those who emphasize supplier-induced demand as a factor in the expendi-
ture increase argue that as physician supply has grown, physicians have in-
creased demand to protect their incomes (for the theory underlying this view
see McGuire and Pauly, 1991). The evidence, however, does not offer much
support to the view that supplier-induced demand is important in the rate of
change. As a crude measure, I list the decade-by-decade changes in physician
supply per person in Table 2. There is no correlation with the similar data on
expenditure given earlier in Table 1.
I do not want to make too much of the lack of a simple correlation among
six observations. One could, for example, argue that economy-wide growth has
slowed since 1970, decreasing demand (ceteris paribus) and offsetting induce-
ment effects from the increase in physician supply. Nonetheless, the lack of any
obvious change in the rate of expenditure growth after 1970, when physician
supply clearly increased, is striking.
A variant of the supplier-induced demand argument is "defensive
medicine," or the use of tests and procedures with little or no value to patients
to minimize the chance of a successful malpractice suit. Although the amount of
such medicine is uncertain, the most widely cited estimate pegged it at around
1 percent of all medical expenditure in 1984 (Reynolds, Rizzo, and Gonzalez,
7
Income elasticities from time series data within countries are typically around 1. For example,
Schieber and Poullier (1989) present data for 20 OECD countries from 1975 to 1987. The countries
have income elasticities that vary from 0.9 to 1.3, with 10 having a value of 1.1. (I use the
"nominal" income elasticities shown in their Table 2 because I believe there are conceptual
problems with the health price deflator they use to estimate "real" elasticities. See the text below.)
In general one might expect that time series income elasticities would exceed the cross section
income elasticities; technology is not held constant in the time series, and the income elasticity for
new technology should be positive, thus adding to the income elasticity for additional care given
technology observed at a point in time. Because of the magnitude of the time-series income
elasticity, I am inclined to believe that the income elasticity relevant to the calculation in this
section, which is the income elasticity for additional care given technology, would be well under 1.
Joseph P. Newhouse 9
Table 2
Decade-by-Decade Growth in Numbers
of Physicians per Person
(annual rate of increase)
1987).
Thus, even if defensive medicine were zero in 1940, its growth can only
account for a trivial fraction of the expenditure increase.
Factor Productivity in a Service Industry
Yet another argument that has been made to account for increases in
medical spending is that medical care is a service. If productivity gains are
lower for services like medical care than in the rest of the economy, then
relative medical prices would rise over time; because demand is inelastic
expenditures would also rise (Baumol, 1988). The magnitude of productivity
gains in medical care is an exceedingly difficult question because of the
difficulty in measuring the product. Perhaps zero productivity growth is appro-
priate for long-term care and home health care. These sectors, however,
represent only about 10 percent of the entire medical care sector. In the light
of the technological change discussed in the next section, I think the assump-
tion of no productivity gain for acute medical care services is implausible;
indeed, a true productivity measure might even go up at or in excess of
economy-wide rates. For example, the treatment of heart attacks has certainly
changed more than haircuts or the performance of Mozart string quartets,
standard examples of services whose productivity has scarcely changed. Thus, it
is not clear that much of the expenditure increase should be assigned to this
factor.
In principle, a price index for medical care offers the potential to shed
light on this point. If medical care inflation were similar to general price
inflation, one could reject the concept that differential productivity growth is
driving the price levels apart. In the 1980s, medical price inflation exceeded
10 Journal of Economic Perspectives
the general consumer price index by 3.4 percent per year, which would seem
to offer some support for the idea that lagging productivity growth is the
reason more is spent on medical care. However, the gap was only .4 percent
per year in the 1970s, 2.0 percent per year in the 1960s, and 1.9 percent per
year in the 1950s.
Moreover, the consumer price index for medical care has severe measure-
ment problems, so severe so that I would not draw any inferences on productiv-
ity from it. Four main problems include:
First, the consumer price index for medical services focuses on the costs of
physician visits and days in the hospital, not the costs of treating ailments. As
Scitovsky (1967) emphasized a quarter century ago, the product the consumer
is really purchasing is the treatment of a medical problem. The relevant cost,
therefore, is the cost of treating, say, a heart attack or appendicitis, not the cost
of a day in the hospital. Especially in the 1980s, length of stay for various
diseases has been falling sharply. Setting aside the issue of whether this reflects
a change in quality, a true price index would need to reflect the total cost of
treatment, but the existing index does not. Moreover, the last day(s) of a stay
are less resource-intensive than the first days. Thus, a fall in the average length
of stay will increase the resource intensity per day, which conceivably could
result in an increase in the price per day; that is, the consumer price index
could be signalling an increased price (per day) when there was actually a
decreased price (per treatment). By focusing on the cost of a day in the
hospital, the consumer price index also fails to register any savings when the
treatment of some diseases, like cataracts, is shifted out of the hospital to
out-patient surgery or when a new drug changes treatment so that surgery is
not required as often, as has happened with ulcers.
Second, the consumer price index has historically used the list price for
medical care, not the actual transaction price. In fact, there are hardly any
transactions at the list price that the CPI uses for hospitals. The Bureau of
Labor Statistics is attempting to correct this problem. But Dranove et al. (1991)
estimate that this factor alone caused the CPI to overstate hospital price
increases in California by 40 percent in the 1980s.
Third, the consumer price index makes no adjustment for quality change.
With the rate of introduction of new products and procedures into medical
care,
surely acting as if quality is unchanged will lead to large overstatement in
the medical portion of the consumer price index.
Fourth, the various components of the medical care portion of the con-
sumer price index—hospital, physician, dental, drug—are combined into an
overall medical care price index using weights proportional to out-of-pocket
expenditure. Because insurance coverage differs between these components,
hospital spending, which accounts for about 40 percent of personal medical
care spending, has a weight in the medical care CPI that is half as large.
Indeed, the weight on hospital spending is only slightly larger than the weight
on dental spending, although dental spending accounts for less than 10 percent
Medical Care Costs: How Much Welfare Loss? 11
of total health care spending. This criticism affects the component price indices
much less, but it certainly affects one's ability to use the overall medical care
CPI to decompose the increase in health care expenditure into increases in
price and increases in quantity, as is needed to test the productivity-based
explanation for growth in overall medical expenditures.
8
For all these reasons I do not believe we have any good empirical basis for
decomposing the medical care expenditure increase into increases in price and
increases in quantity.
Technological Change in Medical Care
Because of the problem in measuring productivity, it is hard to know how
much of the increase all the above factors can account for (assuming no
technological change). My own view is that they account for well under
half—perhaps under a quarter—of the 50-year increase in medical care expen-
diture. Thus, we are left with trying to explain a large residual.
I believe the bulk of the residual increase is attributable to technological
change, or what might loosely be called the march of science and the increased
capabilities of medicine. By technological change I mean not only new types of
physical capital, such as magnetic resonance imaging, but also new procedures,
such as coronary artery bypass grafting. Other examples abound: renal dialysis;
transplantation; artificial joints; endoscopy; monoclonal antibodies; drugs for
mental illness. Both the last example and the polio vaccine example emphasize
that technological change is not necessarily expenditure-increasing, but if it is
on balance expenditure-lowering, as is sometimes argued (Thomas, 1975),
accounting for the rise in expenditure is more difficult than ever.
Trying to attribute a residual to a specific factor is an inherently frustrating
exercise, and the best I can do to support my argument that much of the
residual is attributable to the new capabilities of medicine—new product lines,
if one prefers—is to buttress it with data that I believe are consistent with it.
There are three such sorts of data.
The first are shown in Table 3. If medical technology were constant, then
increased demand from more elderly, more insurance, and more income
should result in more hospital patient days. However, patients are not going to
the hospital more frequently—indeed, admission rates are now barely above
1960 levels and age adjustment would wipe out the difference—nor are
patients staying longer; length of stay has fallen. But the real cost of a day (or a
stay) in the hospital rose by nearly a factor of 4 from 1965 to 1986. (Data are
8
Even the component indices are affected to the degree that the actual services priced have
differential insurance coverage. For example, prior to the late 1970s, insurance commonly did not
cover maternity services, or covered such services with a lump-sum allowance. This caused the
hospital component of the CPI to overweight maternity services if the aim was to decompose
hospital expenditure increases into price and quantity increases.
12 Journal of Economic Perspectives
Table 3
Utilization of Short Stay General Hospitals
not readily available from before 1965.) Thus, what is being done to and for
people who are in the hospital is affecting hospital costs, not an increased
number of people at the hospital.
Remember that the increase in hospital expenditure is the single largest
component of the overall expenditure increase. The evidence that this increase
has occurred in the cost of a patient day, not in the rate of patient days per
person, is certainly consistent with a story that technological change accounts
for the bulk of the increase in costs.
9
The second set of data are data on costs of enrollees in Health Maintenance
Organizations (HMOs). HMOs combine the insurance and delivery functions
and are generally paid a fixed dollar amount per month per enrollee. The costs
borne by enrollees in HMOs have risen at roughly the same rate as personal
health care expenditures, albeit at each point in time they are at a lower level
(Newhouse et al., 1985). Although HMOs appear to eliminate some of the low
benefit (relative to cost) hospitalization at each point in time (Luft, 1981; Sloss
et al., 1987), whatever drives up costs in the predominantly fee-for-service
medical care system also drives up costs in HMOs. The factor or factors
responsible for increasing costs could be common rises in factor prices in both
systems, but common changes in the technology available is also consistent with
the data.
Third, international comparisons also underline the conclusion that dif-
ferent types of medical systems have much the same increases in spending. The
9
Nor have visit rates to physicians much changed. In 1958–59 they were 4.7 per person; in 1970s,
4.6;
in 1980, 4.8; and in 1989, 5.4. Data are from the National Health Interview Survey for the
respective year.
Joseph P. Newhouse 13
annual percent increase in real per capita health spending in the U.S. from
1960 to 1987 was 5.0 percent. The rate of increase was lower in the United
Kingdom, Canada, and Germany, at 3.7, 4.7, and 4.8 percent, respectively. But
the rate of increase was higher in France, Italy, and Japan, at 5.8, 6.0, and 8.9
percent, respectively.
10
In the light of the pronounced institutional differences
among these countries in medical care financing arrangements, the similarity in
the real rate of growth is striking. Thus, whatever is behind the medical care
expenditure rise appears to be common across these countries. The advance in
medical technology is, of course, one such common factor.
Was Technological Change Induced by Insurance?
I come below to some normative comments about the increase in costs.
One's views about the cost increases, however, might differ if one thought the
change was induced by high levels of insurance, perhaps in turn induced by the
tax subsidy, such that there was a welfare loss from too much change. At this
point I only want to point out the fallacy in an argument sometimes heard in
the public debate—that without insurance people could not afford to pay for
much of the technology; hence, the change was induced by insurance, and ipso
facto the technology represents a welfare loss. The essence of the fallacy is that
the appropriate first-best condition is not what would be observed in an
uninsured market, but what consumers are willing to pay for an insurance
policy that would cover the technology in relevant states of the world (Marshall,
1976;
De Meza, 1983; Goddeeris, 1984a, 1984b). In other words, a principal
function of insurance is to transfer income across states of the world; one may
well want more income, for example, in a state of the world where one's
kidneys have failed. The inference that kidney dialysis or kidney transplant
technology necessarily represents a welfare loss because most uninsured con-
sumers could not afford it is thus incorrect.
What Has Been Done About Medical Costs?
Over the years a variety of "cost containment" techniques have been tried.
On balance, these techniques appear to have been beneficial, but they have had
primarily a once-and-for-all effect on the level of medical expenditure, leaving
the steady-state rate of change little affected (Schwartz, 1987). I will discuss
three of the recent efforts to control costs by both the private and the public
sector.
10
The
bulge in Japan is entirely attributable to the decade of the 1960s, when real per capita GDP
in Japan grew by 11 percent per year and real health care expenditure grew by 14 percent per
year, thus helping drive up expenditures on health care along with everything else.
14 Journal of Economic Perspectives
First, initial cost sharing by patients has increased. Private insurers in-
creased deductibles substantially in the early 1980s. For example, the propor-
tion of firms with a deductible of $200 or more in a sample of medium
and large firms rose from 4 percent to 21 percent between 1982 and 1984
(Goldsmith, 1984). Even more strikingly, the number of such firms that had no
initial cost sharing for hospital services fell from 70 percent to 37 percent in
that two-year period. This increased amount of cost sharing almost certainly
was responsible for part of the decline in admissions shown earlier.
11
Although this increase in initial cost sharing appears effective and efficient,
there is little reason to think that it will change the long-term rate of cost
increases. Indeed, another trend in the 1980s, toward caps on out-of-pocket
spending, will increase cost, since it creates a marginal price of zero for most
hospitalized patients.
12
The spread of such caps provides better protection
against risk, but has meant an even greater proportion of hospital patients face
no cost for the marginal service or procedure, consistent with the increase in
services delivered per stay.
Increased enrollment in health maintenance organizations has been a
second approach to cost containment. The federal government has encouraged
enrollment in health maintenance organizations since the mid-1970s as a
cost-containment technique. We have already seen, however, that the effects on
costs were of the once-and-for-all variety; the rate of growth in HMO spending
appears similar to the entire sector.
A third method of addressing costs has been the adoption of prospective
payment systems. In particular, in 1983 Medicare began to reimburse hospitals
using Diagnosis Related Groups (DRGs), which shifted the basis of payment
from one which paid marginal cost approximately in full to one which paid a
lump sum per type of admission, which meant the marginal revenue for an
additional day was zero.
13
Not surprisingly, length of stay fell, but in a few years
bottomed out (Schwartz and Mendelsohn, 1991). Whether there will be an
effect on the steady-state rate of growth in spending remains to be seen. That
will depend upon the degree to which Medicare accounts for new technology in
changing its lump sum over time. Uncertainty about such reimbursement,
11
A much smaller decline in admissions was seen among the elderly, consistent with this story. The
hospital portion of Medicare (Part A) has a deductible that rose in real terms; however, the majority
of Medicare beneficiaries have so-called Medigap or supplementary insurance that typically pays
the deductible. Thus, most Medicare beneficiaries face no effective deductible, and the increases in
the nominal deductible are transformed into increases in premiums.
12
The increased use of caps on out-of-pocket expenditure and increased deductibles left the
out-of-pocket share constant, as noted above. The argument in the text about the marginal price
assumes that price is foreseen. Typically, this will hold if the initial deductible will be small enough
that with high probability it will be exceeded during the hospitalization. There may be some
uncertainty about whether a cap on out-of-pocket payments will be exceeded, however, mitigating
the force of this argument.
13
Marginal revenue is positive for outlier patients, but they are less than 5 percent of cases.
Medicare accounts for just over a quarter of hospital revenues.
Medical Care Costs: How Much Welfare Loss? 15
however, may well decrease spending on the development of new technology
by increasing risk.
The Willingness to Pay for New Technology
Clearly medical expenditures cannot grow forever at a rate 2 to 3 percent-
age points greater than the growth in the economy. Thus, if market forces do
not act to slow the growth, at some point public sector interventions, such as
global budget ceilings, may be desirable. Indeed, legislation contemplating such
ceilings has been introduced. The key issue in appraising such ceilings from a
social welfare point of view is whether consumers are willing to pay for the new
capabilities available to them.
As already noted, the dominant view of health insurance in the economics
literature, at least in the American literature, is that "too much" health insur-
ance leads consumers to demand "too much" medical care at each point in
time,
which is reasonably well established, as well as "too much" technological
change, which is less well established. In two interesting theoretical papers,
Goddeeris (1984a, 1984b) derives the conditions under which a costly techno-
logical change that increased capabilities would increase or decrease welfare. In
the case in which income elasticity for change exceeds zero, surely the interest-
ing case, an innovation that would not be bought without insurance may
nonetheless increase welfare. Whether it does so depends on the marginal
utility of income in the state to which the innovation applies and the number of
low-benefit users induced by the insurance coverage. Although this tells us that
the simple intuition that any subsidy represents a welfare loss does not neces-
sarily apply, it leaves us with the empirical question of how much welfare loss
there might be from the actual rate of change.
Direct evidence is scarce, but some of the evidence cited above suggests the
welfare loss from the additional spending on technology may be less than some
of the rhetoric surrounding the need for cost containment would imply.
First, the real rate of increase in costs is similar across countries, some of
which make centralized decisions about how much to spend on medical care
and all of which have financing institutions that differ from those of the United
States.
14
Countries like Canada and the United Kingdom make explicit bud-
getary decisions about the size of the medical care sector each year and
explicitly trade off medical care against other public sector goods and private
consumption.
14
The U.S. has a large positive residual if current cross sectional health expenditures are regressed
on income (Schieber and Poullier, 1989). A similar regression on earlier data, however, shows the
U.S.
with a much smaller residual (Newhouse, 1977). Thus, relative to GNP growth, U.S. health
expenditure has grown faster than other countries in the 1980s. There is no obvious change in U.S.
financing arrangements in the 1980s that would explain this, however.
16 Journal of Economic Perspectives
Second, the rate of increase in HMO costs in the United States has been
similar to the overall medical care sector. If there were a public preference for
less and cheaper technology, HMOs might have offered it. However, they
apparently do not believe that demand exists for cheaper medical care using a
lower level of technology.
Drawing the inference that consumers are willing to pay for new technol-
ogy from the fact that HMOs have had similar cost increases is open to
argument on several grounds. Some consumers do not face the price difference
between the HMO and traditional reimbursement insurance, because the
employer subsidizes the difference. Others pay the difference with before-tax
dollars. Moreover, offering a markedly outdated technology would open an
HMO to malpractice complaints, since the legal standard used to establish
negligence is the conventional standard of care. Nonetheless, if many con-
sumers felt that new technology wasn't worth the price, it seems odd that we do
not observe some firms trying to enter and offer at least some aspects of 1960s
medicine at 1960s prices.
A Note on The Terminally Ill
One frequently mentioned cause of rising medical expenditure in popular
writing is the treatment of the terminally ill. There is a grain of truth in the
popular perception; among those over 67 years of age, 6 percent died in 1978,
but that group accounted for 28 percent of the expenditure over a two-year
period (Lubitz and Prihoda, 1984).
But taken as a whole, the data offer little support for the notion that society
is wasting an ever-larger share of resources in a fruitless attempt to save those
who are about to die. Spending in the last year of life has not contributed
disproportionately to the
increase
in medical care costs. The share of spending
by those in their last year of life was stable between 1967 and 1979 (Lubitz and
Prihoda, 1984). Moreover, only 6 percent of those who died in 1978 had more
than $15,000 of Medicare expenses, which does not fit the popular image of
heroic efforts being exerted on many terminally ill patients. Put another way,
most dying patients are sick individuals who will receive some sort of care; it
does not appear that a great many of them are receiving enormous amounts of
care.
Furthermore, one usually does not know twelve months before the date of
death that this is one's last year of life. In the late 1970s, physicians were asked
to predict short-term survival probabilities of patients being admitted to an
intensive care unit (Detsky, Striker, Mulley et al., 1981). Those conducting the
study then looked at spending as a function of predicted survival probabilities.
They found that among survivors, expenditure correlated negatively with
predicted survival probabilities (for example, expenditure when the predicted
probability of survival was 25 percent was approximately three times as large as
Joseph P. Newhouse 17
when the predicted probability was 75 percent). Among those who died,
however, expenditure correlated positively with survival probability (for exam-
ple,
expenditure was nearly twice as large when the predicted probability of
survival was 75 percent as when it was 25 percent). Thus, spending was largest
for patients whom physicians expected to live but did not, or for whom
physicians expected to die but did not. These findings are consistent with
rational sequential choice under uncertainty or Bayesian learning; in other
words, many of the 6 percent who spent more than $15,000 may well have
been expected to live.
While the terminally ill undoubtedly absorb some spending of little or even
negative value, it does not appear that such spending is a disproportionate
cause of the increase in medical care costs.
The Uninsured
I now turn from the level of costs to another major health policy issue of
the day, the lack of universal health insurance coverage. About 15 percent of
the U.S. population has no health insurance. The conventional economics view
of this issue is that it is partly distributional; partly an issue arising out of the
connection in the United States between health insurance and one's employ-
ment (for example, those in their 20's seeking their first job have dispropor-
tionately high numbers of uninsured); and partially a market failure resulting
from asymmetric information. As is well known, if the insured knows more
about his or her expected expense than the insurer, there may be no competi-
tive equilibrium, because of adverse selection (Rothschild and Stiglitz, 1976).
Indeed, Akerlof's (1970) classic paper on asymmetric information views the
Medicare program as a public sector remedy for insurance market failure
among the elderly (because they lack the labor-market tie to employer-based
insurance), and Diamond (1992) has recently proposed breaking the connec-
tion between employment and health insurance to remedy selection problems
among the non-elderly.
A program that provided full insurance for the uninsured, according to the
best estimates available, would cause their demand to double (Keeler and
Rolph, 1988). The overall increase in demand for medical care would then be
determined by whether the uninsured are above or below average in their rate
of spending.
The uninsured are a heterogeneous risk group; some of them are individu-
als with a chronic illness who do not have a labor force connection and cannot
purchase individual insurance, or at least insurance that covers their condition.
This group is presumably of above-average risk. Others are people in their 20s
looking for their first job who have chosen not to purchase individual insurance
in part because they believe they are healthy. This group is presumably of
below-average risk. On balance the uninsured as a group probably are
18 Journal of Economic Perspectives
somewhat above average
in
their risk.
On the
other hand, partial rather than
full insurance coverage
is a
more likely scenario
in any
intervention
to
cover
the
uninsured.
Taken
all
together, covering
the
uninsured (exclusive
of
chronic long-term
care) would probably increase demand
for
medical care
by
less than
10
percent,
or
the
equivalent
of
roughly
two
years
of
real growth
in
health expenditure
at
historical rates. Thus, universal insurance, while adding nonnegligible costs,
would
not
wreak havoc
on the
nation's medical care economy.
The method
of
financing
any
increase
in
medical care costs, whether those
costs stem from future technological change
or
from covering
the
uninsured,
does raise
the
issue
of
deadweight loss.
If the
increase
is
financed
by
additional
taxes,
a
middle-of-the-road estimate
of
the losses might
be
around
30
percent
of
the revenue raised (Stuart, 1984; Ballard
et al.,
1985; Browning, 1987).
If
extra
revenue
is
raised
by
imposing costs
on
employers, that will cause labor market
distortions (Summers, 1989). Raising revenue through imposing additional
cost-sharing
on
patients
is
limited
by the
desire
to
avoid imposing much
additional risk, although
the
level
of
risk appears modest
for
usual levels
of
initial cost sharing (Buchanan
et al.,
1991).
All
these factors would need
to be
considered
in a
full analysis
of the
gains from expanding medical coverage,
whether
for the
uninsured
or for
anyone else.
Concluding Thoughts
I mentioned earlier that
the
conventional analysis
of
economists, emphasiz-
ing
how the tax
exemption
for
employer-provided health insurance distorts
choice toward
too
much insurance
and too
much care,
is
valid
as far as it
goes.
However, ending
the tax
subsidy would probably neither address concern
about rising medical care costs,
nor be
unambiguously
a
good policy.
It
is not
clear that insurance
or the tax
subsidy
has
much
to do
with rising
medical costs,
as
opposed
to
high ones.
The tax
subsidy affects
the
demand
for
insurance,
but the
spread
of
insurance cannot quantitatively account
for
much
of
the
increase
in
expenditure except
to the
degree
it has
induced technological
change,
and
there
is
reason
to
think consumers want
to pay for
much
of
this
change. Moreover, average marginal
tax
rates were roughly constant from
1951
to 1967 and
again from
1978 to 1985
(Barro, 1986).
15
After
1986
marginal
tax
rates fell
at the
median income
and
above
and did not
much
increase
at
half
the
median income (Bosworth
and
Burtless, 1992).
None
of
this
is to say
that reducing
the tax
subsidy
to
health insurance
by
some amount does
not
make sense—for example,
by
capping
the
amount
employers
can
contribute
to
employee health insurance tax-free—but eliminat-
ing
the tax
benefit altogether runs
the
risk
of
increasing selection problems
in
15
Robert Barro
has
generously provided
me
unpublished data
on 1984 and 1985
rates.
Medical Care Costs: How Much Welfare Loss? 19
the group health insurance market if young, healthy workers opt for compen-
sation in the form of cash.
16
This, of course, would increase the number of
uninsured.
Whatever is done about the uninsured, the possibility that medical care
costs will continue to rise faster than GNP with no further intervention seems
plausible. I have argued that consumers, at least to this point, may want to pay
for most of the increase. If so, a binding cost ceiling might well impose a welfare
loss,
by preventing medical care consumers and providers from making mutu-
ally advantageous exchanges. Such a loss would increase to the extent that
those services foregone under a cap were not the least valued ones. Physicians
might mitigate such a loss, however, by allocating services among patients in a
way that would jettison the least valued ones.
There is considerable evidence that the level of medical expenditure is too
high, and there can be little question that trying to find once-and-for-all gains is
worthwhile. Suppose, however, that some magic wand could almost costlessly
get rid of medical services whose marginal benefits were less than their marginal
cost. Or perhaps no more realistically than that magic wand, suppose that some
well-crafted reform of the health-care system manages to bring down the level
of American health care costs (as a share of GNP) to the level found in many
other countries. Even so, the argument presented here predicts that if the
march of science continues, after a few years we may wish to be back where we
are now, spending over 12 percent of GNP on medical care and worrying about
whether the increased capabilities of medicine are worth their ever increasing
opportunity costs.
I would like to thank Carl Shapiro, Joseph Stiglitz, and Timothy Taylor for comments
on an earlier version of this paper. Their comments were extraordinarily helpful, but the
usual disclaimer applies.
16
In
the Rothschild-Stiglitz model an equilibrium may not exist if there are a few high risks who
know they are high risk, but are not known to the insurer. This may well be the case in the health
insurance market, although it is difficult to show because one must know what individuals and
insurers know before an insurance contract is signed. Still it is suggestive that 5 percent of
individuals account for 50 percent of the expenditure and 10 percent for 70 percent of the
expenditure.
20 Journal of Economic Perspectives
References
Akerlof, George, "The Market for 'Lemons':
Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mecha-
nism,"
Quarterly
Journal of
Economics,
August
1970,
84:3, 488–500.
Ballard, Charles L., John B. Shoven, and
John Whalley, "General Equilibrium Compu-
tations of the Marginal Welfare Costs of Taxes
in the United States,"
American Economic
Re-
view, March 1985, 75:1, 128–38.
Barro, Robert and Chaipat Sahasakul,
"Average Marginal Tax Rates from Social Se-
curity and the Individual Income Tax," Jour-
nal of
Business,
Part 1, October 1986, 59:4,
555–66.
Baumol, William J., "Containing Medical
Costs:
Why Price Controls Won't Work," The
Public
Interest,
Fall 1988, 93,
37–53.
Bosworth, Barry and Gary Burtless, "Ef-
fects of Tax Reform on Labor Supply, Invest-
ment, and Savings," Journal of
Economic
Per-
spectives,
Winter 1992, 6:1, 3–25.
Browning, Edgar, "On the Marginal Wel-
fare Cost of Taxation,"
American Economic
Re-
view, March 1987, 77,
11–23.
Buchanan, Joan L., et al., "Simulating
Health Expenditures Under Alternative In-
surance Plans,"
Management
Science,
1991, 37,
1067–90.
Chassin, Mark, et al., "Does Inappropriate
Use Explain Geographic Variations in the Use
of Health Care Services?," Journal of
the
Ameri-
can Medical
Association,
November 13, 1987,
258, 2533–37.
Cromwell, Jerry and Janet Mitchell,
"Physician-Induced Demand for Surgery,"
Journal of Health
Economics,
December 1986,
5:4, 293–313.
De Meza, David, "Health Insurance and the
Demand for Medical Care," Journal of
Health
Economics,
March 1983, 2, 47–54.
Detsky, Allan S., et al., "Prognosis, Sur-
vival, and the Expenditure of Hospital Re-
sources for Patients in an Intensive Care Unit,"
New England Journal of
Medicine,
September
17,
1981, 305, 667–72.
Diamond, Peter, "Organizing the Health
Insurance Market,"
Econometrica,
forthcoming
1992,
60.
Dranove, David, Mark Shanley, and
William D. White, "Does the Consumer Price
Index Overstate Hospital Price Inflation?,"
Medical
Care,
August 1991, 29, 690–96.
Economic Report
of
the
President,
1991. Wash-
ington, DC: Government Printing Office,
1991.
Enthoven, Alain, Consumer Choice Health
Plan:
The Only
Practical
Solution to the Soaring
Cost
of
Medical
Care. Reading: Addison-Wesley,
1980.
Feldstein, Martin S. and Elizabeth Allison,
"Tax Subsidies of Private Health Insurance."
In The
Economics
of
Federal
Subsidy Programs,
Part 8. Papers submitted to the Subcommittee
on Priorities and Economy in Government of
the Joint Economic Committee, 93rd
Congress, 2nd Session, July 1974.
Fuchs, Victor R., "The Health Sector's
Share of the Gross National Product,"
Science,
1990,
247, 534–38.
Gerdtham, Ulf, et al., "Econometric Study
of Health Care Expenditures: A Cross-Sec-
tional Study of the OECD Countries," Journal
of
Health
Economics,
forthcoming 1992, 11.
Goddeeris, John H., "Insurance and Incen-
tives for Innovation in Medical Care," South-
ern
Economic
Journal, October 1984a, 51:2,
530–39.
Goddeeris, John H., "Medical Insurance,
Technological Change, and Welfare," Eco-
nomic
Inquiry,
January 1984b, 22:1, 56–67.
Goldsmith,
Jeff,
"Death of a Paradigm: The
Challenge of Competition,"
Health
Affairs,
Fall
1984,
3, 5–19.
Keeler, Emmett B. and John E. Rolph, "The
Demand for Episodes of Treatment in the
Health Insurance Experiment," Journal of
Health
Economics,
December 1988, 7, 337–67.
Levit, Katherine R., et al., "National Health
Expenditures, 1990," Health Care Financing
Review, Fall 1991, 13:1, 29–54.
Lubitz, James, and Ronald Prihoda, "The
Use and Cost of Medicare Services in the Last
Two Years of Life," Health Care
Financing
Re-
view, Spring 1984, 5:3,
117–31.
Luft, Harold S., Health
Maintenance
Organi-
zations.
New York: Wiley, 1981.
Marshall, John, "Moral Hazard," American
Economic Review, December 1976, 66:5,
880–90.
Manning, Willard G., et al., "Health Insur-
ance and the Demand for Medical Care: Evi-
dence from a Randomized Experiment,"
American Economic Review, June 1987, 77:3,
251–77.
McGuire, Thomas G. and Mark V. Pauly,
"Physician Response to Fee Changes with
Multiple Payers," Journal of
Health
Economics,
1991,
10, 385–410.
Newhouse, Joseph P., "Medical Care Ex-
penditure: A Cross National Survey," Journal
Joseph P. Newhouse 21
of Human Resources, Winter 1977, 12:1,
115–25.
Newhouse, Joseph P., Charles E. Phelps,
M. Susan Marquis, "On Having Your Cake
and Eating It Too: Econometric Problems in
Estimating the Demand for Health Services,"
Journal of
Econometrics,
August 1980, 13,
365–90.
Newhouse, Joseph P., et al., Are Fee-for-
Service Costs Increasing Faster than HMO
Costs?"
Medical Care, August 1985, 23,
960–66.
Parkin, David, Alistair McGuire, and Brian
Yule, "Aggregate Health Care Expenditures
and National Income: Is Health Care a Lux-
ury Good?," Journal of
Health
Economics,
June
1987,
6:2, 109–27.
Pauly, Mark V., "Taxation, Health Insur-
ance,
and Market Failure in the Medical Econ-
omy," Journal of
Economic
Literature, June
1986,
24:2, 629–75.
Reynolds, Roger, John A. Rizzo, and
Martin L. Gonzalez, "The Cost of Medical
Professional Liability," Journal of the
American
Medical
Association,
May 22–29, 1987, 257,
2776–81.
Rice, Thomas, "The Impact of Changing
Medicare Reimbursement Rates on Physician-
Induced Demand,"
Medical
Care,
August 1983,
21,
803–15.
Rothschild, Michael and Joseph Stiglitz,
"Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Mar-
kets:
An Essay on the Economics of Imperfect
Information,"
Quarterly
Journal of
Economics,
November 1976, 90:4, 630–49.
Schieber, George and Jean Pierre Poullier,
"Overview of International Comparisons of
Health Care Expenditures," Health Care
Financing Review, 1989, Annual Supplement,
1–8.
Schwartz, William B., "The Inevitable Fail-
ure of Cost Containment Strategies: Why They
Can Provide Only Temporary
Relief,"
Journal
of the
American Medical
Association,
January 9,
1987,
257, 220–24.
Schwartz, William B. and Daniel Mendel-
sohn, "Hospital Cost Containment in the
1980s—Hard Lessons Learned and Prospects
for the 1990s," New England Journal of
Medicine,
April 11, 1991, 324, 1037–42.
Scitovsky, Anne A., "Changes in the Costs
of Treatment of Selected Illnesses,
1951–1965,"
American
Economic
Review, De-
cember 1967, 57, 1182–95.
Sloss,
Elizabeth M., et al., "Effect of a Health
Maintenance Organization on Physiologic
Health: Results from a Randomized Trial,"
Annals of
Internal
Medicine,
January 1987, 106,
103–108.
Stuart, Charles, "Welfare Costs per Dollar
of Additional Tax Revenue in the United
States,"
American Economic
Review, June 1984,
74, 352–62.
Summers, Lawrence H., "Some Simple Eco-
nomics of Mandated Benefits,"
American
Eco-
nomic
Review, May 1989, 79:2, 177–83.
Thomas, Lewis, The Lives of a Cell. New
York: Bantam Books, 1975.
Waldo, Daniel R., et al., "Health Expendi-
tures by Age Group, 1977 and 1987," Health
Care Financing Review, Summer 1989, 10:4,
111–20.
Weisbrod, Burton A., "The Health Care
Quadrilemma: An Essay on Technological
Change, Insurance, Quality of Care, and Cost
Containment," Journal of
Economic
Literature,
June
1991, 29,
523–52.
This article has been cited by:
1. Aviva Aron-Dine,, Liran Einav,, Amy Finkelstein. 2013. The RAND Health Insurance Experiment,
Three Decades Later. Journal of Economic Perspectives 27:1, 197-222. [Abstract] [View PDF article]
[PDF with links]
2. Amitabh Chandra,, Jonathan Skinner. 2012. Technology Growth and Expenditure Growth in Health
Care. Journal of Economic Literature 50:3, 645-680. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
3. Abe Dunn. 2012. Drug Innovations and Welfare Measures Computed from Market Demand:
The Case of Anti-Cholesterol Drugs. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 4:3, 167-189.
[Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
4. Jeffrey R. Brown,, Amy Finkelstein. 2011. Insuring Long-Term Care in the United States. Journal of
Economic Perspectives 25:4, 119-142. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
5. Gruber Jonathan, Levy Helen. 2009. The Evolution of Medical Spending Risk. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 23:4, 25-48. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
6. Alan M. Garber,, Jonathan Skinner,. 2008. Is American Health Care Uniquely Inefficient?. Journal of
Economic Perspectives 22:4, 27-50. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
7. Sherry Glied. 2003. Health Care Costs: On the Rise Again. Journal of Economic Perspectives 17:2,
125-148. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
8. David M. Cutler. 2002. Equality, Efficiency, and Market Fundamentals: The Dynamics of
International Medical-Care Reform. Journal of Economic Literature 40:3, 881-906. [Abstract] [View
PDF article] [PDF with links]
9. Ronald Lee,, Jonathan Skinner,. 1999. Will Aging Baby Boomers Bust the Federal Budget?. Journal
of Economic Perspectives 13:1, 117-140. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
10. James M. Poterba. 1994. A Skeptic's View of Global Budget Caps. Journal of Economic Perspectives 8:3,
67-73. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
11. Joseph P. Newhouse. 1994. Symposium on Health Care Reform. Journal of Economic Perspectives 8:3,
3-11. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
12. David M. Cutler. 1994. A Guide to Health Care Reform. Journal of Economic Perspectives 8:3, 13-29.
[Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
13. Randall P. Ellis,, Thomas G. McGuire. 1993. Supply-Side and Demand-Side Cost Sharing in Health
Care. Journal of Economic Perspectives 7:4, 135-151. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
14. F. M. Scherer. 1993. Pricing, Profits, and Technological Progress in the Pharmaceutical Industry.
Journal of Economic Perspectives 7:3, 97-115. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
... The demographic mainly consists of the age composition and the health condition to measure expenditures [1][2][3], while the non-demographic uses the concept of elasticity to quantify changes in expenditures [4][5][6][7]. Most previous research suggested that neither the concepts of income elasticity nor demographic composition could provide comprehensive explanations regarding the relationship between income and health expenditures [1,3,[8][9][10][11][12]. This induced more research efforts on this topic, including those by Schultz [1], Przywara [3], Fuchs [8], Newhouse [9], Wanless [10], Dormont et al. [11], and Strittmatter and Sunde [12]. ...
... Most previous research suggested that neither the concepts of income elasticity nor demographic composition could provide comprehensive explanations regarding the relationship between income and health expenditures [1,3,[8][9][10][11][12]. This induced more research efforts on this topic, including those by Schultz [1], Przywara [3], Fuchs [8], Newhouse [9], Wanless [10], Dormont et al. [11], and Strittmatter and Sunde [12]. These studies proposed additional likely factors for elucidating more extensive links between economic growth and health expenditures. ...
... Regarding the effects of insurance, some research investigated the influence of insurance on medical care expenditure using the concept of technological changes. For example, Newhouse [9] highlighted the relevance of technological change as one of the factors driving health spending increase in various countries. Newhouse's statement was empirically verified in the USA by Fuchs [69], who found that 85% of a sample of health economics specialists argued that technical progress was the most important factor driving the rapid expansion of health expenditures from the 1960s onward. ...
Article
Full-text available
This paper examines the relationship between insurance development, population, economic growth, and health expenditures for a panel of 31 OECD countries over the period 1995-2021. A dynamic panel data analysis based on cointegration, FMOLS, DOLS, VECM, and Granger causality tests is employed to suggest for the existence of a long-run relationship among variables. The long-run results show that insurance development, national income, and population exhibit positive impacts on health expenditures. The results reveal that insurance factor has larger income effects than substitution effects on health expenditures. Regarding the short-run causal relationship between the variables , the empirical results suggest that economic growth strengthens health expenditure growth, while insurance growth reduces it. In the short-run, insurance development has a crowding-out effect since it produces larger substitution effects than income effects. The results provide political implications that governments need to concern the short-run crowding-out effect of private insurance sections on health expenditures when making fiscal policies on public health expenditures.
... Another important thing deduced from the literature is that spending on health care helps keep consumption patterns stable. 33,34 During a pandemic, people drastically reduce their caloric intake due to restrictions and fear of contracting the disease. Government spending on disease prevention measures, such as vaccines and treatments, makes people feel better about purchasing PREMIER JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS REVIEW goods and services. ...
Article
Full-text available
Purpose: This study investigates the role of fiscal health spending in post-pandemic economic recovery by employing a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model. The objective is to analyse how health expenditures influence key macroeconomic variables, such as output, labour productivity, and public debt, during and after a pandemic. Methods: The DSGE model incorporates health dynamics and simulates three scenarios: (i) no additional health spending, (ii) moderate health spending (2% of GDP), and (iii) high health spending (5% of GDP). The model evaluates the fiscal multiplier of health spending and its effect on economic recovery, output, and government debt. Findings: Results show that increased health spending significantly improves labour productivity and accelerates economic recovery. In the high-spending scenario, each dollar spent on health yields a 2.0 multiplier in output growth. However, the initial rise in government debt requires long-term fiscal adjustments to maintain sustainability. Conclusion: Health investment is crucial for mitigating the economic impacts of pandemics, and it should be integrated into post-pandemic fiscal strategies for both short-term recovery and long-term economic resilience.
... Integrating care, 8 as well as longer-term workforce planning, 9 can improve quality and meet higher demands, while making the system more sustainable. Lastly, technological advances like AI and digitalization may help mitigate potential labor shortages and enhance productivity of the health care sector, although technology is also likely to trigger additional demand for care (Newhouse 1992;Smith 2009;Willemé and Dumont 2015). ...
... Previous studies reveal that one of the reasons for increasing healthcare costs is the adoption and diffusion of new technologies and medical equipment [3][4][5][6][7][8][9][10][11][12]. Barros estimated that at least 30% of the increase in healthcare costs in the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OCED) countries is due to technological change [13]. ...
Article
Full-text available
Background Many studies have shown that using new technologies and medical equipment contributes to increasing health expenditure. Relatively less empirical studies have measured the impact of medical equipment on rising medical costs in China. Against this backdrop, we aim to examine whether the large-scale medical equipment deployment explains the increase in health expenditure. Methods Quasi-experimental research design with a difference-in-differences approach was adopted to explore whether an increase in the number of large-scale medical equipment impacts on outpatient and inpatient costs. Data were obtained from the 2011–2017 Health Financial Annals in Shaanxi province, China. Results The increase in the number of large-scale medical equipment by 1 — regardless of the initial configuration — resulted in the increase of the average cost per outpatient visit and the average cost per inpatient visit by 10.6% (p < 0.05) and 8.0% (p < 0.05), respectively. Our complex difference in differences model illustrates that the increase in the number of large-scale medical equipment by 1 — regardless of the initial configuration—results in an increase in the average diagnostic cost per outpatient visit and the average diagnostic cost per inpatient visit by 27. 3% (p < 0.01) and 25. 5% (p < 0.01), respectively. Conclusions Our findings show that the medical expenditure differs significantly with the increase in the number of large-scale medical equipment. This study mainly revealed the relationship between the growth of the number of large-scale medical equipment and medical expenditure. Our novel perspective was used to measure the phenomenon of excessive use, and to explain the social phenomenon of inaccessible and expensive medical care in China.
Chapter
This study uses machine learning-based causal analysis to analyze the relationship between government health spending and socioeconomic characteristics. The research aims to enhance public health and promote economic stability by allocating significant resources to healthcare. Conventional forecasting techniques may struggle to identify complex causal relationships within health data. Machine learning models like causal forest offer a robust analytical tool for understanding health spending dynamics. Data from developed countries between 1970 and 2021 is used, focusing on factors such as cigarette and alcohol use, net savings, average life expectancy, and rates of drug, alcohol, and suicide deaths. The results show that healthcare spending is significantly influenced by life expectancy and income level, while other factors vary based on regional and demographic variations. The study provides valuable insights for policymakers to develop data-driven, equitable health interventions that address specific needs across diverse populations.
Article
Importance Health care spending in South Korea (hereafter Korea) nearly doubled from 2010 to 2019. However, little is known about the drivers and effectiveness of these spending increases in terms of changes in disability-adjusted life-years (DALYs). Objectives To evaluate the factors contributing to changes in health care spending and DALYs and estimate the value of health care spending from 2010 to 2019 in Korea. Design, Setting, and Participants This cross-sectional study of the population of Korea used 2010 and 2019 data from the National Health Insurance Service for health care spending, and from the Global Burden of Disease 2019 for DALYs. Changes from 2010 to 2019 were decomposed into changes in several factors, including population size, aging, and per-person measures of spending or DALYs. Data analyses were performed from April 2023 to June 2024. Main Outcomes and Measures Health care spending was calculated as the total expenditure on medical and long-term care, and health gains were measured as DALYs averted. The value of health care spending was estimated as the ratio of changes in spending per person to changes in DALYs per person. Results Total health care spending in Korea increased from 55.0billionin2010to55.0 billion in 2010 to 92.0 billion in 2019. Increases in spending per person accounted for 52.9% of the increase, followed by population aging and population size (35.6% and 11.4%). Total DALYs increased from 11.4 million to 12.2 million. Population aging accounted for 269.4% of the increase, followed by population growth (64.0%). However, DALYs per person decreased (−233.4%), reflecting a lower per capita health burden given the country’s age structure. Assuming 50% and 80% of these health improvements could be attributed to health care spending, the estimated spending per DALY averted was 20678and20 678 and 12 924, respectively. The estimate was slightly larger when excluding DALYs not directly impacted by medical care ($23 687). Korea’s spending per DALY averted is at the lower range of estimates and comparable to that of other high-income countries. Conclusions and Relevance This cross-sectional study indicates that increased spending per person, which accounted for half of the total health care spending increase, was associated with improved overall health, evidenced by substantially fewer DALYs. These findings contribute to understanding and evaluating the value of health care spending in Korea.
Article
Full-text available
This paper provides a macroeconomic explanation for the United States suffering from a health disadvantage relative to other rich European countries despite spending much more on health care. We introduce health capital à la Grossman in the neoclassical growth model and assume that its rate of depreciation increases with labor supply. The steady-state share of GDP devoted to health expenditure increases with labor supply, but the relationship between the health capital stock and the number of hours worked is hump-shaped, meaning that there is a country-specific health-maximizing level. We calibrate the model to the United States and assess how much of this “American Health Puzzle” can be explained by the greater number of hours Americans work. Higher labor supply in the US accounts for 2 to 3 percentage points in extra health expenditure as a share of GDP and between 10% and one-third of the American health disadvantage.
Article
Full-text available
We estimate how cost sharing, the portion of the bill the patient pays, affects the demand for medical services. The data come from a randomized experiment. A catastrophic insurance plan reduces expenditures 31 percent relative to zero out-of-pocket price. The price elasticity is approximately -0.2. We reject the hypothesis that less favorable coverage of outpatient services increases total expenditure (for example, by deterring preventive care or inducing hospitalization).
Article
With rare exceptions the provision of actuarially fair health insurance tends to substantially increase the demand for medical care by redistributing income from the healthy to the sick. This suggests that previous studies which attribute all the extra demand for medical care to moral hazard effects may overestimate the efficiency costs of health insurance.
Article
We studied the appropriateness of use of coronary angiography, carotid endarterectomy, and upper gastrointestinal tract endoscopy and its relationship to geographic variations in the rates of use of these procedures. We selected geographic areas of high, average, and low use of these procedures and randomly sampled Medicare beneficiaries who had received one of the procedures in 1981. We determined the indications for the procedures using a detailed review of medical records and used previously developed ratings of appropriateness to assign an appropriateness score to each case. Differences among sites in levels of appropriateness were small. For example, in the high-use site for coronary angiography, 72% of the procedures were appropriate, compared with 81% in the low-use site. Coronary angiography was performed 2.3 times as frequently in the high-use site compared with the low-use site. Under the conditions of this study, we did find significant levels of inappropriate use:17% of cases for coronary angiography, 32% for carotid endarterectomy, and 17% for upper gastrointestinal tract endoscopy. We conclude that differences in appropriateness cannot explain geographic variations in the use of these procedures. (JAMA 1987;258:2533-2537)
Article
This paper relates quality and uncertainty. The existence of goods of many grades poses interesting and important problems for the theory of markets. On the one hand, the interaction of quality differences and uncertainty may explain important institutions of the labor market. On the other hand, this paper presents a struggling attempt to give structure to the statement: “Business in under-developed countries is difficult”; in particular, a structure is given for determining the economic costs of dishonesty. Additional applications of the theory include comments on the structure of money markets, on the notion of “insurability,” on the liquidity of durables, and on brand-name goods.
Article
During 1990, health expenditures as a share of gross national product rose to 12.2 percent, up from 11.6 percent in 1989. This dramatic increase is the second largest increase in the past three decades. The national health expenditure estimates presented in this article document rapidly rising health care costs and provide a context for understanding the health care financing crisis facing the Nation today. The 1990 national health expenditures incorporate the most recently available data. They differ from historical estimates presented in the preceding article. The length of time and complicated process of producing projections required use of 1989 national health expenditures—data available prior to the completion of the 1990 estimates presented here.
Article
Economic theorists traditionally banish discussions of information to footnotes. Serious consideration of costs of communication, imperfect knowledge, and the like would, it is believed, complicate without informing. This paper, which analyzes competitive markets in which the characteristics of the commodities exchanged are not fully known to at least one of the parties to the transaction, suggests that this comforting myth is false. Some of the most important conclusions of economic theory are not robust to considerations of imperfect information.
Article
Between 1947 and 1987 expenditures for health care in the United States grew 2.5 percent per annum faster than expenditures for other goods and services. The health sector's share of the gross national product rose from well under 5 percent in the late 1940s to more than 11 percent in the late 1980s. The expenditures gap has two components: health care prices rose 1.6 percent per annum more rapidly than other prices, while the quantity of health care grew 0.9 percent per annum faster than other quantities. Many factors, including wages, productivity, technology, and insurance contributed to these trends. No single explanation suffices, and no simple solution is apparent.
Article
This paper develops a general model of physician behavior with demand inducement encompassing the two benchmark cases of profit maximization and target-income behavior. It is shown that when income effects are absent, physicians maximize profits, and when income effects are very strong, physicians seek a target income. The model is used to derive own and cross-price expressions for the response of physicians to fee changes in the realistic context of more than one payer under the alternative behavior assumptions of profit maximization and target income behavior. The implications for public and private fee policy, and empirical research on physician response to fees, are discussed.
Article
With rare exceptions the provision of actuarially fair health insurance tends to substantially increase the demand for medical care by redistributing income from the healthy to the sick. This suggests that previous studies which attribute all the extra demand for medical care to moral hazard effects may overestimate the efficiency costs of health insurance.