Figure 2 - uploaded by Dorinel Bastide
Content may be subject to copyright.
Contexts in source publication
Context 1
... trades of a clearing member bank with a CCP are partitioned between proprietary trades, which are in effect hedges of the bilateral trading exposure of the bank, and back-to-back hedges of so-called cleared client trades, through which non-member clients gain access to the clearing services of a CCP: see Figure 2. The contractual cash flows from cleared and bilateral clients to a reference clearing member, dubbed the bank hereafter, are promised in successive turns from the Figure 1. ...
Context 2
... to the CCP (cash flows denoted by P and P on Figure 2), from the CCP to other clearing members, and from the latter to their own clients. As a consequence, the CCP is flat in terms of market risk, as is also each of the clearing members. ...
Context 3
... trades of a clearing member bank with a CCP are partitioned between proprietary trades, which are in effect hedges of the bilateral trading exposure of the bank, and back-to-back hedges of so-called cleared client trades, through which non-member clients gain access to the clearing services of a CCP: see Figure 2. The contractual cash flows from cleared and bilateral clients to a reference clearing member, dubbed the bank hereafter, are promised in successive turns from the bank to the CCP (cash flows denoted by P and P on Figure 2), from the CCP to other clearing members, and from the latter to their own clients. ...
Context 4
... trades of a clearing member bank with a CCP are partitioned between proprietary trades, which are in effect hedges of the bilateral trading exposure of the bank, and back-to-back hedges of so-called cleared client trades, through which non-member clients gain access to the clearing services of a CCP: see Figure 2. The contractual cash flows from cleared and bilateral clients to a reference clearing member, dubbed the bank hereafter, are promised in successive turns from the bank to the CCP (cash flows denoted by P and P on Figure 2), from the CCP to other clearing members, and from the latter to their own clients. As a consequence, the CCP is flat in terms of market risk, as is also each of the clearing members. ...
Context 5
... the general XVA guidelines of Crépey (2022, Section 1), the XVA pricing rebate required by the reference clearing member bank from its corporate clients, dubbed funds transfer price (FTP), comes in two parts: first, the expected counterparty default losses and funding expenditures of the bank, an amount that flows into the bank liabilities and which we refer to as contra-asset valuation (CA = CVA + FVA + MVA as we will see); second, a cost of capital risk premium (KVA), which instead is lossabsorbing 11 and is also used by the management of the bank as retained earnings for 9 cf. Figure 2. 10 these two conditions uniquely characterize R ⋆ (Artzner, Eisele, and Schmidt, 2020, Proposition 2.1). ...
Citations
... When a clearing member defaults, the CCP can hedge and auction or liquidate its positions. The counterparty credit risk cost of auctioning has been analyzed in terms of XVA metrics in Bastide, Crépey, Drapeau, and Tadese (2023). In this work we assess the costs of hedging or liquidating. ...
... If a clearing member d defaults, its client deals and their static hedge are ported as a package to a surviving clearing member (right panel in Figure 2). As market risk is perfectly hedged throughout, such porting has no market impact, but entails a transfer of counterparty credit risk that can be quantified by XVA costs as per Bastide et al. (2023, Section 7) (second row in Table 11). ...
... The purpose of this part is to provide a bridge from the equilibrium setup of Sections 2-5 to the XVA setup of Bastide et al. (2023), so that we are able to provide an overall FTP (6.3) quantifying the market but also credit costs of a given default resolution strategy. We leave for future research the extension of the approach of this paper to a setup where not only the market costs, but also the credit costs, would be treated endogenously as part of a global (or perhaps two-stage 16 ) equilibrium, ideally in the setup of a dynamic model. ...
For vanilla derivatives that constitute the bulk of investment banks' hedging portfolios, central clearing through central counterparties (CCPs) has become hegemonic. A key mandate of a CCP is to provide an efficient and proper clearing member default resolution procedure. When a clearing member defaults, the CCP can hedge and auction or liquidate its positions. The counterparty credit risk cost of auctioning has been analyzed in terms of XVA metrics in Bastide, Cr{é}pey, Drapeau, and Tadese (2023). In this work we assess the costs of hedging or liquidating. This is done by comparing pre- and post-default market equilibria, using a Radner equilibrium approach for portfolio allocation and price discovery in each case. We show that the Radner equilibria uniquely exist and we provide both analytical and numerical solutions for the latter in elliptically distributed markets. Using such tools, a CCP could decide rationally on which market to hedge and auction or liquidate defaulted portfolios.