Article

Observing bacteria through the lens of social evolution.

Department of Ecology and Evolutionary Biology, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ 08544, USA.
Journal of Biology 10/2008; 7(7):27. DOI: 10.1186/jbiol87
Source: PubMed

ABSTRACT Explaining the evolution of cooperative behavior is a long-standing problem for which much theory has been developed. A recent paper in BMC Biology tests central elements of this theory by manipulating a simple bacterial experimental system. This approach is useful for assessing the principles of social evolution, but we argue that more effort must be invested in the inverse problem: using social evolution theory to understand the lives of bacteria.

Full-text

Available from: Carey D Nadell, Jan 30, 2014
1 Follower
 · 
98 Views
  • [Show abstract] [Hide abstract]
    ABSTRACT: This book brings a diverse collection of sixteen papers (essays) about different aspects of the evolution of cooperation and their consequences for various groups. It consists of three parts: (I) The evolution of cooperation at the level of individuals, (II) Cooperation and repeated games, and (III) Cooperation and problems of the commons. The papers discuss such essential questions like how do groups form, how do institutions come into being, and when do moral norms and practices emergeΦ In particular, the concept of cooperation is examined at a higher level than that usually addressed by game theory, especially focusing on the formation of groups and the role of of social norms in maintaining their integrity, with positive and negative implications. Six papers form part I of the book. The first one is by S. A. Frank who discusses the biological history of evolution as an aspect of evolutionary dynamics in the context of the question: how has the tension between conflict and cooperation (between individuals and group) shaped the history of lifeΦ In the second paper, C. Taylor and M. A. Nowak discuss (basing on prisoner’s dilemma) five mechanisms for the evolution of cooperation: kin selection, direct reciprocity, indirect reciprocity, network reciprocity, and group selection. Next S. Bowles and H. Gintis analyse repeated interaction models of cooperation in social dilemmas with groups or self-regarding individuals, and show that none of them adequately explains human cooperation. E. Maskin analyses what outcomes correspond to evolutionary stable strategies in two-player symmetric repeated games when players have positive probability of making a mistake. The fifth paper (by H. De Silva and K. Sigmunt) discusses the effects of added incentives in the evolutionary game dynamics of a public good game. In the last paper of part I, B. Skyrms studies a dynamic model of network formation to analyze paths to cooperation in stag hunt games and some versions of prisoner’s dilemma. Part II of the book also contains six essays. In the first one J. C. Flack and D. C. Krakauer lay the groundwork for a hierarchical theory of the construction and evolution of moral systems. S. Levin discusses the need of extension of game theoretical concepts to address dynamic scales, including analysis of meta-games, in which evolved strategies are diffuse responses to collection of situations. Next D. S. Wilson and D. T. O’Brien analyse their research on cooperation and its consequences at a city-wide scale in Binghampton, New York, showing that integration process is highly relevant to everyday-life. D. D. P. Johnson gives the argument in his essay that belief in God may be adaptive because it helps people avoid social costs. The fifth essay (by J. E. Hare) is about moral motivation from the perspective of Kantian moral philosophy, and it looks at recent literature on the development of human sociality from within game theory. In the last essay of part II, K. A. Apiah argues that much of what is share in the organization of religions globally today is the evolutionary result of diffusion. The last part III consists of four papers, and addresses practical issues involving cooperation and problems of the commons: E. Ostrom on building trust to solve commons dilemmas; S. J. Brams and D. M. Kilgour on how democracy resolves conflict in difficult games; B. O’Neil on the duty to apologize as part of of a normative regime; and R. Sugden on team reasoning and market relationship. Here the suggestions are argued that democratic process can “stabilize cooperative outcomes” by given voters a clear choice between a cooperative outcome and the inferior consequences of falling to cooperate.
  • Source
    [Show abstract] [Hide abstract]
    ABSTRACT: The evolution of mutualism is one of the long-standing puzzles in evolutionary biology. Why would an individual contribute to the group at the expense of its own fitness? Individual bacterial cells cooperate by secreting products that are beneficial for the community, but costly to produce. It has been shown that cooperation is critical for microbial communities, most notably in biofilms, however, the degree of cooperation strongly depends on the culturing conditions. Spatial community structure provides a solution how cooperation might develop and remain stable. This perspective paper discusses recent progresses on experiments that use microbes to understand the role of spatial distribution on the stability of intraspecific cooperation from an evolutionary point of view and also highlights the effect of mutualism on spatial segregation. Recent publications in this area will be highlighted, which suggest that while mechanisms that allow assortment help to maintain cooperative traits, strong mutualism actually promotes population intermixing. Microbes provide simple and suitable systems to examine the features that define population organization and mutualism.
    Frontiers in Microbiology 11/2014; 5:649. DOI:10.3389/fmicb.2014.00649 · 3.94 Impact Factor
  • [Show abstract] [Hide abstract]
    ABSTRACT: Public goods and common-pool resources are fundamental features of biological and social systems, and pose core challenges in achieving sustainability; for such situations, the immediate interests of individuals and the societies in which they are embedded are in potential conflict, involving game-theoretic considerations whose resolution need not serve the collective good. Evolution has often confronted such dilemmas-e.g., in bacterial biofilms-in the challenges of cancer, in nitrogen fixation and chelation, in the production of antibiotics, and in collective action problems across animal groups; there is much to learn from the Darwinian resolution of these situations for how to address problems our societies face today. Addressing these problems involves understanding the emergence of cooperative agreements, from reciprocal altruism and insurance arrangements to the social norms and more formal institutions that maintain societies. At the core are the issues of how individuals and societies discount the future and the interests of others, and the degree that individual decisions are influenced by regard for others. Ultimately, as Garrett Hardin suggested, the solution to problems of the commons is in "mutual coercion, mutually agreed upon," and hence in how groups of individuals form and how they arrive at decisions that ultimately benefit all.
    Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 07/2014; DOI:10.1073/pnas.1400830111 · 9.81 Impact Factor